View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 2011 (October 14, 2011-November 8, 2011)

In This Issue:
Monetary Policy
 The Shout with Operation Twist
 Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth:
October 2011

Banking and Financial Markets
 Sovereign Debt Implications on the European
Banking System

Households and Consumers
 Household Debt

Regional Economics
 Local Government Employment in Ohio,
Pennsylvania, Kentucky, and West Virginia

Inflation and Price Statistics
 Recent Employment Cost Index Estimates
 Inflation In the Developed Countries

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 Emergency Unemployment Compensation and
Long-term Unemployment

Growth and Production
 Weak Wage and Income Growth Is Holding
Consumption Back

Monetary Policy

The Shout with Operation Twist
10.18.11
by John B. Carlson and John Lindner
Much attention has been given to the Federal
Open Market Committee’s September decision to
extend the average maturity of its portfolio by selling short-term Treasury securities and purchasing
longer-term Treasury securities. This policy action is
commonly called operation twist since its intended
effect is to lower long-term interest rates relative to
short-term rates—that is, to twist the yield curve.
In addition to the largely anticipated maturity
extension program announced by the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) in September, the
Committee altered its reinvestment strategy on
agency securities. Instead of reinvesting principal payments and prepayments from agency debt
and agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) in
Treasury securities, the new directive is for those
funds to be reinvested in agency MBS. The policy
statement clearly communicated that this action
was taken to help support conditions in mortgage
markets. But has it been effective?

Agency Securities Holdings
Trillions of dollars
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
12/07

Let’s start with the Fed’s position prior to the September announcement. The balance of agency securities held by the Fed had been declining steadily
since the end of March 2010, when the first round
of large-scale asset purchases was being completed.
After peaking at nearly $1.3 trillion, the amount of
agency security holdings now stands just below $1
trillion.

Agency mortgage-backed
securities
Agency debt

7/08

2/09

9/09

4/10

11/10

6/11

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

The total amount of reinvestment purchases that
will be made will depend on expected rates of prepayment and principal payments, but it is predicted
that somewhere between $200 billion and $300
billion will be purchased through 2012. Initially,
approximately $10 billion of purchases were made
in the first few weeks of the program, with another
$22 billion expected to be reinvested through the
middle of November. The effect of the policy will
keep the Fed’s portfolio of agency securities at
nearly $1 trillion.

2

Mortgage-Backed Security Yields
Percent
3.50
30-year Fannie Mae

3.25

The guidelines for these purchases are very similar
to those established during the initial purchasing
program. Securities will be limited to those that are
guaranteed by Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, or Ginnie
Mae, and they will largely be concentrated in newly
issued agency MBS.

3.00
2.75
2.50
30-year Ginnie Mae

2.25
FOMC meeting
2.00
09/01

09/11

09/21

10/01

10/11

Source: Bank of America Merrill Lynch.

Mortgage-Backed Security Prices
Price (12/31/1986=100)

Price (12/31/1986=100)
630

670
FOMC meeting

625

665
Fannie Mae

620

660

615
655
610
650

605

Ginnie Mae
645
640
09/01

600
595
09/11

09/21

10/01

10/11

Source: Wall Street Journal.

Mortgage Rates
Percent

Percent
4.50
4.45

3.80
FOMC meeting

3.75

4.40

3.70

4.35

3.65

15-year

30-year
4.30

3.60

4.25

3.55

4.20

3.50

4.15

3.45

4.10
09/01

3.40
09/11

Even though the maturity extension program
received the lion’s share of the attention following
the September FOMC meeting, at least part of the
downward spike in mortgage-related yields can likely be attributed to the MBS reinvestment program.
The higher demand for agency MBS created by the
Fed re-entering the market should raise the value of
these packaged securities, lowering the yields. Those
effects were seen immediately on MBS yields for
both Ginnie Mae and Fannie Mae, whose 30-year
current coupon bond yields each fell roughly 50
basis points following the FOMC announcement.

09/21

10/01

10/11

Source: Wall Street Journal.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

