View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 2010 (Septemeber 10, 2010-October 14, 2010)

In This Issue:
Banking and Financial Markets
 Federal Home Loan Banks: The Housing GSE
That Didn’t Bark in the Night?
Monetary Policy
 FOMC Keeps It Steady Ahead
Inflation and Prices
 Recent Developments in Inflation Expectations

Regional Activity
 Job Churning in Regional Labor Markets
Monetary Policy
 Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth
Households and Consumers
 Recent Changes in Household Net Worth

Banking and Financial Markets

Federal Home Loan Banks: The Housing GSE That Didn’t Bark in the
Night?
09.23.10
by James B. Thomson and Matthew Koepke
From the onset of the financial crisis to today,
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have frequented the
financial headlines. Since these two housing-related
government sponsored enterprises (GSEs) were
taken into conservatorship by the U.S. Treasury on
September 7, 2008, they have required $148 billion
in taxpayer funds to cover the losses they incurred.
Recent statements by the acting director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency suggest that the final
bill to the U.S. taxpayer to resolve the insolvencies
of Fannie and Freddie could exceed $400 billion.

Federal Home Loan Bank: Assets and Advances
Dollars in billions
1600
1400

Total assets
Advances

Advances growth

Percent change
50
40
30

1200
Asset growth

1000

20
10

800

0

600

-10

400

-20

200

-30

0

-40
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

However, the Federal Home Loan Bank system,
another housing GSE, has fared somewhat better during the financial crisis. Created as part of
Depression-era reforms to the financial system,
the 12 Federal Home Loan Banks provide liquidity and funding to the housing and small business loan markets primarily through loans known
as advances. Advances are generally secured by
housing-related assets and the small-business-loan
portfolios of their member institutions and qualified nonmember housing agencies. Federal Home
Loan Bank advances can carry a fixed or variable
interest rate and range in maturity from overnight
to 30 years. During the market turmoil in 2007
and 2008, advances from the Federal Home Loan
Banks served as an important source of funds for
depository institutions.
From 2001 to 2005, the consolidated assets of the
Federal Home Loan Banks increased on average 8.8
percent per year before they leveled off in 2006.
This asset growth was driven by strong demand for
Federal Home Bank advances, which grew at a rate
of 7.3 percent over the period and accounted for
62.1 percent of Federal Home Loan Bank assets
in 2009. As the financial crisis began to unfold in
the summer of 2007, the volume of lending by the
Federal Home Loan Banks took off, growing from
just under $641 billion at the end of 2006 to $875

Source: “Federal Home Loan Bank System Annual Reports," 2000-2009.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

2

billion—an increase of approximately 38 percent.
Advances accounted for most the growth in total
assets for the Home Loan Banks in 2007—more
than $23 billion of almost $26 billion. As financial markets returned to normalcy in 2008, both
advances and total assets grew at around a 6.0
percent. They then declined sharply in 2009, and
by the end of the year, total assets and advances
outstanding had returned to 2006 pre-crisis levels.
The decline was driven by a slowdown in advances;
they fell 32 percent from 2008 to 2009.

Federal Home Loan Bank: Assets
Percent of total assets (2009)

Advances
Mortgage loans
held for portfolio
Securities
All other assets

11.1

62.1

19.7

7.0

Unlike Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the Federal
Home Loan Banks hold less than 27 percent of
their asset portfolio in the form of mortgages and
mortgage-backed securities. The bulk of Federal
Home Loan Bank assets consist of advances, which
are secured by the collateral pledged against them
and by a general lien, known as super lien authority, on all of the assets of the borrower. Consequently, the Home Loan Banks have faced noticeably less
severe asset quality problems and credit losses than
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

Source: "Federal Home Loan Bank System Annual Reports", 2000-2009.

Federal Home Loan Bank: Liabilities
Dollars in billions
1400
Consolidated obligations
All other liabilities
Deposits

1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Source: "Federal Home Loan Bank System Annual Reports," 2000-2009.

