View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 2013 (October 17, 2013-November 12, 2013)

In This Issue:
Banking and Financial Markets
 Banks’ Liquidity Position

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 Taking Stock of the Labor Market Recovery

Growth and Production
 Does GDI Point to a Stronger Recovery?

Monetary Policy
 Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth,
October 2013

Inflation and Prices
 Implications of the Government Shutdown on
Inflation Estimates

Regional Economics
 Gentrification and Financial Health

Banking and Financial Markets

Banks’ Liquidity Position
11.12.13
by Lakshmi Balasubramanyan and Patricia
Waiwood

Core Deposits as a Percent of Total Assets
Percent
71
70
69
68
67
66
65
64
63
62
3/2009

3/2010

3/2011

3/2012

3/2013

Source: Federal Reserve, average across Banks for each quarter.

Loan Growth Less Core Deposit Growth
Rate
20
0
-20
-40
-60
-80
-100
3/2009

3/2010

3/2011

3/2012

3/2013

Source: Federal Reserve, average across Banks for each quarter.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

Ensuring adequate liquidity is an integral part of a
financial institution’s management. But how much
liquidity is enough? A financial firm is considered
liquid if it can obtain immediately spendable funds
at reasonable cost exactly when it needs them.
In light of the 2008 financial crisis, new international banking regulations, notably those of the
Third Basel Accord, pay close attention to banks’
liquidity. We make a high-level assessment of how
banks’ liquidity positions have changed since 2009.
(Note that the liquidity measures we discuss in this
article are not necessarily the same as those the Basel Committee suggests. See this report for a discussion of the Basel measures.) Our sample includes
state member, state non-member, and national
commercial banks in the United States. For each
quarter, our charts show averages across all banks in
the sample.
The liquidity position of banks has been improving
gradually since the end of the recession, partly because aggregate core deposits have increased. Core
deposits are those made by customers in a bank’s
general market area; they are a relatively stable
source of funds for lending because they are less
vulnerable than other funding sources to changes in
short-term interest rates. (Core deposits are calculated as total deposits minus total time deposits
of $100,000 or more minus total brokered retail
deposits of $100,000 or less.) Between the first
quarter of 2009 and the second quarter of 2013,
core deposits relative to assets rose steadily from 65
percent to about 70 percent.
But are core deposits capable of funding loan
growth? If not, banks would either have to curtail
lending or dip into more costly sources to fund it.
Neither one of these options is very desirable from
a borrower’s perspective. A simple measure for
capturing this is the difference between the growth
rates of lending and core deposits. Since the end of
2

the recession, this measure has been holding steady
around zero, with the exception of a drop and
rebound during 2012.

Net Non-Core Funding Dependence
Rate
20

A red flag would rise on the liquidity landscape if
banks were relying heavily on non-core funding to
finance loan growth. This is not the case, according to a measure called the net non-core funding
dependence ratio, which, as the name suggests,
gauges how heavily banks rely on non-core funding. This measure has declined steadily from almost
20 percent since 2009:Q1.

18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
3/2009

3/2010

3/2011

3/2012

3/2013

Source: Federal Reserve, average across Banks for each quarter.

US Treasury Securities
Millions of dollars
400

According to the Bank for International Settlements, during the early phase of the financial crisis,
many banks—despite adequate capital levels—experienced difficulties because they did not manage
their liquidity prudently. The crisis drove home the
importance of liquidity to the proper functioning
of financial markets and the banking sector to the
Basel III participants. Our basic analysis of banks’
liquidity position shows that, on average, banks
have improved in managing their liquidity.

350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
3/2009

Banks can tap another source of funds by selling
securities, such as US Treasury bonds, on their
books. Knowing this, we consider banks’ holdings
of US Treasury securities. Though banks’ holdings
have been somewhat volatile, they have increased
gradually. Starting at just under $200 million in
2009:Q1 and standing at just under $300 million
in 2013:Q2, the gradual increase is a plus, albeit a
small one, in our assessment of banks’ liquidity.

3/2010

3/2011

3/2012

3/2013

Source: Federal Reserve, average across Banks for each quarter.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

3

Growth and Production

Does GDI Point to a Stronger Recovery?
11.05.13
by Filippo Occhino

Real Output
Billions of chained 2009 dollars
16000
GDI
15500

15000
GDP
14500

14000
2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bar indicates a recession.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Gross Domestic Income (GDI) both measure the same economic
variable—the aggregate production of goods and
services within the US in a year. GDP computes
it as the sum of all expenditures (consumption,
investment, government spending, and net exports), while GDI computes it as the sum of all
incomes (employee compensation, profits, interest, rent, income from unincorporated businesses,
indirect taxes minus subsidies, depreciation). These
two measures may, sometimes, diverge because of
measurement errors. In the current recovery, in
particular, GDI has been growing faster than GDP.
Between the second quarter of 2009 and the second
quarter of 2013, GDI grew at a 2.65 annual rate,
while GDP grew only at a 2.23 annual rate, quite a
large difference for a four-year-long period. What is
the actual rate at which the economy is growing?
Both GDP and GDI have measurement strengths
and weaknesses, but if we compare the source data
used to compute the two measures, we are led to
put more trust in GDP than GDI as an indicator of
aggregate output. The source data used to compute GDP is generally better because it is mainly
based on business surveys collected for statistical
purposes, and it uses a consistent set of concepts
and definitions. In contrast, the source data used
to compute GDI is produced for a variety of other
purposes, since it is mainly based on financial statements and information from tax and regulatory
agencies, and it uses heterogeneous concepts and
definitions. GDP source data is also timelier—a
much larger fraction of source data is available for
the early GDP estimates than for the early GDI
estimates, so judgment and trend adjustments play
a much smaller role in the early GDP estimates
(See Landefeld 2010 for a thorough discussion of
the topic in this paragraph).
Some evidence, however, favors GDI over GDP as
a measure of aggregate output. Aruoba, Diebold,
Nalewaik, Schorfheide, and Song (2013) estimate

