View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ARM AND
Q ANCH
F I ULLETIN
December 1969

Vol. 24, No. 12

AG R IC U LTUR A L CREDIT IN THE SOUTHWESTERN STATES
Almost $5.5 billion in farm credit was out­
standing in the five states of the Eleventh Federal
Reserve District (Arizona, Louisiana, New Mex­
ico, Oklahoma, and Texas) at the beginning of
1969, 8 percent more than in January 1968. Of
that, $3.5 billion was in real-estate loans.
Banks continued to be far and away the largest
source of non-real-estate loans, accounting for 70
percent of the almost $2 billion outstanding. Pro­
duction credit associations accounted for 23 per­
cent, while the Farmers Home Administration ac­
counted for the remaining 7 percent.
The composition of the credit supply had shifted
considerably over the previous decade, with the
share extended by banks and PCA’s increasing at
the expense of the FHA. At the beginning of 1959,
the FHA accounted for 13 percent of the nonreal-estate loans outstanding to farmers, PCA’s
19 percent, and banks 68 percent. The much
faster rise in loans by PCA’s may have been due
partly to the increased size of commercial farm
loans at banks and to the relatively low loan limits
of the smaller banks.
Life insurance companies were the principal
institutional lender of faim real-estate loans, ac­
counting for 31 percent of those outstanding in the
five District states. But 36 percent were held by
individuals and other noninstitutional lenders.
Banks held 9 percent, Federal land banks 23 per­
cent, and the Faimers Home Administration 1
percent. Although the FHA still had almost $28
billion outstanding in agricultural loans across the
Nation, its importance in real-estate loans had
declined in the Southwest over the previous decade.

F E D E R A L

R E S E R V E

Non-Real-Estate Farm Loans Held by
Principal Lenders
January 1, 1969

(Dollar amounts in thousands)

Area and lender
ARIZONA
Banks ................... .
PCA’s ...................
FHA .....................
Total ................. .
LOUISIANA
Banks ................... .
PCA’s ...................
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

Amount
held

Percent
Percent change,
of
1969
state
from
total
1968

$ 193,074
15,731
3,440
$ 212,245

91

7
2
100

1
10
20

1

$

69,757
52,441
18,676
$ 140,874

50
37
13
100

28
14
-11
16

$

72,290
45,328
8,798
$ 126,416

57
36
7
100

10
13

OKLAHOMA
Banks ................... .
PCA’s ...................
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

$ 295,293
97,213
20,936
$ 413,442

71
24
5
100

5
18

TEXAS
Banks ................... .
PCA’s ...................
FHA .....................
Total .................. .

$ 722,237
224,073
88,134
$1,034,444

70
22
8
100

10
15

-3

DISTRICT
Banks ................. . .
PCA’s .................
FHA ...................
Total ............... . .

$1,352,651
434,786
139,984
$1,927,421

70
23

15

NEW MEXICO
Banks ................... .
PCA’s ...................
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

7

100

1 Less than 0.5 percent.
SOURCE: The American Bankers Association.

B A N K

OF

D A L L A S

_____________________________________________________________________

-3
10

C1)
7

10

8

-3
9

Between the beginnings of 1959 and 1969, the
total amount of real-estate loans made in the five
southwestern states by institutions rose nearly two
and a half times, advancing to nearly $2.3 billion.
The other three institutions increased their volume
of loans substantially. Holding a fairly constant
share of the total, banks increased their share
nearly two and a half times. Loans at life insurance
companies rose 36 percent. But the share extended
by the FHA declined 53 percent.
The amount of farm credit used in each state
varied widely, as did the percentage changes and
the relative importance of lenders. The largest
amount of farm credit was extended in Texas,

Non-Real-Estate Farm Loans Held by
Principal Lenders, 1969 and 1959
January I

(Dollar amounts in thousands)
Percent
change,
1969
from
1959

Area and lender
ARIZONA
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
Total ...............

1969

1959

$ 193,074
15,731
3,440
$ 212,245

$ 79,801
5,863
1,495
$ 87,159

142
168
130
144

LOUISIANA
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
Total ...............

69,757
52,441
18,676
$ 140,874

$ 24,225
16,713
8,605
$ 49,543

188
214
117
184

NEW MEXICO
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
Total ...............

$

72,290
45,328
8,798
$ 126,416

$ 29,565
10,616
7,251
$ 47,432

145
327
121
167

OKLAHOMA
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
"Potal ...............

$ 295,293
97,213
20,936
$ 413,442

$105,785
26,433
17,230
$149,448

179
268
21
177

TEXAS
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
Total ...............