Alternatively, one can examine the impact of the
policy change in the prices of MBS. The 30-year
current coupon MBS prices from Ginnie and Fannie rose sharply on September 21. The indexed
prices for Ginnie Mae and Fannie Mae rose at least
5 index points each, led by a 12-point gain in Fannie Mae’s prices. The higher coupon prices tend to
increase the value of portfolios holding such longterm securities.
Since the securities being purchased are a packaged group of mortgages, another intended effect
of this program will be to lower retail mortgage
interest rates relative to what they would have been
in the absence of the policy action. This result was
observed after the September FOMC meeting, as
the 30-year fixed mortgage rate fell to 4.15 percent.
Smaller declines were also realized in the 15-year
fixed mortgage rate. Combined with the lower
yields on mortgage securities, the cumulative result
should be a more accommodative mortgage market.
In the weeks following the announcement, the effects have dissipated noticeably. While some may be
quick to judge the program as ineffective, the matter is not that clear cut. It could also be argued that
the effect of the policy actions on mortgage rates
have been obscured by the effect of other economic
developments after the September FOMC meeting.
For example, the employment report for October
3

beat market expectations, as did retail sales and the
ISM manufacturing survey. This improvement in
economic conditions had the effect of generally
raising the level of interest rates, offsetting the initial movements created by the Fed’s announcement.
Similarly, the negative news related to the FrancoBelgian bank Dexia had dampening effects on
overall interest rates, including MBS bond yields.

Mortgage-Backed Security Yields
Price
3.50

ISM manufacturing
Employment
report

3.25
3.00

30-year Fannie Mae

2.75
2.50

30-year Ginnie Mae

2.25
FOMC meeting

2.00
09/01

09/11

Dexia up
for downgrade

09/21

10/01

10/11

Source: Bank of America Merrill Lynch.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

The volatile nature of these types of financial markets makes a simple study of yields and prices an
incomplete exercise. However, the immediate effect
of the FOMC statement shows that the policy did
influence markets and that the policy is likely to
influence the expectations of market participants in
the future.

4

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth
Covering September 23, 2011—October 28, 2011
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Margaret Jacobson
Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures

Highlights
October

September

August

3-month Treasury bill rate
(percent)

0.02

0.01

0.01

10-year Treasury bond rate
(percent)

2.28

1.87

2.19

Yield curve slope
(basis points)

226

186

218

Prediction for GDP growth
(percent)

0.8

0.8

0.08

Probability of recession in
1 year (percent)

4.3

7.0

4.8

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP
Growth
Percent
10
8
6

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4
2
0
-2
-4

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

If September saw a flattening in the yield curve in
the wake of Operation Twist (formally, the Maturity Extension Program and Reinvestment Policy of
the Federal Reserve), October saw a reversal, with
the yield curve steepening. Long rates rose back to
summertime levels, and short rates edged up but
remained extraordinarily low. The three-month
Treasury bill rate ticked up to 0.02 percent (for the
week ending October 28), up from the 0.01 percent seen in August and September. The ten-year
rate surged back above 2 percent, to 2.28 percent,
which is up from September’s 1.86 percent. Naturally, the slope increased, up to 226—an increase of
40 basis points.
Projecting forward using past values of the spread
and GDP growth suggests that real GDP will grow
at about a 0.8 percent rate over the next year, even
with the projections in August and September. The
strong influence of the recent recession is leading
toward relatively low growth rates. Although the
time horizons do not match exactly, the forecast
comes in on the more pessimistic side of other
predictions, but like them, it does show moderate
growth for the year.
Following the usual pattern, the steeper slope
indicates a lower probability of recession. Using the
yield curve to predict whether or not the economy
will be in recession in the future, we estimate that
the expected chance of the economy being in a
recession next October is 4.3 percent, down from
September’s 7 percent, and from August’s 4.8
percent. So although our approach is somewhat
pessimistic as regards the level of growth over the
next year, it is quite optimistic about the recovery
continuing.
The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

5

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
Predicted
GDP growth

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4
2

More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.

0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.

2010

2012

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Predicting GDP Growth
We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.
Predicting the Probability of Recession

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
8

One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6
4
2
0
-2
-4

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First, this
probability is itself subject to error, as is the case
with all statistical estimates. Second, other researchers have postulated that the underlying determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated yield
spreads during prior decades. Differences could
arise from changes in international capital flows
and inflation expectations, for example. The bottom line is that yield curves contain important information for business cycle analysis, but, like other
6

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
80

Probability of recession

70
60

Forecast

50

indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For
more detail on these and other issues related to
using the yield curve to predict recessions, see the
Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal Recession?” Our friends at the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York also maintain a website with much useful
information on the topic, including their own estimate of recession probabilities.

40
30
20
10
0
1960 1966 1972 1978 1984 1990 1996 2002 2008
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

7

Households and Consumers

Household Debt
10.27.11
by O. Emre Ergungor

Household Liabilities
Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars

12,000

10,000

3,500
Housegold liabilities
excluding home mortgages

3,000

8,000

2,500
Household home
mortgage liabilities

6,000

2,000

4,000

1,500

2,000
2000

1,000
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

Source: Flow of Funds, Federal Reserve Board.