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

4

the unknown path of aggregate output solely based
on the known paths of GDP and GDI, and find
that GDI is, overall, a more accurate measure
than GDP. For instance, if we use their estimation
method (and the second model in their paper), we
find that aggregate output grew at a 2.51 annual
rate between the second quarter of 2009 and the
second quarter of 2013, closer to the GDI growth
rate than to the GDP growth rate.

Real Output Growth
Four-quarter percent change
4.0
3.5
3.0
GDI
2.5
Output
2.0
GDP
1.5
1.0
2010

2011

2012

2013

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; author’s calculation based on the second
model of Aruoba, Diebold, Nalewaik, Schorfheide and Song 2013.

On balance, the evidence suggests that the growth
rate of aggregate output in the recovery has been
in between the growth rates of GDP and GDI, up
to 0.25 percentage points faster than indicated by
GDP. The implications of this upward revision,
however, are rather limited.
The overall picture of the recovery is not much
changed. Even if we focus on the estimate of aggregate output in the second chart above—which
is obtained with a method that favors GDI over
GDP—the recovery still lacks an initial strong
rebound after the Great Recession, and its pace
continues to be moderate. The current level of output is still well below the forecasts that were made
back in 2007, before the beginning of the crisis (see
Behind the Slowdown of Potential GDP, Jacobson
and Occhino, February 2013).
Higher estimated output growth leads to only
slightly higher statistical estimates of trend output
growth. For instance, if we compute trend GDP
using a band-pass filter that eliminates all cycles
shorter than 30 years from GDP data, we find that
trend output is currently growing at a 2.21 annual
rate. If we apply the same method to the estimates
of aggregate output obtained using the estimation
method of Aruoba, Diebold, Nalewaik, Schorfheide, and Song, we find that trend output is currently growing at a 2.28 percent annual rate, just a
few basis points higher.
Faster estimated growth is only slightly more
consistent with the improvement that the labor
market has experienced in the recovery. While typically output grows fast when the unemployment
rate declines, in this recovery it has grown slowly,
even though the unemployment rate has declined
steadily. Higher estimated output growth, then,
is slightly more in line with past business cycles.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

5

However, the size of the revision is small relative
to the overall decline of the unemployment rate.
An upward revision to output of 0.25 percentage
points over a four-year period—for a cumulative 1
percentage point—roughly corresponds to a decline
in the unemployment rate of only 0.25 to 0.50
percentage points, based on common estimates of
Okun’s Law. This is rather small compared with the
overall decline of the unemployment rate over the
same period—almost 2 percentage points.

References
B. Aruoba, F. X. Diebold, J. Nalewaik, F. Schorfheide and D. Song,
“Improving GDP Measurement: A Measurement-Error Perspective”,
unpublished manuscript, April 2013.
J. Steven Landefeld, Spring 2010, comment to Jeremy J. Nalewaik,
“The Income- and Expenditure-Side Estimates of U.S. Output
Growth”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, pages 112-123.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

6

Inflation and Price Statistics

Implications of the Government Shutdown on Inflation Estimates
10.17.13
by Randal Verbrugge and Sara Millington
Each month, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)
releases estimates of the Consumer Price Index
(CPI) and the Producer Price Index (PPI). The government shutdown, which ended late on October
16, caused a delay in the release of these statistics
and many of the statistics and data products that
rely on them. But the shutdown will also affect the
accuracy of these statistics for months to come.
This article outlines the impact of the shutdown,
particularly on the accuracy of the CPI.
The repercussions on CPI estimates will continue
for at least seven months. Some of these repercussions will occur later this month, but the majority of the influence will occur the next month, in
November, when the monthly overall inflation
estimates derived from the CPI will be subject to
significant error. However, year-over-year inflation
estimates will continue to be quite reliable.
October Impact: Delay and Potential Processing
Error
There is always a half-month delay between the
collection of data and the construction of the CPI:
Releases in the middle of the month of October
pertain to data that were collected during September. Putting this differently, the September inflation rate (the difference between September’s CPI
and the previous month’s CPI) becomes known in
mid-October. Likewise, October data are released
in November.
Since the October release pertains to September
data, and all of these data were collected prior to
the shutdown, the chief October impact of the
shutdown will be that the release of the CPI will be
delayed. Commodity analysts in the BLS usually
spend the entire month processing data flowing in
from field offices around the country. Up until the
shutdown on October 1, these analysts were able
to process some of the data that had been obtained
in September, but as they return to work, they
will have a hard time catching up. The early parts
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