$ 722,237
224,073
88,134
$1,034,444

$289,152
90,221
62,850
$442,223

150
148
40
134

DISTRICT
Banks ...................
PCA’s ...................
F H A .....................
Total ...............

$1,352,651
434,786
139,984
$1 ,927,421

$528,528
149,846
97,431
$775,805

156
190

$

SOURCE: The American Bankers Association.

44

148

but the greatest percentage gains over the 1968
level were in Louisiana, where real-estate loans
increased 14 percent and non-real-estate loans
advanced 16 percent. The smallest percentage
changes were in Arizona, where non-real-estate

Farm Real-Estate Loans Held by
Principal Lenders
January I, 1969

(Dollar amounts in thousands)

Area and lender
ARIZONA
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .
LOUISIANA
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .
NEW MEXICO
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

Amount
held

Percent
Percent change,
1969
of
state
from
total
1968

$

9,768
36,584
103,741
117,946
1,115
$ 269,154

4
14
38
44
(x)
100

4
1
-2
L)
L)
-1

$

65,011
113,238
133,023
151,202
4,969
$ 467,443

14
24
29
32
1
100

7
24
12
14
-12
14

$

7,566
55,334
83,912
123,921
1,478
$ 272,211

3
20
31
45
1
100

-8
7
6
5
-6
5

OKLAHOMA
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

$

84,580
112,006
177,708
217,025
6,504
$ 597,823

14
19
30
36
1
100

11
13
4
7
-8
7

TEXAS
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

$ 163,983
476,365
610,406
667,000
13,658
$1,931,412

8
25
32
34
1
100

16
8
4
7
-6
7

DISTRICT
Banks ................... .
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
Individuals2 .........
FHA .....................
Total ................. .

$ 330,908
793,527
1,108,790
1,277,094
27,724
$3,538,043

9
23
31
36
1
100

11
11
4
7
-7
7

1 Less than 0.5 percent.
- Estimates— individuals and all other sources of funds.
SOURCE: The American Bankers Association.

loans increased 1 percent and real-estate loans
decreased 1 percent.

continued to expand their cattle-feeding opera­
tions.

The cattle industry seems to be a major factor
in the increased demand for farm credit in both
Louisiana and Texas, but for slightly different
reasons. Farmers in Louisiana are becoming more
involved in raising and preconditioning feeder
calves, many of which will be shipped to the High
Plains area of the Southwest. Texas ranchers have

Agricultural Export Industry
Is Big Employer

Farm Real-Estate Loans Held by
Principal Lenders, 1969 and 1959
January I

(Dollar amounts in thousands)

Area and lender
ARIZONA
Banks ...................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
F H A .....................
T o ta l.................

1959

1969

Percent
change,
1969
from
1959

$

9,768
36,584
103,741
1,115
$ 151,208

$

4,250
13,891
37,763
3,584
$ 59,488

130
163
175
-69
154

65,011
113,238
133,023
4,969
$ 316,241

$ 24,598
28,607
22,874
10,126
$ 86,205

164
296
482
-51
267

$

7,566
55,334
83,912
1,478
$ 148,290

$

3,520
15,197
41,612
5,952
$ 66,281

115
264
102
-75
124

84,580
112,006
177,708
6,504
$ 380,798

$ 21,009
37,424
77,288
14,946
$150,667

303
199
130
-57
153

TEXAS
Banks ...................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
F H A .....................
T o ta l.................

$ 163,983
476,365
610,406
13,658
$1,264,412

$ 42,291
211,063
290,055
24,486
$567,895

288
126
110
-44
123

DISTRICT
Banks ....................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
FHA ...................
T o ta l.................

$ 330,908
793,527
1,108,790
27,724
$2,260,949

$ 95,668
306,182
469,592
59,094
$930,536

246
159
136
-53
243

LOUISIANA
Banks ...................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
F H A .....................
T o ta l.................
NEW MEXICO
Banks ...................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
F H A .....................
T o ta l.................
OKLAHOMA
Banks ...................
FLB’s ...................
Life ins. cos..........
F H A .....................
T o ta l.................

$

$

NOTE: State and District totals for 1969 do not equal
totals of the preceding table due to incomplete data for
the “individuals” category.

SOURCE: The American Bankers Association.