Delinquency Rates
Percent of total mortgages
8

30

7

25

Subprime mortgages
6

The level of U.S. household debt relative to disposable income has been declining since the financial
crisis. This household deleveraging is still continuing, according to the latest data. The deleveraging
is taking place primarily because liabilities on home
mortgages are falling. Nonmortgage liabilities have
been flat since 2007.
The primary driver of declining mortgage balances
is mortgage write-offs. Given the persistently high
level of delinquency rates, mortgage write-offs are
likely to remain high. Mortgage balances will drop
further as result, unless purchase-mortgage originations pick up.
So far, purchase activity remains highly subdued.
The most recent data show that originations are still
close to the lowest levels seen during the crisis.

20

5

15

4
3

10

2
Prime mortgages

1
0
2000

5
0

2002
-

2004

2006

2008

2010

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Purchase Mortgage Originations:
One to Four Family
Billions of dollars
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

Refinancing activity has also been declining despite
the historically low mortgage rates.
The obvious culprit is the lack of equity. Median
price appreciation of the refinanced properties
from the time the original loan was made to the
time it was refinanced is -7.4 percent in the most
recent Freddie Mac data. This suggests that the
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are mostly refinancing underwater mortgages in their effort to revive
the housing market. This opportunity to refinance
without equity is not available to mortgages not
owned by the two housing GSEs. Therefore, the
overall refinancing activity is lackluster despite the
low mortgage rates.
It is also worth noting that refinancing activity is
not uniform across all market segments. Currently,
around 80 percent of mortgage originations under
the Freddie Mac loan limit are refinancings. In the
broader market, the refinance share is around 60
percent. This observation also supports our earlier
claim that the housing GSEs are more active in this
market because they can refinance loans that would

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

8

Refinance Mortgage Originations

not qualify for a refinancing in the private market
due to lack of equity or low credit score.

Billions of dollars

The nature of refinancing activity has also changed
in the last few years. While cash-out refinancings
were the most popular type of activity before the
crisis, the current trend is to benefit from low rates
without taking on new debt. This suggests that
refinancings may not give a boost to consumption
the way they did earlier in the last decade.

900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Median Appreciation of
Refinanced Property
Percent
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Source: Freddie Mac.

Mortgages Refinanced for
Higher Loan Amounts

Refinance Shares
Percent of total mortgages
90

Percent of refinancings with 5 percent higher loan amounts

80

100

70
60

Mortgage originations:
1–4 family

80
70

50

60

40
30

90

Freddie Mac
primary mortgage market

50
40

20
30
10
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

20
10
0

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association; Freddie Mac

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

9

Inflation and Price Statistics

Recent Employment Cost Index Estimates
11.02.11
by Kyle Fee

Employment Cost Index and CPI: Services
4-quarter growth rate
16
14

CPI: Services

12
10
8
6

Compensation

4
2
0
1980

Wages and salaries
1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

2008

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The Employment Cost Index (ECI) is one of the
data releases we monitor to help shape our inflation
outlook. The latest figures for the ECI continue to
point to restrained wage growth. Over the past four
quarters, total compensation for private workers is
up 2.2 percent, while wages and benefits are up 1.7
percent and 3.4 percent, respectively. Even though
total compensation for private workers has been
slowly increasing following the end of the recession, much of that increase has been associated
with rising benefits costs and not wage growth. In
fact, wage growth has not returned to pre-recession
levels. Since the recovery began nine quarters ago,
the wage series has made minimal progress toward
2.0 percent growth and remains well off of its 1990
to 2007 average growth rate of 3.3 percent.
Restrained wage growth has implications for the
inflation outlook. Wages are the primary input cost
that business owners must account for when they
set their prices, especially for services. This tight
relationship between wages and prices is evident in
the high correlation (0.89) between wage growth
and the services component of the CPI. Total compensation is also highly correlated (0.88) with the
services component of the CPI.
The correlation with the CPI service measure, while
it does not prove wage increases cause inflation, is
certainly noteworthy. Given that services account
for a large share of the consumer market basket (60
percent), it seems appropriate to make the connection between subdued wage growth and inflation.

CPI: Services
Percent of market basket
61
60
59

Previously, we noted that subdued labor costs will
act as a drag on future inflation. The recent ECI
reading suggests that labor costs are still subdued.

58
57
56
55
54
53
52
51
1987

1992

1997

2002

2007

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

10

Inflation and Price Statistics

Inflation in Developed Countries
11.08.11
by Margaret Jacobson and Mehmet Pasaogullari

Headline inflation in Developed Countries
Percent (seasonally adjusted, 3-month annualized)
15.00
Canada
U.K.
U.S.
10.00
Germany
Japan
5.00

0.00

-5.00

-10.00

-15.00
1/2007 9/2007 5/2008 1/2009 9/2009 5/2010 1/2011 9/2011
5/2007 1/2008 9/2008 5/2009 1/2010 9/2010 5/2011
Sources: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics, Inc.

