View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

The big picture point by point, or “Sunday Afternoon on the Island of La Grande Jatte” (Georges
Seurat, 1886)…Economists who study labor markets and industrial organization have long recognized the general public’s incomplete view of the
dynamic processes at work in the U.S. economy
that create and destroy both jobs and business establishments. When the evening newscaster blithely
announces that 57,000 jobs were created in September, few people recognize that between August
and September a very large number of people
moved into new jobs, even as a similar number left
old jobs; the 57,000 figure is the net result of two
gross flows moving in opposite directions. The public will hear more about these underlying factors
now that the Bureau of Labor Statistics has begun
regular publication of its Business Employment
Dynamics (BED) data.
Because these newly available statistics are collected from more than 6 million nonfarm business
establishments in the United States, they make it
possible to examine employment consequences
from the perspective of business establishments. For
example, the BED data indicate that during the
fourth quarter of last year, the net loss of 70,000 jobs
from the private sector resulted from 7.746 million
job additions and 7.816 million cutbacks. Jobs were
added when expanding establishments contributed
6.1 million jobs and opening establishments contributed 1.6 million. During the same quarter, jobs
were destroyed when contracting establishments cut
6.2 million jobs and closing establishments eliminated another 1.6 million. The result of these
factors, the net loss of 70,000 jobs mentioned earlier,
represents less than one-tenth of 1 percent of net
employment, but comes from a nearly 15 percent
reallocation of labor (7.2 percent new jobs and
7.3 percent lost jobs) in just one three-month span.
During that period, roughly one-fourth of the
6.4 million establishments tracked in the BED data
set added jobs, one-fourth cut jobs, and one-half
displayed no change.
Clearly, when gross flows are as consistently large
as those revealed in the BED data, it is time to confront the reality of how the U.S. economy operates
to reallocate employment across jobs and business
firms. The 1992–2000 economic expansion provides an instructive example. During that period,

job gains from expanding establishments gradually
rose from 5.5 million to 7 million per quarter, but
job losses from contracting establishments drifted
up as well, from 5.5 million to nearly 7 million per
quarter. Until 2001, the gains always exceeded the
losses. Net employment advanced considerably
during the long expansion period, but not without
considerable movement of people from one job to
another as some establishments grew and others
shrank. In addition, some people joined new establishments and left closing ones, roughly 2 million of
each per quarter.
The most recent recession appears as a period in
which job losses from contracting establishments
rose sharply while job gains from expanding establishments fell sharply. At the end of 2002, each force
accounted for roughly 6 million jobs in each direction, producing no net employment gain. The
pattern of establishment openings and closings has
not changed materially during the recession–
recovery period.
Getting below the surface of the aggregate statistics will prove useful in understanding the employment dynamics of particular industries and regions,
and how reallocating both capital and labor across
establishments and regions improves the nation’s
productivity growth over time. For example, previous studies have shown that manufacturing firms
tend to make their largest job-destruction decisions
during economic downturns, and that manufacturing exporters tend to cluster in certain regions
while manufacturing importers cluster in others.
U.S. plants’ survival, employment, and output seem
to be adversely affected by import competition
from low-wage firms. As U.S. firms adjust, they seek
to increase their plants’ capital intensity and hire
employees who are more highly skilled. This
process leads to productivity growth, but also to
worker displacement that creates difficulties for
regions with high concentrations of affected establishments. As the world’s economies open up to
more trade, each country faces challenges in reallocating resources to their most productive uses.
Just as Georges Seurat’s greatest paintings used
the pointillist technique of creating the whole with
tiny points of color, so too the great panorama that
is the U.S. economy is often depicted best by analyzing microdata.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

August Price Statistics

3.75

Percent change, last:
2002
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr. avg.

3.50
CPI
3.25

Consumer prices

3.00

All items

4.0

2.6

2.2

2.5

2.4

Less food
and energy

1.2

1.2

1.3

2.2

2.0

2.50

Medianb

2.8

2.2

2.1

2.9

3.0

2.25

2.75

Producer prices
Finished goods
Less food
and energy

2.00

5.2
1.6

4.3
0.8

3.5
0.5

1.9

1.2

0.9 –0.5

1.75

CPI excluding
food and energy

1.50
1.25
1.00
1995

12-month percent change
4.25 CPI AND TRIMMED-MEAN MEASURES

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

12-month percent change
5 CORE CPI GOODS AND SERVICES

4.00
4

3.75

CPI core services

CPI
3.50

3

3.25

Median CPI b
2

3.00
2.75

1

2.50
2.25

0

2.00
–1

1.75

CPI core goods

1.50

–2

CPI, 16% trimmed mean b

1.25
1.00

–3
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

The Consumer Price Index (CPI) rose
0.3% in August (4.0% at an annual
rate), compared with increases of
0.2% (2.0% annualized) in the previous two months. Part of the CPI’s acceleration resulted from a sharp increase in its energy index, which rose
2.7% in August after far more modest
monthly increases (0.8% in June and
0.4% in July). The primary reason
for energy’s abrupt jump was an
outsize increase in the gasoline
index, which rose more than 6% (an
annualized rate exceeding 100%),

the component’s largest monthly
increase since February.
Excluding energy prices, as well as
the often-volatile food component,
yields a less pronounced increase
in inflation. According to the CPI
excluding food and energy, sometimes called the core CPI, prices rose
0.1% in August (1.2% annualized). The
median CPI and the 16% trimmedmean CPI, other inflation measures
intended to be less influenced by
volatile items, also showed smaller
August increases than the unadjusted

CPI. Each of these trimmed-mean
measures rose about 0.2%.
For the 12 months ending in
August, the CPI rose 2.2%. If food and
energy are excluded, inflation according to the core CPI increased 1.3%.
Clearly, removing some components
from the CPI changes the price trend
picture significantly. Breaking down
the core CPI further shows a growing
price gap between core goods and
core services. Underlying inflation in
the economy’s service sector seems
to have settled at around 3%. In the
goods-producing portion of the
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Cents per gallon
120 GASOLIINE SPOT PRICE a

Cents per gallon
95
GASOLINE FUTURES CONTRACTS b

110
100

90
August 8, 2003

90
80

85

70
60

80

50

September 26, 2003

40

75
September 19, 2003

30
20

70
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Nov.
2003

Dec.

