View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective
Someday, perhaps, remembering even this
Will be a pleasure.
—Virgil, The Aeneid

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland moved to
its present location 75 years ago, in September
1923. The date holds special significance because
we have just completed a substantial renovation
of our building, making it a safer, more efficient
working environment than it has been in
decades. At the same time, thanks to careful historic restoration, some portions of the building
once again reveal the magnificent craftsmanship
devoted to them three-quarters of a century ago.
It seems particularly fitting that a Federal Reserve Bank should occupy an updated, but still
historic, building. Monetary policy requires a
keen understanding of current economic conditions and, equally important, the ability to operate from a solid foundation and with a perspective on the past. The economy of 1998 clearly
differs from that of 1923, but not in every respect.
Recognizing the similarities may prove just as important for fashioning successful monetary policy
as appreciating the differences.
Our economy’s infrastructure has changed
enormously since 1923. Comparing jet planes, interstate highways, and wireless telecommunications to their predecessors leaves little doubt
about the relative productivity and safety levels of
the two economies. Seventy-five years ago, our
nation used a much greater share of its land,
labor, and capital for agricultural and mining industries; the phrase “service economy” would
have drawn blank stares. Women were seen less
in the workplace, and the workweek was much
longer. This is just the beginning of the list we
could compile.
Policymaking was different as well. In 1923,
the federal government’s role in the economy
was much smaller than it is today, in terms of
both fiscal size and regulatory presence. Budgets
were balanced, and private property rights were
very strong. Although the Federal Reserve System
had been created in 1914, the value of the dollar
in 1923 was still keyed to the gold standard. Activist monetary and fiscal policies were more than

three decades away. In fact, Congress would not
establish the Federal Open Market Committee for
10 more years; the Federal Reserve Banks were
just beginning to comprehend the effect of their
individual open market operations on banking
and credit conditions.
But what about the similarities? How could we
possibly liken today’s economy to that of the
early 1920s? Let’s begin with people and the
human condition. As the United States became
industrialized, it developed a large middle class
and with it a consumer-oriented economy. Then,
as now, whatever our standard of living, Americans have always wanted to consume more. Fortunately, our desire for a higher standard of living
is matched by our resolve to create wealth and an
unshakable belief in the notion of human
progress. Accompanying this “can-do” attitude is
a culture that encourages risk-taking. But the
world is a risky place, and our successes in hedging against some of its perils tempt us to imagine
that we can avoid them all.
Economists have learned a great deal since
1923 about how economic systems work and
how policies affect their operation. Nevertheless,
our opinions should be rendered with humility,
for even the wisest among us can claim only an
imperfect understanding of our economy’s workings. Who among the officials present at the dedication ceremony of the Cleveland Federal Reserve Bank in September 1923 could have
foreseen the economy’s trajectory over the ensuing decade? Who among them could have suspected that history would revile them as shortsighted—or worse? They undoubtedly had critics
among their contemporaries as well, as do
today’s policymakers. And we try, as they did, to
do our best with what we know and what we
think we know.
Confidence in our nation’s future abounded
when the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
opened its new doors in 1923. Seventy-five years
later, we can see that this confidence was justified, despite the Great Depression, despite World
War II, despite the Cold War, and despite the
stagflation and malaise of the 1970s. All the reasons that justified this confidence then still justify
it today.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Chicago Board of Trade; and DRI/McGraw–Hill.

Over the past several years, the
Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) collectively has seen little
basis for taking action. The FOMC
last changed the fed funds rate objective in March 1997, increasing it a
scant 25 basis points. This increase
was preceded by a rate cut of the
same magnitude in February 1996.
Thus, for almost three years, the
FOMC has instructed its Trading
Desk to add or drain base money in
order to maintain the fed funds rate
at or just under 5½%. As recently as
the end of August, fed funds futures
prices suggested that the outlook for
the funds rate was more of the same.

Such a long period of passive policy tactics, rare by historical standards, largely reflects the unusual
combination of a long economic expansion and a moderately declining
inflation rate. These favorable circumstances are in part the fruit of a
deliberate policy strategy that recognizes price stability as essential for a
healthy economy.
The FOMC’s strategy for achieving price stability has yielded an environment in which private investment decisions are made on the
basis of economic merit, not as a
hedge against inflation. As a consequence, corporate profits have been

extraordinary in recent years. The
earnings for Standard and Poors
(S&P) 500 companies, for example,
have grown at double-digit rates
over most of the current expansion.
This strong earnings growth provided the fundamental impetus for
the stock market's favorable performance in recent years.
While much of the stock market
increase was based on improved
earnings, a good part was based on
expectations of a sustained continuation of extraordinary earnings
growth enabled by a robust economy. This optimism was evident in
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. Annualized growth rate for 1998 is calculated on an estimated
August over 1997:IVQ basis.
b. Straight lines represent levels and breaks estimated using the opportunity cost of M2, time, and M2 velocity lagged one quarter as regressors with fixed
coefficients.
NOTE: Data are seasonally adjusted. Last plots for M2 and MZM are estimated for August 1998. For M2, dotted lines are FOMC-determined provisional
ranges. For MZM, dotted lines represent growth levels and are for reference only.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland; and DRI/McGraw–Hill.