Earlier this year we saw average consumer prices increase in the United States, largely due to increases
in food and energy prices. Since then, the inflationary pressure brought on by energy prices has been
largely alleviated. A similar trend has happened in
most other developed countries.
Inflation rates for developed countries tend to
move together although the inflation levels can vary
significantly (these data are seasonally adjusted).
For example, over the last few years, CPI inflation
in the UK seems to be significantly higher than in
Germany (and also in other G7 continental European countries not shown in the graph). Japan, not
surprisingly, has the lowest inflation as this country
has been struggling with deflationary pressures.
During the summer of 2008, when oil prices
increased substantially, all of these countries, even
Japan, experienced high levels of inflation. Something similar happened in the spring of 2011, when
inflation increased to around 5 percent in Canada,
the UK, and the United States. Since then, however, inflation has declined.

Energy Price Inflation in Developed Countries What has been the main driver of the increase in
Percent (non-seasonally adjusted, 3-month annualized)
150.00

100.00

Canada
U.K.
U.S.
Germany
Japan

50.00

0.00

-50.00

-100.00
1/2007 9/2007 5/2008 1/2009 9/2009 5/2010 1/2011 9/2011
5/2007 1/2008 9/2008 5/2009 1/2010 9/2010 5/2011
Sources: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics, Inc.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

the inflation in early 2011? The three-month annualized inflation of energy prices (not seasonally
adjusted) showed a volatile pattern in 2011. After
sharply increasing in the spring, the levels reversed
course. Unsurprisingly, energy prices show a very
high correlation across countries, but are also more
volatile in the United States than in other developed countries.
Another culprit causing high levels of inflation was
elevated food inflation. A look at food-price inflation shows that food prices were at a high level in
early 2011, especially in the United States, Canada,
and the UK. However, food-price inflation fell less
than energy inflation. Food-price inflation is still
high. For example, three-month annualized foodprice inflation is 5.7 percent in the United States,
4.1 percent in Canada, and 8.8 percent in the UK
11

Food Price Inflation in Developed Countries
Percent (seasonally adjusted, 3-month annualized)

as of September 2011. However, we have to note
that an episode of high food-price inflation is not
uncommon, as the figure below suggests.

25.00
20.00
15.00
10.00
5.00
0.00
-5.00
-10.00
1/2007 9/2007 5/2008 1/2009 9/2009 5/2010 1/2011 9/2011
5/2007 1/2008 9/2008 5/2009 1/2010 9/2010 5/2011
Sources: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics, Inc.

Core Inflation in Developed Countries
Percent (seasonally adjusted, 3-month annualized)
6.00
5.00
4.00
3.00
2.00
1.00
0.00
-1.00
-2.00
-3.00
-4.00
1/2007 9/2007 5/2008 1/2009 9/2009 5/2010 1/2011 9/2011
5/2007 1/2008 9/2008 5/2009 1/2010 9/2010 5/2011
Sources: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics, Inc.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

Finally, we check inflation excluding food and
energy prices, frequently called core inflation in
the developed countries. Most economists believe
that core inflation measures are better at capturing inflationary pressures and better predictors of
future inflation, as they exclude noisy signals and
temporary factors.
When we look at the development of core inflation
measures in the developed countries, we see several
important facts. First of all, we see a lot less correlation between core inflation levels across countries
than in overall inflation, food-, or energy-inflation.
For example, the deflationary phase that Japan is
experiencing is clearly seen in the core inflation
level, which has been persistently negative since late
2008, except for a few temporary blips.
On the other hand, the UK experienced sharp
increases in core inflation in early 2011, which
may be related to an increase in the country’s VAT
tax. For the United States and Germany, it seems
that the pass-through effects of energy-price increases led to peaks in core inflation—in May for
the United States and in April for Germany. Now
three-month annualized core inflation has declined
to 2.1 percent and to 1.5 percent, respectively. On
the other hand, core inflation in Canada, which
was flat in the summer after higher levels in early
2011, jumped significantly in September.
In summary, we see that in early 2011 major developed countries experienced an increase in inflation
that was driven mostly by higher food and energy
prices. Since then, inflation has stabilized at lower
levels. The core inflation measures, though, showed;
deflation in Japan, low inflation in Germany and
the U.S., and higher inflation in Canada.

