View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

The Economy in Perspective
Thinking productively about monetary policy…
Some of the talk about the “new economy” and
the “old economy” has been highly productive,
spotlighting the dramatic transformation of the
U.S. capital stock and the way its growth drives
domestic economic activity. Not surprisingly,
capital markets reward “new economy” companies, which offer the prospect of explosive growth
as they propagate their products and services in
the larger, older economy. One need not think
that “new economy” firms are valued correctly to
understand why spending on their products has
risen so dramatically and why investors expect
them to generate significant future earnings.
Another positive aspect of the discussion is its
focus on the role of legal systems and business
practices in channeling capital to its highest uses
around the world. Just as economic development
specialists came to understand that nations rich in
natural resources did not inevitably unlock their
wealth, the current experts realize that wealth
creation depends on an ability to organize the
means of production into value-creating enterprises. Legal systems, contract enforcement,
accounting standards, financial infrastructures,
labor laws, and trade policies are all factors in
determining the value of resources in a particular
location. Nations compete not so much with what
they have, but what they can do with what they
can get.
It has been fashionable to assert that the United
States is benefiting from a virtuous cycle of events,
initially set in motion by new technologies. As the
new capital stock is built, economic output accelerates and wages expand along with faster
productivity growth. Everyone has the potential
for becoming wealthier, although those closest to
technology’s epicenter are likely to benefit most.
Since people’s lifetime wealth has increased, it is
natural for them to spend more on themselves. As
a nation, we need not choose between new fiberoptic cable communications backbones and
sport–utility vehicles because U.S. firms have
been able to borrow readily from foreign savers,
even as this nation’s household saving dwindles.
In this virtuous cycle, accelerating productivity
growth naturally puts downward pressure on the
inflation rate, and the U.S. dollar—bolstered by
capital inflows—lowers import prices. The net
result has been a record-setting U.S. economic
expansion with no adverse inflation impacts.
With conditions so good, is it any wonder so
many pundits are already lamenting the unwinding of this virtuous cycle? It is true that unsustainable forces have a habit of ending, and the U.S.
investment boom will eventually fade. What are
some of the plausible consequences when it
does? One is that the U.S. economy could emerge
with a faster rate of trend productivity growth
than before the boom, accompanied by a stronger

trend rate of real GDP growth. Per capita real
earnings could be higher and faster growing than
before, reflecting the better productivity picture.
But as the transition to this improved situation
nears completion, investment activity could slow
dramatically for a time, just as real GDP growth
will recede from its boom-induced pace. At the
same time, we should expect to see some increase in the household saving rate, attenuating
the need for foreign capital. Import growth would
slow, and the current account surplus would
move toward balance.
The challenge for monetary policy in this transition is often misunderstood. During the boom
phase, the monetary authority should expect the
demand for money to increase, along with the
equilibrium real interest rate. If the central bank
desires to hold the inflation rate steady, it most
likely will need to allow money growth to accelerate and its interbank interest rate to increase.
Keeping the interbank rate steady could result in
accelerating inflation. If the central bank wants to
glide on the disinflationary air currents of the productivity boom, it will not permit money growth
to expand commensurately with output.
As the boom fades, the monetary authority must
anticipate that money growth will necessarily slow
and the equilibrium real interest rate will decline.
If the economy emerges from the boom at its target inflation rate, the central bank will need to reduce its interbank rate in pace with the decline in
money demand. If the economy shows undesirably high inflation, the central bank could reduce
its interbank interest rate more slowly, so as to
exert disinflationary pressure.
It should be clear that productivity, investment,
trade, and labor markets all shape the terrain on
which monetary policy decisions are made. The
productivity boom—and its eventual demise—
have implications for inflation, but only insofar as
they complicate policymakers’ ability to understand the dynamic evolution of the economy. As
the “new economy” becomes old, let us hope
that it ages gracefully.
Solution to last month’s puzzle:

1

F
E

2

4

O

9

E

E
C

M

B
12

E

N

M

P

R

M

6

7

I

O

C

U
O

P

5

S
L

8

3

E

M

R

C

S

P

U

I

L

L
O

B

A

I

R

P

11

I

P
14

E

G
L

D

P

S
13

A

I

I

Y

16

J

T

10

E

T

J

15

R

N

O

U

17

N

B

E

A

R
O

18

I

N

F

L

A

T

I

S
19

T

I
21

I

O

N

R
20

Y

C
E

U
N

O
SOLUTION: ___
L ___
A ___
R ___
R ___
Y

___
S ___
U ___
M ___
M ___
E ___
R ___
S

B

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent
7.15 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

Percent, weekly average
6.75
RESERVE MARKET RATES
Intended federal runds rate

7.05

6.25
June 1, 2000
6.95

Effective federal funds rate
5.75

6.85

6.75

5.25

August 1, 2000

July 3, 2000
6.65

Discount rate

August 21, 2000

4.75
6.55
August 30, 2000
6.45

4.25
1996

1997

1998

1999

June

2000

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

Nov.

Dec.

2000

Jan.

Feb.
2001

Percent, weekly average
9
LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

Percent, weekly average
6.5 SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES
1-year T-bill a
6.0

8
Conventional mortgage

5.5
7

5.0

30-year Treasury a

3-month T-bill a
6

4.5

5

10-year Treasury a

4.0

3.5
1996

4

1997

1998

1999

2000

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Constant maturity.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