A recent study by the Department of Labor
shows that exports of food and agricultural prod­
ucts accounted for an estimated 729,000 workers
in 1966, or about 30 percent of all jobs related
to merchandise exports.
About three-fifths of these workers were on
farms. A large number of farm jobs are supported
directly by exports of wheat, for example, since
about half the crop every year moves to overseas
markets. But there are also many other jobs in­
volving exports, such as moving the wheat from
farms to ports or turning out fertilizers and other
materials required to produce wheat.
On-farm jobs related to exports totaled 433,000,
or almost 11 percent of all agricultural employ­
ment. Food processing accounted for another
49.000 jobs. The remaining jobs supported in­
directly by farm and food exports were concen­
trated in the trade, transportation, and chemical
industries.
The relationship between the value of agricul­
tural exports and the number of jobs supported
by exports depends mainly on labor productivity,
or output per worker. As the volume of exports
expands, employment in exports tends to rise. But
the increase is limited by gains in productivity.
Between 1960 and 1966, for example, the value
of agricultural exports (adjusted for price changes)
increased 27 percent but employment related to
these exports declined 6 percent.
The effect of productivity gains on export em­
ployment can be expressed another way. About
160.000 workers were required, directly and in­
directly, for each billion dollars of agricultural
exports in 1960. Six years later, only 118,000 were
required. Such gains in productivity, are, of course,
important in reducing costs, which, in turn, are
important in increasing demand and employment.
With the increased farm use of chemicals and
machinery and the improvements being made in
methods of handling and shipping farm products,
this trend toward a more efficient use of labor in
the production of agricultural products can be
expected to continue.

E C O N O M IC REFLECTIONS
The Cost of Opportunities

One of the main points to be considered in an
investment decision is the cost of the investment,
which means more than just the dollar cost. In
addition to the explicit cost of buying, hiring, or
renting various factors of production, allowances
must be made for the implicit cost, or value, of
resources the owner provides, over and above
those hired from outside sources. The problem,
then, becomes one of estimating the cost of using
resources for one purpose instead of another —
of estimating the cost of foregoing opportunities
that have to be sacrificed.
Although Robinson Crusoe paid out no money,
he learned that picking raspberries cost him the
time and effort he could have spent picking
strawberries. This cost — the sacrifice of doing
something else — is called “opportunity cost.”
The matter of foregone opportunity is a factor in
every decision, for if there were no choices to
consider, there would be no decisions to make.
A dollar spent today is clearly more costly
than a dollar held for a while in some productive
use and then spent later. Suppose, for example,
that a farmer is trying to decide whether to pay
$10,000 for a new combine with an expected
service-life of 10 years or $6,000 for a used com­
bine with a remaining service-life of 5 years. To
simplify the decision process, assume that the
combine is needed and will pay for itself, that the
maintenance costs are the same either way, that
neither machine will have any salvage value at the
end of its service-life, and that the farmer has an
extra $10,000 in cash. This last assumption re­
moves any complications involving consideration
of interest costs. However, the same kind of anal­
ysis would apply regardless of the farmer’s cash
position.
The farmer’s problem is to decide which com­
bine is cheaper, and the answer depends on the
opportunity cost of his money. He must decide
how productive his money would be if he put it
to another use, a decision that would be different,
of course, for everyone. Perhaps the farmer is
short of capital and the additional money would
earn a 15-percent return in his livestock opera­

tion. Perhaps he is content with the size of his
present operation and has no better alternative
use for his money except to invest it in corporate
bonds yielding 8.4 percent. Or perhaps he insists
on keeping his money in a checking account or
safety deposit box. If so, because the money does
not earn anything, there is no opportunity cost.
Also involved in this problem is the concept of
“discounting,” a technique used in determining
the present value of future costs and returns. At
first glance, the $10,000 new combine seems to be
the cheaper alternative. But the present cost of a
$12,000 expenditure in a situation where half
is paid out now and half is paid out for a similar
combine 5 years hence may be less than the
$10,000 cost of a new combine. The difference
in these costs depends on the rate of return the
farmer can receive on the remaining $4,000 in­
vestment for the 5-year service-life of the first
used combine. This is his opportunity cost. In
this example, calculations show that an 8.4-per­
cent opportunity cost of capital would make the
choice a matter of indifference to the farmer. If
the opportunity cost of money were more than
8.4 percent, the used machines would be the better
buy. If none of his alternatives would yield 8.4
percent, the new machine would be the better buy.
Differences in opportunity cost account for one
farmer consistently buying new equipment while
his neighbor always buys used equipment. Both
are rational, but their situations are different and
they face different constraints. The farmer short of
capital and with the opportunity to earn a 15percent return on his investment in livestock
should buy the used machines. But the choice is
a matter of indifference to the other farmer, whose
better alternative, barring pride in ownership of
the new machine, is investing in 8.4-percent cor­
porate bonds. The present value of both pur­
chases is the same to him. The farmer that would
let his money lay idle rather than invest it in some­
thing else is apt to lean toward purchasing a new
combine, and quite rationally, since the present
cost to him is clearly $2,000 less than he would
pay for two used machines.
Prepared by
A r t h u r L. W r i g h t