View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

OK.

So Money
Can’t Buy
You Love.

But It Can Produce
Price Stability.

L

et’s face it. A decade of strong economic
growth, capital investment, budget
surpluses, and improved job

opportunities doesn’t just happen.
It results from an environment where people know that the
dollars they have today will deliver value they can
depend on now and for years to come.

Performance like that takes a special kind of
monetary policy. One that can leverage its
portfolio of networked research talent to create
customized monetary policy solutions in a rapidly
changing global context. Using our acclaimed zero-inflation analytical
platform, we aspire to maintain the dollar’s purchasing integrity 24/7.

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

So, you don’t have to care too much for money. Only what it buys.

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND.
Dollars that Power the World.
www.clev.frb.org

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Trillions of dollars
7.2 THE M3 AGGREGATE

Trillions of dollars
4.9 THE M2 AGGREGATE

4.7

M2 growth, 1995–2000 a
9

M3 growth, 1995–2000 a
12

5%

9

1%

6

6.4

3

3

6%

0

1%

0

2%

6

5%

4.5

6%

6.8

2%

6.0

4.3
5%

6%
5.6

4.1

1%

2%

5%

6%

5.2

3.9

1%

2%
4.8

3.7
1998

1997

1999

Trillions of dollars
19 DOMESTIC NONFINANCIAL DEBT

2000

7%

600

6

Sweep-adjusted base growth, 1995–2000 a
15
10

7%

4
17

1999

Billions of dollars
640 THE MONETARY BASE

Debt growth, 1995–2000 a
8
18

1998

1997

2000

1%

3%

5

2

560

0

3%

10%

0
Sweep-adjusted base b

7%
16

520
3%

7%

5%

15

480
3%

5%

14

440
1997

1998

1999

2000

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2000 growth rates for M2 and M3 are calculated on an
estimated October over 1999:IVQ basis. The 2000 growth rates for debt and the sweep-adjusted base are calculated on an August over 1999:IVQ basis.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts.
NOTE: Data are seasonally adjusted. Last plots for M2, M3, and the monetary base are estimated for October 2000. Last plots for debt and the sweepadjusted base are August 2000. Dotted lines for M2, M3, and debt are FOMC-determined provisional ranges. All other dotted lines represent growth rates and
are for reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Until recently, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) established
growth ranges for the broad monetary aggregates (M2 and M3) and
domestic nonfinancial debt. For some
time, these ranges have not been
meaningful indicators in terms of
defining specific rates consistent with
the goal of price stability. Federal
Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
noted in his October 19 remarks at
the Cato Institute, “We have difficulty
defining those (money growth) limits

with precision, and within any such
limits, there remains significant scope
for discretion in setting policy.”
A casual inspection of the aggregates illustrates the difficulty: For
almost four years, the growth rates of
M2 and M3 have consistently met or
exceeded the upper limit of the
FOMC-determined ranges—yet economic expansion has continued with
relatively modest inflation. This is not
to say that money growth is irrelevant: Inflation is still believed to

result from excessive money growth.
However, “excessive” is difficult to
define over the short term. M2
growth of roughly 6% is not generally
associated with price stability, but
with real output growth averaging a
remarkable 5%, the resulting inflation
has been modest.
Through October, year-to-date
growth rates of M2, M3, and debt are
estimated to be 6.0%, 9.0%, and 5.8%,
respectively. In keeping with the pattern established early this year,
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percent, weekly average
9 LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

Percent, weekly average
6.5 SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES

6.0

8
Conventional mortgage

1-year T-bill a
5.5
7

5.0

30-year Treasury a

3-month T-bill a
6

4.5
10-year Treasury a
5

4.0

4

3.5
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

1996

2001

Percent, weekly average
7.25 RESERVE MARKET RATES

1998

1997

1999

2000

2001

Percent
7.25 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES b
May

7.00

June

April

6.75

6.75

Intended federal funds rate

July
6.25

6.50

August
September

March

Effective federal funds rate

October 25, 2000

6.25

5.75

6.00
5.25

February

5.75
Discount rate

January

4.75

5.50

4.25

5.25
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Jan.

March

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Constant maturity.
b. Last active trading day of the month unless otherwise noted.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

growth in the narrower measures of
money is much less robust. Year-todate growth in the sweep-adjusted
base was only 1.8% through August
(the most recent sweeps data available), partly reflecting an offset to
rapid Y2K-related growth in 1999.
Looking at interest rates, the rapid
and sustained increases in short-term
Treasury yields of 1999 have not
characterized the 1-year T-bill so far
this year. Trading in a relatively narrow range, the 1-year yield was
down 9 basis points (bp) since the
beginning of the year to 5.94% as of
October 20. In contrast, the 3-month

T-bill yield has continued to climb,
reaching 6.3% (up 87 bp this year).
As a result, the inversion at the short
end of the yield curve, which first appeared in July, continues to deepen.
Long-term Treasury yields peaked
simultaneously early in the year and
have largely moved together. Both
the 10-year and 30-year Treasury
bond yields are down (88 bp to
5.68% and 81 bp to 5.77%, respectively) through October 20. The
spread between 30-year conventional
mortgage rates and long-term Treasury yields has widened by around
50 bp over this period. While market

May

July
2000

Sept.

Nov.

Jan.