Jan.

Feb.
2004

Mar.

Annualized quarterly percent change
5 ACTUAL CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST d

12-month percent change
5.0 HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS c
4.5

Oct.

Five to 10 years ahead

4
CPI

4.0
3

Highest 10%

3.5

2

3.0

Consensus

2.5
1
Lowest 10%

2.0
One year ahead

0

1.5
1.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

–1
1995 1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. New York Gasoline Conventional Regular Spot Price.
b. New York Phase II Complex Model Reformulated Gasoline.
c. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
d. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration; University of Michigan; Bloomberg Financial Information Services; and Blue Chip
Economic Indicators, September 10, 2003.

economy, however, an underlying
deflation continues.
While the advance in gasoline prices
accounted for much of August’s CPI
acceleration, spot gasoline prices
have since fallen significantly, more
than 10% during September. Prices
did spike upward late in the month,
after the Organization of Petroleum
Exporting Countries (OPEC) announced its intention to curtail crude
oil supplies. But this increase was
short-lived, and prices have since
fallen below pre-announcement levels.

The prices of gasoline futures contracts were also affected by OPEC’s announcement. But aside from the October contract, prices for future
delivery of gasoline into the first quarter of next year remain well below the
levels of early August. And the trend in
prices into the future is still decidedly
downward.
Nevertheless, August’s pronounced
increase in gasoline prices may have
affected households’ short-run expectations of inflation. Year-ahead
household inflation expectations

rose 0.6% in September and are up
1.1% since July. By contrast, households’ longer-run inflation expectations have stayed reasonably well
anchored at around 3%. Professional
forecasters, attempting to predict
the CPI’s path, expect the index to
register an annualized increase of
about 2% over the next 18 months.
The range of their opinions is rather
wide, however, with about 1.5 percentage points separating inflation
pessimists from inflation optimists.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Billions of dollars
800 THE MONETARY BASE

6%

Sweep-adjusted base growth, 1998–2003 a
15
12
Sweep-adjusted base b

750

Trillions of dollars
2.0 THE M1 AGGREGATE

1.8

7%

9

700

6

6

7%

4

3
0

650

7%

Sweep-adjusted M1 growth, 1998–2003 a
10
8

8%

1.6

8%

2
0

2%

2%
12%

600

6%

1.4

Sweep-adjusted M1 b

5%

Monetary base
8%

550

1.2
500

M1
1.0

450
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Small time deposits

10%

M2 growth, 1998–2003 a
12
9

1,000
10%

6

5%
800

3
0

5.6

1999

Billions of dollars
1,200 MONETARY COMPONENTS

Trillions of dollars
6.8 THE M2 AGGREGATE

6.2

1998

2004

5%

Retail money market mutual funds
Currency

10%
600
5%

5.0
5%

400

Demand deposits

1%
5%
1%

4.4

200

5%

Other checkable deposits

1%
3.8
1998

0
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Growth rates are calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2003 growth rates for the sweep-adjusted monetary base and sweep-adjusted
M1 are calculated on a July over 2002:IVQ basis. The 2003 growth rate for M2 is calculated on a September over 2002:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts. Sweepadjusted M1 contains an estimate of balances temporarily moved from M1 to non-M1 accounts.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Money Stock Measures,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.6.

Growth in the monetary base (total
currency in circulation plus the sum
of total reserves and depository institutions’ vault cash that is not applied
to reserve requirements) moderated
to an annualized 5.7% rate between
January and September, far below its
five-year average of 7.9%. The decline
in base growth resulted mainly from
currency growth’s 3-percentagepoint drop from its five-year average
of 8.2%. This more than offset total
reserves’ 15.9% year-to-date growth.
M1, another narrow monetary
aggregate, consists of currency in the

hands of the public plus demand and
other checkable deposits. Its year-todate annualized growth rate of 8.4%
was roughly 2.8 percentage points
above its five-year average. The
accelerated growth of M1 resulted
primarily from a sharp increase in
demand deposits and other checkable deposits, whose year-to-date
annualized growth rates were 10 percentage points above their five-year
averages. The main causes of this
growth were the surge in home refinancing activity and the decline in
M1 opportunity cost.

M2 grew more slowly than M1
because the broader aggregates are
affected primarily by economic activity, which has been sluggish for the
past couple of years. This slower
growth resulted from declines in retail
money market mutual funds (8.5%)
and small time deposits (9.8%), which
partly offset the rise in M1 growth and
the 18.3% advance in savings deposits.
However, M2 growth accelerated
from 6.8% in 2002 to 7.3% in 2003
so far, reflecting the recent economic
recovery.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Percent
1.375 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

Percent
8 RESERVE MARKET RATES
Effective federal funds rate a

7

1.250
6
August 13, 2003
5

1.125

Intended federal funds rate b

May 7, 2003

4

September 22, 2003
1.000

3

June 25, 2003

Primary credit rate b
2
0.875
Discount rate b

1

0.750
May

0
2000

2001

2002

2003

Sept.
2003

Nov.

Jan.

Mar.