At its August 22 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) left the intended federal
funds rate unchanged at 6.5%.
Citing “rapid advances in productivity” and signs of moderating demand, the FOMC has maintained
the stance of monetary policy at its
two most recent meetings. Previously, the Committee had increased
the target rate 150 basis points (bp)
in a series of five movements (75 bp
of which arguably can be described
as “taking back” cuts associated
with the Russian default); the series

culminated in a 50 bp increase at the
May meeting.
Economists often turn to the
federal funds futures market to
approximate expectations for the
future path of monetary policy. This
measure reveals that the FOMC’s
decision was not unanticipated; in
fact, market participants had
assigned a low probability to an
August increase in early July.
Further, the implied yield curve on
fed funds futures drifted down and
flattened out in August, suggesting
at month’s end that most market

participants do not anticipate rate
increases at any of this year’s three
remaining FOMC meetings.
Yield curve inversions, which
occur when securities of longer
maturity yield less than similar
short-term securities, persist at both
the short and the long end of the
U.S. Treasury yield curve. As of
September 1, the 1-year T-bill yield
(6.23%) was 8 bp less than the
3-month T-bill (6.31%). Similarly,
the 30-year Treasury bond (5.71%)
yielded 5 bp less than the 10-year
Treasury (5.76%).
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percent change, year over year
7 CPI, ALL ITEMS, JANUARY 1983–JULY 2000

Percent change, year over year
7

CPI, ALL ITEMS, JANUARY 1983–JULY 1999

6

6

5.3

5.3
5

5

4

4
3.5

3.5
3

3

2.8

2.7
2

2
1.8
1
1983 1985

1
1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

1983 1985

2001

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

Percent change, year over year
5.0
INFLATION EXPECTATIONS, JANUARY 1983–FEBRUARY 2000

Percent change, year over year
5.0
INFLATION EXPECTATIONS, JANUARY 1983–JULY 2000

4.5

4.5

4.0

2001

4.0

4.0

3.8
3.5

3.5

3.1

3.1
3.0

3.0

3.0

2.9

2.7
2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0
1.5

1.5
1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Median expected change in consumer prices one year ahead as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
NOTE: Horizontal lines indicate statistically different trends (significant at the 5% level), estimated using an algorithm developed by Bai and Perron.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; University of Michigan; Jushan Bai and Pierre Perron, “Estimating and Testing Linear Models
with Multiple Structural Changes,” Econometrica, vol. 66, no. 1 (January 1998), pp. 47–78; and Jushan Bai and Pierre Perron, “Computation and Analysis of
Multiple Structural Change Models,” unpublished, Boston University, 2000.

Inflation experience in the 1990s
was favorable in comparison with
the previous decade. The inflation
rate—as measured by the CPI—was
both lower and less variable than in
the 1980s. With the outcome of the
Gulf War decided in early 1991, concerns about the stability of the oil
supply abated; both inflation and
expectations of future inflation
dropped precipitously. Some analysts at that time identified the disinflation as evidence that a deliberative, credible monetary policy had
successfully avoided repeating mistakes made in the 1970s, when

unfavorable surges in oil prices
resulted in permanent increases in
inflation. In the parlance of monetary policy, the FOMC did not
accommodate such a rise in inflation
in the latter period.
Nor did monetary policy accommodate temporarily low oil prices. In
the 1980s, oil prices dropped
substantially and stayed low for
more than a year before rebounding
sharply. The transitory fall in CPI
inflation in 1986 reflected favorable
oil prices around that time. Similarly,
CPI inflation dipped in the late
1990s. Formal breakpoint-test analy-

sis reveals that unlike the transitory
dip in oil prices in the 1980s, the recent one was associated with a “permanent” downward break in CPI inflation, first perceived in late 1998
and persisting until July of last year.
Moreover, a similar downward break
was found in inflation expectations,
which also appeared evident until
recently, when additional data failed
to confirm a continuing break.
Although the recent dip was
related to a transitory decline in oil
prices, other factors were also
important. The Asian crises in 1997
and the Russian default in 1998
(continued on next page)

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
4-quarter percent change
8 NONFARM BUSINESS OUPUT PER HOUR

4-quarter percent change
8 MANUFACTURING OUPUT PER HOUR

6

6
4.6
3.0

4

4

2

2

2.7

1.4
0

0
1.4

–2

–2

–4

–4
1959

1965

1971

1977

1983

1989

1995

2001

1959

1965

1971

1977

1983

1989

1995

2001

Index, January 1981 = 100, log scale
2,500 SELECTED STOCK INDEXES

Ratio
35 S&P 500 PRICE-TO-EARNINGS RATIO

30
1,000

25
22.8
500

1,200

2,150

1,180

2,080

1,160

2,010

1,140

1,940

1,120
1,100

1,870
1,800

NASDAQ

August 2000, daily

20

S&P 500

14.9

15

10

100

50

5

1959

1965

1971

1977

1983

1989

1995

2001

1981 1983

1985

1987

1989

1991 1993

1995

1997 1999 2001

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

NOTE: Horizontal lines for nonfarm business and manufacturing output per hour indicate statistically different trends (significant at the 5% level), estimated
using an algorithm developed by Bai and Perron. Horizontal lines for the S&P price-to-earnings ratio are averages calculated over the same periods for which
statistically significant trends were found in manufacturing output per hour.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Haver Analytics; Bloomberg Financial Information Services; Jushan Bai and Pierre Perron,
“Estimating and Testing Linear Models with Multiple Structural Changes,” Econometrica, vol. 66, no. 1 (January 1998), pp. 47–78; and Jushan Bai and
Pierre Perron, “Computation and Analysis of Multiple Structural Change Models,” unpublished, Boston University, 2000.

enhanced the attractiveness of
dollar-denominated assets relative to
those of the rest of the world. The
consequent capital flows strengthened the dollar’s value, reducing
import prices and putting downward pressure on domestic inflation.
Capital flows into the U.S. also supported an investment boom,
especially in high-tech equipment,
which in turn contributed to acceleration in labor productivity. Higher
productivity continues to dampen
inflationary pressures, containing

inflation’s rebound despite the recent
doubling of oil prices.
Labor productivity growth was
consistently higher in the late 1990s,
but some formal breakpoint tests fail
to confirm a permanent upward
break in the nonfarm business sector.
The same tests do identify the widely
known downward break around
1973. More significantly, however, a
clear upward break is found in the
manufacturing sector’s productivity.
It is generally recognized that manufacturing productivity is more

accurately measured than that of the
broader nonfarm business sector,
which includes the hard-to-measure
service sector. Moreover, as Federal
Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
recently indicated, the manufacturing sector measure provides little
evidence that productivity has
stopped accelerating.
The value of a stock market
index depends critically on publicly
traded firms’ potential for future
earnings growth. In the aggregate,
earnings growth is directly related
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Trillions of dollars
4.9 THE M2 AGGREGATE