March
2001

rates moved up sharply when the
FOMC tightened by 75 bp in 1999,
rates have not responded in similar
fashion this year despite an additional percentage point increase.
Expectations of policy action,
embodied in implied yields on federal funds futures, have changed significantly since May. The steeply
sloped implied yield curves of the
first two quarters have gradually flattened, culminating in the current inversion of 15 bp between the October 2000 and March 2001 contracts.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Expectations, Markets, and the “Political”Economy
Percent, end of day
2.6 TREASURY INFLATION-INDEXED
SECURITIES (TIIS) SPREAD

Percent
16 ALTERNATIVE INFLATION MEASURES

CPI, all items a

2.1

12

Year-ahead household inflation expectations b

1.6

8

10-year Treasury bond minus 10-year TIIS
4

1.1

0

0.6
1998

1999

2000

1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001

2001

Price (cents)
55 PRESIDENTIAL VOTE-SHARE FUTURES d

Percent
65 PRESIDENTIAL GALLUP POLL c
Percent, October
53

60

Democratic
48
55

50

43
Bush

38
50

45

45

Republican

40
Gore
40

35
May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

Jan.

Feb. March April

May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Year-over-year percent change.
b. Median expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers, lagged 12 months.
c. Beginning September 5, 2000, three-day rolling poll results among likely voters are displayed. Previous polls were conducted at irregular intervals. Values
may not sum to 100% because results for all candidates are not shown. Last plot is October 25.
d. Reform Party contracts (not shown) also trade on the IEM’s 2000 Presidential Vote-Share Market. Last plot is October 25.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; University of Michigan; University of Iowa, Henry B. Tippie College of Business; Bloomberg
Financial Information Services; and the Gallup Organization.

When it comes to measuring people’s
expectations, economists are often
skeptical of the direct approach—
asking them. Instead, economists prefer information derived from markets,
where people have money on the line
and thus have incentives to use information carefully and to reveal their
true beliefs.
The federal funds futures market
provides a market-based gauge of future monetary policy. Likewise, the
Treasury inflation-indexed securities
(TIIS) market provides one measure

of information about inflation expectations. Coupon and principal
payments of TIIS are linked to the
Consumer Price Index (CPI), thereby
ensuring investors a return that is not
influenced by inflation—that is, a real
return. The spread between the
10-year TIIS and the 10-year Treasury
bond provides a measure of market
participants’ expectations for average
CPI inflation during the remaining
time to maturity.
Market information can also be
used to gauge expectations about

other events, such as political elections. While most people are familiar
with national polling organizations
such as the Gallup Poll, fewer know
about the Iowa Electronic Markets
(IEM), a small-scale futures exchange
where contracts’ values are determined by political perceptions.
The IEM operates a Presidential
Vote-Share futures market which
pays $1 times the vote share of the
contract party’s (Democratic, Republican, or Reform) nominee. In other
words, the futures contract trades at
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Expectations, Markets, and the “Political”Economy (cont.)
Price (cents)
75 PRESIDENTIAL WINNER-TAKES-ALL FUTURES a

Democratic National Convention

65
Republican National Convention
Republican
55

45
Democratic

35
Presidential debates
25
May

June

July

August

September

November

October

Price (cents)
80 NEW YORK SENATE WINNER-TAKES-ALL FUTURES c

Price (cents)
60 CONGRESSIONAL WINNER-TAKES-ALL FUTURES b
Non-Republican House, Republican Senate
50

Clinton
60

Giuliani

40
Republican House, Republican Senate
40

30

Lazio

20
20

Non-Republican House, Non-Republican Senate
10

Other Republican

Republican House, Non-Republican Senate
0
Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

0
Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Reform Party contracts (not shown) also trade in the IEM’s Presidential Winner-Takes-All Market.
b. Contract liquidation values are determined by the number of seats won by the Republican party in the U.S. House of Representatives and Senate.
c. Contract liquidation values are determined by the outcome of the U.S. Senate election in New York.
NOTE: Last plot for all charts is October 25.
SOURCE: University of Iowa, Henry B. Tippie College of Business.

the percentage of the popular vote
that market participants believe each
nominee will garner.
In the IEM, one can also purchase
a contract that pays $1 if the candidate of the contract party becomes
president, and pays nothing otherwise. This is known as a winnertakes-all market. The share price for
each party can be interpreted as the
expected probability of that party’s
candidate winning. On September 17,
for example, the contract for the
Republican candidate was trading at

34 cents. If market participants on
that day had felt that George W.
Bush’s chance of winning the election
was greater than 34 percent, they
would have bought more Republican
shares, driving up the price of the
Republican contract.
Markets can be straightforward,
like the Presidential Winner-TakesAll Market, where payoffs are determined by which candidate wins, or
more complex, as in the Congressional Control Winner-Takes-All
Market, which offers four contracts

defined by whether the Republican
party retains control of the House
and Senate. If carefully designed,
markets can even accommodate
surprise events: In the New York
Senate Winner-Takes-All Market,
for instance, the withdrawal of
early favorite Rudolph Giuliani and
Congressman Rick Lazio’s acceptance of the GOP nomination were
accommodated by spinning off
another contact.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Operating Balances
Billions of dollars
40 OPERATING BALANCES a

Billions of dollars
900 GDP PER DOLLAR OF OPERATING BALANCES
800

30

700

600

20

500

400
Reserve balances
10

300

200
Service-related balances
0

100
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Billions of dollars
REQUIRED RESERVES b

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Standard deviation
FEDERAL FUNDS RATE