12

Growth and Production

Weak Wage and Income Growth Is Holding Consumption Back
11.02.11
by Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino

Real GDP and Private Domestic Expenditures
Annualized percent change
12
Real private domestic
expenditures

9
6
3

Real GDP

0
-3
-6
-9
-12
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Notes: Private domestic expenditures is the sum of private consumption and private
investment. Shaded bar indicates recession.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Real Personal Income
Annualized percent change
15
12
Real personal income

9
6
3
0

Real disposable
personal income

-3
-6
-9
-12
-15
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Notes: Disposable personal income is personal income less taxes. Real values
were calculated using the implicit price deflator for GDP. Shaded bar indicates
recession.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

After feeble GDP growth in the first half of the
year, third-quarter data came out a little stronger,
suggesting that the recovery is continuing and
the risk of recession is reduced. According to the
advance estimate from the Bureau of Economic
Analysis, real GDP grew at a 2.5 annualized percent rate in the third quarter, accelerating from its
0.8 annualized percent growth rate in the first half
of the year. Real private domestic expenditures, the
share of GDP that includes private consumption
and investment and excludes government spending
and net exports, also accelerated from 2 percent to
2.7 percent (both annualized growth rates) from
the first half of the year to the third quarter.
Even though third-quarter growth looks stronger,
the pace of the recovery continues to be slow. Over
the past year, real GDP grew only 1.6 percent,
much less than is typical during recoveries. Real
private consumption, which accounts for 70 percent of GDP, also grew slowly—only 2.2 percent in
the last year. One reason why consumption is rising
so slowly is that personal income is rising slowly.
In real terms, personal income grew a modest 2.1
percent in the last year and fell 1.6 percent in the
last quarter (annualized rate). Net of taxes, household income fared even worse. Disposable personal
income grew only 0.8 percent in the last year and
fell 1.9 percent in the last quarter (annualized rate).
With disposable income barely growing, it is no
surprise that household consumption is not growing much either. In fact, unless income accelerates
soon, households will not even be able to sustain
their current low rates of consumption growth for
long. Household consumption is currently growing
at a higher rate than income. This is possible only
because households are lowering their saving rate—
the saving rate dropped from 5.2 percent last year
to 5.1 percent last quarter and to 4.1 percent this
quarter. This pattern cannot continue indefinitely.
Either household income will pick up, or house
13

holds will have to cut back on their consumption
growth to avoid further declines in the saving rate.

Personal Saving Rate
Percent
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Notes: Personal saving rate is personal saving as a percentage of disposable
personal income. Shaded bar indicates recession.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Real Employee Compensation
Percent change from business cycle peak
25

Average, all other cycles
Range, all other cycles
Current cycle

20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

The main reason household income is not growing
at a stronger pace is that wage growth is stagnant.
Real employee compensation grew only 1.1 percent
in the last year and decreased 0.6 percent in the last
quarter (annualized rate). Compensation peaked in
early 2008, fell more than 5 percent during the recession and is still 3.1 percent below that peak, depressed by sluggish employment and wage growth.
It has been lagging relative to other components of
national income—the ratio of employee compensation to national income, the labor share, has been
decreasing steadily since the end of the recession,
and is currently 62 percent, the lowest level in more
than forty years.
While household consumption is growing slowly,
business investment is in better shape. Real fixed
investment grew a solid 7.8 percent in the last
year, driven by 10 percent growth in investment in
equipment and software. Investment growth in the
future could be fueled by corporate profits, which
have rebounded strongly from their recession levels.
In real terms, corporate profits have almost doubled
since their lowest point during the recession, and
they are now in line with the pace of previous
recoveries.

Quarters from NBER peak
Note: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over all other cycles. Real
values are calculated using the implicit price deflator for GDP.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Real Corporate Profits
Percent change from business cycle peak
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40

Average, all other cycles
Range, all other cycles
Current cycle

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

Quarters from NBER peak
Notes: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over all other cycles. Real
values are calculated using the implicit price deflator for GDP.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

14

Banking and Financial Markets

Sovereign Debt Implications on the European Banking System
11.04.11
by Ben Craig and Matthew Koepke
As European leaders work to define the terms of the
European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), concerns have arisen about sovereign debt write-downs
and the impact they could have on the European
banking system. European finance ministers just
approved a plan that would require euro-zone
banks to raise $150 billion (€108 billion) in additional capital over nine months to cover potential
losses. The additional capital would allow banks
to meet a 9.0 percent threshold for tier-one capital after positions in distressed euro-zone debt are
marked-to-market.

Assets and Loans of All FDIC-Insured
Institutions
Dollars in trillions
16
Net loans and leases
Total assets
12

8

4

0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011:Q1
2011:Q2
Sources: FDIC, Haver Analytics.