Trillions of dollars
4.8 THE MZM AGGREGATE
5%

4.7

15

4.5

12

12
5%

9
4.5

1%

4.2

6
5%

3

1%

3
0

5%

10%

9

6

4.3

10%

MZM growth, 1995–2000 a
15

M2 growth, 1995–2000 a

0

3.9

10%

5%
4.1

5%

3.6
1%

10%

5%
3.9

5%

3.3
1%

3.7

3.0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Annualized percent change from fourth quarter of previous year

Percent

14

13.0

YEAR-TO-DATE MZM GROWTH

1998

1997

1999

2000

Ratio
3.60

MZM VELOCITY AND OPPORTUNITY COST

1999
12
2000

9.9

10

3.10

8

Velocity
6.8

2.60

3.7

2.10

6

4

2

Opportunity cost
0

0.6
Jan.

Feb. Mar. Apr.

May June July Aug. Sept.

Oct. Nov. Dec.

1.60
1959

1965

1971

1977

1983

1989

1995

2001

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2000 growth rates for M2 and MZM are calculated on an estimated August over 1999:IVQ basis.
NOTE: Data are seasonally adjusted. Last plots for M2 and MZM are estimated for August 2000. Dotted lines for M2 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges.
All other dotted lines represent growth rates and are for reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

to the productive potential of the
economy. The 1990s’ acceleration in
equity prices was concurrent with
higher manufacturing productivity
growth. The current year’s lull in
stock prices could portend flattening
productivity growth. On the other
hand, the market may have gotten
ahead of itself.
Analysts concerned about inflationary pressures may find additional
comfort in money growth, which is
slower this year than in 1999 virtually

across the board, M3 being the notable exception. Estimated through
August, year-to-date M2 growth
(5.3%) is nearly a full percentage
point below the 12 months ending in
December 1999 (6.2%). More striking
is MZM, which has grown 2.6 percentage points slower this year (6.7%
for the year to date estimated
through August versus 9.3% through
December 1999).
The slowdown in money growth
is consistent with rising interest

rates, which usually implies that the
opportunity cost of money—the cost
of holding it—has increased. MZM
opportunity cost is measured as the
difference between the 3-month
T-bill yield and a share-weighted
average of yields on MZM components. Over time, MZM velocity (the
level of MZM relative to economic
activity) tends to vary directly with
its opportunity cost, but with a lag—
suggesting that MZM velocity may
rise further in the near term.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Interest Rates
Percent

Percent
7.00 YIELD CURVES a

12

CAPITAL MARKET RATES

6.75

Home mortgage, primary conventional

10

Moody's seasoned AAA

January 2000

6.50

8
6.25
July 28, 2000 b
6

6.00

30-year Treasury a

5.75
4

September 1, 2000 b

Municipal bond

5.50
2
5.25
0

5.00
5

0

10

15
20
Years to maturity

25

1989

30

1991

1993

1995

1997

Percent
1.6 YIELD SPREAD: 10-YEAR INTEREST RATE SWAP c
MINUS 10-YEAR TREASURY BOND a

Percent
1.6 YIELD SPREAD: 3-MONTH COMMERCIAL PAPER
MINUS 3-MONTH TREASURY BILL

1.4

1.4

1.2

1.2

1.0

1.0

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

1999

0

0
1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
b. Average for the week ending on this date.
c. Quote for semiannually fixed rate versus 3-month U.S. $LIBOR.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

The yield curve has inverted further
since last month, with yields on maturities of two years and above
falling, and those below two years
rising. The entire curve is inverted,
except for 3- and 6-month bills.
The Treasury yield curve gets most
of the attention because it acts as a
risk-free benchmark for the financial
market, but information abounds in
the yields of risky maturities as well.
Thus, among longer-term rates, the
drop in yields since January has been
much less pronounced than for
30-year Treasuries. Treasury rates

apparently are having less impact on
mortgage rates than in the past. Similarly, the yield spread between
Moody’s AAA bonds and long bonds
has increased from 114 basis points
(bp) in January to 184 bp now.
The increased spread also shows
up at the 10-year maturity, between
interest rate swaps and Treasuries.
This number is alarming if it retains
its traditional significance as a measure of risk in the financial markets,
reaching levels not seen since the
Russian default and the collapse of
Long Term Capital Management.

Is the market really so fearful?
Two considerations argue that it is
not: First, lower long-term Treasury
yields may be heavily influenced by
supply reductions. If this, rather than
a flight to quality, explains why safe
rates have dropped while risky rates
have remained steady, then there is
less cause for concern. Second,
shorter maturities, such as three
months, where supply considerations have less impact, show risk
spreads at a low level.

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
3.75 TRENDS IN THE CPI

July Price Statistics

3.50
Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

1999
5 yr.a avg.

Consumer prices
All items

Median CPI b

3.25
3.00

2.8

3.6

3.6

2.5

2.7
2.75

Less food
and energy
Median b

2.7

2.2

2.4

2.4

1.9

2.50

3.5

3.0

2.7

2.8

2.3

2.25
CPI, all items

Producer prices
Finished goods

2.00

0.0

2.4

4.1

1.5

2.9

1.6

0.8

1.5

1.1

0.8

FOMC
central
tendency
projections
as of
July
1999 c

1.75

Less food
and energy

1.50
1.25
1995

12-month percent change
3.75
PCE CHAIN-TYPE PRICE INDEX AND CPI
3.50

1996

1998

1997

1999

2000

2001

Annualized quarterly percent change
4.5
ACTUAL CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST d
4.0
Actual
Blue Chip forecast

3.25
CPI, all items

3.5

3.00
2.75

Top 10 average

3.0
Bottom 10 average

2.50
2.5

FOMC
central
tendency
projections
as of July
2000 c

2.25
2.00
1.75

2.0
1.5

1.50
1.0

1.25
PCE Chain-Type Price Index

0.5

1.00
0.75
1995

0

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
2001

IVQ

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Upper and lower bounds for inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
d. Blue Chip Panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, August 10, 2000.