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Monthly average of depository institutions’ daily balances on deposit with Federal Reserve Banks.
b. Monthly average of daily reserve balances and vault cash applied to reserve requirements.
c. Actual reserves adjusted for changes in reserve requirements, plus estimated required reserves saved through sweep accounts.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Banks’ operating balances on
deposit at Federal Reserve Banks
have been declining over most of
the past decade. Banks hold these
balances for two reasons: as reserve
balances that, along with vault cash,
satisfy legal reserve requirements
and as service-related balances that
banks voluntarily contract to hold for
handling interbank payments.
(Balances other than these are relatively stable and low.) The decline
in operating balances can be gauged
roughly by the rapid increase in the
ratio of nominal GDP to balances. In
effect, more and more economic and

financial interbank business is being
transacted with a progressively
smaller amount of central bank
deposit money.
The decline in the actual volume
of operating balances is masked by
related, more familiar measures of
base money. Operating balances are
the quantity that the Federal Reserve
controls in implementing monetary
policy through open market operations to regulate the federal funds
rate. Monitoring the supply of base
money, however, requires careful
attention to shifts in demand such as
those instigated by changes in

reserve requirements and by new
banking technologies such as sweep
accounts that economize on required
reserves. Making those two adjustments turns the 1990s’ decline in
actual bank reserves into an increase
in the reserves component of the
monetary base.
Policy analysts also have been
concerned that volatility in the fed
funds rate might increase as
uncontrollable changes in the daily
supply of central bank money loom
larger in determining its quantity.
This, however, does not seem to
have been a problem.

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Gold
Dollars per troy ounce
550
GOLD SPOT AND FUTURES CONTRACT PRICES a

Millions of troy ounces
300 CENTRAL BANKS’ GOLD RESERVES

500

250
Futures price

450
200
400
150
350
100
300
Spot price
50

250

0

200
1988

1992

1996

2000

U.S.

Germany

France

Japan

U.K.

4/27/2000

10/26/2000

Dollars
80 GOLD FUTURES CALL OPTIONS c

Dollars per troy ounce
5
GOLD SPOT AND
FUTURES PRICE BASIS b
0

70

–5

60

–10

50

–15

40

–20

30

–25

20

–30

10
0

–35
1988

1992

1996

2000

11/16/1998

5/12/1999

11/1/1999

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Gold futures are based on the Bloomberg generic series. The current security is June 2001.
b. The basis is the spot price of gold less the futures contract price.
c. Call price on December 2000 futures at a strike price of $270 per troy ounce.
SOURCES: World Gold Council, Gold Demand Trends; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

For those who think it is the “only
real money” as well as those who,
with Lord Keynes, consider it a
“barbarous relic,” gold retains its
fascination. Over the past decade,
however, it has been a poor investment because its dollar price has
generally declined. Much of this
decline can be traced to concerns
over gold’s future role in the world
monetary system. Central banks hold
over one-fourth of the total gold
supply, so their actions—and rumors

about their actions—have a significant effect on gold prices.
One way to gauge expectations
about price movements is to look at
the futures market, but this is less true
for gold than for most other commodities. Gold, with a large supply
and low storage costs, is often a “fullcarry market,” with the futures price
tied to the spot price by the cost of
borrowing money and carrying the
gold forward. Thus, with a few
exceptions, the basis (the difference
between the spot and futures price)

responds more to interest rates than
to gold conditions.
The options market, which is particularly sensitive to changes in risk,
may provide more information. The
option to buy a December 2000 gold
futures contract became more valuable in late September 1999 when
European central banks announced
they would limit gold sales. This not
only increased the price of gold but
also resolved uncertainty, pushing
the call price higher.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Exchange Rates
Cents/yen
1.05 YEN SPOT AND FUTURES EXCHANGE RATES a

Dollars/euro
1.2 EURO SPOT AND FUTURES EXCHANGE RATES a

Yen futures
1.00
1.1
0.95

Euro futures
Euro spot

1.0

0.90
Yen spot
0.85

0.9
0.80

0.8

0.75
1/4/1999

6/24/1999

12/15/1999

6/7/2000

10/25/2000

Dollars/euro
16 EURO SIX-MONTH CALL OPTION, IMPLIED VOLATILITY b

1/4/1999

6/23/1999

12/10/1999

6/2/2000

10/25/2000

Yen/dollar
25
YEN SIX-MONTH CALL OPTION, IMPLIED VOLATILITY b

20
12

15

8
10

5

4
1/4/1999

6/24/1999

12/15/1999

6/7/2000

10/25/2000

1/4/1999

6/24/1999

12/15/1999

6/7/2000

10/25/2000

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Euro and yen futures are based on the Bloomberg generic series. The current securities are March 2001 futures contracts.
b. Volatilities implied by the call options on exchange rates are based on the Bloomberg generic series.
SOURCE: Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

Since June, the euro has continued
its slide against the dollar, but many
of the reasons cited for its decline
fail a simple test. If the cause of the
euro’s weakness is merely the relative strength of the U.S. economy or
a high degree of confidence in Alan
Greenspan, the dollar should show
comparable strength against the
Japanese yen, but that does not
seem to be the case. Rather, the yen
has held steady against the dollar in
both spot and futures markets.

We can gain another perspective
by looking at the option markets
for these currencies. Because options are very sensitive to the
volatility of the underlying asset, it
is possible to use modern option
pricing techniques to back out an
implied volatility from an option
price. This gives a market measure
of uncertainty based on expected
volatility, that is, how much exchange rate variability market
participants expect.

The charts tell two quite different
stories about the euro and the yen.
Uncertainty about the euro has
been growing since June. While the
euro has fallen against the dollar,
the markets have seemed increasingly uncertain about the direction
of the exchange rate. This means
that recovery is a possibility, but the
downside is that people lack the
confidence for investment. Implied
volatility for the dollar-to-yen
exchange rate has been declining
since June of this year.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND MEDIAN CPI

September Price Statistics

3.75
Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

5 yr.a

1999
avg.

