View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Tbe Economy in Perspective
Potentialpl-oblems . .. Has the economy been
expanding beyond its potential, threatening to
boost inflation? Or has the level of econonlic
activity only now reached its potential? Can it
grow at rates of 3% or Inore in real terms before inflation begins to drift up?
The Commerce Department recently announced that real GDP rose 2.25% during the
last four quarters, a pace consistent with n~ost
analysts' estimates of the growth rate for potential GDI? The Labor Department followed with
a report that the nation's unemployment rate
held steady at 5.2% in October, a figure at or
below conventional estimates for full employment. No wonder speculation about inflation's
future course remains intense.
The concept of potential output (or full eruployment in the labor ~narliet)has a long, checkered history in n~acroeconomics.Early Keynesians aclvancecl the idea, arguing that since
inflation would result from resource utilization
above potential, and cleflation would arise from
underutilization, governments should use monetary and fiscal policies to keep the level of actual
economic activity equal to its potential.
Keynesian econornists in the 1960s thought
that potential output changecl very slomrly, and
that its value could be closely pinpointecl.
I<ennecly-Johnson era policymalters also believecl that inflation and unemployment, which
they regarclecl as inversely related, coulcl be
tradecl off against one another in a preclictable
way through the use of elernand-management
stmtegies. Against the bacliclrop of the Great Depression, an event that created public fear of
wiclespreacl unenlployment, the Keynesians'
faith in full ernployrnent is unclerstanclable; however, in view of the accelerating inflation of the
late 1760s ancl the poor economic perfornlance
of the 1770s, their confidence seems misplaced.
By the early 1970s, many econo~nistsembraced a more sophisticatecl ~~ersion
of potential
output, callecl the natural rate concept. Milton
Friedman, among others, theorizecl that actual
unelnploynlent would ala-ays gravitate towarcl a
"natural rate" of unemployment. The actual and
natural rates woulcl equalize only when inflation
nlatchecl the rate that people had already incorporatecl into their wage- anel price-setting plans
(that is, expected inflation). Natural-rate aclvocates emphasizecl that clemand-management
policies shoulcl not be usecl to holcl unemployment permanently below the natural rate, since
this strategy m~oulclresc~ltin escalating inflation.
Policymakers coulcl, however, attenlpt to keep
unemployrnent at the natural rate ancl accept the
prevailing pace of inflation.
Aclvocates also reasonecl that the natural rate
of unemploy~nentcould fluctuate both slowly-

through changes in the con~positionof the labor
force, for example-ancl
quickly-through
changes in tax policy, unemployment compensation benefits, nlininlunl wage laws, and other
factors affecting labor supply. Proponents of
this logic urged policymakers to be more cautious in estinlating economic potential and less
ambitious in their objectives. Nevertheless, the
practice of using demancl-management policies
to guide the economy along a path of full resource ~~tilization
persisteel throughout the
1970s. And, although the intellectual basis for
taking greater care in policy design and implenlentation had been established, macroeconomic performance was dismal.
Have we learned from our experiences? Many
economists have abancloned potential output as
a conceptual guide for policymakers. Some
think the idea itself is banltl~ipt,depencling as it
does on being able to quantify the supply and
procluctivity of lancl, labor, ancl capital in some
idealized state of econonlic activity. Others accept the concept, but m~orryabout not being
able to aclequately estiinate potential output or
current and future econonlic conclitions. These
factors combine to rnalie an "output gap" framework problematic for policynlakers who try to
lteep real econonlic activity on any predetermined path, including that of full employruent.
Despite these shortcomings, many econonlists still cherish the ambition of closing the
output gap. This is partly because politicians
ancl the public have been conclitioned for
decades to think that econonlic policy toolsprincipally those of monetary policy-shoulcl
be continually geared towarcl keeping aggregate clernancl high. Ironically, although economists realize that monetary policy can be used
to stinlulate aggregate demand, nlost of the evictence suggests that these effects are short lived.
Conten~porarynlacroeconornic theorists teach
that nlonetary policy does not affect the econonly's level of potential output ancl cannot be
relied on to lteep output mo\~ingalong a precletermineel path. Monetary policy can be used
systen~aticallyfor only one purpose-to determine the price level. Indeed, a low inflation environluent is nlonetary policy's best contribution
to better econo~nicconctitions.
Closing the output gap remains a popular aspiration because people want to believe it can
be clone. Even though history has shown repeatedly that estinlates of potential output are unreliable, when the nest generation of econornists
and policymalters arrive on the scene they inevitably push-or get pushed-to create inflation. Unfortunately, our nation's ability to learn
that fill1 elnploynlent is no guide for macroecononlic policy has fallen far short of its potential.