7

of the month are typically periods of heightened
activity, and there are strict limits on the amount
of overtime work that these analysts can undertake.
October’s CPI may also be subject to processing
error; under normal conditions, processing error is
miniscule, but under rushed conditions it is easy to
imagine some processing errors inadvertently creeping in.
Of course, the fact that many prices will not be collected in October will have repercussions later on.
In fact, these repercussions do not end until May of
2014.
November through May Impact: Sampling Error
There are two kinds of errors that might enter the
November release of October CPI data. First, it is
possible that there will be some processing error.
During the months of October and early November, commodity analysts will be rushing to catch up
their processing of the October data, subject again
to the constraint of limited overtime.
Second, and more importantly, is sampling error.
All statistics are prone to some sampling error,
leading to uncertainty surrounding those statistics.
By definition, statistics are based upon a sample of
the data, rather than the entire universe of data. An
estimate of the average is only an estimate; most
likely, the estimate is a little too high or a little too
low.
Statisticians measure the amount of uncertainty (or
the degree of accuracy) in a given statistic with another statistic, the standard error. The standard error of a statistic can be used to construct confidence
intervals, or likely ranges for the true value given
the specific estimate obtained from the sample. In
particular, the chance that an estimated statistic is
farther than one standard error away from the true
value is about 30 percent, while the chance that a
statistic is off by more than two times the standard
error is less than 5 percent. For example, if the
standard error is 0.4 percent, then we know that
there is less than a 5 percent chance that the statistic misses the true value by 0.8 percent or more. All
else equal, a bigger sample yields a more accurate
statistic; in other words, a bigger sample yields a
statistic with a smaller standard error.
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

8

Since the CPI price collection relies upon field staff
visiting shops, some of the October data will never
be collected. As a result, the November CPI release,
which is based upon October data, will have a
much bigger standard error due to the smaller sample. We can estimate how much bigger by weighing
the potential size of the October sample against
typical sample sizes, historical standard errors, and
the likely inflation rate.
The October sample will be half its usual size. Price
collection happens during the working days of the
month. The government was shut down for 11
working days, so the missing data represent about
50 percent of the price quotes (since there are 21
working days a month on average).

CPI Uncertainty: Monthly
Percent change
1.00

Historical CPI inflation estimates

Hypothetical
future CPI
inflation estimate

0.80
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.00
-0.20

Ordinary range of uncertainty
October range of uncertainty

-0.40
-0.60
2/13

3/13

4/13

5/13

6/13

7/13

8/13

9/13

10/13

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics/Haver Analytics.

The monthly standard error was most recently estimated by the BLS to be 0.03 percent for the 2011
CPI, based upon 83,300 price quotes. A standard
error estimate of 0.03 percent is probably still
the best estimate for post-2012 data. The median
monthly percentage price change in the CPI for
this period was 0.14 percent (roughly corresponding to an annualized average of about 1.6 percent),
and the available evidence suggests that the noise in
CPI estimates does not fall appreciably when inflation is low. However, with approximately half of
the price quotes missing, the standard error would
rise to at least 0.042 percent.
This level of error gives rise to considerable uncertainty about the true monthly inflation rate. For
example, suppose that the October CPI ends up
being estimated at its median, 0.14 percent, and
we wish to have a wide-enough confidence interval
so that we are wrong only 5 percent of the time. In
this case, the range of uncertainty about this 0.14
percent estimate would be that true monthly inflation in September was somewhere between 0.05
percent and 0.22 percent.
Impact on Annual CPI Statistics
While the monthly inflation rate will be subject
to this uncertainty, other commonly used statistics
computed using CPI data will have smaller errors.
For example, the estimated standard error in yearover-year inflation under ordinary circumstances
is 0.07 percent, but that is compared to a median

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

9

of about 1.88 percent in 2013. Because the yearover-year inflation rate is computed based upon
twelve separate one-month inflation estimates,
even if one particular month has a standard error as
large as 0.042 percent, this will cause only a modest increase in the uncertainty of this twelve-month
measure. Furthermore, in the situation we are
examining, errors in the October CPI (released in
November) start to be cancelled out in the November CPI (released in December).
Why doesn’t the October CPI error just disappear in the November CPI (which is released in
December)? If the prices of all goods and services
were collected each month, then this is exactly
what would happen. For example, if the October
inflation estimate happened to be too high because
of missing price quotes, then—once those prices
were once again collected—the November inflation
estimate would be too low, owing to all those price
changes being properly accounted for, and that
would be the end of it. Any errors due to a small
sample that cause a problem in one month would
be exactly reversed in the next month, so that the
price level—the index itself, not the inflation estimate—would go back to where it would have been,
had all the data actually been collected in October.
But since not all prices are collected every month,
not all of the error will be reversed right away. In
fact, the price index will not return to its original
course for another six months. This period is so
long for cost reasons. The BLS has divided all the
goods and services it collects prices on into three
categories: goods whose prices are collected each
month in all cities; goods whose prices are collected
only every other month in most cities (exceptions
are Chicago, Los Angeles, and New York City,
where all commodities and services except rents are
priced monthly); and rents. Rents are collected only
every six months; if the rental price on a particular
rental unit is collected in January, then the rent on
that unit will next be collected in July.
Because of this, pricing errors that relate to
monthly items (such as food) will be reversed in
the November inflation estimate. But pricing errors
that relate to bimonthly items (such as vehicles in
Cleveland or women’s shoes in Baltimore) will not
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