3.50
3.25

Consumer prices

Median CPI b

All items

6.4

2.8

3.5

2.5

2.7

3.3

2.7

2.5

2.4

1.9

3.1

3.2

2.9

2.8

2.3

Finished goods 11.0

2.6

3.3

1.6

2.9

Less food

3.00
2.75

and energy
Median b
Producer prices

2.50
CPI
2.25
2.00
FOMC
central
tendency
projections
as of July
1999 c

1.75

Less food
and energy

4.1

2.2

1.2

1.2

0.8

1.50
1.25
1995

1996

1998

1997

1999

2000

12-month percent change
4.00 PCE CHAIN-TYPE PRICE INDEX AND CPI
3.75

Four-quarter percent change
6 EMPLOYMENT COST INDEX AND PRODUCTIVITY

3.50

5

2001

3.25
CPI
3.00

4

2.75

ECI

2.50

3
2.25

FOMC
central
tendency
projections
as of July
2000 c

2.00
1.75
1.50

2
Output per hour, nonfarm business sector
1

1.25

PCE Chain-Type Price Index

1.00
0.75

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Upper and lower bounds for inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.

The CPI rose 0.5% (6.4% annual rate)
during September, after falling for the
first time in more than 14 years the
month before. September’s retail
price numbers were driven principally by the CPI’s energy component,
which rose by a substantial amount in
September (56.8% annual rate) after
falling in August. In fact, the correlation between monthly percent
changes in the CPI’s energy component and the CPI has been nearly
97% in 2000, suggesting how strongly
energy price movements have affected the overall CPI.

Accordingly, it might be instructive
to consider the CPI without energy
prices to see whether other goods
prices show a similar pattern. If they
do, we might suppose that broader
price pressures are at work in the
economy. But in September, the CPI
excluding energy rose at an annual
rate of 2.7%, almost exactly the same
as in August. Moreover, while energy
prices have been very volatile
throughout 2000, the CPI excluding
energy has been quite stable, posting
quarterly increases at annual rates of
2.4%, 2.7%, and 2.7% to date this year.

One closely watched indicator of
future price increases at the retail
level is the quarterly Employment
Cost Index (ECI). Part of its popularity results from two theories that
emphasize the importance of labor
market dynamics in determining the
inflation rate. According to one of
these views, if firms are forced to pay
workers more for the same output,
the cost increase will ultimately be
passed on to consumers in the form
of higher goods prices. The other
view holds that causation runs in the
opposite direction: The expectation
(continued on next page)

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Percent of market basket
60 SELECTED MARKET-BASKET ITEMS

12-month percent change
4.0 CPI AND EURO-AREA HICP
3.5

50
CPI
Euro-area HICP a

3.0
40

CPI
2.5

30

2.0
Euro-area HICP a

20

1.5
10

1.0

0

0.5
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Goods b

2001

Services b

Energy

Food

12-month percent change
5 GOODS AND SERVICES PRICES

12-month percent change
4.5
ADJUSTED CPI AND EURO-AREA HICP
4.0

4

Euro-area HICP, services a
3.5

CPI, services

3
3.0
CPI using HICP market basket c

2

2.5

2.0

1

Euro-area HICP, goods a

Euro-area HICP a
1.5

0
1.0

CPI, goods
–1

0.5
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices.
b. Excludes food and energy items.
c. This adjustment applies the euro area’s HICP market-basket shares for 2000 to the entire time series of CPI data. The limited extent of the CPI’s
disaggregation makes this adjustment only an approximation.
NOTE: Price data are not seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Eurostat.

of higher goods prices in the future
induces workers to seek greater
compensation gains. In either case,
third-quarter ECI data give little cause
for concern. Year-over-year ECI
increases were larger in 2000 than in
the recent past. But unlike those
earlier increases, they have not
exceeded productivity growth.
European countries seeking
entrance to the continent’s Economic
and Monetary Union must demonstrate (among other things) a
measure of price stability. The
Harmonized Index of Consumer
Prices (HICP) provides a consistent

basis for comparing inflation performance across nations. It also permits
evaluation of inflation in the entire
11-nation euro area, whose monetary
policy is controlled by the European
Central Bank.
A look at the two prominent retail
price measures for the euro area and
the U.S. suggests that Europe’s inflation performance is superior. However, this sort of comparison may be
misleading because the two areas’
market baskets differ so significantly,
most noticeably in the very different
proportions of goods and services in
each index. A more valid comparison
involves applying the market basket

of the euro area’s HICP to price data
from the CPI.
The result suggests that the two
regions’ inflation performances are
more similar than the unadjusted
indexes show, but inflation in
Europe since 1998 is still shown to be
lower than in the U.S. Disaggregating
each retail price measure into price
indexes for goods and services
reveals the reason: Although the inflation rate for goods has recently
been somewhat lower in Europe
than in the U.S., Europe’s inflation
rate for services has been well below
that of the U.S. since 1996.