Number of Problem Banks and Total Assets
Dollars in billions
500
400

Total asset
Number of banks

Number
1000
800

300

600

200

400

100

200
0

0

The additional $150 billion of capital, while steep,
was less than the $417 billion (€300 billion) that
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) estimated
the cumulative spillover effects of the write-downs
on the euro-zone banking system would be. According to the IMF’s September Global Stability
Assessment Report, cumulative spillovers from
the high-spread area (Belgium, Greece, Ireland,
Italy, Portugal, and Spain) account for nearly $278
billion (€200 billion) of the $417 billion, with an
additional $139 billion attributed to interbank
exposures. The IMF expects the spillover effects
to mostly affect the banking systems in the highspread euro area. Nonetheless, the Bank for International Settlements exposure tables show that
the banking systems of Germany, France, and the
United Kingdom have significant exposure to the
high-spread euro area, accounting for nearly 70.0
percent of the euro-zone’s total exposure.

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 YTD
Sources: FDIC, Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

The specter of sovereign defaults and bank exposures to the debt has increased credit risk in the
euro zone interbank lending markets. Evidence of
the increased credit risk can be seen by examining
the euribor-OIS spread. Since June, the euriborOIS has risen to levels not seen since the financial
crisis of 2008. The euro interbank offered rate
(euribor) is the rate at which banks participating in
the European Union money markets are willing to
lend to other banks for a specified term.
15

Bank Coverage Ratio
Dollars in trillions
2.0
1.6

Ratio

Allowance for loan losses
Total bank equity capital
Bank coverage
ratio

30
25
20

1.2
15

euro zone. Since May 2011, the net due to foreignrelated offices has increased from −22.0 billion (the
foreign-related bank had a balance with the U.S.
subsidiary) to $289.6 billion (the U.S. subsidiary
has a balance with the foreign-related bank). This
increase suggests that foreign banks are using their
U.S. subsidiaries to shore up liquidity.

0.8
10
0.4

5

0.0

0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011:Q1
2011:Q2

Source: FDIC.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

16

Regional Economics

Local Government Employment in Ohio, Pennsylvania, Kentucky, and
West Virginia
11.02.11
by Stephan Whitaker
In the past year, policymakers in the Fourth District and across the nation have focused tremendous
attention on local government employees. In aggregate across the United States, local government
employment has fallen approximately 3 percent
since the recession. The ratio of local government
employment to total payroll employment rose
sharply in the year after the recession because there
were widespread layoffs of private sector workers.
Private sector jobs, and the local tax bases they
support, have recovered only slowly. In the national
figures, cuts in local government employment are
bringing the ratio of public to private workers back
to where it was before the recession. In the Fourth
District, only Ohio has cut local government payrolls in line with the national trend. However, the
ratios of public to private workers are returning to
their pre-recession levels in all four states.
Local government employment has historically
been a stabilizing force during recessions. That is
because when the economy slows down, local government employment usually remains stable, and
the workers who stay employed help to support demand for goods and services until growth returns.
Local government payrolls can usually weather
a recession because the largest source of local tax
revenue is property taxes. In past recessions, property values did not decline, or they recovered before
the multiyear tax assessment process reflected the
declines. Local sales and income taxes fall during
recessions and recover afterward, which forces some
temporary reduction of payrolls.
Local taxes receipts fell during the most recent
recession, as they normally do. To help local governments bridge the decline in tax receipts and
avoid layoffs, Congress directed a major portion of
the 2009 American Recovery and Reinvestment Act
($180 billion of the $787 billion) to state and local
governments. In the intervening months, sales
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

17

Change in Local Government Employment
Percent
8
6
West Virginia
4
2
Kentucky

Pennsylvania

0
U.S.

Ohio
-2
-4
-6
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Local Government Employment as a Percent
of Total Nonfarm Employment
Percent
11.5
U.S.

West Virginia
11.0
10.5

Ohio

10.0
Kentucky
9.5
9.0

Pennsylvania

8.5
8.0
2001

2003

2005

2007

and income taxes have only partially recovered,
and property taxes are now falling as the dramatic,
nationwide decline in property values is being
reflected in the assessment process. State revenues
are still below 2008 levels, and many states are cutting aid to local governments. For example, Ohio
is cutting state-to-local transfers by 28 percent in
FY2012. This may force municipal governments to
raise taxes or lay off employees.