Federal Home Loan Bank:
Growth in Liabilities
Annual percent change
30
Liabilities
Consolidated obligations
Capital

20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Source: "Federal Home Loan Bank System Annual Reports," 2000-2009.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

The majority of funding for the Federal Home
Loan Banks comes from the issuance of bonds
known as consolidated obligations. The term consolidated obligations refers to the fact that when an
individual Home Loan Bank issues debt, that debt
is a joint obligation of the 12 Federal Home Loan
Banks. In other words, consolidated obligations, irrespective of which Home Loan Bank issues them,
are the collective liability of all of the Home Loan
Banks. This feature of the debt reduces the risk associated with the default of any individual Home
Loan Bank and contributes to the perception that
the liabilities of the Federal Home Loan Banks have
tacit government backing.
The rapid expansion of advances from 2007 to
2008 was financed with consolidated obligations,
which grew more than 26 percent in 2007 and
nearly 7 percent in 2008. Growth in total liabilities
followed essentially the same pattern as consolidated obligations; however, over the same period,
Federal Home Loan Bank capital grew at slightly
lower rates. The inability of the Federal Home Loan
Banks to accumulate capital as fast as their balance sheets were expanding in 2007 and 2008 put
3

Federal Home Loan Bank: Capital Adequacy
Dollars in billions
60
50

Total capital
Capital ratio

Ratio
6.0
5.0

40

4.0

30

3.0

20

2.0

10

1.0

0

downward pressure on the system’s capital ratio,
which dropped from 4.4 percent at the end of
2006 to 3.8 percent at the end 2008. A capital ratio
below 4 percent falls below the threshold of core
capital to assets that a commercial bank is required
to hold under current capital adequacy rules in the
United States. The ratio rose above the threshold
again in 2009 (to 4.2 percent), even though the
level of capital fell nearly 17 percent, because the
shrinkage in the system’s balance sheet was large
enough to offset the loss.

0.0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

Source: "Federal Home Loan Bank System Annual Reports," 2000-2009.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

4

Monetary Policy

FOMC Keeps It Steady Ahead
09.27.10
by Ben Craig and Matthew Koepke

Eurodollar Forward Rate Curve
Percent
1

0.75
September 20, 2010
0.5
September 22, 2010
0.25

0
10/10

1/11

4/11

7/11

10/11

1/12

4/12

7/12

10/12

Source: Bloomberg.

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
Total securities held outright (dollars in billions)
2500
Mortgage backed securities
2000
1500
1000

Agency securities
Treasury securities

500
0
9/07

2/08

8/08

2/09

8/09

2/10

8/10

Sources: Board of Governors, Haver Analytics.

On September 21, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) reaffirmed its commitment to keep
the Federal Funds rate within the range 0 to 1/4
percent, as the economy continues with its fragile
recovery. Though the National Bureau of Economic
Research declared that the recession ended in
June of 2009, the recovery has been hampered by
pervasive unemployment and soft income growth.
Moreover, as the Committee noted in its statement,
underlying inflation is below the level it deems
necessary, in the long term, to fulfill its mandate of
maximum employment and price stability.
The market anticipated that the FOMC would
maintain exceptionally low rates for an “extended
period of time,” and these expectations are clearly
reflected in Eurodollar futures. Eurodollar futures
are forward rate agreements that allow market
participants to speculate on or hedge against movements in short-term interest rates. In the case of
Eurodollar futures, investors are betting on the risk
associated with short-term changes in the Libor
rate. The Libor rate is most associated with the cost
of borrowing U.S. dollars for private, high-quality
borrowers. By examining the Eurodollar forward
rate curves, it is apparent that the FOMC’s policy
decision did not dramatically impact the market’s
expectations for interest rates going forward.
In addition to maintaining the federal funds rate
at record lows, the Fed has sought to improve
market function by purchasing longer-term securities. Since August 2007, total assets on the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet have expanded from $869
billion to nearly 2.3 trillion. The expansion in the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet is the result of purchases of agency debt, mortgage-backed securities
(MBS), and longer-term treasuries.
The Federal Reserve ceased purchasing agency
securities at the end of the first quarter 2010. Additionally, as a result of lower mortgage interest
rates, some of the principal of the MBS and agency

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

5

securities held by the Federal Reserve had been
repaid. As result, the level of agency and MBS debt
on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet has declined
modestly. In order to maintain an accommodative
monetary policy, the Fed plans to reinvest payments
of principal on agency and MBS securities into
longer-term treasuries. Even with principal repayments on MBS and new purchases of long-term
treasuries, MBS still account for nearly 54 percent
of Federal Reserve’s balance sheet.