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Index, log scale a
10 NOMINAL AND REAL GDP

b,c

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IIIQ
(Advance estimate)

8

Change,
billions
of 1996 $

5.52
6

Real GDP
63.3
Consumer spending
69.8
Durables
16.2
Nondurables
22.2
Services
32.6
Business fixed
investment
23.8
Equipment
23.6
Structures
1.2
Residential investment –8.9
Government spending –14.3
National defense
–9.4
Net exports
–7.4
Exports
42.8
Imports
50.3
Change in private
inventories
1.3

Nominal
4

7.19

2

3.29

Real

10.22

3.19
2.98
1
1969

1974

1979

1984

1989

1994

2.7
4.5
7.5
4.9
3.7

5.3
5.3
9.3
5.4
4.3

6.9
8.5
1.7
–9.2
–3.6
–10.2
—
16.2
13.9

12.9
14.0
9.3
–1.2
2.1
–1.3
—
11.7
13.7

—

—

1999

Annualized percent change from previous quarter
9 GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST b
8

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

4.2

MARGIN OF ERROR FOR 2000:IIIQ ADVANCE GDP GROWTH d

Final estimate
Advance estimate

7

3.7

Blue Chip forecast, October 10, 2000

6
3.2
5
30-year average
4
2.7
3
2

2.2

1
0

1.7
IIIQ

IVQ
1999

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IIQ

IQ
2001

Two-thirds of revisions

Nine-tenths of revisions

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. The indexes’ initial values of 1 represent the level of real and nominal GDP in 1969:IIIQ, when nominal GDP passed $1 trillion. The numbers along the plot lines
are average annual growth rates of nominal and real GDP, measured at business-cycle peaks (dotted vertical lines) approximately a decade apart. Most recent
growth rates are for the period ending 2000:IIIQ.
b. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
c. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
d. The margin of error, which is based on the 1978–99 period, represents the range of positive and negative revision between the advance and final estimates.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; National Bureau of Economic Research; and Blue Chip
Economic Indicators, October 10, 2000.

Nominal GDP crossed the $10 trillion
threshold in 2000:IIIQ, according to
the advance estimate released late in
October. Since 1969, when nominal
GDP was at $1 trillion, increases in
real GDP have contributed less to
reaching the $10 trillion mark than
have price level increases. Of course,
some of this may be an illusion created by the oft-noted upward bias in
measures of inflation. More certain
is the decade-by-decade slowing in
nominal GDP’s rate of increase.
Slowing inflation more than offset
increases in real GDP’s growth rate.

Real GDP’s annual rate of
increase was only 2.7% in the
advance estimate for 2000:IIIQ, considerably slower than in the recent
past. The final estimate, when released near year’s end, could be
higher or lower than this, though
advance estimates tend to be conservative and the final estimate is more
often higher than lower. Taken at face
value, the substantial reduction of
GDP growth in the past quarter may
have resulted more from special
factors than from any underlying
weakness in the economy. In fact,

consumption expenditures contributed 3 percentage points to
growth in the third quarter, up from
only 2.1 percentage points in the second quarter. Nonresidential business
investment, while dampened from its
second-quarter pace, still added
another 0.9 percentage point to GDP
growth, representing a small increase
in spending on structures and a
moderate increase in spending on
equipment and software.
The combined 3.9 percentage
points that consumption and business fixed investment contributed to
(continued on next page)

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Percentage points
3 CONTRIBUTION OF CHANGE IN INVENTORY

Percentage points
4 CONTRIBUTIONS TO 2000:IIIQ REAL GDP GROWTH

TO GDP GROWTH
3

2

2

Exports

1

Nonresidential
fixed investment

1

Change in
inventory
0

Personal
consumption

Residential
investment

–1

0

–1

Government
expenditures

–2

–2

Imports
–3

–3

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Ratio
Hundreds of current dollars per acre
120 AGRICULTURAL LAND VALUE AND PRICES
10

23

Land value a
110

Percent
20

Percent
26 FARM INCOME AND SUBSIDY

18

Subsidies/farm national income b

9

100

8

90

20

16

17

14

14

12

7
Output prices/input prices

10

11
Corporate farm profits/farm national income c

80

6
1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

8

8
1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Nominal dollars.
b. Subsidies to operators as a share of total U.S. farm national income.
c. Corporate profits as a share of the sum of proprietors’ income and corporate profits, with adjustments for inventory valuation and capital consumption.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Agriculture; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census.

GDP growth were offset by a small
decline in residential housing investment and a somewhat larger and
unlikely-to-be-repeated decline in
government expenditures, mostly at
the federal level. The government
sector typically contributes about half
a percentage point to GDP growth
rates, so this quarter’s decline dragged
GDP growth down about one full
percentage point. On the other hand,
because the contribution of exports
increased more than that of imports,
net exports’ dampening influence on

GDP growth was less than it has
been over much of the current
expansion. This, too, seems unlikely
to continue unless the U.S. economic
expansion slows dramatically relative
to expansions in countries that
demand our exports. Inventory accumulation was essentially unchanged
from the previous quarter—an
unusual event in itself.
There is some question whether
farmers have shared in the prosperity
of the last two economic expansions.
Price margins in farm production

have shrunk nearly 30% over the last
15 years as the ratio of output to input
prices declined. Paradoxically, the
value of farm land has soared during
the same period. Government subsidies have helped to offset bad years,
but the general trend in assistance has
been down. Just as in other industries,
reduced margins have put pressure on
small operators. The corporate share
of farm income has risen as growing
numbers of farmers find it more
profitable to sell their land than to
farm it.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
350 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT GROWTH

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

300
1997

1998

1999

YTDa

Oct.
2000

Payroll employment
280
Goods-producing
48
Mining
1
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
27
Nondurable goods –2

251
22
–3
37
–12
–2
–11

229
4
–3
25
–18
–6
–12

182
9
1
19
–12
–4
–7

137
38
4
34
0
0
0

229
20
30
22
120
28

225
16
36
10
124
28

174
15
24
2
106
19

99
23
4
20
17
20

250
200
150
100

Service-producing
b
TPU
Retail trade
FIREc
Services
Government

50
0

232
16
24
21
141
17

–50

Average for period (percent)