2009

2011

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Since the beginning of the recession, the trend in
local government employment has taken a different path in each of the Fourth District states. In
West Virginia, there has been a modest increase in
local government payrolls. In Pennsylvania, there
was a slight increase and a decline. Kentucky’s local government employment has been essentially
unchanged. In Ohio, the situation is much different. There has been a decline in local government
employment, reaching a level in September 2011
that is 4 percent below the level just before the
recession. Ohio has cut local public payrolls more
than the nation as a whole.
If local government payrolls are placed in the context of total payrolls, the Fourth District trends all
reflect the national pattern. During the recession,
private payrolls dropped sooner and faster than
public payrolls. The states of the Fourth District,
like the nation as a whole, witnessed a half-point
increase in the percentage of total employees working for local governments in the year following the
recession. Now, in three Fourth District states, the
ratio appears to be returning to its level during the
previous decade. In Pennsylvania and Kentucky,
municipal payrolls are almost flat and the ratio
is falling, so other employment is recovering. In
Ohio, the public sector workforce is declining to
match the diminished private sector workforce.
In West Virginia, the ratio is steady, as public and
private payrolls sustain similar growth.
Local government employees as a percent of total
nonfarm payrolls are below the national average in
all the Fourth District states. Pennsylvania stands
out with a percentage 2 points lower than the nation since the 1990s.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

18

MSA/Employment

MSA

Local Government Percent of
Total Nonfarm Employment
December 2006November 2007

Local Government Percent of
Total Nonfarm Employment
October 2010September 2011

Change
TNF

Local
government

Cleveland

10.9

−7.1

−3.8

11.2

Canton

10.4

−7.7

−3.5

10.9

Dayton-Springfield

10/1

−8.2

−3.0

10.7

YoungstownWarren

9.7

−6.9

−1.2

10.3

Toledo

9.5

−7.8

−7.8

9.9

Akron

9.6

−5.5

−4.1

9.7

Cincinnati

8.5

−5.5

−3.4

8.7

Columbus

8.6

−3.4

−1.3

8.7

Pittsburgh

8.1

−0.9

0.9

8.2

Lexington

7.2

−4.3

7.0

8.1

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The metropolitan areas within a state always exhibit
larger variations that get smoothed out in averaging. Since the recession, the ratio of public employees to total employees has increased in every metro
area of the Fourth District. In most cases, both
total and local government payrolls have fallen, but
government payrolls have not fallen as far. Cincinnati and Columbus support relatively low percentages of their employment in the local government
sector, similar to the average for Pennsylvania.
The Cleveland MSA was the only Fourth District
metro area to enter the recession with a percentage
of workers in the local government sector that was
above the national average, and it remains above
the national average.
In the coming months, municipalities will have to
make some difficult decisions. They will choose between raising taxes, laying off employees, reducing
compensation, or some combination of the three.
The aggregate impact of their decisions will be felt
in the economies of their metro areas and states.
It will be interesting to see if local government
employment will continue to serve as a stabilizing
force as it has in the past.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

19

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

Emergency Unemployment Compensation and Long-term
Unemployment
11.08.11
by Murat Tasci and Mary Zenker
The recent recession was the longest on record since
the Depression. As it wore on, more and more
workers entered the ranks of long-term unemployed. To minimize the impact of these unemployment conditions on household incomes, the federal
government implemented an unemployment insurance benefit called the Extended Unemployment
Compensation (EUC) program. The program allows unemployed workers to collect unemployment
insurance benefits longer than they normally would
be able to. In this article, we provide some context
for interpreting the program’s effect on the unemployment rate.
The EUC program was implemented in tiers. In
June 2008 (7 months after the recession started),
Congress legislated the first tier: unemployed workers could receive an additional 13 weeks of benefits.
Five months later, that period was extended an additional 7 weeks and henceforth referred to as Tier
1. Tier 2 was introduced at the same time and gave
an additional 13 weeks of benefits to those in states
with unemployment rates above 6 percent. A year
after it was enacted, Tier 2 extended benefits by
1 week and made the extension unconditional on
state unemployment rates.
As the economy continued to stagnate, more tiers
were introduced. In November 2009, the Tier 3
extension went into effect, adding 13 weeks of
benefits in states with unemployment rates above
6 percent, and Tier 4 gave an additional 6 weeks of
benefits in states with unemployment rates above
8.5 percent. All of the tiers together amount to a
potential maximum additional benefit duration
of 53 weeks. Adding that to the what the states
provide—the traditional 26 weeks of benefits and
20 additional weeks of extended benefits—amounts
to potentially being able to receive unemployment
insurance benefits for 99 weeks (just about 2 years).

