View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A M ERICA ’S FO R EIG N A ID PROGRAM
Robert E. Baldwin, professor of economics, University of California,
Los Angeles
I

n t r o d u c t io n

An evaluation of foreign aid can usefully begin with an emphasis
upon three significant political and economic developments in the
postwar world. First, the security of the United States has been
threatened seriously since World W ar I I by the rise of a powerful
group of Communist nations that are hostile to capitalistic countries
such as our own. Moreover, it is increasingly apparent that the re­
sultant political struggle between the western capitalistic countries
and this Communist bloc may continue for many years.
A t the same time the United States was trying to turn back the
challenge of international communism, it was confronted with another
fundamental change in international relations. This is the attain­
ment of political independence by a number of nations th at formerly
were alined closely to certain western countries. A major way in
which these nations exercise their newly gained independence is by
attempting to raise their living standards. In this effort, they are also
joined by other relatively poor countries that previously had attained
a large measure of political autonomy. The conviction that their
long-endured poverty can be eliminated deeply influences the actions
of the political leaders of these regions. However, in their attempts
to carry out the objective of accelerated economic growth, many of
these nations are not as yet firmly committed to the methods either
of democratic capitalism or of totalitarian socialism. Consequently,
the programs and policies followed by these countries are necessarily
of vital interest to both the West and the Communist group.
A third point to keep in mind while analyzing the American foreign
aid program is th at international financial difficulties have plagued
many of the western capitalistic countries since the end of the war.
Although much progress has been made toward solving this problem,
the rebuilding of a stable, relatively free pattern of international
trade with these nations is still not completed.
W ithin the framework of these postwar developments, two major
sets of questions must be answered in considering the foreign aid
policy of the United States. They a re : (1) Is the current volume and
regional distribution of foreign aid by this country adequate; and
(2) Is the economic and financial form of this aid satisfactory.
T

he

V

olum e

and

R

e g io n a l

D

is t r ib u t io n

of

F

o r e ig n

A

id

The adequacy of the magnitude of America’s foreign aid program
is a question th a t must be decided in terms of the relative importance
of our various competing national policy objectives and the limited



595

596

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

volume of resource available to achieve these goals. In particular, it
must always be remembered that satisfactory international political
and economic relations are only one of many objectives of national
policy. Furthermore, expenditures by the Federal Government are
only one method of attempting to achieve this specific goal.
W ithin recent years, the threat of Communist aggression caused
this country to allocate most of its foreign aid for the purpose of pro­
viding direct m ilitary assistance to our close allies. To-meet the
immediate danger of war there can be lititle question about the wisdom
of this decision. Such foreign assistance clearly can indirectly
strengthen our military capabilities more than would be the case if
these funds were employed directly for increasing the potential of our
own m ilitary services. We must, however, make certain th at these
funds are received by nations who would make effective fighting
partners in case of a general conflagration.
The appropriate volume of direct military aid would seem to de­
pend upon the maintenance of a balance of m ilitary power between
the free and Communist worlds. Shifts in foreign policy—appar­
ent or real—on the part of the Communist nations should not be al­
lowed to cloud their basic hostility to the West. The only adequate
guide for defense expenditures in the West is an appraisal of the mili­
tary strength of the potential adversary. An appraisal of this type
is a difficult task, but the risks involved are so great th at we must
be sure not to underestimate the military power of the Communist bloc.
Although a policy of m ilitary strength may prevent a general con­
flict and also retard Communist expansion by means of small-scale
wars, it does not adequately meet the problem of thw arting the spread
of communism by peaceful methods. One means of partially dealing
with this m atter is by attempting to increase the economic power of
those nations in which there are democratic leanings but in which
communism is still a real threat. The more fully these countries can
satisfy the economic desires of their people through democratic meth­
ods, the more secure will be the international position of the United
States. However, to view the problem of raising the level of eco­
nomic well-being throughout the free world solely in terms of the
struggle between the West and the Communist bloc is to adopt a much
too narrow view of our foreign policy problems. In many countries
communism is not an immediate danger,' yet there are beginnings of
a profound revolution in traditional social, political, and economic
ways of life. To minimize the significance of this upheaval for the
United States would be to take a dangerously shortsighted view of
our interests. Our interests clearly are to help these nations achieve
their political, economic, and social goals within the framework of a
stable, democratic, and capitalistic system. F or with; this type of
government the chances of gaining the type of world peace we seek
are greatest.
In addition to shifts th at are occurring in the pooer parts of the
free world, our foreign policy must also take into account the prob­
lems faced by some of the older capitalistic nations. In these na­
tions our interests are less social or political and more economic.
We are especially concerned with their economic ills that appear in
the form of periodic balance of payments difficulties. Such difficul­
ties tend to lead to the imposition of additional quantitative restric­



