View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL EXPENDITURES FOR NATIONAL SECURITY
M ILITA R Y E X P E N D IT U R E S, ECONOMIC GROWTH, AND
STA B ILITY
A rthur E. Burns, professor of economics, dean, The Graduate
Council, The George Washington University
I t is difficult to fit m ilitary expenditures into the “growth and
stability” pattern currently being studied by the Joint Economic
Committee. Although military outlays are not necessarily incon­
sistent with the objective of stability and growth, they may be and at
times have been. During war and periods of tension such as the
present, the national security objective is paramount. Expenditure
levels and patterns are not likely to be greatly influenced, or influenced
at all, by considerations of growth or stability. Other instruments
of policy are usually required to assume a measure of stability.
The impact of military expenditures on growth and stability de­
pends on many thing besides the level, rate of change, duration, and
pattern of such expenditures. The source of funds is obviously im­
portant. Heavy reliance on deficit financing during World W ar II,
in contrast to the tax financing of the Korean war, produced different
results from the stabilization point of view. Differences in tax struc­
tures to finance any given level of expenditures are likely to alter the
impact of military outlays. Consumer and business expectations may
differ from one period to another. The levels of employment and
plant utilization clearly affect the impact on prices, production, and
growth. And, obviously, so do governmental policies which affect
the responses of the system. These and other variables play a part in
determining the effects of military expenditures on the growth and
stability of an economy.
Moreover, a distinction between short-run and long-run conse­
quences of m ilitary outlays, particularly on the matter of economic
growth, throws light on the problem. I t is important, also, to go
behind the military expenditures to the indirect consequences th at may
flow from them. Under some circumstances these consequences may
be highly stimulative to employment, output, and income. The “stir­
ring up” impact of World W ar I I on the depressed American economy
helps to account for the growth of the last decade. Many technical
developments and new products developed for m ilitary purposes have
a high transfer value to the civilian economy. Again this reflects it­
self in growth potential. These indirect consequences help reduce the
real cost of the military to the economy as a whole over time.
One of the striking fiscal facts of the present and recent past is the
size of m ilitary expenditures. Large-scale military outlays seem des­
tined to remain in the Federal budget for an indefinite period. This
9 7 7 3 5 — 5 7 -------3 4




509

510

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

constitutes a sharp break with past experience, and bears obviously on
the question of future economic stability and growth. A short review
of military expenditures up to World W ar I I brings out the changed
role of m ilitary expenditures in the American economy.
H

is t o r ic a l

R

e v ie w

Throughout the 19th century total Federal expenditures moved
upward, from about $10 million annually to some $400 million an­
nually at the close of the century. D uring the 1920’s they averaged
about $3 billion, and in the late 1930’s some $9 billion. The wars of
1812 and 1861-65 boosted Federal expenditures greatly; postwar out­
lays for both war-connected outlays 1 and civil purposes remained
permanently above prewar levels. Compared with prewar expendi­
ture levels postwar outlays following the W ar of 1812 approximated
150 percent; following the Civil W ar the percentage was 230. Fol­
lowing W orld W ar I the postwar expenditures were about 260 percent
of prewar.
W ars not only increase total expenditures but they seem to exert
a permanent outlay-increasing effect on the postwar periods. This
effect shows up more strongly in civil than in war-connected expendi­
tures. U p to W orld W ar I I , the war-connected component showed
a persistent decline (except in war years) as a percentage of total
Federal outlays. To be sure, war-connected outlays have exceeded
civil expenditures in all years except a few during the 1850’s and
again during the 1930’s. But the war-connected share trended down­
w ard; it was a smaller percentage of total outlays during the 1930’s
than at any other time in United States history.
The great growth in Federal expenditures, both m ilitary and civil,
throughout United States history was accompanied by a rapid rise
in population. Less than $2 per capita per y e a r2 in the first decade
of the 19th century, they rose to $10 in the 1890’s, and to $25 in the
1920’s. Depression spending policies brought a further threefold
increase by the end of the 1930’s. War-connected expenditures per
capita per year accounted for only one-third of the per capita Fed­
eral expenditures just before World W ar II, in contrast to four-fifths
in the first decade of the 19th century.
W artime per capita expenditure changes are of course substantial.
The percentage increase over prewar per capita outlays shows a high
degree of uniformity. During the Civil W ar, W orld W ar I, and
World W ar I I, the percentage increases are 733, 776, and 630. The
high level of depression spending by the Federal Government during
the second half of the 1930’s moderated the percentage increase in
per capita outlays in W orld W ar II.
C

osts

P

er

S e r v ic e m a n

The long-term changes in m ilitary expenditures per serviceman
are of particular importance for the problem at hand. Estimates
prepared by M. Slade Kendrick (in 1926 prices) place the cost per
1 Costs of the military services, veterans, and interest on the public debt. See M. Slade
Kendrick, A Century and a Half of Federal Expenditures, Occasional Paper No. 48, National
Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1955.
1 In 1926 prices, as shown in Kendrick, op. cit.