Civilian unemployment

4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

3.9

–100
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

IIIQ Aug. Sept. Oct.
2000

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS d

Percent
8.2

64.5

7.6

Year-over-year percent change
40 MASS LAYOFFS
30

Employment-to-population ratio
64.0

7.0

63.5

6.4

63.0

5.8

20
All industries
10

0

Civilian unemployment rate
62.5

5.2

62.0

4.6

–10
Manufacturing
61.5

4.0
3.4

61.0
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

–20

–30
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Year to date.
b, Transportation and public utilities.
c. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
d. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Total nonfarm employment showed a
net gain of 137,000 workers last
month, comparable to September’s
gain of 148,000 (adjusted for the
effect of strikes and the layoff of the
last sizeable contingent of temporary
census workers). Other labor market
measures also show relative equability: The unemployment rate remained
at 3.9%, while the employment-topopulation ratio inched up one-tenth
of a percent to 64.4%.
Employment gains were concentrated primarily in construction and

a few service-producing industries.
Construction has experienced two
months of strong seasonally
adjusted employment gains due to
this fall’s unusually light layoffs. In
the service-producing sector, transportation and public utilities
showed strong gains, as did finance,
insurance, and real estate.
The unemployment rate has fallen
steadily over the last five years, but
has there been a corresponding
decrease in extended mass layoffs?
This series, which includes layoffs of

at least 50 workers lasting at least 31
days, has been very volatile; no clear
trend has emerged. The data do
show that the number of mass
layoffs in the manufacturing sector
rose rapidly during the 1998 financial
crisis. As the world economic situation improved in 1999, the number
of mass layoffs fell precipitously in
the export-sensitive manufacturing
industry; for the overall industrial
base, the decline was also steep
though less dramatic.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Poverty in the U.S.
Percent
40 NATIONAL POVERTY RATES, 1973–99

Percent
30 POVERTY RATES BY GENDER, 1999

35
25

Black

Male
Female

30
20
25
Hispanic a
20

15
All groups

15
10
10
White

5

5
0

0
1973 1976

1979

1982

1985

1988

1991

1994

1997

Percent
22 POVERTY RATES BY AGE GROUP, 1995 AND 1999

All groups

White

Black

Hispanic

Percent
25 POVERTY RATES FOR CHILDREN AND SENIORS, 1985–99

19
1995
1999

21
Children b

16
17
13
13
10
Seniors c
9

7

4

5
Under 18 18–24 25–34 35–44 45–54 55–59 60–64 65–74 Over 75

1985

1989

1993

1997

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Includes Hispanics of all races.
b. All persons under the age of 18.
c. All persons 65 and over.
NOTE: The U.S. Census Bureau distinguishes between “all whites” and “non-Hispanic whites.” Unless otherwise noted, “whites” refers to the Census Bureau
classification of non-Hispanic whites.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

Poverty, a persistent problem in the
U.S., will soon be getting more
attention, both nationally and locally.
Nationally, the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reauthorization Act of 1996, which has set
federal welfare policy for the past
five years, must be reconsidered by
Congress in 2001. In Ohio, legislation
enacted in 1997 set a three-year limit
on the receipt of welfare cash assistance benefits. The first recipients to
reach this limit were removed from
the welfare rolls as of October 1.

How do we define poverty?
According to the U.S. Census Bureau,
an individual younger than 65 was
living in poverty in 1999 if his or her
annual income was less than $8,667.
For individuals 65 and over, the
poverty threshold was $7,990. A family of four, with two adults and two
dependent children under 18, was
considered to be living in poverty if
its household income did not exceed
$16,895. These definitions were derived from estimates of minimum nutritional and housing standards that
were made in 1963 and updated

annually on the basis of changes in
the Consumer Price Index.
In 1999, 11.8% of Americans lived
in poverty, the lowest rate since 1979.
Although poverty rates for blacks and
people of Hispanic origin were considerably higher than the national
average, they were equal to or below
the lowest rates recorded since 1959,
when the first Current Population
Survey was taken. The poverty rate
for blacks fell to a record low of
23.6% in 1999; for Hispanics, the rate
dropped to 22.8%, close to the lows
recorded for that group in the 1970s.
(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Poverty in the U.S.(cont.)
Percent
40 HOUSEHOLD POVERTY RATES BY WORK STATUS, 1999

Percent
20 POVERTY RATES AMONG WORKERS

35
Worked full time
16

White
Black
Hispanic

30

Worked part time
Did not work

25

12

20
8

15

10
4
5
0

0
1995

1997

All groups

1999

Percent
80 HOUSEHOLD POVERTY RATES BY FAMILY STATUS, 1999

White

Black

Hispanic

Percent
60 POVERTY RATES OF HOUSEHOLDS WITH CHILDREN
BY FAMILY STATUS, 1999

70
Total
60

50

With no workers
With one or more workers

White a
Black
Hispanic

40
50

30

40

30
20
20
10
10
0

0
All households

Married couple
families

Single female
householder

Single male
householder

All households

Married couple
families

Single female
householders

Single male
householders

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Includes whites of Hispanic origin.
NOTE: The U.S. Census Bureau distinguishes between “all whites” and “non-Hispanic whites.” Unless otherwise noted, “whites” refers to the Census Bureau
classification of non-Hispanic whites.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