the price-earnings ratio, which
reached historical highs. A belief
that the strong domestic economy
could continue to be insulated from
the turmoil occurring in Asia was reinforced by output growth that
showed no signs of slowing through
1998:Q1.
Recent weeks, however, have
produced other concerns. Stock
markets in Russia and elsewhere in
Eastern Europe have fallen precipitously. The markets of Asia continue
to slide. The drop of nearly 20% in

the S&P 500 stock index since its
peak in July suggests that investors
have begun to doubt the continued
insularity of the U.S. economy in the
face of world financial crises. Stock
market corrections of around 20%
are rare, but three of them have occurred in the past 11 years. Little is
known about the mechanisms that
precipitate such large corrections.
Moreover, they are not identifiable
until after they have occurred.
One potential problem would be
an accelerating world financial crisis

that leads to extraordinary demands
for liquidity within the U.S. When
such circumstances have occurred
before (as in 1987), the Fed has
stood ready to supply all legitimate
needs. At this point, however, liquidity appears to be sufficient. MZM
measures domestic asset holdings
which have zero maturity and hence
are available on short notice. MZM
has grown more than 10% in 1998.
The broader M2 money measure has
increased more than 7% for the year.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy, 1923

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Currency held by the public plus bank vault cash.
b. Money income divided by money stock (currency plus demand deposits).
SOURCE: Robert Shiller, Market Volatility. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989; Standard and Poors Security Price Index Record; and Milton Friedman and Anna
Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States 1867–1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963, pp. 774–802.

In 1923, the staff of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland moved into
a newly dedicated building with
fresh responsibilities, for in the
spring of that year the Federal Reserve Board had officially recognized
the Banks’ Open Market Committee.
For the first time, Reserve Bank officials had a forum in which they
could collectively exert a definite,
conscious influence on economic
developments. The tactics by which
the Committee could affect credit
conditions had only recently been
developed.
The celebrated economist Irving

Fisher later recounted how these
powers were accidentally discovered: In an effort to increase earning
assets in the early 1920s, the 12
Reserve Banks began to purchase
government securities in the open
market. To their surprise, profits declined. They soon realized that these
purchases lowered the volume of rediscounting and increased the level
of member bank deposits, depressing Reserve Bank income by more
than the income earned on purchased securities. Most importantly,
they recognized that the consequence of increased reserve deposits
was an expansion in credit.

The strategy of policy then sought
to mitigate the inflationary effects of
excessive gold imports. Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz noted, in
their Monetary History of the United
States, 1867–1960, that great emphasis was placed on the distinction between “productive” and “speculative” uses of credit. There was
concern that credit expansion might
finance a “speculative accumulation
of commodity stocks, which in turn
would produce a disequilibrium between production and consumption
and subsequently a contraction in
prices and economic activity.”

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Interest Rates

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. All instruments are constant-maturity series.
b. Estimate of the yield on a recently offered, A-rated utility bond with a maturity of 30 years and call protection of five years.
c. Bond Buyer Index, general obligation, 20 years to maturity, mixed quality.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and historical data from Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Banking and
Monetary Statistics. Washington, D.C.: National Capital Press, 1943.

All along the maturity spectrum, interest rates have moved lower in the
past month. Longer rates fell the
most, however, producing a noticeable flattening of the yield curve.
The 3-year, 3-month spread, for example, dropped from 41 basis points
to 2 basis points because the 3-year
rate fell 43 basis points and the 3month rate dropped only 4 basis
points. Likewise, the 10-year, 3month spread dropped from 43 to
17 basis points. Some analysts have
ascribed these lower rates to a flight
to quality, as investors became

worried about both domestic and
foreign investments.
The geopolitical nature of such
risks—think of East Asia, Russia, and
the effects of counter-terrorist strikes
—virtually demands a historical perspective, one befitting the 75th anniversary of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland’s building. When
this Italianate palazzo was first dedicated in 1923, interest rates had seen
a long downward trend as the inflationary disruption of World War I
gave way to the relative normalcy of
the Roaring Twenties. In September
1923, the Monthly Business Review, a

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
publication, noted “slightly firmer
tendencies in money rates.” But
short-term rates on U.S. government
bills still had plenty of ups and
downs left in them; indeed, from the
historical perspective of those days,
recent shifts look rather tame.
Longer-term capital market rates
show intriguing similarities and differences across the years. Long-term
Treasury bonds now yield more than
municipal bonds, while public utility
bond rates remain much higher than
either of them, most likely indicating
a continuing risk difference.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Rates

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

NOTE: All data are quarterly and extend through 1998:IIQ.
a. S&P 500 stock index.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and DRI/McGraw–Hill.