511

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

serviceman per year at somewhat less than $1,000 during the 1820’s.
F ifty years later they had increased on the average only 50 percent.
M ilitary technology had changed, but not in a revolutionary manner.
In the years preceding W orld W ar I the annual average approxi­
mated $2,400; the increase came largely from changes in naval ship
construction. In nearly a century before World W ar I the average
annual outlay per serviceman had risen somewhat less than 300
percent.
United States participation in World W ar I was of such short
duration that cost figures are somewhat unreal. They averaged
$3,300 per serviceman in 1918 and $6,000 2 years later. Between
1922 and 1938 they ranged from $2,300 to $4,000 per year, averaging
about half again as high as pre-World W ar I. W orld W ar I I costs
averaged nearly $9,000 per serviceman for the years 1941-45. In
contrast the 1861-65 costs averaged somewhat under $1,000 per year.
Between World W ar I I and the Korean war costs per man came to
$5,000 annually, about twice the cost per man of 20 years earlier.
Korea cost more per man per year than did World W ar II.
The enormous and rapid changes in m ilitary technology explain a
large measure of the increased cost per serviceman per year during
the present century. Compared with the last 2 or 3 decades, the 19th
century was technologically quiescent in the m ilitary sphere. Not
only have costs per man increased but the present era keeps a larger
percentage of men of m ilitary age under arms. The high levels of
military outlays and their dominating position in the Federal budget
reflects these facts.
M

il it a r y

E

x p e n d it u r e s a n d

N

a t io n a l

O

u tput

U ntil recently m ilitary expenditures as a percentage of gross na­
tional output have always been of relatively small importance. The
Kuznets estimates beginning with 1869 range from 1.3 percent for
that year down to 0.4 percent for most of the 1880’s and 1890’s.
From 1900 until World W ar I the average is 0.8 percent. This went
up to 16 percent in 1918 but by 1923 the percentage was back to 0.8,
the prewar average. From 1931 to 1939 m ilitary outlays averaged 1.3
percent of the depressed gross national product of those years.
World W ar I I changed matters abruptly. By 1943 some 40 per­
cent of gross national product went into the military. The extensive
demobilization after that war brought military outlays down to 5
percent in 1948-49. W ith Korea the percentage rose to 14; since
then military outlays have averaged 9 to 10 percent of gross national
product.
The recent period is thus unique. The complexity and scale of
military operations during 1941-45 caused an unprecedented com­
mitment of output to war purposes. Since then rapid changes in
military technology, the maintenance of large armed forces, and the
extensive deployment of these forces contribute to the present large
commitment of resources to military purposes.
The attached table shows for 5-year intervals the volume of Fed­
eral outlays and the war-connected outlays since the beginning of
the present century. From 1936-40 to 1941-45, total expenditures
rose $56 billion per year, of which $50 billion is military. While civil
expenditures in the aggregate have risen from pre-World W ar I I



512

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

to the present, there has been little or no real per capita growth in
such expenditures over this period of time.
Thus, the budget problem is mainly caused by W orld W ar I I ,
Korea, and the world tensions summed up as the cold war. To the
extent that growth and stability are affected by Federal expenditures,
it is the m ilitary component of such expenditures th a t dominates the
picture.
M

il it a r y

E

x p e n d it u r e s ,

G

row th, and

S t a b il it y

I t was pointed out above that one of the unique features of the
present era in American history is the tremendous amounts spent
since 1940 on the military. In terms of the m ilitary absorption of
gross national product, the present peacetime rate or percentage is 8
to 10 times that of the 1930’s, about 12 times th a t of the 1920’s, and
more than 20 times th at of the 1880’s, and 1890’s.
The resources thus committed to the support of the m ilitary are not
available for other purposes, i. e., to achieve increased productive
capacity and a growth m consumption levels. A comparison of re­
cent rates of gross national product absorption by the m ilitary with
the rates of earlier periods raises some searching and disturbing ques­
tions about the prospects of long-term growth m productive capacity
and consumption levels. These questions frequently bring forth
gloomy answers.
Federal expenditures
[Millions]

Years

1901-5
........................................................................................
1906-10
......................................................................................
........................ .............................................................
1911-15
1916-20............................. .............................................................
1921-25............................. ................................................................
192&-30 .......................................................................................
1931-35 . ........................ ...............................................................
1936-40 ........................... ..............................................................
1941-45
........................................................................................
1946-50 ................................ .................................................... ......
1951-55 .........................................................................................