Whether the July price statistics
show inflation to be high or low
is a matter of perspective. Judged
against this year’s performance, the
July numbers appear modest. The
Consumer Price Index (CPI) rose an
annualized 2.8% for the month, or
about ¾ percentage point under its
12-month average increase. However, the July data also indicate that
retail prices continued to rise at the
somewhat elevated pace set in
1999—about one percentage point
above their 1997–99 average
growth rate. Also, signals from

July’s so-called “core” inflation
statistics (statistics that attempt to
distinguish between transitory and
permanent movements in the data)
were a bit high. The CPI excluding
food and energy items rose 2.7% in
the month, or roughly ¼ percentage
point higher than its 12-month average, while the median CPI jumped
3.5%, more than ¾ percentage point
higher than its 12-month average.
Finally, the PCE Chain-Type Price
Index, an alternative measure of retail prices, has risen slightly more
than 2½% in the past 12 months,

nearly the highest growth trend
posted in more than five years.
Economists expect retail price
data to moderate gradually over the
next several quarters before stabilizing around the 2½% level by next
spring. Inflation pessimists see the
trend in the CPI leveling off at a rate
slightly under 3¼%, while the inflation optimists see the price data
holding to just under 2%.
Potential pressure on domestic
resource markets is considered (at
least by some economists) to be an
(continued on next page)

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
12-month percent change

Billions of dollars
130
U.S. IMPORTS AND EXPORTS

6

IMPORT PRICE INDEX AND THE CPI

120
4
CPI

110
2

100
0

Imports
90

–2

80

Exports
–4

70

Import Price Index, excluding petroleum products

60
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Annual percent change
14 BLUE CHIP FORECAST OF 2000 INFLATION a
12

10

–6
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Annual percent change
9
BLUE CHIP FORECAST OF 2000 GDP a
December 10, 1999
8
August 10, 2000

December 10, 1999
August 10, 2000

7
6

8
5
6
4
4
3
2

2

0

1

–2

0
Canada Mexico Japan U.K. South Germany Taiwan France Brazil
Korea

Hong China
Kong

Canada Mexico Japan U.K. South Germany Taiwan France Brazil
Korea

Hong China
Kong

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Blue Chip Panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators,
December 10, 1999 and August 10, 2000.

important unknown in the inflation
outlook for the remainder of this
year and next. However, the notion
that future inflation trends can be
forecasted by evaluating resource
markets is hotly debated, with some
analysts using slack economies
abroad to explain why U.S. resource market conditions have
been particularly uninformative
about inflation in recent years. They
argue that the availability of ample
foreign resources meant that U.S.
demand was not met with the same
cost pressures—hence inflation
pressures—as in the past. The U.S.
trade gap has widened sharply

since the summer of 1997, a period
when import prices exerted substantial downward influence on
U.S. retail prices.
According to this view, a key
factor in the U.S. inflation outlook
is the continued sluggishness of
economies abroad. Should other
nations’ production start to gain significant momentum and command
greater amounts of their productive
capacity, the U.S. economy’s ability
to forestall an upward surge in inflation would be greatly diminished.
Surprisingly, while foreign economies have shown greater-thanexpected strength this year, their own

inflation performance has been generally less than expected. For each of
11 major U.S. trading partners, real
economic growth has been tracking
above analysts’ expectations, in many
cases more than a percentage point
higher. However, inflation performance in seven of these countries is
tracking somewhat lower than
analysts had projected. Overall,
despite the generally stronger world
economic activity, nonpetroleum import prices this year have continued
to have a net dampening influence
on U.S. retail prices.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Annualized percent change from previous quarter
9
GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST a

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IIQ
(Preliminary estimate)
Change,
billions
of 1996 $

Real GDP
119.7
Consumer spending
44.7
Durables
–11.5
Nondurables
15.7
Services
37.7
Business fixed
investment
45.5
Equipment
46.0
Structures
3.2
Residential investment
0
Government spending 18.8
National defense
13.1
Net exports
–31.8
Exports
34.9
Imports
66.6
Change in private
inventories
42.7

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

5.3
2.9
–5.0
3.4
4.4

6.0
5.4
9.4
5.4
4.5

10.9
17.8
4.8
0
4.9
16.2
—
13.5
19.5

10.5
16.4
7.2
0.1
4.2
4.2
—
10.0
14.7

—

—

8

Actual percent change
Advance estimate

7

Preliminary estimate
Blue Chip forecast, August 10, 2000

6
5
30-year average
4
3
2
1
0
IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

1999

IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

2000

IIQ
2001

Percent change

Percentage points

INVENTORY INVESTMENT AND GDP GROWTH

CONTRIBUTION TO 2000:IIQ REAL GDP GROWTH RATE a

8

2.5
Advance estimate
Preliminary estimate

Real GDP growth c
6

2.0

4
1.5

2
1.0

0

0.5

–2
Inventory investment’s contribution to real GDP growth
–4

0
Nonresidential fixed investment

Inventory investment

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
c. Annualized percent change from previous quarter.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, August 10, 2000.