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
Percent of total securities held outright
55
Mortgage backed securities
50

45

40
Treasury securities
35
1/10
2/10
3/10
4/10

5/10

6/10

7/10

8/10

9/10

Sources: Board of Governors, Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

6

Inflation and Prices

Recent Developments in Inflation Expectations
10.05.10
by Timothy Bianco and Mehmet Pasaogullari

Headline CPI and Core CPI Inflation
Percent
6
Core CPI
(12-month percentage change)

4
CPI (12-month percentage change)

2
Core CPI (3-month annualized
percentage change)

0

-2
2007

2008

2009

2010

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

A persistent downward trend in prices has created
some concern about whether there will be further
disinflation or even a deflation in the future. Here
we review what inflation expectations foretell for
the future inflation. Since people consider the
future level of general prices when they set their
own prices, inflation expectations reflect not only
their perceptions about the future but they are also
an important determinant of future inflation. In
addition, there is some empirical evidence showing
that the expectations are among the best predictors
of future inflation.
One market-price-based measure of expected inflation is the inflation swap rate. An inflation swap
is a financial instrument that allows one party to
exchange a variable inflation rate for a fixed inflation rate, the swap rate, with another party. The
variable rate of the swap we review here is the CPI
rate. We also look at the Cleveland Fed’s modelbased inflation expectation measure, which utilizes
the information in the term structure of nominal
Treasuries that is, the distribution of yields on
securities of different maturities. For further information about these measures, read Joe Haubrich’s
commentary. One-year inflation expectations from
these measures started declining in the spring of
2010. Although there was an uptick in the Cleveland Fed’s August estimate and a smaller uptick in
the swap rates, they are pointing to a continued period of disinflation. As of the end of August 2010,
these measures reflect an expectation of annual CPI
inflation between 0.8 and 1.4 percent.
In addition to these measures, we reviewed estimates of inflation expectations derived from
surveys. The first is the University of Michigan’s
Survey of Consumer Attitudes and Behavior (the U
of M Survey, hereafter), which comes out monthly
and asks consumers about the change in prices they
expect over next 12 months, without specifying a
consumption basket. The second measure is from
the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF), which

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

7

One-Year Inflation Expectations
Percent
6
University of Michigan

4
2

SPF

0

Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland

-2
-4
Inflation Swap Rate

-6
2007

2008

2009

2010

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Bloomberg, University of Michigan.

SPF One-Year Expected Inflation
Percent
4

is conducted quarterly by the Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia. We produce monthly figures by
interpolating the quarterly figures. These survey
measures have recently shown higher inflation expectations than market- and model-based measures.
Further, they have been more stable this year. The
median one-year inflation expectation from the U
of M Survey is 2.7 percent (as of the end of August)
and the one-year CPI inflation expectation from
the SPF is 1.7 percent. Despite the fact that these
are lower than their long-term average values, they
nonetheless indicate that forecasters and consumers
assign a very small likelihood of deflation next year.
The SPF measure of one-year inflation expectations
has become more uniform across the individual
respondents. Furthermore, the lowest individual
response for the one-year inflation expectation is
0.5 percent, indicating that none of the individual
forecasters expects deflation by the third quarter of
2011.

Top 10 percent

3
Median
Range (Top 10 percent
minus Bottom 10 percent)

2

Bottom 10 percent

1

0
2007

2008

2009

2010

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

SPF Probabilities for the Current Year
CPI Inflation
Percent probability
100

0.0-0.9
1.0-1.9

90

2.0-2.9
3.0-3.9

80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3
2010
2009
2007
2008

In addition to asking forecasters for their individual
inflation forecasts for different periods, in 2007
the SPF started asking them to assign probabilities
to different ranges of inflation. In particular, SPF
asks forecasters how likely they think it is that the
annual core CPI inflation will be in a particular
range in the fourth quarter of the current year and
the next year. Their responses show that the average
probabilities assigned to the lower ranges of 0.0–0.9
percent and 1.0–1.9 percent for the CPI inflation
rate have increased in the last two quarters. The
average probabilities obtained in the third-quarter
survey for those two ranges for the current year are,
for example, 47 percent and 45 percent, respectively.
Similarly, the average probabilities for those ranges
for the annual core CPI for the fourth quarter
of 2011 have increased throughout 2010. They
reached 74 percent together in the third quarter.
However, the average probability of the upper half
of the 0.0-1.9 percent range is considered as almost
two times more likely than the lower half of the
range. In addition, although not shown in the chart
below, the average deflation probability is 2 percent
for this period.