S

0

8

8

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

8

Monetay Policy
Blll~onsoi dollarsa
460
MONETARY BASE

440

-

420

-

400

-

380

-

360

-

Billions of dollarsa

, ' Average growth rate = 7 3%

280 0
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

Billions of dollarsa
3,800

Billions of dollarsa
7,000

6,900
3,700
6,800
6,700

3,600

6,600
3,500

6,500
6,400

3,400
6,300
6,200

3,300

6,100
3,200
19

6,000
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

a. Seasonally adjusted.
b. Chain-weighted 1992 dollars.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Over the last five years, the narrower monetary aggregates have
tenclecl to grow 111ore rapidly than
their [nore broadly definecl counterparts. In particular, the monetary
lxtse grew I'aster than MI,\vliich in
turn grew faster than M2. One contrihutor to this phenomenon may
have been the rapid increase in the
amount of currency held outsicle the
I1.S.over this periocl. Since currency
represents a larger fraction of tile
1nonet:tsy h:lse than, say. M2,rapicl
growth in currency will have a Inore

noticeable ililpact on the narrower
:tggrega tes.
In a growing economy, the
; ~ ~ n o u nof
t money in circulation
nl~lstexpand over time to facilitate
the incre:tsing number of tr:tnsactions hetsveen buyers and sellers. In
any given year, the total value of
final goods and services transactions
is meas~ireclby real GDP. Over long
periocls, therefore, we woulcl expect
the growth mte of the monetary aggregates to be at least as large as the
growth sate of real GDP. However, if
the monetary aggregates grow faster

than real GDI' over sustailled periocls, then there is a danger of ..too
much money chasing too few
goocls." 'rhis can lead to an erosion
in the purchasing power of
money-othe1wise
known as inflation. Notice that the average annual
compound growth rate of &/I2over
the last five years (2.3%) is ve1y
close to the average growth rate of
real GI)I-' (2.4%). This may help to
explain the low levels of inflation
espcricnced over this periocl.
(coi ~tiizrled017 nextpagt.)

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percent

20

1 M I GROWTH: ACTUAL VERSUS PREDICTED

Real GDP, deviation from trend in percent

5

Real GDP, deviation from trend in percent
5

4

4

3

3

2

2

1
1

0
0
-1
-1

-2
-2

-3

-3

-4

-5
-1 0

-5

0

5

10

15

Unanticipated money growth (actual less predicted), percent

20

-4

-5

-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
Unaniicipated change in interest rate (actual less predicted), percent

4

a. Predicted values are constructed by regressing each variable on its own lagged value and a constant term over the entire sample period.
b. One-year nominal interest rate is the nominal one-year Treasury yield.
c. Real growth is measured in chain-weighted 1992 dollars, seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Monetary policy is thought to influence the level of real economic
activity over the course of the business cycle. In this regarcl, two principal tools that the Federal Iieserve
has at its clisposal are the growth
rate of the money stocli ancl the
level of short-term nolninal interest
rates. By regressing the growth rate
o f the M I money stocli on its lagged
value and a constant terrn, w e can
construct a simple one-cluarteraheact forecast for preclictecl &I1
growth. A plot of preclictecl versus

actual PI1 growth shows that large
forecast errors occur whenever the
actual series experiences a sudden
~ ~ p ~ v aor
r c lclownward n~ovement.
These errors can be interpretecl as a
measure of "unanticipated" money
gro~vth.An analogous procedure
can I,e used to construct a measure
of i~nanticipateclchanges in the oneyear nominal interest rate.
The deviation of real GDI' from
its trencl line provides a measure of
the business cycle conlponent of
real econo~nicactivity. A scatterplot

of this measure versus the level of
~111:lnticipatecl
money gro\vth reveals
:I \\leal< negative relationship between the two variables, 1 ~ 1 to n e
that is extremely i~nprecise.Fro111
this eviclence. it does not appear
that un:tnticipatetl money growth
exerts an important inflilence o n
real economic activity. In co~ltlxst,
there seems to Ile a positive relationship between the business cycle
component of real GDP ancl unanticipatecl changes in the one-ye;lr
(cot~tintredon tre.~/
pqri