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

597

tions on trade by these countries and sometimes to curtailment of the
volume of resources devoted to military preparedness in order to cope
better with their international economic problems. Since these poli­
cies are not in the interests of the United States, the question of possible
economic aid to these countries is also relevant.
But is economic aid a sufficiently effective means of implementing
our foreign policy of combating communism and of promoting a
world in which we can prosper in peace? The experience of economic
aid under the Marshall plan must certainly be judged as encouraging.
By 1950 most of industrial Europe regained its prewar level of pro­
duction and the great dollar shortage of the immediate postwar years
was significantly reduced. Financial crises have occurred since then
but the fear that an economically weak Europe would be an easy prey
to communism has long since passed. As a result, economic aid to
industrial Europe was greatly reduced. There still remains, how­
ever, the need to develop a stronger international organization to help
these nations—as well as the rest of the world—to meet short-run
balance of payments strains.
Although the Marshall plan was highly successful, one must be
cautious about generalizing from this experience in discussing methods
of furthering our interests in the poorer parts of the free world. The
problem in postwar Europe was to rebuild a war-disrupted industrial
structure. These countries already possessed the economic and social
requisites for successful economic growth. Moreover, their govern­
ments were of the type with which the United States could maintain
harmonious relations. The main task for us was to help restore their
economic strength as quickly as possible in order to turn back the
threat of Communist aggression and to renew mutually profitable
economic relations.
The situation in the undeveloped areas is quite different. In these
regions it is not mainly a matter of restoring economic strength within
a framework of established social, political, and economic institutions
but of creating an environment in which sustained and faster develop­
ment can occur. To accomplish this goal significant changes in the
social, economic, and political milieu of these nations are required.
Many of these countries have long been caught in a vicious circle of
poverty. Being poor they do not possess the means to save nor the
purchasing power to encourage a large volume of investment in manu­
facturing. In addition, the efficiency of the people as productive
agents is low, and their natural resources are poorly utilized. To
break out of the circle of poverty necessitates more than the provision
of capital funds; it also requires a modification in their cultural pat­
terns that will be conducive to growth.
When the problem of accelerating development in the poor countries
is viewed in this manner, arguments for economic aid claiming that
the recipient nations will become friendlier toward the United States
or that they will turn away from communism as their living standards
rise appear rather superficial. Establishing a creditor-debtor relation­
ship or a donor-donee one certainly does not breed friendship in any
deep sense. Nor is democratic capitalism necessarily correlated with
a rising standard of living. Indeed one must be careful about assum­
ing that economic aid will make a significant contribution toward
permanently raising living standards in the poor regions. A case for