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

8

SPF Probabilities for the Current Year
CPI Inflation
Percent probability
100

2.0-2.9
3.0-3.9

0.0-0.9
1.0-1.9

90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3
2010
2009
2007
2008
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Long-Term Inflation Expectations
Percent
4

University of Michigan
(medium-long term), median

3

2
SPF median (10-year)

1

Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland (10-year)

Inflation swap rate
(10-year)

TIPS-derived 5-year
forward inflation rate

0
2007

2008

2009

What about long-term inflation expectations? Like
short-term expectations, the market- and modelbased figures are more volatile than survey-based
expectations. They have been declining since April.
For example, the five-year breakeven inflation rate
declined from 2 percent to 1.2 percent, five-year
forward breakeven inflation rate (computed from
the five- and 10-year TIPS and nominal Treasuries)
declined from 2.8 percent to 1.9 percent between
the end of April and August 2010, and the 10-year
expectations from Cleveland Fed model declined by
0.3 percent to 1.7 percent in the same period. On
the other hand, the 10-year CPI inflation expectation from the SPF survey stayed at 2.5 percent in
the same period. However, although not shown
in the chart below, the market-based measures of
inflation expectations have been steadily increasing
since the end of August. For example, the 10-year
inflation swap rate increased by 0.2 percent to 2.3
percent, and the five-year forward rate increased by
more than 0.4 percent.
Overall, short-term inflation expectations have
been lower than their long-term average values.
However, they still do not reflect a significant shortterm deflation risk. Market-based measures of longterm inflation expectations declined up through the
end of August, but they have increased since. Longterm inflation expectations derived from surveys,
meanwhile, have been more stable over the year.

2010

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Bloomberg, University of Michigan, Federal Reserve Board.

For more information on Cleveland Fed estimates of inflation
expectations, visit http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/data/inflation_expectations/index.cfm.
Joseph G. Haubrich “A New Approach to Gauging Inflation
Expectations.” Economic Commentary. http://www.clevelandfed.
org/research/commentary/2009/0809.cfm.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

9

Regional Activity

Job Churning in Regional Labor Markets
09.27.10
by Jayson Gerbec, Miriam Singer, and Adam Smith
A recently developed data source, the U.S. Census
Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household Dynamics (LEHD) database, is providing new information on the dynamics of U.S. labor markets.
The LEHD provides quarterly data on worker and
employment flows and allows for a rich description
of both worker and job turnover at relatively fine
levels of geographic detail. A key feature of data on
employment flows is that they show the amount of
job creation and job destruction that occurs greatly
exceeds the net employment change. That is, there
is considerable job and worker “churning” that is
hidden by reports that focus on net employment
change.
The measurement of worker reallocation is important to economists for a number of reasons.
In particular, unemployment rates are related to
worker flows, and one key driver of worker flows is
the underlying flows in jobs across employers. As
employers change size, they shed and add workers,
resulting in hirings and separations. As we’ll show
below, there has been some decline in excess reallocation in local labor markets, and this is consistent
with the general trend in worker flows reported in
research by the Cleveland Fed.
Excess Job Reallocation (Unweighted)
Percent of employment
14
12

10
8
6
4
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

We measure the amount of job churning that has
occurred in 190 of the largest metropolitan labor
markets in the United States—the top quartile
of U.S. labor markets with respect to size—since
2001. The measure we use is the excess job reallocation rate, which is calculated as job creation
plus job destruction minus the absolute value of
net employment change, all divided by the level of
employment for the given time period. It reflects
the amount of a metro area’s employment flows
that exceeds its overall employment growth. Net
employment growth is often less than a percentage
point annually for a location, while excess job reallocation is roughly 10 times as large.