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Growth rate of per capita GDP, percent

1 CROSS-COUNTRY GROWTH AND INFLATION

Growth rate of per capita GDP, percent

I

ICROSS-COUNTRYGROWTH AND INFLATION VARIABILITY I

Inflationvariability

lnflation, percent

Growth rate of per capita GDP, percent

Inflation oercent

lnvestmentltotalincome, percent

Inflation variability,percent

NOTE: Data for Brazil were removed from the data set. lnflation variability is defined as the standard deviation of inflation within a given year, averaged over
the time period of the sample.
System. Finance and
SOURCE: Ruth Judson and Athanasios Orphanides, "lnflation, Volatility, and Growth," Board of Governors of the Federal R e S e ~ e
Economics Discussion Series No. 96-19, May 1996, pp. 15-17.

nominal interest rate. However, this
picture may simply reflect the Federal Reserve's response to c)~clical
changes in nominal mtes. Thus, ca~1sation may run from real GDI' to
unanticip:ltecl chzlnges in interest
rates, lather than \.'Ice versa.
Sollle policynlalters believe that
high ancl variahle mtes of inflation
are detri~nentalto economic growth.
A cross-countl-). comparison s h o ~ v s
that very high levels of inflation tencl
to h e associated with lo\ver growth

rates. Mow~ever,at lower levels of inflation, there does not seem to be
much of a l i ~ i l tbetween the two variables. A similar story applies to the
relationship between growth and inflation variability. There appears to
he a positive relationship between
the level of inflation and its v:lriability. One possible explanation is that
governments which undertalte illadvised monetary policies that leacl
to higll ancl variable rates of inflation
are also more lilcely to enact fiscal
ancl regulatory policies that are

harmh~lto growth. Fiscal policy can
influence gro~vththrough channels
such as tax rates, which affect people's incentives to \vorlt, save, invest.
ancl talte entrepreneurid risks. There
is a positive relationship between the
share of income clevotecl to capit:il
investment ancl economic gro\i~th.
This suggests that policies which encourage investment-such as tax
policies that remove clisincelltives for
private saving-will sti~n~llate
econornic gro\vth.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Interest Rates
Percent, weekly averages

Percent weekly averages
75

9.5 [CAPITAL MARKET RATES

YIELD CURVESa

70

-

65

-

60

-

55

-

50

I

l

l

I

Basis points
700

600

500

400

300

200

100
0
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

2.5

3.0

3.5
4.0
45
50
3-month Treasury yield, percenlage po~nts

5.5

6.0

a.
b.
c.
d.

All instruments are constant-maturity series.
Estimate of the yield on a recently offered, A-rated utility bond with a maturity of 30 years and call protection of five years.
Bond Buyer Index, general obligation, 20 years to maturity, mixed quality.
Three-month instrument is quoted from the secondary market on a yield basis; 10-year instrument is a constant-maturity series.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

'The yielcl ccirve has flattenecl since
~ s eslast month. with ;ill I . ; L ~falling
cept those on short-term bills of
three ancl sis months. The .?-year. 3month spre:tcl clroppecl to 95 basis
points ancl the lO-)~ear, .?-month
spread tell to 141 basis points. Despite this decline, the yield cume re~ n a i n ssteeper ancl straighter than it
w a s at the beginning of the year.
Longer-term capital market rates
have been moving clown since early
Septernl~er..A1 one extreme, utilities
have fallen by 30 l~asispoints: at the

other. state and local boncls have
clroppecl hp only 11. This has closecl
the spreacls between utilities and
other rates, even pushing utility
Iates below mortgages. A longer
perspective confirms the yielcl curve
picture-long
rates in the broad
nlarket senlain significantly above
their Januasy level.
Is there any relatioll between the
level of the yielcl curve and its slope?
When the short rate rose in 1994,
the yielcl spread initially rose n-ith it.
Marliet observers attributed this to

preclictions of even larger future increases. heighteneel infl~ltionfears,
or greater uncertainty over rates.
Soon the pattern reversed, ho~vever;
conforming to the generally negative relationship between short rates
ancl the yield spreacl. A higher short
rate usually means a flatter yielcl
curve. since long rates clo not increase by quite 21s much. This represents a tendency. howevec not an
exact relationship, ancl 1996 saw the
spreatl xviclen clespite little change in
short-term rates.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