598

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

general foreign aid based upon the development of sources of raw
material supplies and of markets for our manufactures also should
not be pushed too strongly. I t is not at all obvious that these objectives
are best satisfied by a large-scale Government-sponsored aid program.
Does it follow that the oenefits to the United States of an economic
aid program to the poor countries are so problematical that such aid
is not justified? I think not. I t should be recognized, first, th at
fundamental economic, social, and political changes are already occur­
ring in these regions. W hether we step in and assist these nations
develop is not going to affect the underlying forces making for change.
We may be able to influence the forms of expression of these forces
but not their basic nature. In short, the United States is confronted
with changing political, economic, and social forces in these countries
to which we must adapt.
Although most poor countries in the non-Communist world are not
undertaking devleopment programs within the framework of minimal
direct government sponsorship that existed in such nations as Great
Britain and the United States during the 19th century, they are fol­
lowing policies closer to capitalism than to the type of detailed plan­
ning practiced by a completely socialistic state. Their poverty and
backwardness may necessitate more state activity than under American
capitalism, but these characteristics at the same time tend to discourage
the use of all-embracive planning techniques. F o r the very lack of
administrative and entrepreneurial skill makes the communistic tech­
nique of deliberate industrialization highly risky.
Thus, the United States faces the problem of adapting to deep-seated
revolutionary forces that in most of the poor nations at the present
time are being channeled into forms of political and economic activity
that are reasonably acceptable in terms of our foreign policy interests.
Our chances of living in a peaceful and prosperous world would seem
to be greater if the development programs of these regions are success­
ful than if they are not. I f they succeed the chances of strengthening
democracy and free enterprise in the poor countries would seem to be
increased. Failure in their development efforts will strengthen the
positions of those advocating complete planning and the kind of un­
democratic political methods usually associated with this policy. How­
ever, even with successful development programs in the poor countries,
it should be stressed that what we should seek is a strengthening of
political independence, democratic forces, and capitalistic traditions
m these countries rather than the creation of carbon copies of American
political or economic institutions and of governments that are pre­
pared to follow blindly our political leadership.
Coupled with the challenge of adapting to the new forces in the
poor countries as well as the tendency of these nations presently to
follow political and economic methods that satisfy our foreign policy
objectives is the belief by most investigators of the development prob­
lem in poor areas that well-conceived economic measures on the part
of the rich countries can significantly help the underdeveloped nations.
Many of these countries do not seem to be too fa r away from a thresh­
old of sustained growth. Efforts by the poor regions alone, however,
may not be sufficient to break out of the vicious circle or at least may
delay the breakthrough for a long time. A certain amount of help
from the rich nations may provide the push needed to reach a self


ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

599

generating growth position. I t is emphasized, however, that merely
making large sums available under very loose controls or adopting
other measures to encourage foreign investment is by no means
sufficient to guarantee success. This is a very different case from that
of postwar Europe where the problem of utilizing available funds
productively was not so serious. There is a much greater possibility in
the poor countries that economic aid may not be used in the most pro­
ductive manner. The reason for this rests on the very characteristics
that make these countries poor. As a result, if economic aid is to be
successful in raising standards of living, it must be channeled through
organizations which carefully appraise the development plans and
potentials of these countries. The program should be designed to
further the establishment of conditions of self-sustained growth rather
than to raise living standards by relief benefits. This implies the
application of rather rigid economic criteria in determining the amount
of aid a particular country might profitably utilize.
I f it is concluded that economic aid to the poor countries is a worth­
while policy for the United States to pursue, then what should be
the volume of this aid? One way to approach this question is to
ask what are the needs of the poor countries in order to raise per
capita income a certain percentage. A United Nations study in 1949
concludes that an annual capital import of well over $10 billion is
required to raise per capita income 2 percent per year in the poor
countries as a whole. Since the current flow of foreign investment
funds into the poor countries is probably about $2 billion, the volume
of additional aid necessary to accomplish this objective would be very
substantial. A more recent study by Professors Millikan and Rostow,
however, presents a much lower figure. These authors estimate the
additional volume of capital assistance that the poor countries can
absorb productively to be between $2.5 billion and $3.5 billion annually
for the next 5 years. They maintain that this volume of assistance
together with existing sources of investment funds should produce
“rates of growth of per capita income of at least 1 or 2 percent per
year.” 1
Although estimates of this sort necessarily are very rough, the
Millikan-Eostow figure seems more reliable than the United Nations’
figure. I t is computed in a less mechanistic manner and takes into
account the important concept of capital-absorptive capacity. I t can­
not be stressed too strongly that the problem of development is much
more than one of capital accumulation. Labor skills must be im­
proved, enterepreneurship developed, natural resources more fully
utilized, market imperfections reduced, attitudes changed, etc. W ith­
out these development requirements the productivity of capital de­
creases very rapidly. However, even given strenuous efforts to meet
these needs, the time involved in fulfilling them implies that the
ability of the poor countries to absorb capital productively within the
next 5 years is strictly limited.
Another method of gaining a better perspective on the volume of
capital assistance to poor countries that might be appropriate on the
p art of the rich nations is to consider past experience in this area.
1 Max F. M illikan and W. W. Rostow, A Proposal, Key to an Effective Foreign Policy,
Harper & Bros., New York, 1957, p. 100.