Since the beginning of the 1980s,
the personal savings rate (the ratio
of personal savings to disposable
personal income) has steadily declined. Monthly estimates show this
seemingly alarming trend continuing, with the personal savings rate
falling to 0.1% in June, the lowest
level on record. July’s number (0.8%),
though slightly better, is still paltry.
Before becoming too alarmed,
however, we should consider how
useful a measure the personal savings rate really is. People save, after
all, to increase the stock of resources
from which they or their heirs can
enjoy future consumption. We tradi-

tionally think of this as setting aside
a portion of money income in financial assets. There are other ways to
save, however; one is to purchase
durable goods. In fact, there has been
a sharp rise recently in consumer
expenditures on durable goods.
These are counted as consumption
in the official measure; therefore, to
correctly account for savings, a fraction of durable goods purchased
using disposable personal income
should be added to the personal
savings rate. Another way to save is
to enjoy capital gains on existing
assets. These gains, made greater (at
least until recently) by the strength

of the stock market, should be added
to both income and savings, which
would also raise the savings rate.
More fundamentally, the personal
savings rate is just too narrow a
measure to capture the source of
capital accumulation in the U.S. A
more relevant statistic is net national
savings, which combines the savings
behavior of households, businesses,
and governments. In this case, the
news is better, with the second quarter net national savings number
maintaining a level comparable to
what has been observed over the
past 15 years.

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices, 1998 and 1923
July Price Statistics
Annualized percent
change, last:
5 yr.

1997
avg.

1.7

2.5

1.7

2.1

2.2

2.6

2.2

3.0

2.8

2.8

3.0

2.9

Finished goods

2.8

1.2

–0.3

0.9

–1.2

Less food
and energy

1.7

2.3

1.1

1.0

0.0

Commodity futures
pricesc
–36.5 –30.4 –16.2

–1.4

–3.5

1 mo.

3 mo.

All items

2.2

2.2

Less food
and energy

2.1

Mediana,b

12 mo.

Consumer Prices

Producer Prices

2000

FRB Cleveland •September 1998

a. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
b. The median CPI component structure and market basket were updated in May 1998, and the weighting scheme was revised.
c. As measured by the KR–CRB composite futures index, all commodities. Data reprinted with permission of the Commodity Research Bureau, a Knight–Ridder
Business Information Service.
d. Upper and lower bounds for CPI inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
e. January 1997–July 1998.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and the Commodity Research Bureau.

Consumer prices continue to hover
just under the lower bound of the
FOMC central tendency established
in July 1998, with the Consumer
Price Index (CPI) rising an annualized 2.2% in July. The median CPI,
an alternative measure of core inflation, continues to hold around the
2.8% (annualized) mark. Shifting
focus to wholesale prices, recent
Producer Price Index (PPI) data
show some upward pressure, rising
at a 2.8% annualized rate in July.
Several components used to calculate the CPI have shown relatively

large price movements over the last
18 months. By and large, these have
offset one another, although the
extreme price declines have generally represented a greater share of
the market basket than have the
extreme increases. In the first category, the energy components have
plummeted more than 11% (annual
rate). In the second, prices for many
foods, such as fresh fruits and vegetables, have moved sharply higher
over the last 18 months.
Before the Federal Reserve
was established in 1913, and cer-

tainly before it achieved any wellorchestrated management of credit
markets (which occurred about 10
years later), “monetary policy” was
based on the establishment of a single price-level objective — the price
of gold. Money stocks were adjusted
to keep the price of gold at a nearly
constant $20.64 per ounce. Indeed,
students of money and banking are
often surprised by the stability in
gold prices over the period economists call “the gold standard,” until
they understand that gold “defined”
(continued on next page)

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices, 1998 and 1923 (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. The lines break in 1919 due to a change in the definition of the gold series.
SOURCES: Office of the Director of the Mint, Annual Report, 1944; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; National Industrial Conference Board, Inc.,
The Cost of Living in the United States, 1914 – 26. New York: National Industrial Conference Board, Inc., 1927, pp. 158–59; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau
of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970, part 2. Washington, D.C.: 1975, p.164; and Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz,
A Monetary History of the United States, 1867– 1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963, pp. 704–22.