10

be reversed until the December inflation estimate is
released (in January). To see how this works, consider a hypothetical example.
Suppose that the true average price increase of
automobiles in Cleveland between August and December is 1.0 percent per month. Of course, some
cars rise more in price, and some rise less in price.
Suppose that the BLS normally collects 30 vehicle
prices per month, but owing to the shutdown, it
was only able to collect 15 vehicle prices in October. And suppose that these vehicles just happened
to be cars that experienced quite rapid increases in
price, so that the estimated October price increase
for Cleveland automobiles happened to be 1.9 percent. The missing price quotes are not used in the
October CPI, but the BLS still estimates the missing prices. It does so by assuming that those prices
also rose by 1.9 percent.
In December, the BLS field staff is once again able
to visit all the dealerships in their Cleveland sample. Those rapid-price-increase cars are again priced,
and their two-month price changes enter the inflation estimate as usual. But this time the field staff is
also able to collect prices from those other vehicles,
the ones that did not experience much inflation.
The estimated inflation rate is based upon the
actual price versus the estimated October price—so
the estimated inflation rates are negative for those
cars. As a result, the December inflation estimate
will be about 0.1 percent.
This means that over the four-month period, September to December, the average inflation rate for
cars in Cleveland ends up being about 1.0 percent,
as it should be. (For a more detailed description
of BLS methods used in constructing the CPI, see
chapter 17 in the BLS Handbook of Methods,
available at www.bls.gov.)
Meanwhile, since rents are only collected every six
months, errors would only be removed in the April
collection. In other words, any error in the October
rent inflation estimate would be reversed in the
April inflation estimate.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

11

In terms of CPI inflation estimates, then, the following summarizes the errors owing to the shutdown:
October—delays and possible processing errors in the September CPI estimate
•

November—sampling error in the October
CPI estimate
•

December—unwinding of October sampling
error in monthly items in the November CPI estimate
•

January—unwinding of October sampling
error in bimonthly items in the December CPI
estimate
•

May—unwinding of October sampling error
in rents in the April CPI estimate
•

Other Aggregate Statistics
The CPI is not the only statistic that will be affected
by the government shutdown. The Federal Reserve
System focuses on the price index associated with
the Personal Consumption Expenditure estimate in
the national accounts. This index is called the PCEPI. Since CPI data movements underlie most of the
PCE-PI computation, most of the errors and any
delays in the CPI would be reflected in the PCE-PI.
Furthermore, the PCE-PI computation will be affected by other data products produced by the BLS.
The BLS produces Producer Price Indexes, which
will also be delayed and subject to errors over the
coming months. These data are used fairly intensively in the PCE-PI as well.
These delays and errors don’t just influence inflation
estimates: any errors in PCE-PI translate directly
into errors in aggregate consumption estimates.
Furthermore, aggregate GDP computations will
also suffer from missing producer price data; these
directly impact productivity estimates and aggregate output estimates. However, aggregate GDP
computations occur quarterly, based upon three
months of data. Most of the error in the CPI that
was induced by the small sample will disappear by
December.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

12

Implications of Uncertainty in Price Measures
Monetary policymakers are keenly interested in
inflation, and one of the main challenges they face
is distinguishing signal from noise in the current
inflation data. Even in the best of times, some part
of the inflation data is simply noise—transitory
movements in inflation, either up or down, that go
away in a month or two.
Some of these transitory movements are due to
sampling error in the CPI. Some are due to temporary movements in prices that will reverse themselves in a few months. Analysts within the Federal
Reserve System spend enormous time and effort to
try to determine whether the latest aggregate price
movement is mostly transitory or mostly persistent
and what the true underlying trends in inflation
are.
An increase in the standard error of the CPI reduces
its usefulness to policymakers. It makes it hard to
judge whether a number like 1.5 percent reflects
real inflation, or whether it is simply error. For
example, if the inflation rate is mistakenly reported
as too high, the monetary authority might begin
raising interest rates prematurely, threatening the
recovery. If the inflation rate is mistakenly reported
as too low, the monetary authority might keep interest rates too low for too long, which could ignite
inflation.
To avoid policy errors, the usual advice—based
on the “Brainard” theory of policy practice under
uncertainty—is for policymakers to react more cautiously than they otherwise would, when faced with
data that is measured with more error than usual.
Similarly, an increase in uncertainty about inflation
estimates reduces the usefulness of those estimates
to consumers, workers, and producers, and also
makes planning errors more likely. For example, in
the hypothetical cars-in-Cleveland scenario above,
consumers tracking auto prices might be alarmed
by the seemingly rapid rise in car prices and be
prompted to buy too quickly. Cleveland auto dealers might be encouraged to raise their prices more,
thinking that they are only doing what everyone
else is doing.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

13

The government shutdown caused increased uncertainty in the economy for a host of reasons. The
increased uncertainty for policymakers owing to
increased uncertainty in the CPI is another contributor to that overall uncertainty. But since the
shutdown was resolved in mid-October, the degree
of increased uncertainty in the CPI over the coming months will not seriously damage the Federal
Reserve System’s ability to determine the current
state of the economy.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