600

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

The conclusion from this approach is that there has been a sharp
decline, especially since W orld W ar I, in the relative significance of
international investment. During the 50 years prior to World W ar I
B ritain was easily the most important international investor. By 1913
about 40 percent of total long-term foreign investments were British
investments. France and Germany were the second and third largest
foreign investors, respectively. B ritain’s overseas investments aver­
aged 4 percent of her national income during the entire period 1870­
1913 and equaled 7 percent of her national income in the years between
1905 and 1913. One-quarter of British capital was exported to
regions that today are considered to be underdeveloped.
Private long-term foreign investment by the United States in the
record year of 1956 was $3.4 billion, or about 1 percent of national
income. A 4-percent level for this country in 1956 would have raised
this figure to $13.7 billion. I f this volume of private investment were
undertaken by the United States today and one-quarter of it was made
in the poor countries, most of the additional 'capital needs estimated
by Millikan and Rostow for the poor regions could be met from private
American sources alone.
A fter World W ar I, the international investment position of the
rich nations changed drastically. During the war B ritain liquidated
nearly one-quarter of her overseas investments, and throughout the
1920’s her annual net capital exports averaged only about a third of
the amount just before the war. France and Germany suffered even
greater relative foreign investment loses than the United Kingdom.
The United States, on the other hand, emerged from the war as a
creditor nation and became the chief source of international loans dur­
ing the 1920’s. American private exports of long-term capital aver­
aged over 1 percent of national income during this period. About
30 percent of portfolio investments and 50 percent of direct invest­
ments by this country between 1920 and 1931 were directed toward the
underdeveloped areas. Most of this investment was undertaken in
Latin America.
In the 1930’s long-term foreign investment again dropped sharply.
Political instability, the effects of the world-wide depression, and
governmental controls caused this period to become one of negligible
long-term private foreign investment. The United States in par­
ticular ceased to continue its lending role of the 1920’s. Total Amer­
ican foreign investments actually fell from $17 billion in 1930 to $11
billion in 1939. A fter W orld W ar I I private foreign investment by
this country increased again but the average volume in constant prices
between 1946 and 1952 was only one-half of the 1919-29 average.
The flow of private funds since 1953, however, is somewhat more en­
couraging. But British capital exports in real terms from 1953 to
1956 averaged only 7.5 percent of her capital exports in 1913.
As noted, private long-term investment by the United States in
1956 was $3.4 billion. Canada and Western Europe absorbed about
60 percent of this sum, while Latin America received 25 percent of
the investment funds. The remaining 15 percent was divided between
the poor nations of Africa and Asia, and such countries as Australia,
New Zealand, and Japan. Direct private investment in 1956 was $2.8
billion. About 44 percent of this type of investment was made in the
underdeveloped countries (mainly in Latin America).



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

601

In addition to private investment the United States, of course, has
provided substantial governmental assistance to other countries since
the end of the war. Between July 1, 1955, and June 30, 1956, for
example, Government expenditures for foreign assistance were $5 bil­
lion. The underdeveloped countries (mainly 7 defense support coun­
tries) received $1.5 billion of this aid. I f foreign assistance by the
Government is added to private long-term foreign investment in 1956,
the ratio of these two items to national income is 21/2 percent.
A consideration of the current needs of the poor countries and of the
past experience of private foreign investment by the rich countries
in these areas leads to the conclusion that, if anything like the pre­
World W ar I international investment pattern could be restored, the
capital problems of the poor countries would be solved. Fortunate­
ly, the United States at least does seem to be approaching again her
role in the 1920’s of a major source of capital funds. But this will
still leave many of the capital needs of the poor nations unfulfilled.
Therefore, in view of the opportunities for strengthening our national
security, for reducing our long-run defense expenditures, and for
opening-up both new raw material sources and markets for manu­
factured products that are linked with an increased flow of capital
funds to the underdeveloped parts of the world, it would seem to be
clearly in our national interests to attempt to increase the stream of
our capital exports.
F