May

July

2004

Percent
8.0
IMPLIED FORWARD RATES AND IMPLIED

Percent, weekly average
7.0 YIELD CURVE c,d
6.5

7.5

6.0

7.0

5.5

6.5
August 15, 2003

YIELDS ON EURODOLLAR FUTURES

September 19, 2003, eurodollar futures

6.0

5.0

5.5

4.5

July

September 19, 2003

September 19, 2003, forward rates

5.0

4.0

4.5

May 9, 2003

3.5

4.0

3.0

June 27, 2003, eurodollar futures

3.5

2.5

3.0

June 27,2003

2.0

2.5

1.5

2.0

1.0

1.5

0.5

1.0

0
0

5

10

15

20

0.5
2003 2004

June 27, 2003, forward rates

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Weekly average of daily figures.
b. Daily observations.
c. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
d. Average for the week ending on the date shown.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases H.15; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

At its September 16 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
did not change either the federal
funds rate target (1%) or the primary
credit rate (2%). At its August and
September meetings, the FOMC
affirmed that “the accommodative
stance of monetary policy, coupled
with robust underlying growth in
productivity, is providing important
ongoing support to economic activity.” Furthermore, it “believes that
policy accommodation can be maintained for a considerable period.”

Considering these statements, it is
understandable that no future policy
actions seem imminent. Virtually
none of the participants in federal
funds futures markets expect a rate
hike this year, although a few are starting to bet that the FOMC might start
hiking rates sometime in the first half
of next year.
An important determinant of
future interest rates is what funds
rate the market expects will prevail in
the future. This expectation may be
measured by forward rates, which are
calculated from the yield curve on

U.S. government bonds or by the
yield on eurodollar futures. These
measures are very similar, but rates
based on eurodollar futures are
higher than forward rates calculated
from government bonds. The extra
risk present in eurodollar futures suggests that implied forward rates are
better at gauging future policy actions.
Although this measure is likely to be
an overestimate, it suggests that the
funds rate may be hiked 100 basis
points by the end of 2004 and perhaps
250 basis points by the end of 2005.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Business Cycles and Monetary Policy
Percent
6.0 IMPLIED FORWARD RATES

Percent change from trough
6 EMPLOYMENT

5.5
5

August 15, 2003
5.0

4

4.5

Average a

September 19, 2003
4.0

3

3.5
2

May 9, 2003

3.0

1

2.5
June 27, 2003

1991:IQ expansion

2.0

0

1.5
2001:IVQ expansion

–1

1.0
0.5
2003

–2
2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

1

3
4
Quarters from trough

2

5

6

Percent change from trough
7 PRODUCTIVITY b

Percent change from trough
11 REAL GDP

2001:IVQ expansion

10
6
9
8

5

Average a
7

4
6

Average a

5

1991:IQ expansion

3

4
2001:IVQ expansion

3

2

2

1

1991:IQ expansion
1

0

0
1

2

3
4
Quarters from trough

5

6

1

2

3
4
Quarters from trough

5

6

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Average of expansions that started in 1975:IQ, 1980:IIIQ, and 1982:IVQ.
b. Nonfarm business sector.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” H.15, Federal Reserve Statistical Releases.

The period after the 1991 recession,
dubbed the “jobless recovery,” was
not historically typical; the current
episode, sometimes called the
“job-loss recovery,” is even more
anomalous. In the typical recovery,
employment has increased nearly 5%
six quarters after the National Bureau
of Economic Research officially announces that the recession is over.
In the six quarters since the NBER’s
most recent end-date announcement,
however, employment has fallen
nearly 1%. Not surprisingly, real output also has languished, rising only 4%
since 2001:IVQ. This contrasts with

the 9% that GDP has usually advanced
at this stage in a recovery.
Should monetary policy concern
itself with slow job growth? Initially,
the answer seems unambiguous. Job
losses—and thus a stubbornly high
unemployment rate—suggest slack
or unused economic resources. Monetary policy could potentially help
employ these resources. According
to this view, output running below
potential has also kept inflation
low—indeed, it has decreased inflation somewhat—since the recession
ended. This bleak situation is masked
by strong growth in productivity,

which has increased more since the
trough than it typically does. Potential output, led by strong productivity,
is advancing, but GDP’s inability to
keep up with these advances leaves a
persistently high output gap.
The view that monetary policy
should try to stimulate output is not
universal, however. Some fear that
the federal funds rate, currently at 1%,
cannot be further eased without
pushing it to a point where further
cuts would be impossible. At that
point, monetary policy might be powerless to offset further unwelcome
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Business Cycles and Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percentage point change from trough b
1.5 CORE INFLATION

Basis point change from trough
100 EFFECTIVE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
50

1.0

0

2001:IVQ expansion

Average a

0.5

–50

0

–100
2001:IVQ expansion

–0.5

–150

1991:IQ expansion
–1.0
Average a

–200
1991:IQ expansion

–1.5

–250
–2.0

–300

–2.5

–350

–3.0

–400
1

2

3
4
Quarters from trough

5

1

6

3
4
Quarters from trough

2

Percentage point change from trough c
0.50 ONE-YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS

Percent
2.50 TEMPORARY LAYOFF RATE d

0.25

2.25

5

6

2.00

0
2001:IVQ expansion

1.75

–0.25
1.50
–0.50
1.25
–0.75
1.00
1991:IQ expansion

–1.00

0.75

1982:IVQ expansion
–1.25

0.50

–1.50

0.25
0

–1.75
1

2

3
4
Quarters from trough

5

6

1967

1972

1977

1982

1987

1992

1997

2002

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: Shaded areas indicate recessions.
a. Average of expansions that started in 1975:IQ, 1980:IIIQ, and 1982:IVQ.
b. Inflation is calculated from personal consumption expenditures less food and energy, Chain Price Index.
c. Median expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
d. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases H.15; and University of Michigan.

declines in inflation or forestall another recession.
Even without these worries, it is not
certain that monetary policy should be
accommodative. This prescription
generally assumes that there is a positive output gap. Unfortunately, the
output gap is not observable, so monetary policymakers must try to gauge it
by examining other variables, such as
unemployment and inflation. But this
is an imperfect method that can be
misleading for at least two reasons.