The preliminary estimate of GDP
growth for 2000:IIQ, at 5.3% (annualized), is 0.1 percentage point
higher than the advance estimate,
according to the August release.
The increase reflects upward revisions to inventory investment and
exports, offsetting an upward
revision to imports and downward
revisions to consumer spending
(especially durable goods) and nonresidential
fixed
investment.
Residential investment remained
unchanged. These revisions hint
that economic growth may be

tapering off; Blue Chip forecasters
are predicting a quick decline to
about 3%.
A sharp increase in inventory investment could signal a future slowdown. Whereas the previous trend
of increasing inventories has not
kept up with strong demand and
sales, the second-quarter increase
outpaced sales. If demand remains
moderate, retailers might cut back
on new orders, prompting a manufacturing slowdown and easing
labor markets. Sectoral data show
the inventory-to-sales ratio rising

notably in retail trade rather than in
wholesale or manufacturing, though
their levels are still extremely low by
historical standards. Unfilled manufacturing orders are substantial; even
if demand eases, they could keep
manufacturers and workers busy
into the near future.
Employment has grown steadily
during the current expansion. In fact,
since mid-1997, total employment has
remained above the level that some
analysts believe triggers accelerating
inflation. From this perspective, policies that succeeded in preventing
(continued on next page)

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Thousands of orders

Ratio

Percent
9

INVENTORY AND UNFILLED ORDERS a
1.46

470

Trillions of chain-weighted 1996 dollars
9.5

ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE VERSUS POTENTIAL

8
Unemployment rate
7

450

Real GDP

Manufacturers’ unfilled orders b

Retail trade

1.42

NAIRU

6

8.5

5
Potential real GDP

Total trade

430

1.38

4
7.5

3
1.34

410

2
1

390

1.30
IIQ

IVQ
1996

IIQ
1997

IVQ

IIQ
IVQ
1998

IIQ
1999

IVQ

PCE Chain-Type Price index c
6.5

0
1990

IIQ
2000

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Percent of total spending
70 COMPOSITION OF GOVERNMENT SPENDING

Percent of GDP
GOVERNMENT SPENDING AND RECEIPTS
Federal spending

60

20

State and local

50
Federal receipts

40
15

Federal defense
State and local receipts

30

20

10

Federal nondefense
State and local spending

10

0

5
1952

1960

1968

1976

1984

1992

2000

1952

1960

1968

1976

1984

1992

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Ratio of inventory-on-hand to sales; chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Excluding defense capital goods.
c. Annualized percent change from previous quarter.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and Congressional Budget Office.

unemployment from falling below the
estimated nonaccelerating inflation
rate of unemployment (NAIRU) would
have reduced current employment by
more than 1,600,000 jobs. During the
same period, real GDP has exceeded
an analogous estimate of the trend
level of potential U.S. economic output. Again, if policies had tried to
keep output rising along its estimated
potential level—and had succeeded—
the cumulative real output forgone
would have been just over $450 billion in 1996 dollars. Despite the suggestion that inflationary pressures
should accompany recent levels of

employment and output, the personal
consumption price index measure of
inflation is near 2.5%.
The election year and recent
debate over budget surpluses have
called attention to the role of
government receipts and expenditures. As a share of GDP, state and
local spending and receipts more
than doubled between the Korean
War and the early 1970s, but have
changed little since then. Federal
spending increased irregularly
during the late 1960s and 1970s, but
the past decade has erased most of
that increase. Likewise, federal

government receipts have grown by
nearly as much as expenditures have
decreased—so much that, for the first
time since 1966, federal receipts
exceeded expenditures for two consecutive years. Patterns in the
combined expenditures of all governments show that the share of federal
nondefense expenditures has risen
slightly over the past half-century.
Most notably, the share of state and
local expenditures has doubled and
the share of federal defense expenditures has declined by half.

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
350

Labor Market Conditions

AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT

Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

300
1997

1998

1999

YTDa

Aug.
2000

Payroll employment
280
Goods-producing
48
Mining
1
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
27
Nondurable goods –2

251
22
–3
37
–12
–2
–11

229
4
–3
25
–18
–6
–12

182
15
1
15
–2
4
–5

–105
–79
0
0
–79
–43
–36

229
20
30
22
120
28

225
16
36
10
124
28

167
4
28
0
108
20

–26
–64
–35
25
160
–122

250
200
150
100

Service-producing
b
TPU
Retail trade
FIREc
Services
Government

50
0
–50

232
16
24
21
141
17

Average for period (percent)

–100

Civilian unemployment

4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

4.1

–150
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

IIQ June July Aug.
2000

8.2

Percent
1.6 YIELD SPREAD: 3-MONTH COMMERCIAL PAPER
MINUS 3-MONTH TREASURY BILL

7.6

1.4

64.0

7.0

1.2

63.5

6.4

1.0

63.0

5.8

0.8

62.5

5.2

0.6

4.6

0.4

4.0

0.2

3.4

0

Percent
65.0

Percent
LABOR MARKET INDICATORS d

64.5
Employment-to-population ratio

62.0

Civilian unemployment rate

61.5
61.0
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Year to date.
b. Transportation and public utilities.
c. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
d. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and The Conference Board, Help-Wanted Advertising Index.

In August, total nonfarm employment registered its largest monthly
decline (105,000) since 1991.
Although private-sector employment
growth has slowed recently, declines
in total nonfarm employment over
the last two months may overstate
the sluggishness of the labor market.
Payroll decreases due to layoffs at
the conclusion of the decennial census are ebbing, and private-sector
payroll growth would have exceeded
100,000 last month (instead of
17,000) if not for the now-resolved
Verizon strike. Another labor market

measure, the unemployment rate,
shows little change. It rose one-tenth
of a percent to 4.1% in August; since
October, it has fluctuated between
3.9% and 4.1%.
Is the labor market really slowing?
A measure of labor demand would
help answer this question; unfortunately, the U.S. has never consistently measured the job vacancy rate.
A proxy gauge of labor demand,
however, is the Help-Wanted Advertising Index, a national average of
the number of job ads appearing in
the newspapers of 51 markets.