.
Average
annual
Federal
expend­
itures
$536
639
720
8,065
3,579
3,183
5, 215
8,192
64,038
42,335
63,216

Average
annual
war-con­
nected
expend­
itures
$388
456
520
4,657
2,186
1,707
1,792
2,661
52,415
30,900
47,100

Percent
war-con­
nected

72
71
73
58
61
54
34
32
82
71
74

Source: Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1956, p. 355.

While the comparison of rates of absorption seems to jnstify deep
concern, several points need consideration as possible offsetting in­
fluences.
1. Resources diverted ,to m ilitary support may not be entirely
diverted from civilian alternatives. For any given increment of out­
put absorbed by the military, the civilian alternatives sacrificed in the
time period might range from zero to the full amount. Some or all
of the resources diverted to the military m ight have remained unemloyed but for the expansion of m ilitary expenditures. I f there is
sacrifice in the time period, and if the loss is in investment, additional
sacrifices will accrue beyond the time period.
2. The value of the output absorbed by any given increase in mili­
tary expenditures does not necessarily measure the value of output
diverted from the civilian sector. As noted above, some of the diverted



513

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

resources might have remained unemployed. But the point holds
even where resources diverted to the military are diverted from the
civilian sector. F or example, when resources shift from low-valued
products—e. g., agriculture—to high-valued products—e. g., radar
equipment for the m ilitary—increment of gross national product
absorbed by the military exceeds in value the output denied to the
civilian sector. Structural shifts in output are a characteristic of
the development of the economy over tim e; they have special signifi­
cance for the particular problem at hand.
3. Comparison of rates of absorption of gross national product by
the m ilitary over long periods of time may be deceptive. Seventy
years ago the military absorbed 0.5 percent of gross national product;
today the rate is 20 times greater. However, the stimulative effects
per dollar spent have probably changed. I t was noted above that
military technology changed slowly during most of the 19th century
when compared with the last several decades. While it produced
something of transfer value to the civilian sector in the metallurgical
field, the contribution to collateral civilian industry appears small
compared to recent contributions. Research and development for
the military during the last two decades have created new industries,
new products, transformed older industries, and introduced innumer­
able changes in methods. The twentyfold increase in the rate of
absorption of gross national product by the m ilitary now, compared
with the 1880’s, does not mean a twentyfold increase in the military
burden to the economy.
The indirect consequences of net value to the civilian economy are
not limited to such fields as atomic energy, the electronics industry,
synthetics, food processing, and the like. Asian flu vaccine is a product
of Army research which might spare the loss of a substantial amount
of gross national product.
The first two points may be brought out by reference to the increases
in military outlays and gross national product caused by the Korean
war. Here the short-run implications of an increase in military out­
lays are discussed.
T

he

M

il it a r y

P

rogram ,

1950-53

The Korean war broke out in mid-1950 at a time when the economy
was recovering from the relatively mild recession of 1949. The fight­
ing stopped in mid-1953. M ilitary expenditures rose sharply from
1950 to 1953, and wth them production, employment, and income.
The tabulation below shows production changes, by m ilitary and
civilian uses, in 1952 prices, at annual rates for the first 6 months of
1950 and 1953.
[In billions]
Gross national product
Total

1st half 1960........................................ ............. .............................
1st half 1963...................... ......................................................... .