First, falling inflation does not necessarily imply a positive output gap.
There is a lot of persistence in the
inflation series, so inflation may continue to decline even after the gap has
been closed. Adherents of this view
observe that, although inflation has
declined slightly since the trough, the
drop is smaller than is typical during a
recovery. Nor do the job losses since
the trough, troubling though they are,
necessarily indicate a positive output
gap. The so-called natural rate of unemployment (the unemployment rate

consistent with “full employment”) is
also unobservable. During periods
when the economy is undergoing
major structural change, this natural
rate will be high. Even though the
causes of the current job-loss recovery
are still unclear, it seems increasingly
likely that much of its unemployment
results from structural, rather than
cyclical, changes. Temporary layoffs,
which indicate cyclical unemployment, barely increased during the
most recent recession.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Japanese Intervention
Yen per dollar, closing New York spot rate
124 JAPANESE FOREIGN EXCHANGE INTERVENTION a

Billions of yen
1,200

1,000

122
Dollar intervention on day without euro intervention
Exchange rate
120

800

118

600

Dollar intervention on day with euro intervention
116

400

114

200

0

112
January

February

March

April

May

June

July

August

September

October

2003
Yen per dollar, closing New York spot rate
350 JAPANESE EXCHANGE RATE

Japanese Purchases of U.S. Dollars

Actual

Expected
(if random)b

Did official Japanese
purchase of dollars...
...prompt a dollar
appreciation?
...moderate a dollar
depreciation?

300

250

15

16

5

20

200

150

...appear generally
successful?

20

Total interventions

35

Total days in sample

21
100

172
50
1973

1978

1983

1988

1993

1998

2003

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. The Japanese Ministry of Finance has not yet released daily details on foreign exchange interventions after June 2003. However, from July 1 through
July 29, intervention operations totaled approximately $17.1 billion (equivalent). From July 30 through August 29, the ministry did not conduct any foreign
exchange intervention.
b. Assumes that successes have a hypergeometric distribution.
SOURCES: Japanese Ministry of Finance; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

The Japanese Ministry of Finance has
recently come under criticism for its
frequent, heavy interventions in the
foreign exchange market. Although
these transactions sometimes give
the yen a bit of a nudge, they seem
incapable of offering the competitive
push that critics fear.
During the first half of this year,
the Japanese Ministry of Finance entered the foreign exchange market
on 35 days. Many of these interventions were unannounced and conducted so as to disguise their official

nature. All of them involved official
purchases of dollars, which suggests
that the Ministry of Finance sought
to prevent—or at least minimize—
any depreciation of the dollar against
the yen.
Twenty of these transactions—
nearly 60% of the total—appeared
successful in terms of either promoting an appreciation or moderating a
depreciation of the dollar. But 60%
is not a very good success rate. Given
the choppy nature of day-to-day exchange rate movements, one would

expect 21 such successes to occur
purely by chance. The Ministry of
Finance would have to score at least
26 successes to claim an influence on
the exchange rate.
Studies of intervention have shown
that the Japanese Ministry of Finance
has sometimes affected day-to-day
movements in the yen-dollar exchange
rate. But these interventions did not
affect exchange rate fundamentals and
therefore did not give Japan any competitive trade advantage.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

International Reserves: Expensive Insurance
Billions of dollars
600 FOREIGN EXCHANGE RESERVES

Billions of dollars
120 FOREIGN EXCHANGE RESERVES

500

100

400

80

Singapore
Japan
300

60
China

200

40

Malaysia

Thailand

Hong Kong
20

100
Korea

Indonesia

0

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

Japanese yen

Korean won

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Billions of dollars
Percent of total foreign holdings
50
500 FOREIGN HOLDINGS OF U.S. TREASURIES b

Percent change, February 2002–September 2003
5 U.S. DOLLAR DEPRECIATION RELATIVE
TO FOREIGN CURRENCIES a

0

2004

Thai baht

400

Japan

40

300

30

–10

200

20

–15

100

–5

Singapore dollar

China
Major Currency Index

10
Hong Kong Germany

U. K.

Korea

Taiwan

Indonesian rupiah
0

0

–20

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. China and Hong Kong peg their exchange rate to the dollar.
b. Includes both private and official holdings.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Survey of Current Business, July 2003; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.10; International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; and Bloomberg
Financial Information Services.

Since the 1997–98 financial crisis,
many East Asian countries have
greatly increased their holdings of
foreign exchange reserves as insurance against exchange rate fluctuations and international crises. Foreignexchange reserves are highly liquid,
interest-bearing instruments denominated in one of the world’s key
currencies—U.S. dollars, Japanese
yen, or euros. The exact currency
compositions of countries’ reserve
portfolios are confidential, but the
lion’s share seems to be in dollars.
Japan, China, Taiwan, Hong Kong,
South Korea, and Singapore are now

the world’s largest holders of foreign
exchange reserves.
Some of these countries have
acquired foreign exchange to keep
their own currencies from appreciating. At its current exchange rate peg,
the People’s Bank of China must continuously buy dollars to satisfy an excess demand for renminbi. Similarly,
in recent years, the Japanese Ministry
of Finance has frequently purchased
dollars to prevent the yen from appreciating against the dollar.
Once a country holds a foreign
exchange portfolio, it can sell it to
defend its currency’s exchange value,

an important ability in an international financial crisis. The debt of
most emerging market economies is
denominated in foreign currencies,
not in their own. The depreciation
that typically accompanies a financial
crisis causes the local currency value
of foreign debts to soar, making debt
servicing costs even more onerous.
Holding substantial international
reserves seems expensive. The return
typically earned, though safe, is small
compared to the interest costs of the
holder nation’s debt and relative to
the return on investment in domestic
development projects.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Percentage points
3.0 CONTRIBUTION TO PERCENT CHANGE IN REAL GDP

a

Real GDP and Components, 2003:IIQ
(Preliminary estimate)