a dollar. But it was only the price of
gold that was stabilized, as is suggested by wide swings in the price
of gold relative to the price of
another precious metal, silver.
But stabilizing the stock of
money relative to gold does not
necessarily stabilize money’s power
to purchase other goods and services, particularly over short time
horizons. Of course, during the
early years of the Federal Reserve
System, the market basket purchased by most households was
more limited than it is today. In
1923, food accounted for roughly

40% of the CPI market basket, compared with only about 15% today.
Still, the dollar cost of a representative market basket fluctuated widely
during those years. Some analysts,
like the noted economist Irving
Fisher, urged the Fed to stabilize an
index for the price of a broadly defined basket of goods and services.
It was also around this time that
the Federal Reserve System began to
fully appreciate the impact it could
have on national credit markets —
and, presumably, on industry and
trade—through open market operations. Between 1913 and 1923, the
System allowed the growth rate of

the money stock to rise at twice the
pace of the previous 10-year period,
and this expansion appears to have
been accompanied by a stronger
pace of real income growth. But the
period also saw a sharp rise in
prices (which averaged about a 5½%
annual rate during the first 10 years
of the Federal Reserve System, compared with only about a 1% pace
during the previous 10-year period).
Cutting back on the expansion of
money in the 1923 –29 period, the
System witnessed a falloff in the
growth of business activity, along
with a flattening of prices.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity—Past and Present
a

Real GDP and Components, 1998:IIQ
(Preliminary estimate)
Change,
billions
of 1992 $

Real GDP
Consumer spending
Durables
Nondurables
Services
Business fixed
investment
Equipment
Structures
Residential investment
Government spending
National defense
Net exports
Exports
Imports
Change in business
inventories

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

30.2
72.2
18.8
18.5
36.0

1.6
5.8
11.0
5.0
5.2

3.6
5.2
11.5
4.2
4.4

28.0
31.4
–2.3
10.5
11.6
6.8
–47.8
–19.0
28.8

12.6
18.1
– 4.5
14.8
3.7
9.6
—
–7.4
10.0

13.2
17.8
0.8
9.4
0.8
–3.7
—
1.0
11.3

– 52.3

—

—

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1992 dollars.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, August 10, 1998.

New estimates of gross domestic
product for 1998:IIQ revealed nothing new about the economy. Preliminary real GDP growth was 0.2%
higher than in the advance estimate.
This reflected slight upward adjustments in a number of components,
largely offset by small downward
adjustments to imports and inventory investment. It remains the case
that GDP growth declined sharply
from the 5.5% pace of the first quarter to 1.6% in the second. Two-thirds
of this reduction can be attributed to
slower inventory accumulation,
which increased less than half the

first-quarter amount. The rest of
the slowing in GDP can be traced to
less rapid increases in investment
spending for producers’ durable
equipment, including informationprocessing equipment. Forecasters
expect some pickup in GDP growth
through this year and next, but only
at a subdued pace.
Consistent with these forecasts,
real final demand (GDP minus inventories) remained strong, growing
0.1% more than the 4.3% first-quarter
annual rate, despite the drop in GDP
growth. More recently, both retail
sales and retail trade inventories

have declined, but this probably
reflects the influence on the automotive sector of the now-settled
General Motors strike, not any slowing in consumer demand. For the
third consecutive quarter, business
investment in structures grew more
slowly than final demand. While
producers’ durable equipment expenditures increased less rapidly than
in the first quarter, they remain quite
strong at four times the growth rate
of final demand. Residential construction showed a similar pattern,
increasing more than three times
more rapidly than final demand.
(continued on next page)

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity—Past and Present (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census,
Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970, part 2. Washington, D.C., 1975; and National Association of Realtors.

Sales of new houses remained
strong in July. Moreover, exuberant
sales (and purchases) of existing
homes continued to show evidence
of shifts in housing asset portfolios
analogous to those evident in financial markets. In July, sales of existing
homes reached a new all-time peak.
The U.S. economy hit a businesscycle peak in May of 1923, the year
this Bank’s main building was dedicated. That peak was followed by a
short, mild contraction that ended in
July of the next year. Still, the U.S.
was in the midst of a construction
boom. Downtown areas of many

cities were undergoing major expansion of office space. Cleveland was
in the forefront of U.S. industrial development, building on a base of
petroleum refining, iron and steel
production, automobiles and parts,
and machine tools.
The site chosen for the Cleveland
Bank adjoined a massive planned
development of splendid governmental structures grouped around a
huge public esplanade. Nearby was
the Terminal Tower project, a gigantic complex that included large office buildings, a hotel, and a department store, all atop the new railroad
and interurban trolley terminal.