Sources: U.S. Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household
Dynamics (LEHD); authors’ calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

10

Excess Reallocation in Metropolitan Areas
Percent of MSAs
12
10
8
6
4
2
0

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

Percent of employment
Notes: MSAs refers to metropolitan statistical areas. Averages were calculated
using first-quarter rates between 2001–2009.
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household
Dynamics (LEHD); authors’ calculations.

Reallocation and Labor Market Size
Average excess job reallocation rate
14
13
12
11
Pittsburgh
10

Columbus

9
8

Cleveland

7
Cincinnati

6
5
11

12

13

14

15

16

Log of employment
Notes: Averages were calculated using first-quarter rates between 2001–2009.
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau’s Longitudinal Employer-Household
Dynamics (LEHD); authors’ calculations.

For more information on how unemployment rates relate to worker flows,
visit http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/commentary/2010/2010-11.cfm.

The figure below shows the distribution over time
of excess employment flows across metropolitan
areas. It shows the median, 25th and 75th percentiles, and the minimum and maximum values for
the first quarter of each year from 2001 to 2009.
Median excess job reallocation rates decline from
9.7 percent in 2001 to 8 percent in 2006, and
then experience a slight uptick to 8.2 percent in
2009. The interquartile range is typically 2 to 2.5
percentage points with little discernible pattern
either in the expansion or contraction of the range
over time. However, there is considerable spread in
excess reallocation rates across metropolitan areas,
with some areas experiencing annual rates above 12
percent of employment and others below 6 percent.
There is also persistence in excess reallocation rates
across metropolitan areas. That is, some metropolitan areas have a tendency to have higher reallocation rates while others have lower rates. The
8-year average excess job reallocation rates for the
largest 190 MSAs go from a low of 5.7 percent to
a high of 13.1 percent. The Fourth District’s four
largest MSAs (Pittsburgh, Cleveland, Cincinnati,
and Columbus) have similar levels of excess job
churning—they all fall within one standard deviation of the mean excess reallocation rate. Cleveland
has the lowest reallocation rate of the four cities
(8.3 percent), while Pittsburgh has the highest (9.6
percent).
While the 190 metropolitan areas in our sample
represent the largest labor markets in the nation,
they differ quite a bit in size, ranging from 70,000
to 5.9 million workers. Excess reallocation is only
moderately correlated with the size of the local
labor market, with larger metropolitan areas having
somewhat higher levels of reallocation.
What else could be behind these differences in
metropolitan area reallocation rates? It is likely a
combination of industry structure and firm heterogeneity. In particular, differences in both the size
and age distributions of firms are likely sources of
variation in the magnitude of employment flows
across metropolitan areas.

For more information on unemployment after the recession, visit http://
www.clevelandfed.org/research/commentary/2010/2010-11.cfm.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

11

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth: September 2010
Covering August 26, 2010–September 17, 2010
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Timothy Bianco

Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures
Long rates took a turn higher over the past month,
adding a bit of steepness to the yield curve, as short
rates stayed level. The three-month Treasury bill
rate edged down to 0.15 percent from August’s
(and July’s) 0.16 percent. The ten-year rate rose to
2.74 percent, up from August’s 2.61 percent, but
still down from July’s 2.97. The slope rose 10 basis
points to 255, up from August’s 245, down from
July’s 281.

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP Growth
Percent
11
GDP growth (year-over-year change)
9
7
5
3
1
-1
Ten-year minus threemonth yield spread

-3
-5
1953

1960

1966

1973

1980

1987

1994

2001

2008

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Board.

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
11
One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

9
7
5
3
1
-1

Ten-year minus
three-month yield spread

-3
-5
1953

1960

1966

1973

1980

1987

1994

2001

2008

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

Projecting forward using past values of the spread
and GDP growth suggests that real GDP will grow
at about a 1.0 percent rate over the next year, the
same numbers as August and just down from July’s
1.14 percent. Although the time horizons do not
match exactly, this comes in on the more pessimistic side of other forecasts, although, like them, it
does show moderate growth for the year.
The NBER has declared an end to the recession,
putting the trough at June 2009. Having this data
has materially changed the recession probabilities
coming from the model. Using the yield curve to
predict whether or not the economy will be in recession in the future, we estimate that the expected
chance of the economy being in a recession next
September stands at 2.9 percent, well below the
August number of 18.5 percent, though the numbers are not strictly comparable. The change reflects
the addition of another year of nonrecession data
(as declared by the NBER), rather than any massive
improvement in the economy.