Annualized
Change, percent change, last:
billions
Four
of 1996 $
Quarter
quarters

Real GDP
77.4
Personal consumption 63.0
Durables
56.1
Nondurables
6.7
Services
13.1
Business fixed
investment
20.9
Equipment
19.6
Structures
2.2
Residential investment
6.5
Government spending 35.9
National defense
40.5
Net exports
–35.8
Exports
–2.6
Imports
33.3
Change in business
inventories
–22.4

3.3
3.8
24.3
1.4
1.4

2.5
2.9
8.2
3.4
1.7

7.3
8.2
4.2
6.6
8.5
45.8
__
–1.0
8.8

1.0
4.0
–8.0
6.7
4.1
13.7
__
–0.9
3.1

__

__

2003:IIQ

2.0

Government
spending

1.5
1.0
Residential
investment

0.5

Exports

0
Business fixed
investment
–0.5
Change in
inventories

–1.0

Imports

Percent change from previous year
7 REAL PERSONAL INCOME AND SPENDING TRENDS

Final percent change
Blue Chip forecast

4.0

Last four quarters

Personal
consumption

–1.5

Percent change from previous quarter b
5.0 REAL GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST
4.5

2.5

6
Real disposable personal income

30-year average

3.5

5

3.0
4
2.5
3

2.0
1.5

2
Real personal
consumption expenditures

1.0
1
0.5
0

0
IIQ

IIIQ
2002

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2003

IVQ

IQ
2004

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars. Components of real GDP need not sum to the total because the total and all components are deflated using
independent chain-weight indexes.
b. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, September 10, 2003.

The final estimate of real gross domestic product (GDP) for 2003:IIQ
was 3.3%, revised up 0.2 percentage
point from the preliminary release,
with modest boosts in some sectors
offsetting slight declines in others.
Housing, inventories, and government spending contributed more to
growth than was previously reported,
whereas capital spending and net
exports contributed less. Spending
on durable goods, the strongest component of personal consumption

expenditures, rose 24.3% for the
quarter. Leading the way for government spending, defense spending
went up $46 billion, an annualized increase of 45.8% over the previous
quarter and 13.7% over the past year.
Residential investment remained
strong, up 6.6%.
The revisions did not affect which
categories contributed most to the
2003:IIQ increase in real GDP. These
remained personal consumption
expenditures (2.7 percentage points),

government spending (1.6), and nonresidential fixed investment (0.3).
Inventory investment (–0.7) and imports (–1.2) continued to constitute a
significant drag on real output growth.
Blue Chip forecasters are optimistic about the outlook for GDP
growth in the next few quarters.
They forecast growth of 4.5% in
2003:IIIQ and 3.9% in each of the two
quarters after that, well above the
3.1% average growth rate of the last
30 years. Supporting this optimistic
(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Percent change from previous business peak a
4 MANUFACTURING CAPACITY UTILIZATION b

Billions of dollars
Billions of dollars c
340
485
MANUFACTURERS' INVENTORIES AND NEW ORDERS

2

0

333

475

326

465

Average, 1948–2000

–2
Current business cycle
–4

New orders
319

–6

455

Inventories

–8
312

445

–10
305

–12
0

3

6

9

12
15
18
21 24
Months from previous peak

27

30

33

Percent change from previous quarter c
30 REAL BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT AND COMPONENTS

435
1/01

36

7/01

1/02

7/02

1/03

7/03

Billions of dollars c
900 CORPORATE PROFITS d

20
Total real business fixed investment

850

Structures
10
Equipment and software
800

0

–10

750

–20
700
–30

650

–40
1/00

7/00

1/01

7/01

1/02

7/02

1/03

1/00

7/00

1/01

7/01

1/02

7/02

1/03

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Seasonally adjusted.
b. The shaded area represents a 95% confidence interval (the 1948–2000 average, plus or minus two times the standard error).
c. Seasonally adjusted at annual rates.
d. Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

view, real disposable income rose almost 3.3% over the last year, outpacing the 2.7% posted by real personal
consumption expenditures.
Observers seeking confirmation
that the economy continues to improve must look beyond August’s
72.7% reading for manufacturing
capacity utilization. Although this
series performed better than usual
in the six quarters since the last business cycle peak, its performance
relative to previous business cycles

worsened over the last few months
and is now in the lower range of the
average postwar experience.
Fortunately, there are also several
positive signs for future economic activity. Even though manufacturers
have continued to economize by trimming their inventories, new orders
have trended up for the last two years.
Another positive sign is that overall
business fixed investment rebounded
nearly 8% in 2003:IIQ. In fact, investment in equipment and software grew

8.2% and has risen in four of the last
five quarters. Investment in structures
grew 7.2%, its first increase since
2001:IIQ.
Finally, corporate profits have continued their comeback, rising 10.8%
between 2003:IQ and 2003:IIQ. If
corporate profits remain strong,
firms will be in a good position to
take advantage of new opportunities
and perhaps raise employment.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
300 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT CHANGE
250

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

Preliminary
Revised

200

Jan.–Aug. Sept.
2003
2003
–49
57

2000
161

2001
–149

2002
–39

–1
7
–9
2
–11

–124
–1
–123
–88
–35

–64
–4
–57
–41
–16

–44
12
–54
–38
–17

–17
14
–29
–17
–12

Service providing
162
Information
15
Financial activitiesa
6
b
PBS
40
Education and health
32
Leisure and hospitalityc
22
Government
22