I~fllationand P r i m
12-month oercen: chanoe

September Price Statistics
Annualized percent
change, last:
Imo.

1995

9 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr.

avg.

Consumer Prices
All items

3.1

3.2

3.0

2.9

2.6

Less food
and energy

3.7

2.8

2.6

3.0

3.0

Mediana

2.1

2.8

2.9

3.0

3.2

Finished goods 2.8

2.3

2.7

1.6

2.1

Less food
and energy

3.4

0.8

1.4

1.6

2.6

Commodity futures
pricesb
-9.3

1.1

1.9

2.8

5.4

Producer Prices

Four-quarter percent change

Percent oi iorecasts

70

Y."

IQ

IIIQ IVQ
1995

lia

IQ

IIIQ Iva
1996

Ila

la

ila

itla

1997

Iva

IDISTRIBUTION
OF ECONOMISTS, 1997 CPI FORECASTS~ I

1.8-2.2

2.3-27

2.8-3.2
3.3-3.7
Annualized percent change

38-4.2

a. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
b. As measured by the KR-CRB composite futures index, all commodities. Data reprinted with permission of the Commodity Research Bureau, a Knight-Ridder
Business Information Service.
c. Upper and lower bounds for CPI inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
d. Consensus forecast of the Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; the Commodity Research Bureau; and Blue Chip
Economic Indicators, January 16 and October 10, 1996.

.

,

I h e S e p t e ~ ~ i t )price
o ~ stat15tlc5 remain gei~e~,ill\
In Ilne \\ ~ t hthe11 3%
trencl of tile Ici5t fen 1e,rrs 711e 1'10ducer 1)tlce Inclex .ind the Consumel 1'11ce Inclex (01'1) lose dt dnnclal~/ecl [,ires of 2 Si%/ir.inti 3 1%
during the month (tmt .I 111t h l g h e ~
when foocl .mcl enel#) goods .ire
cxcluclecl) R,IIto elcite the Cl'I 15
LIP 3 2%) \\ h ~ l ei t 5 core me,lsures
(the CI'I e\clucl~ngfoocl .mcl eneig]
ancl the medl'in CI'I) hci\ c I l5en .it ,I
slightl) mole rnocle~.lte 2 8%)/o>,~cc

llnless retail prices break sharply
from their recent trend, it's liltely
tilac [lie inclex will e n d the pear at
the lo\\-er end of the Fec1er;il Ope11
M:krliet Com~nittee'sJuly central tendency projection (3%4), but near the
top of the r-ange set for 1997 (2%%
to 3'%).
Economists gener:tlly agree that
the CPI will remain at or very near
3%) tthro~lglithe encl of nest year.
F c n w tllan 40% foresee a CPI gain
of less t112111 2.8% or Illore than 3.2%
in 1997. Last Jailuary, at>out 30%

~>reclictecla clrop below the 2.8%
level. ancl 34% espectecl a rise o f
muse that1 3.2(H).
Economists look at several factors
in ascertaining the econonly's nearterm inflationary course, but chief
among them are the past stance of
monetary policy ancl the degree to
which economic resources are capacity constrainecl. The latest Blue
Chip S L I ~ reveiils
I . ~ ~ a wicle range of
opinions reg:~rcling the future path
f c o t z t i ~ ~ ion
~ e ?zextpc~g~)
~l

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Annual percent change

Chanoe in CPI lorecasts, oercentaae ooints

I

O LONG-RUN INFLATION OUTLOOK

-2.5

-2.0

-15

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

Change in real GOP forecast, percentage points
Annual percent change
2 E.