For national
security

For civilian
use

$302
367

$19
52

$283
315

+65

+33

+32

514

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

A t the first-half 1953 rate, the m ilitary absorbed some 14 percent of
gross national product compared with 6 percent in 1950. The incre­
ment to total output over this period was quite evenly shared by the
military and civilian sectors.
Along with the rise in output went an increase in employment, from
59 million to 62 million, and hours worked per week in nonagricultural employment increased from under 40 to 41. Combining the in­
crease in people at work and the increase in the workweek suggests
an 8- to 10-percent rise in total time worked. F o r this added time
worked the economy obtained a 21-percent growth in gross national
product. The civilian sector by itself increased 11 percent.
Gross national product per person employed rose from $5,100 in
1950 to $5,900 in 1958, or 16 precent. The disparity in changes in out­
put and in hours worked may be explained, in part, by the shifts in
employment, from lower value products to higher value products.
Farm employment declined from 1950 to 1953, while industrial em­
ployment rose some 2 million, virtually all in the durable-goods in ­
dustries. Of the latter, spectacular increases occurred in the aircraft,
ordnance, and other war-related industries characterized by high­
valued end products.
Over this period, personal income increased; approximately half
this increment was taken in higher Federal taxes, which increased $32
billion. A fter all additional taxes, the public at large had $30 billion
more income in early 1953 than in early 1950.
Taxing, spending, and savings patterns in this period are of inter­
est. The immediate increase m Federal taxation brought in more
cash receipts than cash expenditures for the 3-year period. The ag­
gregate cash surplus was in excess of $2 billion. This is the first siz­
able war the United States financed fully from taxation.
W ith the outbreak of war, consumers and business engaged heavily
in forward buying before m ilitary procurement began making its*
added demands on the economy. The civilian spurt in forward buy­
ing came to an end early in 1951. The consumption ratio dropped as
consumer fears of shortages abated. Meanwhile, the forward buying
produced a quick 10-percent increase in price indexes. By the second
quarter of 1951, the inflationary pressure eased; in fact, many price
lines declined. Personal savings increased, and consumer expendi­
tures gradually expanded with production as the war progressed.
Civilian and m ilitary buying coordinated themselves well during this
period, bringing about a high degree of stability for a war period.
By the end of the war, in 1953, consumer savings were at a poSt­
World W ar I I high. P er capita consumption was at its highest level.
In real terms, residential housing had declined, but all other construc­
tion and business investment in durable equipment increased. Credit
restraints curbed consumer durable-goods purchases to some extent,
and allocations restrained the growth of business investment some­
what.
T

he

Q

u e s t io n

or R

eal

C o st

The facts outlined above show the main features of the m ilitary
impact on the national economy during Korea. T hat impact was
clearly stimulative. A big m ilitary effort was supported and, at the
same time, the civilian economy advanced to new high ground in all
important respects.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

515

In terms of the earlier discussion, to what extent did this increased
military program involve a diversion from the civilian economy, and,
therefore, a real cost or burden ?
Although no conclusive answer is possible, the facts do not point to
a major diversion from the civilian economy in the buildup of the mil­
itary program. The civilian gross national product expanded. But
the real question is: Would the civilian sector have had more than
the $32 billion increase it in fact had in 1953 over 1950 in the absence
of the Korean conflict ? T hat is, would 1953’s gross national product
have exceeded $334 billion without the stimulus of rearmament?
Some indication might be had from the percentage changes in pro­
duction over the period 1946-56. The average annual rate of increase
in civilian gross national product over this 10-year period is 3.5 per­
cent. In only 1949 and 1954—both moderate recession years—did
civilian gross national product decline. From the period immediately
before the outbreak in Korea, through the end of that war, civilian
gross national product increased an average of 3.5 percent. In 1951 it
was above, and in 1952 below the tre n d : in 1953 it was back on the
3.5-percent trend line. Again, from 1953 to the high levels of 1956,
civilian gross national product increased at an average annual rate of
3.5 percent—down in 1954, but up in 1955 and 1956.
The figures suggest th at the expansion in the military program be­
ginning in 1950 was superimposed on the growth curve (in real terms)
of 3.5 percent per annum. So far as the civilian sector is concerned,
the plus and minus figures during the 3 years of the Korean war
just about cancel out, give or take a few billion dollars of output.
I t can always be argued, of course, that civilian gross national prod­
uct could have increased at a rate in excess of 3.5 percent over the years
of the Korean war. But there is no compelling reason to believe that
gross national product would have exceeded by much the 1953 total
(give or take a few billion). There was no great backlog of consumer
demand or of private investment (or both) in 1950 to support any
unusual spurt in output. The mild recession of 1949 indicated that
World W ar I I backlogs were largely worked off, and the increase in
voluntary savings after 1950 suggests th at consumers were buying all
they wanted. By any reasonable standard, a $334 billion gross na­
tional product and 62 million employment would have represented a
very prosperous state of affairs in 1953.
The main point is that the actual 1953 level of gross national prod­
uct was high when related to the trend from 1946 to 1956. The bulge
can be largely explained by the special shift in production and em­
ployment due to war orders. Much of this bulge ($33 billion in 1953
over 1950), and perhaps most of it, does not seem to have entailed a
shift from the civilian sector of the economy. From the facts avail­
able, it seems that the added gross national product absorbed by the
increased defense program from 1950 to 1953 was an increment to
output that might not riave been produced in the absence of the mili­
tary buildup.
I t is true, of course, th at consumers would probably have spent
even more than they did in 1952 and 1953 had taxes not increased.
But the data seem to suggest that the increment to consumer income
taken by the increase in taxation is that portion of income th at con­
sumers would not have had in the absence of the military buildup. In