In previous business cycles, the
index posted steep increases, quickly
followed by precipitous declines.
The current expansion seemed to
follow this pattern until 1994; since
then, the index has remained fairly
stable. Despite this expansion’s
record length and extremely low
unemployment rate, the index has
not reached levels attained in the
1970s and 1980s. This could reveal
deficiencies in the index because
new technologies such as the Internet have given employers alternative
ways to advertise new jobs.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Market Trends
Percent of total employment
40 NONFARM EMPLOYMENT BY INDUSTRIAL SECTOR, 1949 AND 1999 a
35
1949
1999

30

25

20

15

10

5
0
Manufacturing

Retail

Government

Transportation

Service

Wholesale

FIRE b

Construction

Mining

Productivity Gains, 1970–95
Employment (thousands)
Industry
Railroad transport
Steel
Textiles
Agriculture
Apparel
Coal mining
Manufacturing

1970
633.8
627.0
974.8
3,463.0
1,363.8
145.1
19,367.0

1995
238.4
241.6
663.2
3,440.0
935.8
104.4
18,524.0

Percent change, 1970–95
Employment
–62.4
–61.5
–32.0
–0.7
–31.4
–28.1
–4.4

Output

Productivity
per worker

29
3
62
132
55
59
100

244
197
138
134
126
121
110

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. The agriculture, fishing, and forestry industry is not included because it represents a relatively small share of nonfarm employment.
b. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics and Occupational Safety and Health Administration; and W. Michael Cox and Richard Alm,
Myths of Rich and Poor (New York: Basic Books, 1999).

Among the most striking labormarket trends of the past 50 years is
the shift in employment from the
goods-producing sector to the service sector. Two interrelated forces
have generated this long-term
change in the sectoral composition
of U.S. employment. One is the
changing composition of output, reflecting changes in taste, real
income, and relative prices. The
other is rising labor productivity in
many industries, which resulted
from the application of new

technologies and knowledge, much
of it embedded in modern capital
equipment and better-educated
workers, enabling the introduction
of new products and services.
In the post–World War II years,
manufacturing accounted for approximately one-third of total nonfarm employment, while the service
industry comprised less than 15%.
Fifty years later, the shares are
roughly reversed, with service industries doubled and manufacturing
halved. Mining’s share of employ-

ment, however, fell even more precipitously (75%) than that of manufacturing. As the workforce has
expanded, a larger share of workers
has entered service-producing industries, where solid gains occurred in
the employment shares of retail, government, and finance, insurance, and
real estate. However, wholesale
trade’s share declined slightly, and
the share employed in the transportation and utilities industry was
roughly halved. Sharp productivity
increases over the last 25 years have
(continued on next page)

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Market Trends (cont.)
Thousands
1,600 EMPLOYMENT GROWTH IN
COMPUTER-RELATED OCCUPATIONS

Percent
60 EMPLOYMENT GROWTH, 1993–99

1,400

50
Computer engineers, scientists, and systems analysts

1,200

40
1,000

30
800

20
600
Computer programmers

400

200
1982

10

0
1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

10 INDUSTRIES PROJECTED TO GAIN
THE LARGEST NUMBER OF JOBS, 1998–2008

Total
manufacturing

High-tech
manufacturing

Total services

10 INDUSTRIES PROJECTED TO LOSE
THE LARGEST NUMBER OF JOBS, 1998–2008

Computer and data processing services

Apparel manufacturing

Personnel supply

Federal government

Eating and drinking places

Weaving, finishing, yarn, and thread mills

State and local government education

Crude petroleum and natural gas extraction

State and local general government

Blast furnaces and basic steel products

Offices of physicians

Electric services

Home health care services

Motor vehicle manufacturing

Educational services, private

Railroad transportation

Management and public relations services

Clothing and accessories stores

Nursing and personal care facilites

0

500

1,000

High-tech services

Newspapers

1,500

2,000

–200

–150

–100

–50

0

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

allowed some industries to expand
output while reducing employment.
Between 1970 and 1995, overall
manufacturing employment dropped
almost 5%, but manufacturing output
doubled, constituting a 110% increase in productivity per worker.
Within the manufacturing sector, output per worker has increased 197%
in the steel industry over the last 25
years, 138% in the textile industry,
and 126% in apparel.

These huge productivity gains
have not been limited to the goodsproducing sector. Railroad employment, a subset of the transportation
industry, fell more than 60% during
the 1970–95 period, but productivity
per worker soared 244%. With such
employment shifts over time, increased productivity expands the set
of goods available for consumption.
Growth in high-tech employment
is one trend that highlights the shift

from a labor-intensive, goods-producing economy to one dependent
on human capital and service production. The U.S. has experienced
great technological gains in the
1990s, and, as expected, high-tech
employment growth has far outpaced the rest of the economy. A
look at computer-related occupations
over the last 15 years reveals remarkable growth: While the number of
computer programmers increased
(continued on next page)

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Market Trends (cont.)
PENNSYLVANIA PROJECTED JOBS GROWTH, 1994–2005

OHIO PROJECTED JOBS GROWTH, 1996–2006
Other computer scientists

Personal and home care aides
Electronic pagination system workers

Computer engineers
Computer systems analysts

Computer engineers

Computer support specialists

Systems analysts

Database administrators

Home health aides

Desktop publishing specialists

Human services workers

Paralegal personnel

Preschool and kindergarten teachers

Medical assistants

Computer support specialists

Physical, corrective therapy assistants

Physical therapists

All other therapists

0

20

40

60

Residential counselors

80
100
Percent growth

120

140

160

180

50

55

60

65

85

90

Telemarketers, door-to-door sales

Physical and corrective therapy assistant aides

Computer engineers

Personal and home care aides

Systems analysts

Computer support specialists

Paralegals

Systems analysts

Hotel desk clerks

Physical therapists

Personal/home care aides

Medical assistants

Cleaners/servants, private

Paralegals

Musicians

Home health aides

Artists/commercial artists

Surgical technologists
Dental hygienists

60

80

WEST VIRGINIA PROJECTED JOBS GROWTH, 1996–2006

KENTUCKY PROJECTED JOBS GROWTH, 1996–2006

50

75
70
Percent growth

Counter and rental clerks

70

80
Percent growth

90

100

30

60

90
120
Percent growth

150

180

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCES: Commonwealth of Kentucky, Workforce Development Cabinet, Labor Market Information Division, Research and Statistics Branch, Kentucky
Occupational Outlook to 2006; State of Ohio, Bureau of Employment Services, Labor Market Information Division, Ohio Job Outlook to 2006; Commonwealth of
Pennsylvania, Department of Labor and Industry, Bureau of Research and Statistics, Pennsylvania Workforce 2005; State of West Virginia, Bureau of
Employment Programs, Department of Research, Information, and Analysis, Occupational Projections:1996 to 2006.