a. Individual forecasts of the Blue Chip panel of economists. October 10, 1996.
b. Consensus forecast of the Blue Chip panel of economists.
c. Survey of the Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: Blue Chip Economic Indicators, October 10, 1996; and Blue Chip Econometric Detail, September 10, 1996

of inflation :Inel econr~micgro~vth.
About half of those responding to
the October 10 poll see inflation adcelerati~lgin 1997, b ~ l tof those, only
about 40%) expect the economy to
g r o w at a k~sterr:lte. Of the econonlists \v21o 1,elieve hat inflation will
moclerate nest year. most also see the
economy slowing from its 1996 pace
and, I X ~ S L I I ~ ; I ~p I~~~~ t, t i less
~ l g strain
on capacity. Only :I small number of
responclenis :lnticipatc both faster
growth :uncl lo\xrer inflation (6%).
Over the longer term, economists
generally believe that inflation is

preclominantly the outcome of rnonetary policy. The most opti~ilistic
long-term outlook comes from the
Office of Management and Buclget
(OMB). which projects a 2.7% increase over each of the five years
spanning 1998 ancl 2002. Both the
Co~lgressionalB~lcigetOffice (CBO)
:uncl the Blue Chip panel see inflation moderating slightly before
sho\iTing a s~llallrising trencl between 2000 ancl 2002. O\~erall,the
three groups expect that rnonetaly
policy will keep itflation in the 2%?4
to 3% ~utlgethrough 2002.

This is :I slightly less sanguine
long-term outlool< than economists
gave seven months ago. Indeed, in
the past year, surveys of econonlists
have listed inflation as an increasingly serious problem fdcing America. ~vhilethe threat of economic recession is seen as having recetlect.
Still, neither inflation nor a clownturn in the business cycle Llppears
high on the list of important concerns. Topping this year's list-21s in
1995-is the growth in government
spending and entitlements.

I

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

EconomicActiviy
Percent change from preced~ngquarter s a a r

IGDP
AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST

IQ

Percent change from corresponding month of previous yea1
7

110

ilia
1996

Iva

la

I

IIIQ
1997

IIQ

IVQ

Percent of Iota1 consumer spending

a. Chain-weighted data in 1992 dollars, seasonally adjusted annual rate.
b. Seasonally adjusted annual rate.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, October 10, 1996

Accorcling to initial Commerce Department esti~nates,the economy
slowecl to a 2.2%)sate of growth in
the third cluarter, down from 4.7% in
1996:IIQ. Except for husiness fixed
investlllent ancl the pace of inventory
accumulation, most sectors wealcenecl. Consumer spencling \\;as flat!
while residential in\.estment and
fedel21 government spencling cleclined. Net exports continned to kill,
a result of the relati1.e strer~gtho f
the U.S. economy.

Economists generally expected
this slowclown. Although growth of
approximately 2.0% to 2.3% is
l,elo\ij historical norms, it cloes not
seem unusual given that the economy is operating at high levels of resource ~ltilizationand that procluctivity growth has declined over the
past decade or so. Through 1997,
forecasters expect output to remain
in the '1.8% to 2.3% range.
Judging the economy's performance on a year-over-year rather than

a quarter-to-cluarter basis probahly
gives a cleaser picture of how various sectors are faring. From this perspective, the growth of consumer
spending has ~natchedthe overall
pace of the economy during the past
four quarters. Consu~llershave tilted
their purchases toward clurable
goocls since 1991, with about 13% of
now going
their total expenclit~~res
for these items. Because durables
(coirtin~led012 nextpclge)

0

O

O

Q

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Q

EconomicActivig (cont.)
Billions of current dollars, ~.a.a.r.~

Percent change s a a r a
25

20

Billions 3i curreni dolla:~, s a 2.r."