–25
–15
7
–63
51
–2
46

25
–14
5
–10
37
7
16

–5
–11
11
11
17
4
–13

74
–4
10
66
9
–3
–15

Payroll employment

150
Goods producing
Construction
Manufacturing
Durable goods
Nondurable goods

100
50
0
–50
–100

Average for period (percent)
Civilian unemployment
rate

–150

4.0

4.8

5.8

6.0

6.1

–200
1999 2000 2001 2002

IVQ
2002

IQ

July

IIQ IIIQ
2003

Aug. Sept.
2003

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS

Percent
6.5

Percent
9.0 PRIVATE-SECTOR GROSS JOB GAINS AND LOSSES
AS A SHARE OF EMPLOYMENT

Employment-to-population ratio
6.0

64.5

8.5
Gross job gains

5.5

64.0

8.0
63.5

5.0

63.0

4.5

62.5

4.0

7.5
Gross job losses

7.0

Civilian unemployment rate
3.5

62.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

6.5
7/92

7/93

7/94

7/95

7/96

7/97

7/98

7/99

7/00

7/01

7/02

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
a. Financial activities include the finance, insurance, and real estate sector and the rental and leasing sector.
b. Professional and business services include professional, scientific, and technical services, management of companies and enterprises, administrative and
support, and waste management and remediation services.
c. Leisure and hospitality includes arts, entertainment, and recreation, as well as accommodation and food service.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

After losing a revised 41,000 jobs in
August, total nonfarm employment
posted a net gain of 57,000 in September, its first increase in eight
months. The revisions halved the figure reported earlier.
In September, goods producers lost
17,000 jobs net, compared to the average net monthly loss of 81,000 since
the March 2001 peak. Manufacturing
employment’s decline continued, but
at a much slower pace (29,000 in September compared to the 54,000 average monthly loss from January to August). Construction remained strong,
growing by 14,000 jobs in September.
Service providers added 74,000 jobs,

most of them (66,000) in professional
and business services. Financial activities increased by 10,000 jobs, consistent with the January–August average
monthly change. Education and health
services added 9,000. Government
continued to shed jobs (15,000) in
September. A drop of 4,000 continued
the downward trend in information
services, which has lost jobs every
month this year.
The unemployment rate remained
unchanged at 6.1%. The employmentto-population ratio inched down 0.1
percentage point to 62.0.
In September, the Bureau of Labor
Statistics began to publish a new data

series, Business Employment Dynamics, which tracks private business establishments’ quarterly net gains and
losses. As a share of employment,
gross gains exceeded gross losses
every quarter from September 1992
through December 2000, producing a
net increase in the number of jobs.
The 2001 recession caused a large temporary increase in the rate of gross job
losses and a large decline in the rate of
gross job gains. The surprisingly weak
employment growth of 2002 reflected
reluctance to hire workers rather than
continued job losses at contracting and
closing establishments.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The United Auto Workers’ Contract
Constant 2002 dollars
29 AUTO PRODUCTION WAGES

Contract Highlights
What the UAW achieved:
Wage rate increases of 2% in the third year and 3% in
the fourth year.

27

Motor vehicles, average a

A pension increase for future retirees.
25

Better medical coverage.
What the auto companies achieved:
For the first two years, bonuses will substitute for wage
increases.
Current retirees will not receive monthly pension
increases.

UAW assembler, straight time
23

21
Motor vehicle parts, average

Created flexibility to close or sell plants.
Higher employee copays for name-brand prescription
drugs.
Tougher restrictions on absenteeism.

19

17
1992 1993

UAW Membership at the End of 2003:IQ

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001 2002

Characteristics of UAW Workers

General
Motors

Delphi

Ford

Daimler
Visteon Chrysler

Active
members

117,780

30,100

72,570

21,880

60,170

Median ageb

Retired
members

228,550

6,310

77,460

*

57,490

Surviving
spouses

63,480

140

24,220

*

17,580

GM/
Delphi

Ford/
Visteon

Daimler
Chrysler

48.9

44.1

43.0

Average years of
serviceb

23.3

16.6

14.8

Percent of members
eligible to retire
within five yearsc

60%

39%

33%

*Included with Ford employees.

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
a. Motor vehicles comprise automobiles and light trucks. The data series for motor vehicles and motor vehicle parts are reported as production workers’
average hourly earnings.
b. End of 2001:IVQ.
c. End of 2003:IQ
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; United Auto Workers; and Detroit Free Press.

In September, the United Auto Workers (UAW) finished negotiating its
contract with the Big Three automakers—General Motors, Ford, and
DaimlerChrysler. During this round,
the UAW aimed to speed negotiations and create a cooperative environment, hoping to help the Big
Three maintain their domestic market share and limit the expansion of
transplant factories, the largely nonunion domestic plants of historically
offshore automakers. Honda, Toyota,
and Nissan are the three largest
foreign-owned producers in the U.S.

The UAW agreed to accept bonuses
instead of wage increases in 2004 and
2005, followed by wage increases of
2% in 2006 and 3% in 2007. Auto production workers’ actual average earnings, as measured by the Bureau of
Labor Statistics, typically exceed the
contract figure reached in negotiations
($27.80 per hour in 2002). This occurs
because some workers belong to
higher-wage trades and many receive
additional pay for working overtime or
night shifts.
Workers in plants making motor
vehicle parts earn substantially less.
The new UAW contracts with Delphi,
formerly part of General Motors, and

Visteon, formerly part of Ford, include
wage concessions to help keep them
competitive.
Because the UAW represents far
more retirees than active workers,
pensions and associated retirement
benefits were key issues in the negotiations. The number of retirees covered under the contract is expected
to keep rising as companies continue
to trim their labor forces and encourage early retirement. The contract
increased future retirees’ pensions
9% over four years but reigned in the
costs associated with current retirees
by eliminating monthly increases.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Motor Vehicle Production
Millions of units
20 LIGHT VEHICLE SALES IN THE U.S. MARKET a

2002 MARKET SHARE

18
16

Big Three import sales

International imports
Other
19%

14

Chrysler Group
13%

Foreign-owned plants in the U.S.