14

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

Taking Stock of the Labor Market Recovery
10.18.13
by Maggie Jacobson and Murat Tasci
A number of factors are putting the pace of labor
market improvements on center stage for many
financial market observers. At its September 2012
meeting the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) decided to provide further policy accommodation using large-scale asset purchases,
and citing anemic growth in the economy and no
substantial reduction in the unemployment rate,
declared that it would continue to buy agency
mortgage-backed securities until the outlook for
the labor market had improved substantially. At
the time of that meeting, the unemployment rate
stood at 8.1 percent, having been above 8 percent
for an exceptionally long period—43 consecutive
months. Moreover, in December 2012 the FOMC
announced that the low level for the federal funds
rate would be appropriate at least as long as the
unemployment rate remains above 6-1/2 percent.
Whether improvement is viewed as substantial is
inherently a judgment call that the FOMC will
make. In this article, we provide a broad summary
of the changes in the major labor market measures
for the US economy over the last year. (Note that
due to the lapse in federal funding, the BLS did not
release the employment report for September on
October 4, as originally scheduled.)
Employment as reported by business establishments (payroll survey) expanded on average by
184,000 workers every month in the last year. The
most recent data we have (for the month of August) suggests slightly lower growth, at 169,000.
Monthly payroll changes are always volatile, but
even the smoother 6-month moving averages have
stayed above 160,000 this year so far. Employment
growth has been very broad based across different
industries. All major sectors, with the exception
of government, increased payrolls on average each
month. Professional and business services added
51,000 jobs per month, leading the pack, followed
by trade, transportation, and utilities (43,000),
leisure and hospitality (35,000) and education and
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

15

health (31,000). Even though the strong performance in manufacturing and construction in the
early part of 2013 declined somewhat, these sectors
have added 2,000 and 14,000 jobs, respectively, per
month over the past 12 months on average. One
point to note, however, is that the 3-month average suggests the pace of the increase has lost some
momentum over the last several months, with the
last three months registering fewer than 150,000
new jobs every month on average.

Payroll Employment Monthly Change
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
600
400
200
0
-200
6-month moving average
-400
August: +169,000
3-month: +148,000
6-month: +160,000
12-month: +184,000

-600
-800
-1000
2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

Note: Shaded bar indicates recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Unemployment Rate Decomposition,
September 2013
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
300
-0.8
-0.3
200

Change in
unemployment rate
0.0

-0.2

-0.1

100
0
-100
-200
-300

Employment
Unemployment
Labor force

-400
12-month
average
change

3-month
average
change

June

July

August

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

Employment as reported by households (household
survey) has increased by more than 160,000 jobs
a month on average since August 2012. Monthly
changes in the household survey can be much more
variable than the payroll survey, as it comes from a
smaller sample.
This variability can make it hard to interpret the
data. For instance, in the most recent household
data we have (August 2013), the labor force shrank
by a sizeable 312,000 workers, employment fell by
115,000, and unemployment declined by 198,000.
As a result, the 0.1 percentage point decline in the
unemployment rate in the month of August could
be perceived as being due to a decline in the size of
the labor force. However, over the past 12 months,
the general picture remains relatively healthy, with
the increase in employment (+167,000) accompanied by a decline in the stock of the unemployed
(−97,000) and a modest rise in the size of the labor
force (+70,000). This combination of changes has
resulted in a sizable decline in the unemployment
rate over the past 12 months of 0.8 percentage
points.
Elsewhere in labor market data, one can find other
encouraging signs, such as very stable levels of
average workweek hours for production workers as
well as other private employees. Current levels are
essentially the same as before the recession, suggesting very little potential for improvement on this
measure going forward. Employers’ demand for
more labor most likely will be met with new hiring
rather than more hours per worker. Nevertheless,
we observe that manufacturing overtime hours have
increased by a bit since a year ago, from 4.1 hours
to 4.4 hours per week. As a result, data on the
labor demand of employers in the near term, such
16

as job openings from JOLTS or the help-wanted
online advertising index by the Conference Board,
all point to a relatively firm demand for hiring by
employers going forward.
Labor Force Participation

Percent

Percent

66.0

68

65.0
67

64.0
63.0

66

Labor force participation rate
(August: 63.2%)

62.0
61.0

65

60.0
64

59.0
58.0

63

Employment-to-population ratio
(August: 58.6%)

57.0
56.0
2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

62
2013

Note: Shaded bar indicates recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics (household survey).

Unemployment and
the Share of the Long-Term Unemployed
Percent
12

Percent of all unemployed
50
45

10
8

40
Unemployment rate

35
30

6

Not all labor market indicators are as encouraging. For instance, the monthly average increase of
70,000 workers in the labor force is far below the
level needed to keep the labor force participation
rate stable with a growing population. As a result,
labor force participation has continued to decline
gradually over the past year, falling from 63.5
percent to 63.2 percent, one of its lowest points
since the late 1970s. As the population active in the
labor market shrinks—relative to the total population—observed increases in the employment pool
of 167,000 per month do not increase the fraction
of the population that is employed. The employment-to-population ratio has been virtually stuck
around 58.5 since the beginning of the recovery in
mid-2009.
Another reason to be cautious about overstating the
extent of improvement in the labor market is the
composition of the employed and the unemployed.
Two observations stand out. First, a significant fraction of the unemployed consists of the long-term
unemployed, workers who have been unemployed
for more than six months. These workers will
suffer more from the long-term consequences of
the recession. Second, a substantial portion of the
employed consists of workers who are employed
part-time due to economic reasons. The breadth of
part-time employment underscores the presence of
labor market slack even among the employed.