52% in the 1983–98 period, the number of computer engineers, scientists,
and systems analysts dwarfed this figure, registering 421% growth over the
same period. Just as overall employment growth in the service-producing sector has exceeded that of the
goods-producing sector, high-tech
service jobs have grown roughly 12
times as fast as those in manufacturing since 1993.
Projections for the U.S. and the
Fourth District suggest that the shift

in employment share from goods
production to service production
will continue. Nationally, the 10 industries projected to gain the most
jobs in 1998–2008 will be in the
service-producing sector (seven in
services, two in government, and
one in retail trade). Estimates for the
Fourth District indicate an identical
trend: Each state projects its 10
fastest-growing job categories will
be in the service-producing sector.

States’ projections for occupation
growth show two noteworthy trends.
First, the high-tech industry is
expected to continue growing at a
phenomenal rate. Of particular interest is the trend in Ohio, where hightech jobs are projected to account for
the six fastest-growing occupations
in the 1994–2005 period. Second, the
health care industry is projected to
see large growth as well: In Kentucky, it will comprise seven of the
10 fastest-growing occupations.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Federal Home Loan Banks
Billions of dollars
600 LIABILITIES

Billions of dollars
500 ASSETS
450

Advances
Investments
Other assets

400

Deposits and borrowings
Consolidated obligations
Other liabilities

500

350

400

300
300

250
200

200

150
100

100

50
0

0
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996 1997

1998 1999

1991

2000

1992

1993

1994

1995

1998

1999

Cash and due
from banks
2%
Fixed assets
1%

7

Capital
Capital/assets

30
All other assets
1%

2000

Percent
8

35

Net mortgage
loans
48%

1997

Billions of dollars
40
CAPITAL

COMPOSITION OF OTHER ASSETS

Interest
receivable
48%

1996

6

25

5

20

4

15

3

10

2

5

1

0

0
1991

1992 1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998 1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCE: Federal Home Loan Bank System, Quarterly Financial Report, June 30, 2000, and annual reports.

The 12 Federal Home Loan Banks
are stock-chartered, governmentsponsored
enterprises
whose
original mission was to provide
short-term advances to member
institutions, funded by deposits
from those institutions. Membership
was open to specialized housingfinance lenders, mostly savings and
loan associations and mutual
savings banks. As their traditional
clientele has shrunk and the financial system has consolidated, the
FHLB system has reinvented its role

in financial markets. FHLB advances
now represent an important funding
source for member institutions’
mortgage portfolios, having risen to
$436 billion by the end of 1999:IIQ
and far outstripping all other FHLB
investments and assets.
The lion’s share of funding for
FHLB assets came from $564 billion in
consolidated obligations of the FHLB
system—bonds issued on behalf of the
12 banks collectively. The market
views these bonds as implicitly backed
by the U.S. government; hence, FHLBs

can raise funds at rates of return below
those paid by AAA-rated corporations.
Member institutions’ deposits and
short-term borrowings, along with
other liabilities, contributed few funds.
FHLBs have added to their capital as
they have grown, although the pace of
asset growth has outstripped capital
growth since 1996, and the capital-toasset ratio fell to 4.9% by mid-2000.
In 1997, the FHLB of Chicago initiated the Mortgage Partnership
Finance Program, whereby it invests
directly in mortgages, in addition to

(continued on next page)

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Federal Home Loan Banks (cont.)
Millions of dollars
2,500 EARNINGS

Millions of dollars
3,000 COMPOSITION OF INCOME
2,500

2,000
Net interest income

2,000

Net noninterest income

1,500

1,500

1,000
1,000
500

0

500

–500
–1,000

0
1991 1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000 a

Percent

1991

1992

1993

1994 1995

0.8 PROFITABILITY

Percent
12 RETURN ON EQUITY

0.7

10

1996

1997 1998 1999

2000 a

Ratio
24

Return on equity

0.6

20

Equity multiplier b

8

16

6

12

0.4

4

8

0.3

2

4

Net interest margin
0.5
Return on assets

0.2

0
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997 1998

1999

2000

0
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

a. Data through first half of year.
b. Equity multiplier is the ratio of total assets to equity.
SOURCE: Federal Home Loan Bank System, Quarterly Financial Report, June 30, 2000, and annual reports.

supporting members’ own portfolios
through advances. Currently, most
FHLBs offer this program; the
$10.4 billion in mortgages that they
hold represents almost half of their
other assets. This portfolio is projected to be a major source of asset
growth for FHLBs and it represents a
significant departure from their
original mission.
FHLB’s earnings have grown
steadily since 1994. Their $1,059 million in net income for the first half of
2000 compares favorably to $974 million for the first half of 1999. Break-

ing down earnings into interest and
noninterest sources reveals that, like
commercial banks and savings and
loans, FHLBs’ earnings come primarily from net interest income (interest
income less interest expense). Net interest income grew steadily from
$735 million in 1992 to $2,533 million
at the end of 1999; for the first half of
2000 it measured $1,581 million, up
from $1,163 million for the same
period in 1999.
A steady increase in operating
expenses, especially in employee
compensation and benefits, has

driven an increasingly negative
spread between noninterest income
and noninterest expense since 1993.
Improvements in earnings and net
interest income have resulted from
strong asset growth rather than
improvements in underlying profitability. Return on assets declined
during the 1990s from 75 basis
points (bp) in 1991 to 36 bp at the
end of 1999. The annualized return
on assets through 2000:IIQ is 34 bp.
The net interest margin rose from
44 bp at the end of 1999 to 52 bp
in mid-2000, still a far cry from the
(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Federal Home Loan Banks (cont.)
Billions of dollars
500
ADVANCES
450

Thousands of borrowers
6
BORROWERS

Commercial banks
Thrifts
All other

400

5
Commercial banks
Thrifts
All other

350
4
300
250

3

200
2

150
100

1
50
0

0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Thousands of members
8
MEMBERSHIP

1996

1997

1998

2000

CAPITAL

Commercial banks
Thrifts
All other

7

1999

All other
4%

6

5
Thrifts
51%

4

Commercial
banks
45%

3

2

1
0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCE: Federal Home Loan Bank System, Quarterly Financial Report, June 30, 2000, and annual reports.