Producers' durable equlpme

15
10
5
0
-5
-1 0
-1 5
-20
-25

IQ IlIQ
1990

lQ lllQ
1991

IQ IIlQ
1992

lQ lllQ
1993

lQ Ill0
1994

Billions of 1992 dollars. s.a a.ra

l a lllQ
1995

lQ IIlQ
1996
Ratio

Percent chanoe from corres~ondinomonth of orevious vear

a. Seasonally adjusted annual rate.
b. Chain-weighted data in 1992 dollars, seasonally adjusted.
c. Excludes inventory valuation adjustment.
d. Includes inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustment.
e. Seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Economic Analysis.

typically provicie ho~~seholcls
with a
stream of ser-vices over many years,
their purchase is some\vl;hat analogous to savings. With r e d clisposable personal income growing :it a
3% clip ancl with consumer conficlence holciing steacly. the oiitlook
for this sector is hi\.ol.able. Consumers may I1al.e pared their- spencling over the summer rnonths to improve their 1,alance sheets.
Business fisecl investriient remains strong, particul:lrly in comput-

ers ancl transportation equip~nent,
and healthy corporate profits ancl
cash flow should continue to bolster
this area. Resiclential investment also
remains solicl, notwithstanding the
third-cluarter downturn.
Despite an accelerateel accumulation of nonfarm business inventories
in 1996:IIIQ, stockpiling does not
see111 excessive. The ratio of total inventories to shipments has remainecl
fairly flat over the past two years.

The incl~~strial
production inclex,
which tr-acks output alllong the nation's manufacturers, utilities, and
mines, has risen at a 5.7% annualized rate since January, with especially large gains in business equipnlent production. Although new
orclers for manufacturing declined in
August. they increased a healthy
4.5% over last year. Advance estim:ltes indicate that clurable goods
orders grew 5.9Oh on a year-overyear basis in September.

f

Federal Deficits and the Economy
Percent o i GDP

Percent 01 GDP

1

15 FEDERAL GOVERNMENT DEFICIT AND DEBTa

Percent 01 GDP

Percent or GDP

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Percent

GO

Index, 1980 = 100

a. U.S. federal government debt is debt held by the public less that portion held by the Federal R e s e ~ System.
e
Deficit is the year-to-year change in the
federal government debt.
b. Calculated using the 10-year Treasury rate and the expected inflation rate from the Survey of Professional Forecasters.
NOTE: 1996 data are the average of the first two quarters.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow o f Funds Accounts of the United States; and the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
Survey of Professional Forecasters.

Accortling to conventional \\.istiom.
U.S. government I~utlget deficits
compete against private investtilent
for a fised supply of' loana1,le fi~ncls.
The resulting increase in real interest r:ltes ;ittracts foreign lentlers.
who I,icl up the clollar's eschange
value in their zeal to acc1i1ir.ehigheryielcling U.S. securities. A clollar appreciation resi~ltsin n current account cleficit, n-hich is a necessary
counterpart to an inflow of' foreign
savings (see page 19).

'I'he p ~ ~ b l ewith
m this accepteel
psogression is that except for the fiscal espansion of the early 198Os, the
relevant cl;~tado not seem to m:irch
in step. Statistical analyses of these
connections also fail to offer 1111et~itivocalsupport.
An alternative way of examining
f'sc:il policies focuses on how particillas tax ancl spending progl-arns infli~ence savings, production, ancl
worli effort, ratlies than on the
clef'icit per se. To illustrate this idea
in t h e estreme, we coulcl conceiv-

ably lower the cleficit by raising
tases 011 c:lr)ital gains, on the
wealthiest inclividuals, ancl on payrolls, while simultaneously cutting
e s p ~ ~ d i t u r for
e s roacls :ind po1-t~.Although such policies might lower
the buclget cleficit, they alrllost cert;iinly xvoilld raise real interest rates
I,y cliscouraging saving ancl han?pering procluction. In this view, deficits
1,ecorne lilie shaclo\vs cast h y Inore
deep-seated and consequential fiscal
clistortions.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Exchange Rates and Inflation

Percent change from corresponding quarter of previous year

Percent change irom correspond~ngquarter of prevlous year

l 2 [TRADE-WEIGHTED DOLLAR AND IMPORT PRICES

IQ IIIQ IQ Ilia IQ IIIQ IQ IIIQ IQ IIIQ IQ IIIQ IQ Ilia
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
Percent chanae from correspond~nqquarter oi previous year

I

l2

ITRADE-WEIGHTED
DOLLAR AND EXPORT PRICES

IQ IIIQ

IQ iila la IIIQ IQ IIIQ IQ IIIQ

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

I

IQ Ilia IQ IIIQ

1995

1996

Percent chanae irom corresoond~noauarter of orevious vear

a. Index, 1980=100.
b. Index, 1990=1.0.
c. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland;
and Citibank.