25
20

4

15
10

2
Unemployed more than 27 weeks

5

0
0
1948 1955 1962 1969 1976 1983 1990 1997 2004 2011

Note: Shaded bars indicate recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

The fraction of unemployed workers who have
been unemployed for more than six months skyrocketed during the course of the recession, almost
tripling to 45 percent at one point. This fraction
has nudged down a bit but still stands at 37.9
percent as of August 2013. Early in the recovery,
one concern was that these unemployed workers
are provided with incentives to stay unemployed
due to the generous unemployment compensation
enacted as part of the Emergency Unemployment
Compensation (EUC) legislation and extensions.
Early in 2010, there were 5.8 million unemployed
workers receiving EUC and extended benefits com17

bined, when the number of long-term unemployed
workers was hovering around 6.5 million. As of
August 2013, the size of the long-term unemployed
pool has shrunk to 4.2 million, along with a much
sharper decline in the number of beneficiaries of
EUC and extended benefits, to a mere 1.5 million.
It is hard to discern whether those unemployed
exited the pool because they found jobs or because
they just gave up and dropped out of the labor
force. However, the sheer size of the smaller pool of
beneficiaries suggests that EUC cannot be a major
factor in explaining the persistence of long-term
unemployment.

Size of the Long-Term Unemployed Pool
Millions
7
6

Received emergency
unemployment
compensation

5
4
3
2

Unemployed 27 weeks
or more

1
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Note: Emergency unemplyoyment compensation includes Emergency
Unemployment Compensation tiers 1-4 (2008-2012) plus extended benefits. Shaded
bars indicate recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Part-time employment could serve as a way to
adjust the labor force in the wake of a large downturn, and in fact it seems like this is what happened
during the last episode. Even though employment was shrinking by large numbers, the pool of
part-time workers was increasing to unprecedented
levels. For instance, in the first six months of 2009,
part-time employment increased by 205,000 per
month on average. Meanwhile, total employment
was shrinking by 450,000 workers per month
over the same period, led by a 650,000 per month
decline in full-time employment. It is likely that
much of this situation is explained by employers
reducing the work hours of their full-time workers.

Reason Given for
Part-time for Economic Reasons
Percent, seasonally adjusted
5

4

3
Slack work
2

1
Could only find part-time work
0
1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

2008

Part-time employment due to economic reasons
surged during the recession. The sum of the two
categories in the BLS report that are used to calculate the number of those employed part-time due
to economic reasons—part-time due to slack work
and part-time due to lack of full-time job availability—was nearly equal to 6 percent of all employment in the United States at one point. This has
declined somewhat but still stands at 4.8 percent as
of August 2013.

2012

Note: Shaded bars indicate recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

Since September 2012, we have received a lot of
information about the labor market that is encouraging and suggestive of overall improvement. There
are, however, still soft spots indicating continued
weaknesses. When the FOMC emphasized the
importance of labor market improvements last year,
Committee members were looking at a very weak
labor market outlook. Most members expected the
unemployment rate to drop below 8 percent by the
18

Changes in Part-time and Full-time Employment
Six-month moving average
600
Employment

Full-time

400
200
0
Part-time
-200

end of 2013 and to settle between 6 percent and
6.8 percent by the end of 2015 (as reported in the
Summary of Economic Projections). Since then,
the unemployment rate has declined to 7.3 percent.
The most recent projections, from September 2013,
show that most Committee participants now expect
the unemployment rate to be somewhere between
7.1 percent and 7.3 percent by the end of this year
and somewhere between 5.4 percent and 5.9 percent by the end of the projection period, 2016.

-400
-600
-800
1969

1974

1979

1984

1989

1994

1999

2004

2009

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; author’s calculations.

Unemployment Rate and Central Tendency of
FOMC Survey of Economic Projections
Percent
9.0

Forecast

8.5
8.0
September 2012
7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
September 2013

5.5
5.0
2012

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

19

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, October 2013
Covering October 5, 2013–October 18, 2013
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Sara Millington
Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures

Highlights
October

September

August

Three-month Treasury bill rate (percent)

0.08

0.02

0.05

Ten-year Treasury bond rate (percent)

2.66

2.64

2.73

Yield curve slope (basis points)

258

262

268

Prediction for GDP growth (percent)

1.1

0.9

Probability of recession in one year (percent)

2.12

2.23

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; authors’ calculations.