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth
The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
12

yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.

Yield-Curve-Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
5
GDP growth (year-over-year change)

4
3
2
1
0
-1

Ten-year minus
three-month yield spread

-2

Predicted
GDP
growth

-3
-4
-5
2002

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Board;
authors' calculations.

More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.

Predicting GDP Growth
We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90

Predicting the Probability of Recession

80
70
60

Probabilty of recession

50
Forecast

40
30
20
10
0
1960

1966

1972

1978

1984

1990

1996

2002

2008

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: NBER; Federal Reserve Board; authors' calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution.For more detail on these and other issues re
13

lated to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” The Federal Reserve Bank of New York
also maintains a website with much useful information on the topic, including its own estimate of
recession probabilities.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

14

Households and Consumers

Recent Changes in Household Net Worth
10.07.10
by Daniel Carroll

Household Balance Sheet
Billions of U.S. dollars
90000

Total assets

80000
70000
60000

Net worth

50000
40000
30000
20000

Total liabilities

10000
0
Q1
Q4 Q3 Q2 Q1 Q4 Q3 Q2 Q1 Q4 Q3 Q2
2002 2002 2003 2004 2005 2005 2006 2007 2008 2008 2009 2010
Source: Haver Analytics.

Assets by Primary Subcategory
Billions of U.S. dollars
50000

45000

Financial assets
40000

35000
30000

Tangible assets

25000
20000
2009:Q1

2009:Q2 2009:Q3 2009:Q4 2010:Q1 2010:Q2

Source: Haver Analytics.

During the housing bubble, the nominal value of
household assets grew rapidly, peaking in the third
quarter of 2007 after rising 64 percent over the
course of just five years. During that same time,
total household liabilities grew by 66 percent.
However, because liabilities were considerably
smaller than total assets, households’ net worth
(the difference between total assets and liabilities)
still grew by 63 percent. After peaking, the value of
household assets fell precipitously. In the first quarter of 2009, household assets had lost 21 percent of
their value from their peak. Total liabilities, on the
other hand, remained relatively unchanged, causing
household net worth to crash by almost 26 percent.
Since bottoming out in early 2009, household
assets have grown again. At the same time, total
liabilities have slowly declined, pulling household
net worth up by 9.6 percent in the last year. In
the second quarter, however, this trend changed,
as both assets and net worth fell by approximately
$1.5 trillion. The decline in assets did not come
from tangible assets. Both real estate and consumer
durable goods, which comprise tangible assets,
have been increasing steadily since the beginning
of 2009. The decline in total assets was brought on
instead by a very sharp decline in financial assets.
This category dropped by $1.7 trillion last quarter.
Decomposing financial assets, four of nine subcategories of financial assets declined last quarter: corporate equities, pension fund reserves, mutual fund
shares, and deposits. The total loss from those four
sources was $1.97 trillion, with nearly 80 percent
of the decline coming from corporate equities and
pension fund reserves.
The fall in the stock market over the second quarter
can account for the large movement in assets. From
the beginning of April to the end of June, the S&P
500 Index fell by 7.1 percent. Since that period, the
stock market has, despite some subsequent large
swings, made up some of its lost ground, suggest

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

15

Quarterly Change in Declining Components
of Financial Assets

ing that household net worth will likely resume its
upward trend when the third quarter balance sheet
data becomes available.

Billions of U.S. dollars
0

-200

-400

-600

-800

-1000

Pension fund reserves
Corporate equities
Deposits
Mutual fund shares

Source: Haver Analytics.

S&P 500 Weekly Average
Billions of U.S. dollars
1250
1200
1150
1100
1050
1000
950
1/1
2/26
1/29
3/26 4/23 5/21 6/18 7/16 8/13 9/10
1/15
3/12
4/9 5/7 6/4
7/2
7/30 8/27 9/24
2/2
Source: Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

16

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | October 2010

17