12

Toyota
10%

10

Ford
21%

8
Honda
7%

6

General Motors
30%

Big Three domestic sales b

4
2
0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

Index, 1997=100
130 LABOR PRODUCTIVITY

Thousands
900 NONFARM EMPLOYMENT c
800

120
Motor vehicle parts

700

110
600
Motor vehicle parts
100

500

Motor vehicles

400
90
300
Motor vehicles

80

200
100
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

70
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted unless otherwise noted.
a. The international firms included are Honda, Mitsubishi, Nissan, Subaru, and Toyota.
b. Domestically produced sales, including Canada.
c. Not seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and United Auto Workers.

The future of domestic motor vehicle
production was a critical issue in the
recent United Auto Workers’ negotiations. In 1999, Ford, General Motors,
and DaimlerChrysler (the Big Three)
agreed not to close any facilities for
the term of the contract. In the most
recent round, the UAW agreed to let
those automakers reduce some of
their excess capacity by closing certain facilities, some potentially in the
Fourth District.

Cars produced in foreign-owned
plants have continued to gain U.S.
market share, despite the steady
stream of incentives offered by
domestic manufacturers. Total sales
of light vehicles (automobiles and
light trucks) are still reasonably
robust: 16.4 million over the last 12
months. The Big Three’s share of
total sales fell from about 82% in
2002:IIQ to 79% in 2003:II.
Honda, Toyota, and Nissan, whose
cars are selling very well, are producing

more of them in U.S. plants. Honda
now makes an annual 815,000 units in
the U.S., roughly 68% of the number
they sold here in the last 12 months.
During that period, Toyota and Nissan
produced a combined 1.1 million
units, about 49% of their U.S. sales.
Although total U.S. sales and production figures have been remarkably steady for a recession, employment in motor vehicle assembly and
parts has been trending down since

(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Motor Vehicle Production (cont.)
MANUFACTURING OF MOTOR VEHICLES AND EQUIPMENT AS A SHARE OF EMPLOYMENT, 1990

7.3%
4.7%

2.9%

Not reported a
Less than 0.25%
0.26%–0.50%
0.51%–1.00%
1.01–2.00%
More than 2.00%

MANUFACTURING OF MOTOR VEHICLES AND EQUIPMENT AS A SHARE OF EMPLOYMENT, 2002

6.0%
4.4%

2.5%

Not reported a
Less than 0.25%
0.26%–0.50%
0.51%–1.00%
1.01–2.00%
More than 2.00%

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted unless otherwise noted.
a. These states do not meet the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ reporting standards, primarily because their auto industry employment is low.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and United Auto Workers.

June 2000. Productivity growth in
these industries has been substantial.
Since 1999, the parts industry, which is
characterized by intense competition,
has shown the strongest gains.
The Fourth District has a relatively
large stake in auto production. In
2002, auto and parts production
accounted for 2.5% of Ohio’s workforce and 1.1% of Kentucky’s, compared with the national average of
0.9%. The Fourth District’s overall

share has been fairly stable since
1990, with auto production consolidating around the I-75 corridor and
expanding south. Much of the District’s gain in auto employment
occurred because foreign automakers located substantial facilities here.
Honda’s Ohio plants employ 1% of
the state’s assembly workers and
have drawn many suppliers to the
area. Similarly, the Toyota plant that
opened in 1998 in Georgetown,
Kentucky, accounts for almost all

of that state’s assembly jobs and
increased employment in parts production as well.
The District’s auto manufacturing
jobs will probably drop, more likely
because of workforce attrition than
through the recently negotiated closings of plants under the new UAW
contract. The Ford assembly plant in
Lorain, which employs 1,700 workers,
is the largest of the plants in the District that are suggested for closure.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FDIC-Insured Commercial Banks
Billions of dollars
25 NET INCOME a

Billions of dollars
120 SOURCES OF INCOME
Total interest income

Net operating income
20

100

15

80

10

60

5

40
Securities and other gains/losses

Total noninterest income

0

20

–5

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Percent
4.7 NET INTEREST MARGIN AND ASSET GROWTH

2003 b

1995

Percent
12

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Percent
1.5 EARNINGS

2003 b

Percent
20

Asset growth rate
10

4.5

Return on equity

Return on assets

1.4

16

1.3

12

1.2

8

1.1

4

Net interest margin

8

4.3

6

4.1

3.9

4

3.7

2

3.5

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 b

1.0

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 b

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
b. Through 2003:IIQ. Data are annualized.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

In 2003:IIQ, FDIC-insured commercial banks’ net operating income improved slightly from the previous
quarter and recovered strongly from
its dip in 2002:IVQ. Compared to the
second quarter of last year, it was
up 5.0%. Net income (net operating
income plus securities gains and
losses) also improved, increasing 9.2%
from a year ago. Lower credit losses
and substantial gains on securities
sales fuelled overall earnings growth.
Commercial banks’ total interest
income, $85 billion, was unchanged

from the previous quarter. Falling
interest rates made this figure significantly lower than the $113 billion
reported in 2000:IVQ. Total noninterest income continued to grow, rising
7.9% from a year ago, another sign
that the earnings pressures affecting
banks during the 2001 recession are
finally abating.
Overall earnings (interest plus dividends earned on interest-bearing
assets minus interest paid to depositors and creditors, expressed as a
percentage of average earning assets)

improved, even though the net interest margin declined from 4.09% in
2002 to 3.85% in 2003:IIQ.
Low interest rates are one cause of
shrinking margins, but strong asset
growth is just as important. FDICinsured commercial banks’ assets
grew an annualized 11.7% in 2003:IIQ,
the best showing in almost a decade.
But even with near-record asset
growth, depository institutions’ 1.4%
return on assets was the highest since
1989. At 15.3%, return on equity was
also at its highest level since 1999.
(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FDIC-Insured Commercial Banks (cont.)
Percent of assets
63 NET LOANS AND LEASES