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
Predicted
GDP growth

4
2
0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

GDP growth
(year-over-year
change)

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, authors’ calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

Concerns over the debt ceiling apparently had
some impact on the shorter end of the yield curve,
pushing the three-month Treasury bill rate up to
0.08 percent (for the week ending October 18),
the highest level since March and a big jump up
(at these low levels, anyway) from September’s
0.02 percent and even August’s 0.05 percent. The
ten-year rate moved up, but not as much (either
absolutely or proportionally) to 2.66 percent, above
September’s 2.64 percent, but below August’s 2.73
percent. The slope decreased to 258 basis points,
down from September’s 262 basis points, and August’s 268 basis points.
The steeper slope had a negligible impact on projected future growth. Projecting forward using past
values of the spread and GDP growth suggests that
real GDP will grow at about a 1.2 percentage rate
over the next year, even with September’s rate and
just up from August’s rate of 1.1 percent. The influence of the past recession continues to push toward
relatively low growth rates. Although the time
horizons do not match exactly, the forecast comes
in on the more pessimistic side of other predictions
but like them, it does show moderate growth for
the year.
The slope change had only a slight impact on the
probability of a recession. Using the yield curve to
predict whether or not the economy will be in recession in the future, we estimate that the expected
chance of the economy being in a recession next
October is 2.24 percent, up from last month’s 2.12
percent and just above August’s 2.23 percent. So although our approach is somewhat pessimistic with
regard to the level of growth over the next year, it is
quite optimistic about the recovery continuing.

20

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
Probability of recession

80
70
60

Forecast

50
40
30
20
10
0
1960 1966

1972 1978 1984 1990

1996 2002 2008

2014

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, authors’ calculations.

The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.
More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.
Predicting GDP Growth

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

8

We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.
Predicting the Probability of Recession

6
4
2
0
10-year minus
three-month yield spread

-2
-4
-6
1953

1960

1967

1974

1981

1988

1995

2002

2009

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
numbers quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materi
21

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

8
6
4
2
0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-4
-6
1953

1960

1967

1974

1981

1988

1995

2002

ally different from the determinants that generated yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For more detail on these and other issues related to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” Our friends at the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York also maintain a website with
much useful information on the topic, including
their own estimate of recession probabilities.

2009

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

22

Regional Economics

Gentrification and Financial Health
11.06.13
by Daniel Hartley
Gentrification is a form of neighborhood change.
While it does not have a precise definition, it is
commonly associated with an increase in income,
rising home prices or rents, and sometimes with
changes in the occupational mix and educational
level of neighborhood residents.
Gentrification is sometimes viewed as a bad thing.
People claim that it is detrimental to the original
residents of the gentrifying neighborhood. However, a look at the data suggests that gentrification
is actually beneficial to the financial health of the
original residents. From a financial perspective, it is
better to be a resident of a low-price neighborhood
that is gentrifying than one that is not. This is true
whether residents of the gentrifying neighborhood
own homes or do not and whether or not they
move out of the neighborhood. This is interesting
because one might expect renters to be hurt more
by gentrification, and one might also be concerned
that people who moved out of the neighborhood
did so because they were financially strained.
In this article I consider a measure of gentrification
based on neighborhood home values, and examine
how this measure correlates with changes in credit
scores and debt delinquency measures in gentrifying neighborhoods.
Variation in Gentrification across Large Cities
For the purpose of this analysis, I will say a neighborhood is gentrifying if it is located in the central
city of a metropolitan area and it goes from being
in the bottom half of the distribution of home prices in the metropolitan area to the top half between
2000 and 2007. Housing prices are a good measure
of gentrification since they provide a summary of
the various amenities in the neighborhood. Changes in neighborhood amenities such as increases
in school quality or decreases in crime should be
reflected in changes in neighborhood home prices.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

23

The number of neighborhoods that could have potentially undergone gentrification within this timeframe is large and varies greatly across US cities.
Looking at the 55 largest US cities in 2000 shows
that the share of neighborhoods that fit my definition ranges from 17 percent in Seattle to 95 percent
in Baltimore. The number of neighborhoods that
did actually gentrify by 2007 is smaller. Though all
cities experienced some gentrification, most saw less
than a third of neighborhoods with the potential to
gentrify do so. Four cities saw significant shares of
the neighborhoods that could gentrify, do so: Boston (61 percent), Seattle (55 percent), New York
(46 percent), and San Francisco (42 percent). In
Boston, the gentrifying neighborhoods represented
about a fourth of the entire city’s population. In
other cities, the proportion was much smaller.

Gentrifying Cities
Proportion of low-price
census tracts in the city
(those with below-median
MSA home value), percent

Proportion of the city’s
low-price tracts that
gentrified, percent

Proportion of the
city’s total number of
tracts that gentrified,
percent

Boston

43

61

26

Seattle

17

55

9

New York City

40

46

18

San Francisco

31

42

13

Washington, DC

55

35

19

Atlanta

59

31

18

Chicago

57

28

16

Portland

48

28

13

Tampa

73

24

18

Los Angeles

51

23

12

Denver

52

23

12

Virginia Beach

31

23

7

Minneapolis

71

22

16

New Orleans

59

20

12

Austin

51

19

10

Jacksonville

61

17

10

Nashville

58

16

9

St. Louis

84

16

13

Anchorage

50

15

7

Honolulu

28

15

4

Las Vegas

53

15

8

Colorado Springs

48

14

7

Philadelphia

81

14

11

Metropolitan
Statistical Area
(MSA)

Table continued on page 9.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

24

Gentrifying Cities (continued)
Proportion of low-price
census tracts in the city
(those with below-median
MSA home value), percent