orms of

C a p it a l A

s s is t a n c e

I f a larger volume of capital assistance to poor countries is an im­
portant policy goal for this country, what financial and economic
forms should this assistance take ?
One of the most important issues in this connection is the extent to
which aid should take the form of private versus public investment.
There are several important advantages of private investment. Since
it is made within the framework of business profit calculations, private
investment funds are likely to be employed productively. Further­
more, to the extent that this type of investment consists of direct rather
than portfolio investment, it is likely to be accompanied by an inflow
of managerial and entrepreneurial talent. This can be an effective
method of helping to train the labor force in poor countries. Direct
private investment also has the advantage of freeing a country from
fixed charges that must be annually transferred abroad. Finally, a
larger part of the earnings from direct investment as compared with
portfolio investment are likely to be reinvested within the recipient
country.
Because of these important benefits from private investment, vigor­
ous efforts should be taken to increase the flow of this type of funds.
Most writers contend that this flow can be expanded through such
measures as investment treaties, tax incentives, investment guaranties,
and the provision of better information concerning investment oppor­
tunities abroad. But the majority of investigators in this field do not
believe that the kind of additional capital needs estimated by Millikan
and Rostow for the poor countries can be satisfied mainly by private
investment, particularly within the next few years. The risks and
impediments involved in private foreign investment can be minimized
only over a fairly long period of time.



602

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

There are also some drawbacks to an exclusive reliance on private
investment. By far the largest part of British and American foreign
investment has been devoted to the development of food and raw
material exports and tertiary industries closely associated with the
marketing of these exports. In short, there understandably has been
an export bias to private foreign investment. The great international
flow of capital in the 19th and early 20th centuries also was directed to
regions of recent settlement such as the United States, Argentina, and
A ustralia and was accompanied by a large movement of trained labor.
The relatively skilled type of labor that emigrated to these sparsely
populated regions and the nature of the commodities produced for
export were important factors in causing the large-scale investment
in industries closely related to exports to create a mechanism of sus­
tained growth. In most of the poor countries the flow of capital and
labor was either insignificant or the type of labor emigrating to these
nations and the nature of the export industry were such th at foreign
investment did little to produce a cumulative growth process.
In many of the poor countries the current prospects for the creation
of the type of balenced economy necessary for sustained development
by means of investment in industries closely associated with exports
are not very favorable. First, productive opportunities for a sig­
nificant expansion in the type of export industries that attract foreign
capital do not exist in a number of these countries. Moreover, m
those nations in which opportunities are present the high proportion
of the investment in extractive industries does not directly contribute
to an increase in the levels of skill and industrial training of very many
people nor does it induce much complementary investment in tertiary
industries. The taxation of profits from this investment, however,
can serve as an important source of revenue. Although private in­
vestment by foreigners in export industries should be encouraged for
this reason, it does not f ollow th at the existence of this tax revenue will
lead to balanced self-sustained growth in any automatic manner.
Total resources available from taxes and royalties paid by foreigners
are not now nor likely to be in the near future sufficiently large to meet
the capital requirements necessary for this goal. Furthermore, as the
experience of certain countries in the Middle E ast indicates, the avail­
ability of capital funds does not ensure rapid development. A wellconceived program is needed, administrative and managerial skills in
government and business must be improved, levels of general education
and vocational training of the labor force must be raised, natural re­
sources must be more fully exploited, reforms in the system of land
tenure are often needed, etc. In short, accelerated development re­
quires the removal of the characteristics of backwardness and under­
development as well as of capital deficiency.
Public foreign assistance must be relied upon to aid in the develop­
ment of those sectors in which private foreign investment is not likely
to be undertaken and in which government revenues as well as the nonfinancial resources of the poor areas are insufficient to initiate a cumu­
lative growth process. The size of the type of aid th at would seem
desirable in terms of our development goal is difficult to estimate. On
the one hand the internal needs of the rich countries are so pressing
that massive assistance to poor areas that turns out to be mostly a form
of relief because of its unproductive uses must be ruled out. On the