69 bp margin earned in 1991 and
the 300–400 bp margins typical of
depository institutions.
Despite continued increases in
leverage since 1996, return on
equity fell to 7.02% in the first half of
2000 from 7.33% at the end of 1999.
Such persistently weak returns on
assets and equity have put further
pressure on FHLBs to undertake
nontraditional lines of business.
The FHLBs’ changing role is
evident in its membership, which
has increased steadily to a record

7,594 institutions at the end of
2000:IIQ. Notably, commercial
banks now represent 73% of members, numbering 5,526 at midyear.
Thrift institution membership continues to decline, reflecting the
consolidation of the thrift industry.
Another 486 members were drawn
from other housing lenders, including credit unions and insurance
companies, up nearly 10% at the
end of June from the beginning of
the year.
Nevertheless, thrifts
remain the heaviest users of FHLB

advances, accounting for 58% of the
$436.6 billion in advances at midyear. Advances to commercial banks
have increased over the past five
years, reaching $175 billion at
2000:IIQ. Provisions of the Financial
Modernization Act of 1999 allow
FHLBs to make advances against
community banks’ small business
loan portfolios, which should stimulate banks’ use of advances in the
future.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The U.S.Trade Deficit
Billions of dollars
5 TRADE BALANCE

Billions of dollars
20 TRADE BALANCES: GOODS AND SERVICES

0
10
–5

Net trade in services
0

–10

–15

–10

–20
–20
Net trade in goods
–25
–30
–30
–35

–40
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

1992

2000

1993

1994

1995

12-month percent change
3.75
PCE CHAIN-TYPE PRICE INDEX AND CPI
3.50

Foreign currency per dollar

3.25

10

12

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Yen per dollar
160

FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES

140
CPI, all items

Japanese yen

3.00
2.75

120

8
100

2.50

Mexican peso
FOMC
central
tendency
projections
as of July
2000 c

2.25
2.00
1.75

80

6

60
4

1.50

40

1.25

2
PCE Chain-Type Price Index

20

1.00

Canadian dollar

0.75
1995

0

0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The monthly U.S. trade deficit has
been essentially unchanged since
March, with a slight decline in the
services surplus offset by a slight decline in the goods deficit. This June’s
deficit of $30.6 billion was about 25%
larger than last June’s. If monthly
deficits for the rest of 2000 were
somehow to remain at this level, the
annual deficit would be only 36%
greater than in 1999. Last year’s
deficit exceeded 1998’s by 59%.
The deficit with Canada, our
largest trading partner, was $4.3 billion, 50% more than a year ago.
The exchange rate with Canada,
however, has remained relatively

stable. With Mexico, our secondlargest trading partner, the deficit
was $2.3 billion, 9% more than a
year ago. The exchange rate with
Mexico also changed little from a
year ago but is somewhat volatile.
The June deficit with Japan was
$6.3 billion, slightly less than a year
ago; the exchange rate, while stable
in recent months, has depreciated
somewhat in the past year.
A country that runs a trade deficit
is absorbing—through consumption
and investment—more of the world’s
resources than it is producing. Such a
country also is spending beyond its
current income and must borrow

from abroad to finance its expenditures. This economic fact of life guarantees that a nation’s net inflow of
foreign capital will always exactly
match its current-account deficit.
To understand the competitiveness
of U.S. goods and services in foreign
markets, it is important to gauge
movements in the dollar’s value.
Because the dollar often appreciates
against some currencies and depreciates against others, economists construct weighted-average indexes of
exchange rates to gain an overall perspective. Usually, the weights reflect
trade shares between countries. The
Major Currency Index (MCI), for
(continued on next page)

19
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The U.S.Trade Deficit (cont.)
Index, March 1973 = 100
110 TRADE-WEIGHTED EXCHANGE VALUE OF THE U.S. DOLLAR (MAJOR CURRENCY INDEX)
105

100
Real
95

90
Nominal
85

80

75
12/95

6/96

12/96

6/97

12/97

6/98

12/98

6/99

12/99

6/00

TRADE-WEIGHTED EXCHANGE VALUE OF THE U.S. DOLLAR (OTHER IMPORTANT TRAINING PARTNERS INDEX)

FRB Cleveland • September 2000

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

example, includes currencies heavily
traded in financial markets like those
of the G-10, the euro area, and Australia. The Other Important Trading
Partners (OITP) Index reflects movements of the dollar against currencies
of U.S. trading partners in Asia, Latin
America, Eastern Europe, and the
Middle East. Adjusting for inflation
differentials between the U.S. and its
trading partners provides indexes of
the dollar’s average real value in
foreign trade.
A country may incur a trade deficit
in various ways, each with different
implications for its exchange rate.

If ebullient domestic demand alone
were responsible for widening the
deficit, the dollar would depreciate as
the deficit widened. But while the
U.S. trade deficit has been growing
steadily since 1997, the value of the
dollar has not declined in currency
markets. That is, despite the increasing net flow of dollars to be exchanged with foreign currencies in
trade, the foreign currency price of
dollars has not generally declined.
Both the MCI and the OITP indexes of the dollar’s value have
appreciated slightly this year and
significantly since 1997. This real

appreciation suggests that, despite
the growing deficit, U.S. goods and
services are becoming less pricecompetitive abroad, while foreign
goods grow more price-competitive
in the U.S. This is not all bad, if demand in the U.S. essentially exceeds
our economy’s productive capacity.
Dollar appreciation suggests that
investment opportunities in the U.S.
have attracted an increasing inflow of
foreign capital. This demand for dollars brings appreciation that makes
foreign goods less expensive than
domestic ones.