In the mid-1920s, housing starts in
the nation shot up to levels that were
unequaled until the release of pentup demand created by the Great Depression and World War II. Suburban
housing developments like Shaker
Heights epitomized inner-ring suburbs, catering to a growing uppermiddle class that appreciated thirdfloor maid’s quarters and two-car
garages. The economic contraction
of 1924 produced a slight dip in the
level of GNP, but the “new era” of
“permanent prosperity” soon seemed
to have resumed.

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Labor Market Conditionsa
Monthly average change
(thousands of employees)

1995

1996

1998
Year to August
1997 date

185
8
-1
2
10

233
31
3
0
28

282 237 365
42
4 109
21 -15
95
3
-2 117
20
22
16

Service-producing
178
Services
112
Government
9
Household employment 32

202
117
9
232

240 233 256
142 115 135
20
26
57
240
49 101

Payroll employment
Goods-producing
Manufacturing
Motor vehicles
Construction

Average for period

Civilian unemployment
rate (%)
5.6 5.4
Diffusion index
(3 month)
57.8 64.0

5.0

4.5

4.5

65.8 62.5 58.0

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Seasonally adjusted.
b. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

August’s nonfarm employment
growth was exceptional (365,000),
partly because of workers’ return
after the General Motors strike. Despite this headline statistic, however,
there is increasing evidence that
labor market growth is slowing. Removing the effects of the GM strike,
the goods-producing sector has
added only 4,000 jobs over the last
eight months. In recent months, the
number of industries showing employment growth has declined
markedly. The current diffusion

index for nonfarm payrolls shows
that only 58% of detailed industries
experienced employment gains over
a three-month period, versus 72% as
recently as December 1997.
Interestingly, the household survey (used to calculate the unemployment rate) registered the slowing more immediately. While the
payroll employment series has continued to show growth in most
months, household employment
has not shown any statistically significant employment gain for the

last several months. The household
survey’s weaker measured employment growth halted the downward
trend in the unemployment rate.
Unemployment fell to 4.3% in May
and has since risen to 4.5%. Typically, the payroll and household series do not deviate for many
months, but no firm explanation for
this deviation has yet been offered.
Productivity growth has also
slowed. In the latest quarter, the
increase was only 0.1% for nonfarm
businesses.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets of the 1920s
Labor Market Conditionsa
Monthly average change
(thousands of employees)

1921

Payroll employment
Goods-producing
Mining
Construction
Manufacturing

1922 1923 1924 1925

–247 120 214 –30
–210 84 126 –54
–23 –3 24 –9
14 14
4
8
–200 72 98 –52

62
32
–1
10
22

Service-producing
Transportation
and public utilities
Wholesale and
retail trade
Government

–38
–45

37
4

88
31

25
–6

30
2

10

26

32

10

14

–6

1

6

9

7

Manufacturing
workweek (hours)a

43.1 44.2 45.6 43.7 44.5

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Includes all production workers in Manufacturing.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United
States: Colonial Times to 1970, part 2. Washington, D.C., 1975.

Looking back to the labor markets
of the 1920s requires using annual
estimates derived much later, which
somewhat reduces the accuracy of
the data. These estimates show that
the labor market was booming in
1923, as the economy recovered
from the large employment declines
experienced two years earlier (3
million jobs lost). While the net gain
for 1923 (214,000 workers per
month) is quite similar to recent increases, it was added to a far
smaller labor force. At the time, this
number of workers expanded the
nation’s employment almost 10%; in
contrast, adding an average 237,000

workers a month over the year ending August 1998 increased payroll
employment only 3%. Note that in
the 1920s, the manufacturing sector
(36% of nonfarm payroll employment in 1923) accounted for almost
half of the employment changes.
Manufacturing today plays a small
role in total jobs growth.
The fact that employment was
much more volatile in the 1920s
showed in unemployment rates,
which frequently averaged less than
4% for the year. Economists would
expect low unemployment rates in
this period, partly because the unemployment insurance system now

in use was initially funded as part of
the Social Security Act of 1935. The
lack of unemployment insurance
makes the 1921 unemployment rate
(over 10%) far more alarming than
the high unemployment rates of
later years.
Productivity growth was stronger
(10-year average growth was 2% in
the 1920s, compared to only 1%
over the 10 years ended 1998:IIQ)
but erratic. Between 1921 and 1922,
annual productivity growth fell from
over 8% to below – 2%. Change of
this magnitude has been unknown
in the post-World War II era.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inventories, Imports, and Output