516

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

a financial sense, the program was self-financing; the increased in­
come taxed away was created in the production of gross national
product that would not have been produced but for the program.
A general statement of the problem may be made as follows: Should
the stimulus provided by an expanded military program lead to an
increase in the total output sufficient (a) to satisfy the normal ex­
pectations of the public and (b) to provide for expanded m ilitary
requirements, then the program in real terms is self-financed, in the
sense described above. In monetary terms, should the program create
an excess of money income over normal expectations, and added taxes
take only this excess, then no income anticipated is lost and no real
cost incurred. The 1950-53 experience seems to have approximated
this condition.
The Korean war has been used as an illustration. A fuller use of
resources was probably achieved during this period in consequence of
m ilitary procurement. And production shifted toward higher value
end products. Thus, the increment to gross national product ab­
sorbed by the m ilitary entailed no corresponding loss to the civilian
economy; on the contrary, there appeared to be, at most, a relatively
small diversion from the civilian economy.
This argument is limited to a particular short-run period. Under
other circumstances, such as those prevailing from 1955 to the present,
a comparable expansion of m ilitary expenditures would probably have
caused a considerable diversion from the civilian economy.
S ome L

ong-R u n

C o n s id e r a t io n s

Over a long period of time, the problem is more complex. A pro­
longed commitment of resources at the present rate to military p u r­
poses cannot avoid the problem of diversion. I f m ilitary outlays
bring about a somewhat fuller and more stable level of output than
would otherwise occur, this would be a partial offset. And the stimu­
lus of research and development having transfer value would consti­
tute another offset. More needs to be known about these possible
effects of a sustained and dynamic military program.
On the long-run problem, some interesting estimates have been pre­
pared by Dr. John W. Kendrick, as p a rt of a forthcoming publication
of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Dr. Kendrick broke
down gross national product totals (measured in 1929 dollars) into
(1) that portion required for the maintenance of population and cap­
ital stock, and (2) the margin over maintenance. The m argin over
maintenance, in turn, is allocated to (1) national security, (2) pro­
vision for the growth in population (both consumer goods and cap­
ital), and (3) the margin for economic growth, both consumption and
capital.
The accompanying table shows the percentage distribution of gross
national product, by time periods, for each of these uses.
F or present purposes, columns 3 and 5 are most im portant—and
disturbing. The margin over maintenance of population is, in the
absence of major war and major depression, relatively inflexible. E x ­
cluding W orld W ar I I and the great depression, it has ranged within
16.6 and 14.6 percent of gross national product. As the nationalsecurity component of this margin increases, the growth component
is squeezed, with the major squeeze applied to capital growth.



517

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
Percentage of gross national product for —
1

2

Heal gross
national
product

1889-98............ .
1899-1908_______
1909-18.......... ........
1919-28_________
1929-36..................
1937-47..................
1948-53............— .

100
100
100
100
100
100
100

3

4

5

Maintenance
Provision for
Margin for economic
of population Maintenance growth of
progress
population
(including
of national
(consumer
consumer
security
and capital
and capital) Consumption
Capital
goods)
83.1
83.5
85.1
85.4
97.7
76.9
83.4

0.5
.8
3.3
1.7
.9
17.5
9.2

6.7
6.9
6.0
5.2
3.5
3.1
4.5

1.2
1.6
1.3
2.0
.1
2.2
.9

8.5
7.2
4.3
5.7
-2 .2
.3
2.0

The estimates bring out the possible impact of war and depression
on long-term growth. But there is a difference: W ar helps to finance
its own extravagances, but prolonged depression never does. Even
though sudden spurts in m ilitary expenditures may involve some, and
perhaps a large, element of self-financing (in both real and monetary
term s), sizable and prolonged m ilitary expenditures probably do so to
a lesser extent, and conceivably might not at all. In the long run the
growth outcome may depend upon the extent to which military re­
search and development adds back to gross national product a stimulus
that offsets in part the real cost of the military. Over a long enough
period there might be a complete offset.
In any event, the impact of military expenditures on both growth
and stability involves far more than consideration of the expenditures
themselves. Revenue sources are vital. Faced with the long-run
prospects of large-scale military outlays, revenue sources based on
nongrowth considerations—emergency war needs, social-reform pol­
icies, and simple ease of collection—need constant reexamination. Eco­
nomic growth may be regarded as an economic, political, and military
necessity. To the extent that a large-scale military establishment also
continues as a necessity, growth needs may require that it be increas­
ingly a charge against consumption.