Percent
0.6

Percent of loans and leases
1.2 ASSET QUALITY

0.5

1.0

61

Problem assets
0.4

0.8
Net charge-offs

59
0.6

0.3

0.4

0.2

0.2

0.1

57

55

53

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 a

Percent
9 HEALTH

0
1995

Percent
2.00

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 a

Ratio
8.0 CORE CAPITAL

Percent
200
Coverage ratio

8

1.75

7

1.50

7.9
Unprofitable banks

Problem banks

6

1.25

5

1.00

4

0.75

3

0.50

2

0.25
0

1
1995

1996

1997

1998

180
Core capital (leverage) ratio

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 a

7.8

160

7.7

140

7.6

120

7.5

100
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003 a

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Through 2003:IIQ. Data are annualized.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

In 2003:IIQ, FDIC-insured commercial banks’ net loans and leases
fell slightly to 56.3% of total assets
from 57.8% a year ago. Net loans and
leases rose 8.4%, but total assets grew
11.2%, producing a slightly lower yearover-year ratio. Although the ratio was
well below the 2000:IIIQ high of
61.3%, lending was brisk in 2003:IQ,
partly because low interest rates
boosted refinancing activity.
Asset quality showed signs of improvement in 2003:IIQ. Net chargeoffs (uncollectible loans and leases

removed from the balance sheet,
minus recoveries) fell to 0.9% of total
loans, the first decrease since 1999.
Problem assets (nonperforming loans
and repossessed real estate) fell to
0.41% of loans and leases from 0.53%
at the end of 2002. Improved asset
quality reflects the lower debt-servicing
costs that result from refinancing at
lower interest rates and aggressive
tightening of lending standards.
FDIC-insured commercial banks’
improved asset quality is also apparent in the decline of unprofitable

institutions to a 5.4% share in 2003:IIQ.
Problem banks (those with substandard exam ratings) fell to a 1.4% share
of all banks. The coverage ratio (prudential reserves as a share of noncurrent loans and leases) rose from 127%
at the end of 2002 to 136% in 2003:IIQ,
the first increase since 1997. Core capital, which protects commercial banks
against unexpected losses, remained
flat at 7.84%. All of these performance
indicators point to strengthening in
the banking sector.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks
Percent, daily
7 MONETARY POLICY TARGETS a

Trillions of yen
–35

6

CHANGES IN POLICY RATES SINCE LAST FOMC CUT b

–30

5

C countries

–25
Bank of England

4
3

Bulgaria

–20

B countries

–15

European Central Bank

Mexico

–10

2
Federal Reserve

1

Sri Lanka

–5

0

0

–1

5
Bank of Japan

A countries
Indonesia
Norway

10

South Africa

–3

15

Lithuania

–4

20

–5

25

–6

30

–2

Brazil

Turkey

Venezuela

35

–7
4/1

9/28

3/27

9/23

3/22

0

–2

2003

2002

2001

9/18

Trillions of yen
36 BANK OF JAPAN c

–6
–4
Percentage points

–8

–10

–12

12-month rate
4.0 INFLATION RATES

33
Current account balances (daily)

U.K.

30

3.0

27
24

2.0

Current account balances

21
Euro area

18

1.0
U.S.

15
12

0
Japan

9
Current account less required reserves
6

–1.0
Excess reserve balances

3
0

–2.0
4/1

10/1
2001

4/1

10/1
2002

4/1

10/1

1/99

1/00

1/01

1/02

1/03

2003

FRB Cleveland • October 2003

a. Federal Reserve: overnight interbank rate. Bank of Japan: a quantity of current account balances (since December 19, 2001, a range of quantity of current
account balances). Bank of England and European Central Bank: two-week repo rate.
b. A countries are Israel and Peru; B countries are Canada and Thailand; C countries are Czech Republic, Malta, New Zealand, Philippines, South Korea, Sweden, and Taiwan.
c. Current account balances at the Bank of Japan are required and excess reserve balances at depository institutions subject to reserve requirements plus the
balances of certain other financial institutions not subject to reserve requirements. Reserve requirements are satisfied on the basis of the average of a bank’s
daily balances at the Bank of Japan starting the sixteenth of one month and ending the fifteenth of the next.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bank of Japan; European Central Bank;
Bank of England; Wholesale Markets Brokers Association; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

The major central banks’ operating
targets have not changed over the
past three months, but interest rate
cuts in other countries have been
common. The Bank of Japan’s supply
of current account balances crept up
within the unchanged target range
of ¥27 trillion–¥30 trillion. However,
that gain was small compared to the
almost sixfold gain in daily average
balances since August 2001. The
Bank of Japan also has announced a
one-year extension of its program for

purchasing stock from commercial
banks’ portfolios; like the U.S. Federal Open Market Committee, it has
discussed improving communication
of its policy intentions to the public.
In a September 14 referendum, 56%
of Swedish voters favored retaining
the krona as their national currency
instead of adopting the euro. Thus,
with the U.K. and Denmark, Sweden
remains a member of the European
Union but not of the European System
of Central Banks.

Inflation rates for the euro and the
dollar have converged over the past
year to a point just below the ECB’s
target ceiling, while Japan’s deflation
rate has moved up toward zero. The
U.K.’s inflation rate, however, has
stuck stubbornly above the government’s 2.5% target and is more than
one percentage point higher than an
alternative inflation index comparable to that used by the ECB. The government has announced that it will
target that alternative index starting
next year.