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Annual rate, percent
b. Deviations from trend, percent.
c. High import growth is defined as more than 12.6%, which is twice the sample mean.
d. High import levels are 3% above their trend.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Substantial inventory accumulation
and a surge in imports have accompanied the strong GDP growth of
the last two years. Throughout this
period, some analysts have warned
that the inventory buildup signals
a substantial slowdown in output growth — perhaps even a
recession — as firms respond to a
perceived inventory “overhang” by
cutting back production. Other
commentators have suggested that
if the buildup is largely composed
of imported goods, then the
implications for future output

growth may be less dire, since a
smaller overhang would exist for
domestic firms.
A fundamental problem with this
argument is that historical data do
not support its basic premise: that
high inventory investment consistently precedes slow—or negative—
future output growth. In fact, the relationship between high inventory
investment and future output growth
is very cloudy, whether one looks at
the next quarter or the next year.
Though unable to see a clear relationship between inventory invest-

ment and future output growth, we
can still ask whether that relationship is influenced by a strong surge
in imports. The answer is “not
much.” If anything, a surge in imports portends stronger output
growth than occurs in periods with
no such surge. Of course, high import growth does not imply that the
inventory buildup is in imported
goods. Examining how the import
composition of inventories affects
future output growth would require
much more detailed data.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Regional Conditions in the 1920s
Employment by Occupation Groups, 1920a
(percent)
KY

OH

PA

WV

Fourth District
States

U.S.

46.8

15.7

8.3

25.6

16.5

26.4

6.1

2.6

9.7

21.0

7.7

2.6

Manufacturing

17.5

41.7

41.6

23.8

37.5

30.6

Transportation

5.9

7.5

8.3

7.6

7.7

7.4

Trade

7.7

10.7

9.9

7.1

9.7

10.2

Public services

2.0

1.4

1.6

0.9

1.5

1.9

Professional services

2.6

5.1

4.8

4.6

4.6

5.2

Personal services

7.2

7.0

7.5

5.5

7.2

8.2

Clerical

4.1

8.3

8.3

3.8

7.5

7.5

Agriculture, forestry, and animal husbandry
Mining

Leading Ohio Industries, 1923
Value of
product

Share of
total

(Millions of dollars)

(Percent)

Steel works and rolling mills

709

14.1

Foundry and machine-shop
products

338

6.7

Rubber tires and tubes

391

7.8

Steam-railroad repair shops

108

2.1

Electrical machinery, supplies, etc.

174

3.5

Motor vehicles, excluding
motorcycles

355

7.0

Motor vehicle bodies and parts

144

2.9

Clay products, excluding pottery,
and nonclay refractories

57

1.1

Pottery, including porcelain

43

0.8

Boots and shoes other than rubber

61

1.2

2,666

52.8

All other

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Persons aged 10 years and over.
SOURCE: Arthur Fredrick Blaser, Jr. The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. New York: Columbia University Press, 1942; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Monthly Business Review, vol. 7, no. 9 (September 1, 1925), p. 5; and The Cleveland Plain Dealer, Federal Reserve Bank Section, "Fourth District Reserve Bank
Serves Iron and Steel Center of the United States," August 26, 1923.

The Fourth Federal Reserve District
encompasses eastern Kentucky,
Ohio, western Pennsylvania, and
six counties in the northern panhandle of West Virginia. When these
boundaries were established in
1914–15, they contained the world’s
largest concentration of finished
steel manufacturers.
The Census of 1920 established
nine main categories of employment. About 61.8% of the Fourth
District states’ labor force was em-

ployed in one of the three major
categories — agriculture, manufacturing, and mining activities — a
proportion exceeding the national
average of 59.6%. The District had a
larger share of workers employed in
both mining and manufacturing
firms than the nation and a smaller
percentage of workers engaged in
agriculture.
Clearly, it was a highly industrialized region. A nearly continuous
string of steel mills and factories
extended from Cleveland through

the Mahoning Valley and on to
Pittsburgh. In many other counties
throughout the District, manufacturing was the largest employer among
the three major industry groups, but
activities within manufacturing were
diversified. In fact, steel works and
rolling mills accounted for only
14.1% of the leading manufacturing
industries in Ohio in 1923. Moreover, even in counties throughout
the District where mining or agriculture was the dominant employer,

(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Regional Conditions in the 1920s (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Persons aged 10 years and over, gainfully employed in manufacturing, as a percentage of all such persons engaged in agriculture, manufacturing, and mining.
SOURCE: Arthur Fredrick Blaser, Jr. The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. New York: Columbia University Press, 1942; The Cleveland Plain Dealer, Federal
Reserve Bank Section, “Fourth District Reserve Bank Serves Iron and Steel Center of the United States,”August 26, 1923; and Inter-University Consortium for
Political and Social Research, “Historical, Demographic, Economic, and Social Data: The United States, 1790–1970,” http://fisher.lib.virginia.edu/cgi-local/
censusbin/census/cen.pl?year=930.