Across all races, poverty was more
prevalent among women. The highest rate occurred among black
women. Slightly more than one out
of every four black or Hispanic
women lived in poverty in 1999.
That year, the incidence of
poverty by age group (that is, the
age distribution of those living alone
or with others in households whose
income is below the poverty line)
was highest among individuals
18–24, who surpassed children as
the most impoverished group.
However, people aged 65–74 were

the only group whose poverty rate
rose between 1995 and 1999.
Despite that increase, this group had
one of the lowest rates in 1999.
Poverty rates for both children
(under 18) and seniors (older than
65) have been falling since 1993.
Since 1996, the number of working poor has declined. Although
workers’ poverty rates did not
decline substantially for blacks or
whites, a large reduction for Hispanics occurred in 1995–97. Poverty
rates among workers changed much
more noticeably in 1997–99, when

they dropped more than a full
percentage point for all three ethnic
categories. Despite these declines,
the prevalence of poverty among
working blacks and Hispanics is still
nearly three times that of nonHispanic whites.
For households, the presence of
one worker (even one with only a
part-time job) significantly decreases
the prevalence of poverty for all
races and family types. Among
blacks, individuals who did not work
were over seven times more likely to
live in poverty than those who
(continued on next page)

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Poverty in the U.S.(cont.)
Percent
18 POVERTY RATES BY REGION b

Percent
20 POVERTY RATES BY AREA OF RESIDENCE, 1999
Poor
Severely poor a

16

South

15

West
14
Northeast

10

12
Midwest

5

10

8

0
Metropolitan
(total)

Metropolitan
(central city)

1995

Metropolitan
Nonmetropolitan
(outside central city)

Percent
30 POVERTY RATES BY REGION, 1999

1996

1997

1998

1999

Percent
22 POVERTY RATES IN FOURTH DISTRICT STATES c
White
Black

25

20

Hispanic

West Virginia
20

18

15

16
Kentucky

10

14
Ohio

5

12

0

10

Pennsylvania
Northeast

Midwest

South

West

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. The Census Bureau defines the “severely poor” as those living in households whose income is no more than half the amount set as the poverty threshold.
b. Regions are those defined by the Census Bureau.
c. To compare poverty rate changes at the state level, the Census Bureau uses two-year moving averages. So, for example, the 1999 figure is the two-year
average for 1998–99.
NOTE: The Census Bureau distinguishes between “all whites” and “non-Hispanic whites.” Unless otherwise noted, “whites” refers to the Census Bureau
classification of non-Hispanic whites.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

worked full time. Households
headed by single females of all races
had a 30.4% poverty rate, the highest
of any household category. This figure skyrockets to 67.9% if no one in
the house worked during the year.
Among households with children,
poverty rates were lowest for marriedcouple families. They were highest for
single female householders, among
whom rates for blacks and Hispanics
were almost 20 percentage points
higher than those for whites.
Like race, gender, and family
structure, place of residence also

showed differences in both poverty
and severe poverty. Individuals living in metropolitan areas, but not
within the central city’s limits, had a
significantly lower poverty rate than
those living in a central city or nonmetropolitan area.
Nationally, poverty was most
prevalent in the Northeast (a change
from 1995, when poverty was highest in the South), and least prevalent
in the West. Rates in both the Midwest and Northeast increased in
1998–99, despite a decline in the U.S.
as a whole. Racial differences in

poverty varied widely across regions.
Poverty rates have declined in
every Fourth District state but Ohio,
which saw an increase of 0.5 percentage point in 1998–99. The precipitous
drop in Kentucky’s poverty rate has
moved the state from the fourthhighest poverty rate in 1994 to 13th in
1999. West Virginia remains the
Fourth District’s highest ranking state
(4th), while Pennsylvania enjoys the
lowest rank (30th). Ohio, although
below the national poverty rate,
ranks 24th among the states.

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions
Percent
50 CONSUMER LOAN MARKET SHARE a

Percent
16 UNPROFITABLE INSTITUTIONS

45

14

Large banks
40

12
35
10

30
25

8
Pools of securitized assets

Credit unions

20

6

15

All banks

Credit unions

4

10
2

5

Small banks
0

0
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

Percent
RETURN ON EQUITY

1996

1997

1998

1990

1999

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998 1999

Percent
1.6 RETURN ON ASSETS
1.4
Credit unions
1.2
Small banks

1.0

0.8

0.6
All banks
0.4

0.2
0
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Shares do not total 100%. The difference includes finance companies, savings institutions, and nonfinancial businesses.
NOTE: Bank data are for FDIC-insured commercial banks; credit union data are for federally insured credit unions. Small banks are defined as commercial
banks with total assets less than $100 million.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Bulletin; Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile
and Statistics on Banking; and National Credit Union Administration, Year-end Statistics for Federally Insured Credit Unions.

The dominant trend in the
consumer loan market is toward
securitized loans (loans that are
packaged and sold off as securities).
Their market share jumped from
9.52% to 30.51% in the last decade.
However, the decline in the market
share of large commercial banks
may give an inaccurate impression
because the data are based on balance sheets after securitized assets
are taken off the originating bank’s
books. We would obtain a more
precise picture by assigning to each

institution its share in the pool of
securitized assets, but unfortunately,
we lack this information. Still, we
note that although banks control a
larger share of the consumer loan
market than do credit unions, this is
not true across all bank sizes. In
fact, the market share of small
banks (those with total assets under
$100 million) is smaller than that of
credit unions. Moreover, the
Supreme Court ruling of February
1998, which capped credit unions’
expansion by limiting their mem-

bership pool, does not seem to
have affected their performance or
their presence in the consumer
lending market.
The rise in the percent of unprofitable institutions over the last five
years may be explained by greater
competition in the consumer loan
market. This figure rose from a low
of around 4% in the first half of the
1990s to 7.24% for banks and 9.39%
for credit unions. This explanation is
reinforced by evidence of flatter
return on assets and equity for banks
(continued on next page)