Proportion of the city’s
low-price tracts that
gentrified, percent

Proportion of the
city’s total number of
tracts that gentrified,
percent

Albuquerque

47

13

6

Houston

55

13

7

Miami

62

12

8

Cincinnati

72

12

9

Fresno

57

11

6

Tuscon

67

11

7

Charlotte

40

11

4

Phoenix

64

10

7

San Diego

46

10

5

Columbus

65

9

6

Indianapolis

60

8

5

Kansas City

68

8

6

Corpus Christi

45

8

4

Sacramento

64

8

5

Milwaukee

83

7

6

Pittsburgh

73

7

5

Dallas

52

7

4

Memphis

62

7

4

San Antonio

58

7

4

Lexington

52

7

3

Cleveland

93

7

6

Oklahoma City

55

7

4

Buffalo

78

6

5

El Paso

46

6

3

Omaha

54

6

3

Raleigh

35

4

2

Metropolitan
Statistical Area
(MSA)

Toledo

72

4

3

Wichita

57

4

2

Oakland

83

3

3

Baltimore

95

3

3

Tulsa

53

3

2

Detroit

94

3

2

Total

57

17

10

Sources: Neighborhoods are defined using Census 2000 tract boundaries. Median home value tabulations for
Census tracts come from the 2000 Census and the 2005–2009 American Community Survey. I use 2007 as a
shorthand for the 5-year tract level estimates from the 2005–2009 American Community Surveys.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

25

Changes in Gentrifying and
Nongentrifying Neighborhoods,
2000–2007
Change (percent points)
Gentrified

Not gentrified

Home prices

157.7

49.8

Rents

21.0

16.5

Incomes

10.5

−5.6

Proportion with bachelor’s degree

7.3

2.3

Proportion of owner-occupied
housing units

3.3

−0.3

Change in

Sources: Neighborhoods are defined using Census 2000 tract boundaries. Median
home value tabulations for Census tracts come from the 2000 Census and the
2005–2009 American Community Survey. I use 2007 as a shorthand for the 5-year
tract level estimates from the 2005–2009 American Community Surveys.

Gentrifying tracts saw bigger increases in home
values, rents, incomes, education levels, and owner
occupancy rates than low-price tracts that did not
gentrify.
Neighborhood Gentrification and Credit Scores
Rising home values, educational levels, and incomes are all positive developments. But some
people have voiced concerns about the side effects
of gentrification. The most common is that gentrification displaces existing residents from the neighborhood. Renters face higher rents, and homeowners may face higher property taxes, possibly causing
liquidity problems even though their home values
have increased. To assess how the existing residents
fare in neighborhoods that gentrify, I examine how
gentrification is associated with changes in their
credit scores. The credit score used is the Equifax
Risk Score, which provides a summary measure of
a person’s creditworthiness and is one of the scores
used by lenders to decide whether or not to make a
loan to someone.
How does gentrification correlate with changes
in individuals’ Equifax Risk Scores? I looked at a
number of regressions which aimed to assess the
differences in changes in Equifax Risk Score from
2001 to 2007 between residents of gentrifying and
nongentrifying neighborhoods, controlling for
the individuals’ ages and credit scores in 2001. In
other words, how much did the creditworthiness of
people in gentrifying neighborhoods increase compared to people with similar ages and initial credit
scores in nongentrifying neighborhoods?
Living in a neighborhood that gentrified between
2000 and 2007 is associated with about an 8 point
higher increase in credit score compared to living
in a low-price neighborhood that did not gentrify.
Improving credit outcomes in gentrifying neighborhoods are also reflected in delinquency rates. The
share of people with an account 90 or more days
past due fell by 2 percentage points in gentrifying
neighborhoods relative to other low-price neighborhoods during this period (again controlling for age
and initial credit score).
Furthermore, interesting patterns emerge when I
compare changes in the credit scores of the resi-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

26

dents of neighborhoods that gentrified to those that
did not gentrify, based upon whether the residents
had a mortgage in 2001. Mortgage-holding residents are associated with about the same increase in
credit scores in gentrifying neighborhoods as nonmortgage-holding residents. Even though some
homeowners do not have mortgages, so having a
mortgage is not a perfect proxy for homeownership, this result suggests that renters in gentrifying
neighborhoods benefit by about the same degree as
homeowners.
Another way to cut the data is to compare movers
and nonmovers across gentrifying and nongentrifying neighborhoods. Interestingly, there is a slightly
larger increase in credit score (1.5 points more)
associated with residents of the gentrifying neighborhoods who moved to a different neighborhood
relative to those who lived in a gentrifying neighborhood but did not move. So it appears that, on
average, movers are even slightly more positively
affected by gentrification than nonmovers.
The data seem to show that there is a positive
change in the financial health of the existing residents of gentrifying neighborhoods as measured by
their Equifax Risk Score ™ and delinquency rates.
This positive change is present for mortgage holders, for nonmortgage holders, for those that stay in
the neighborhood, as well as for those that move
out. The one caveat is that because the data only go
back to 1999, I am unable to distinguish between
residents who arrived in the neighborhood just two
years prior to 2001 and those who are long-time
residents.
Credit score data is generated by Equifax and the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

27

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2013

28