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

603

other hand, if the aid is too small, it may not be sufficient to start a
cumulative upward growth movement and therefore also may be but
a form of subsidy. In terms of the estimated needs of the poor areas
and the outlook for alternative sources of assistance it would appear
that an additional appropriation by the United States Government of
perhaps $1.5 billion annually for a 5-year period would be a prudent
step. But a much more careful survey of the opportunities to absorb
capital assistance productively in the poor regions is necessary before
any firm opinion can be given on this matter.
An im portant part of such a program should consist of greater
technical assistance to the poor countries. Sums such as the $116
million appropriated for this purpose by the United States in 1954
and the $70 million budgeted by the United Nations in the same year
are entirely too modest in view of the opportunities in this area.
Technical assistance essentially is a form of investment in the people
of these countries. I t must be remembered that nations such as the
United States, Canada, and Australia developed under the impetus
of a simultaneous flow of capital and labor. The people who emi­
grated from Europe brought with them the know-how and production
experience that had been slowly acquired in the European nations.
We cannot expect any similar migration to the poor countries of today.
The problem therefore is to provide an alternative method of transfering technical knowledge to these areas. For with this knowledge
the poor countries not only will be able to utilize more productively the
investment funds provided by the rich countries but will be able to use
their existing resources better. A United Nations study estimates, for
example, that if poor countries devoted 1 percent of their national in­
come to agricultural services, they would be able to reap a 50 percent
increase in output within 20 years or less without any substantial in­
crease in capital or widespread reorganization of the agricultural sys­
tem.
Technical assistance should take the form of grants rather than
loans. Although its effects on raising the incomes and foreign ex­
change earning capacity of the poor countries are likely to prove
considerable, these repercussions will be indirect and occur only
gradually. To insist upon the repayment of these sums plus interest
charges may place the poor countries in a very difficult balance-ofpayments position and generally discourage the use of technical aid.
Efforts also are needed to integrate the several technical assistance
programs by means of some central international organization.
In addition to our direct military assistance, the principle of grants
is also appropriate for the economic aid that we believe is necessary
in order to help those countries receiving direct military assistance to
utilize this m ilitary aid effectively. Since the purpose of economic
aid of this sort is not directly related to the goal of establishing a
self-sustaining growth process, it should not be judged on the grounds
of economic productivity.
The remaining part of our foreign-aid program, including most of
the additional aid recommended here, should be in the form of loans.
Although it may well be even in our national interests to give to the
poor countries the entire amount of the additional aid suggested here,
the loan principle is necessary to help insure the most productive uses
of these funds and to encourage the creation of a framework of self­



604

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

sustained development. Interest rates, however, should be low and
should vary among countries d e p e n d i n g upon their level of develop­
ment. Provision for long-run, flexible repayment terms are also
necessary.
In summary, there seem to be convincing reasons for the United
States to increase its volume of foreign assistance to the poor coun­
tries. Basically, they follow from the attachment of a high priority
to the long-range goal of destroying Communist imperialism and of
creating a peaceful and prosperous world. In economic matters, as
in all forms of human endeavor, a situation must be judged in terms
of alternatives. There is no question but that an expanded aid pro­
gram will place additional burdens on the American people. But
these burdens are inconsequential compared to the kind they might
have to carry if communism continues to spread throughout the world
and if the poor countries fail to achieve a reasonable measure of suc­
cess in pursuing their peaceful national aspirations. Increased
economic assistance is no automatic guaranty that the goal of a peace­
ful and prosperous world will be established, but the potential dangers
of the future in relation to the possibilities for reaching this objective
partly by means of economic aid appear to indicate th at this aid is
well worth the risks involved.