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions (cont.)
Percent
70
NET LEASES AND LOANS/TOTAL ASSETS b

Percent
7 TOTAL OPERATING PROFIT/TOTAL ASSETS a

65
6

Credit unions
60
Credit unions
55

5

Small banks
50

Small banks
4

45

40

3
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

Percent
2.5 DELINQUENT LOANS/TOTAL LOANS

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

1996

1997

1998

1999

Percent
0.8 NET CHARGE-OFFS/TOTAL LOANS
0.7

2.0
0.6
Small banks

Credit unions
0.5

1.5

0.4
1.0

Small banks

0.3

Credit unions

0.2
0.5
0.1
0

0
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. Operating profit is calculated before cost of funds.
b. Leases and loans for credit unions equal loans only, since credit unions do not provide leases.
NOTE: Bank data are for FDIC-insured commercial banks; credit union data are for federally insured credit unions. Small banks are defined as commercial
banks with total assets less than $100 million.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile and Statistics on Banking; and National Credit Union Administration,
Year-end Statistics for Federally Insured Credit Unions.

and declining returns for credit
unions. Credit unions were star performers in the first half of the 1990s
but seem to have lost their competitive edge: Their return on assets declined from 1.4% in 1993 to 0.9% in
1999. In the banking industry, we
notice again that bank size affects
performance measures. Despite the
industry’s high return figures overall,
small banks’ returns trend downward, closely following credit union
data. This suggests that increasing
competition mostly affects the
performance of small institutions.

We focus on small banks and
credit unions because they are comparable in size and business line.
The weak performance of credit
unions, observed in their equity and
return on assets, is also evident in
their assets’ deteriorating ability to
generate profit. Starting in the mid1990s, small banks have continuously generated more operating
profit per dollar of assets than have
credit unions. The difference is less
than half a penny on each dollar, but
the trend is persistent.

Credit unions lend more aggressively than small banks. Although
small banks closed the wide gap in
the share of loans in total assets (from
12.71% in the late 1980s to 6.28% in
1999), the difference is still higher
than the 2.43% difference in 1993.
The percent of delinquent loans
in banks’ total loan portfolio improved significantly over the last
decade. For small banks, this figure
declined from 2.03% in 1990 to
0.9% in 1999. For credit unions, the
decline was from 1.7% to 0.75% over
(continued on next page)

19
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions (cont.)
Percent
75 TOTAL LOANS AND LEASES/TOTAL ASSETS a.b,c

Total assets (billions of dollars)
125 ASSETS a,b

100

Small banks
Credit unions

Small banks
Credit unions

70

75

65

50

60

25

55

50

0
Northeast Mid-Atlantic

Southeast

Central

Midwest

Northeast

Pacific

Mid-Atlantic Southeast

Central

Midwest

Pacific

Central

Midwest

Pacific

Return on equity (percent)
15 RETURN ON EQUITY a,b

Return on assets (percent)
1.5 RETURN ON ASSETS a,b
Small banks
Credit unions

Small banks
Credit unions

1.0

10

5

0.5

0

0
Northeast Mid-Atlantic

Southeast

Central

Midwest

Pacific

Northeast

Mid-Atlantic Southeast

FRB Cleveland • November 2000

a. The states are divided into the following six regions, following the usage of the National Credit Union Administration. Northeast: Connecticut, Maine,
Massachusetts, New Hampshire, New York, Rhode Island, Vermont. Mid-Atlantic: Delaware, District of Columbia, Maryland, New Jersey, Pennsylvania
Virginia, West Virginia. Southeast: Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Louisiana, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, Tennessee.
Central: Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, Missouri, Ohio, Wisconsin. Midwest: Arizona, Colorado, Iowa, Kansas, Minnesota, Nebraska, New Mexico,
North Dakota, Oklahoma, South Dakota, Texas, Utah, Wyoming. Pacific: Alaska, California, Hawaii, Idaho, Montana, Nevada, Oregon, Washington.
b. Figures are for the end of 1999.
c. The ratio of total loans and leases to assets for credit unions equals total loans to assets, since credit unions do not provide leases.
NOTE: Bank data are for FDIC-insured commercial banks; credit union data are for federally insured credit unions. Small banks are defined as commercial
banks with total assets less than $100 million.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation; and National Credit Union Administration, Year-end Statistics for Federally Insured Credit Unions.

the same period. On net charge-offs,
both industries achieved a small but
significant improvement. The ratio
of net charge-offs to total loans is
down to 0.49% for credit unions and
0.37% for small banks.
In every region except the Midwest, credit unions surpass small
banks in total asset size. The
difference is especially striking in the
Pacific region, where credit unions’
total assets average $91 million and

those of small banks $14 million.
Credit unions also are distributed
more uniformly across the regions.
The difference in asset size between
the region with the largest amount
and the region with the smallest
amount is $99 million for banks and
$44 million for credit unions. In all
regions, credit unions hold a larger
share of their assets in loans than do
small banks.

Measures of equity and return on
assets show that credit unions’ performance is more homogeneous
across the country, while small
banks do well in the central
(ROA: 1.02%) and midwestern
(ROA: 1.16%) states but do poorly
in the mid-Atlantic (ROA: 0.15%),
northeastern (ROA: 0.65%), and
Pacific (ROA: 0.59%) states.