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

20

Initially, EUC benefits were available to anyone
who had exhausted his or her regular benefits
before March 28, 2009. However, as the recession
wore on this date was continually moved later and
later and is currently January 3, 2012.
Unemployment insurance is intended in general to
provide some additional income during extended
periods of unemployment, but it also creates incentives that can lead to effects that would otherwise
not occur. One possible incentive might be that
unemployment insurance encourages people to stay
in the labor force who would otherwise drop out,
since receiving benefits is conditional on searching for work. Or unemployment insurance might
incentivize people to reject employment offers
by raising their reservation wage, the wage above
which they will accept a job.
We can check the data to see if either of these effects is occurring as a result of EUC. Consider first
whether EUC incentivizes unemployed workers to
stay in the labor force when they would otherwise
drop out. As their EUC benefits expire, unemployed workers can choose to leave the labor force
or to stay in. If they leave, the number of long-term
unemployed workers will decrease (all else equal),
since, by definition, a worker receiving EUC is
counted among the long-term unemployed. If they
stay, they continue to seek work but receive no
further unemployment benefits.

Long-Term Unemployed and Emergency
Unemployment Compensation
Millions
7
6

If EUC creates this incentive, we ought to observe
evidence of workers exiting the labor force as their
benefits expire. Over the past two years, however,
though we have seen a noticeable decline in the
number of those receiving EUC and extended state
benefits, the number of long-term unemployed
workers has been stuck around 6 million and shows
little sign of downward momentum.

5
4
EUC Tiers 1-4
(2008-2011) + EB

3
2

Unemployed 27
weeks or more

1
0
2005

2007

2009

The earliest workers who took advantage of of the
full 99 weeks of unemployment insurance would
have used up all their benefits around June 2010.
As can be seen in the chart below, the number of
people receiving EUC began declining markedly in
2010.

2011

Note: Shaded bars indicate recession.
Sources: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

The fact that the decline in EUC recipients has
not been coupled with a decline in the long-term
21

unemployed suggests those workers are staying in
the labor market. This is not certain, however, as
there are constant inflows to the long-term unemployed pool from the “medium”-term unemployed
pool. Additionally, staying in the labor force is not
unequivocally bad. Some analysis by Jesse Rothstein
suggests that EUC, because it keeps workers in the
labor force, may have increased the share of unemployed workers who were later reemployed.

Average Replacement Rates by State
Percent
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
DC AZ AL GA FL MO TN DE NE CT TX MI MD ND WV WA IN CO MN PA NH KY KS RI HI
AK LA MS WI VA SC NY CA MT ID WY SD VT IL ME UT NC OH OR IA AR NJ NM NV

Sources: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; as of September 2011

Market Tightness (V/U)
Percent
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, authors’ calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

Consider now whether EUC creates an incentive
to reject employment offers. In the chart below, we
show a rough approximation of a statistic called a
replacement rate. The replacement rate measures
how much of their prior income EUC recipients
are able receive with EUC. We lack direct data on
this, but we can measure how much the average
EUC benefits in a state are relative to the average
wage in that state. This statistic is our proxy for the
replacement rate. With an average replacement rate
across all states of about 36 percent, we can surmise
that when workers are receiving unemployment
benefits, they are generally dealing with a nontrivial
decline in income. This creates some uncertainty
about the strength of the claim that receiving EUC
provides an incentive to turn down a wage offer.
However, these incentive effects could be weaker
when there are not many job openings available in
the economy. We can look at a metric called market tightness to relate the number of unemployed
persons to the number of available jobs. Essentially,
this measure gives the number of vacancies per
unemployed worker. When market tightness is
really low, there are too many unemployed workers chasing too few job openings. Looking at this
metric, we see a low level of market tightness in
the economy, suggesting there is a low probability of exiting the unemployment pool on average.
Potentially, a low demand for labor will dampen
the incentive effects of unemployment insurance
benefits. Hence, a more plausible reason for the
elevated level of the long-term unemployed is a lack
of demand for labor, rather than an incentive effect
of EUC motivating people to stay in their current
unemployed state.
Given that EUC significantly lengthened the length
of time benefits could be received and increased
22

the number of eligible workers, the existence and
significance of these incentive effects on the unemployment rate is a key issue. An EUC incentive effect may be there, but the data shown here,
even though only suggestive, do not indicate a
very strong effect. Our reading of the economic
literature on this issue suggests that the effect of the
EUC is relatively minimal, accounting for about
0.6 to 0.8 percentage points of the unemployment
rate by the end of 2010 (see the Rothstein paper
mentioned earlier). The Rothstein study focuses on
both of the incentive effects mentioned above and
provides evidence that the unemployment exit rate
was not significantly affected by the availability of
EUC. The low levels of job openings we observe
in the data support this view, suggesting that the
scarcity of available jobs might explain the bulk of
the unemployment rate.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

23

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | November 2011

24