manufacturing still made a substantial contribution.
From 1890 to 1930, the District’s
population growth was closely related to the development of mining
and manufacturing. Counties dominated by these industries accounted
for 92.3% of the population increase
for the entire District — a trend that
has been reversed more recently.
By 1930, the Fourth District had
11,555,730 residents, 9.4% of the
nation’s inhabitants. More than a

quarter (27.4%) of them lived in
the counties containing Pittsburgh,
Cleveland, and Cincinnati, the areas
with the largest number of manufacturing establishments.
Although manufacturing was dominant, the District also had important
agricultural and extractive industries.
Farming was widespread and accounted for 16.5% of the District
states’ employment in 1920. A large
share of farm workers lived in eastern Kentucky, a state where agricul-

ture was the principal occupation
for 46.8% of all workers.
By 1930, 19.2% of the nation’s
mining workers lived and worked
in the 47 eastern counties of the
Fourth District. A year earlier, these
counties had produced 36.1% of the
nation’s bituminous coal. Coal mining was particularly important because it was the foundation upon
which the industrial development of
the District rested.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Small Business Lending

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Small business loans (for $1 million or less) secured by nonfarm, nonresidential properties, plus commercial and industrial loans to U.S. addresses.
b. Dollar value of all small business loans as a fraction of total business lending.
NOTE: All data are for FDIC-insured domestic commercial banks.
SOURCE: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income, June 1994–98.

Since 1994, banks have been required
to report the volume of their small
business loans (defined as loans of
less than $1 million). The total volume of such lending has grown
steadily over the past five years,
from $269 billion in 1994 to $336
billion in 1998, a rise of almost 25%.
The Northeast is a striking exception to this growth trend. There,
small business lending has declined
in four of the past five years.
Interestingly, the fastest-growing

segment of this market is for loans
of less than $100,000, which number
4.79 million in 1998, a jump of 22%
from the previous year. Of course,
the largest loans (those with principal amounts of more than $250,000)
still account for over half of all small
business lending — $181 billion out
of a total $336 billion in 1998 (not
shown in chart).
Caution is warranted in interpreting
these data, however. Banks report
their lending based on the office

through which the loan is booked
rather than the location of the borrower. Recent merger activity, therefore, may cause shifts in lending
across regions when there is no
actual change in the credit available
to borrowers in those regions. Such
apparent shifts may be partly
responsible for the strong lending
growth posted in the Southeast and
Central regions, given the aggressive
acquisition strategies of many banks
headquartered there.

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions — Then and Now

Member Bank Conditions
Total Assets
1923:IIQ
1998:IIQ

Percent of total
for all districts
1. Boston
2. New York
3. Philadelphia
4. Cleveland
5. Richmond
6. Atlanta
7. Chicago
8. St. Louis
9. Minneapolis
10. Kansas City
11. Dallas
12. San Francisco
Total for
all districts

Total Loans
1923:IIQ
1998:IIQ

Total Deposits
1923:IIQ
1998:IIQ

Number of Banks
1923:IIQ 1998:IIQ

7.39
29.07
7.12
9.95
4.39
3.54
14.68
4.28
3.37
4.58
2.91
8.73

5.08
17.85
3.79
10.37
16.97
8.19
11.00
3.68
4.41
3.21
3.90
11.54

7.70
26.76
6.26
9.80
4.92
3.93
15.36
4.37
3.69
4.73
3.21
9.28

4.79
13.10
4.08
12.04
17.57
8.96
11.23
3.70
5.28
3.02
3.44
12.80

7.25
29.60
6.80
9.80
4.04
3.42
15.11
4.18
3.38
4.65
2.66
9.11

5.00
15.16
1.48
9.24
13.88
7.80
11.84
3.92
5.13
4.67
6.23
15.65

4.33
4.33
8.33
7.31
8.93
6.38
5.38
14.55
6.30
10.03
11.62
8.70

1.73
3.28
4.13
6.31
7.05
9.17
14.68
8.40
9.33
16.66
13.08
6.19

32,687a

3,569,960a

18,750a

2,222,583a

27,087a

579,644a

9,856b

3,632b

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Millions of dollars.
b. Number of member banks.
NOTE: Data in table are for all member banks of the Federal Reserve System. These represented 63% of all bank assets in 1923:IIQ and 72% in 1998:IIQ.
SOURCES: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income, June 1998; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Banking and Monetary Statistics. Washington, D.C.: National Capital Press, 1943.

One of the most common misperceptions about the Federal Reserve’s
12 districts is that their boundaries
are anachronisms. Considering the
twentieth century’s dramatic population shifts and economic changes,
this notion goes, how can lines
drawn near the century’s beginning
reflect banking needs at its end?
Perhaps surprisingly, banking activity is more evenly distributed
across the Federal Reserve districts
today than it was when the Fourth
District’s Cleveland building was

dedicated in 1923. At that time,
nearly 30% of all assets of the System’s member banks were concentrated in the New York District;
today that figure is less than 18%.
A calculation of the HerfindahlHerschmann index, a standard measure of market concentration, shows
that the concentration of banking assets within the System has declined
substantially (from 1,432 in 1923 to
1,134 in 1998). A similar story can
also be told about other measures of
banking activity.

The Fourth District’s relative importance as a banking center has
grown in the last 75 years. Although
the number of its member banks has
continued to decline — falling in
1998 to 229, or 6.31% of all member
banks in the Federal Reserve System—total assets and lending activity in the Fourth District remain
strong. Indeed, it now provides over
12% of all lending by the System’s
member banks.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Current-Account Deficits
U.S. Balance of Payments
(Billions of dollars)
1991

–4

–189

–184

Capital flows

52

185

133

23

39

16

Other U.S.
government

3

–2

–5

Direct investment

–9

–24

–14

Securities

24

283

260

8

1

–7

Other bank

3

–113

–117

(Discrepancy)

–47

4

51

Other nonbank

(Billions of dollars)

Total securities
U.S. purchases
of foreign securities

1991

1998a

Changeb

24

283

260

–46

–21

25

Savings, Investment, and
Foreign Capital Flows
(Billions of dollars)
1991

Savings

Foreign purchases of:
U.S. Treasury
securities

19

–6

–24

U.S. currency

15

3

–13

Private

35

307

1998a

934

1,483

Changeb

549

931

1,130

199

Government

3

352

349

Foreign capital
inflowc

4

189

185

937

1,604

667

–1

–68

–67

Domestic
investment
(Discrepancy)

U.S. private
securities

Changeb

Current account
Official reserves

Foreign Purchases and Sales of Securities

1998a

272

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. 1998 values are based on first-quarter data.
b. Data may contain rounding errors.
c. Includes balance-of-payments statistical discrepancy as unreported capital flows.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Any U.S. current-account deficit
must be accompanied by a foreigncapital inflow of equal magnitude.
Movements in dollar exchange
rates and changes in the spreads
between U.S. and foreign interest
rates preserve this balance in our
international accounts. How far exchange rates and interest rates must
adjust to maintain this equilibrium,
however, depends on both the financial instrument and the output
that the capital finances. Capital

flows into liquid assets are prone to
rapid, abrupt flight that can produce
swift, extensive exchange- and
interest-rate adjustments. Likewise,
flows that sustain domestic consumption may require larger rate
adjustments than flows sustaining
domestic investment.
We lack data on the maturity
structure of foreign investments, but
we can link the $184 billion increase in our current-account deficit
since 1991 to a sharp increase in
foreign holdings of U.S. private

securities. These are probably more
prone to flight than are official reserves or foreign direct investments
that represent controlling interests
in U.S. businesses.
The connection between domestic savings and investment and the
current account deficit is clearer.
Since 1991, capital inflows associated with the expanding currentaccount deficit have been accompanied by even larger increases in
domestic savings and investment.

19
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Germany’s Hyperinflation, 1923
Growth in Discounted Reichsbank Bills
January 1921–
January 1922

155%

January 1922–
January 1923

3,410%

January 1923–
December 1923a

January 1924–
December 1924

6.8 (1015 )%

173%

FRB Cleveland • September 1998

a. Fiscal reforms took place in December 1923.
SOURCE: Thomas J. Sargent, “The Ends of Four Big Inflations,” in Robert E. Hall, Inflation: Causes and Effects. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982,
pp. 41–97.

In January 1923, French and Belgian
troops occupied the Ruhr Valley to
compel repayment of World War I
debts — set at 132 billion gold
marks—from a wavering Germany.
Workers resisted the incursion
through absenteeism, supported by
German welfare payments. The nation’s fiscal position had already
deteriorated as the Socialist government tried to meet foreign
obligations and to mend the tattered
social fabric by deficit spending. An
inflation tax is easy to collect and
requires no parliamentary wran-

gling. Soon after the occupation
began, Germany capitulated to the
French and Belgians and the deficit
ballooned further still.
The German central bank discounted enormous amounts of
government treasury securities in
1922 and 1923, along with massive
quantities of private commercial
paper. By late 1923, the government was financing almost its entire
budget through money creation.
The inflation rate averaged 40% per
month in 1922, then jumped to
3,666% per month in 1923, with an

astounding 29,525% in October. The
public responded by shifting as
rapidly as possible from marks into
foreign currencies and commodities.
Consequently, prices rose faster than
the money stock — that is, the real
money stock fell.
This hyperinflation ended in
1924 following fiscal reforms, reorganization of the central bank, and
relief from the crushing burden
of war reparations. But the events
of 1923 have continued to color
German attitudes about monetary
policy to this day.