When the clollar clepreciates in the
foreign exchange market. Americans must pay more for foreign
goocls. Although the price effects
of exchange-rate changes can ripple
through stanclarcl price indeses.
under no circ~~mstances
can a clollar
clepreciation cause inflation.
Exchange rates never move on
their o\\.n; sather, they responcl as
other economic events change the
s ~ t p p l yancl clemand for clollars. If
t h e clollar clepreciates because the
F c d e 1 ~ 1 Iieserve increases the
money supply excessively. then the

tnoneta~yexpansion, not the accompanying dollar clepreciation. is the
cause of inflation.
If the clollar depreciates because
foreigners-for whatever reasonb u y fewer American exports, the
price of U.S. inlports will eventually
rise. The increase in import prices,
however, can be sustained only if
some other prices fall, the money
supply increases, or the velocity of
money rises. The first conclition is
not inflationary and will only affect
those aggregate price indexes that
weight import prices more heavily

t1l:in the prices that h l l . The second
conclition is also ~~nliltely.
If anything, the central bank will react
to a n unwantecl clepreciation by
tightening-not easing-monetary
policy. Finally, if higher clomestic
interest rates acconlpany a depreciation, \-elocity night rise. Evidence
o f s ~ ~ an
c heffect is lacking, however.
Inflation is a decline in t h e
purchasing po\ver of money that
manifests itself in higher prices.
I-Iigher prices are not always eviclence o f inflation.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workersa

I AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT GROWH I
t 185
s-producing
-5
Manufacturing
-12
9
Service-producing 190
110
4
36
9
Household employ. 34

160
-10
-22
15
170
70
12
44
31
253

280
34
24
10
246
84
12
1
122
171

-35
-53
-59
8
18
56
4
27
-67
313

210
17
6
10
193
119
26
62
-40
259

Average for period

Civilian unemployment
5.6

5.2

5.1

5.2

5.2

L""

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996
to dale

Ill0 Aug. Sept. Oct.

1996

Percent

Percent

Percent change, year over yeara

9
8
7
6

5
4

3
2

1
1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

a. Seasonally adjusted.
b. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
c. Production and nonsupervisory workers.
d. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

After a slight clecline in Septeml>er.
nonfilsm payrolls rose by 210,000
in Octol>er, contin~~ing
the trencl of
moclerate p i n s that l ~ e g a nin 1995.
T h e eml1loyment-to-po1~~11i1tim
KItio rem:lined essentially ~lnchangecl
from September: ho\vever, it stands
half a percentage point higher than
a yeas ago. Unemployment lielcl
steady at 5.2%. comparecl to 5.5% in
Octol~es1995 ;mcl 5.6% cluring all of
last year. In :iddition, the nleclian cluration of unemployme~~t
fell to 8.3

weelis from 8.9 weeks in September.
The largest employment gains occurred in services, LIP 119,000, and
retail ttxcle, up 62,000. The governIllent sector experienced the only
clecli~le for the month, clropping
40.000 jobs on the heels of Septemlxr's 67,000 loss. Goocls-proclucing
inelustries adclecl 17,000 jobs, a welcome ti~rnarounclafter September's
sharp 53,000 decline.
There is little eviclence of increasing w g e growth, as base wages anct
salaries rose at a n annual rate of

al~out3.1%1in the thircl q u a ~ ~ conlec
parecl to 3.2% anel 3.1% in the first
ancl scconcl cluarters, respectively.
Growth in benefits has continuecl its
gerleral clownwarcl trencl. with the
annual rate of increase falling from
Illore than 7%)per year in 1990 to
ahout 2% today. I'otal compensation
growth retreateel over the first half of
~ tS ~ O W ~ O W sI Ie e ~ n s
the ctecacle, b ~ the
to have n~otleratcclsomewiiat in recent months, avemging sliglitly rnorc
th2u11 2.6% (:inn~ializecl).

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Average Annual Productivity Growth:
Nondurables
(Percent)

Total mfg.
Nondurables
Food
Tobacco
Textiles
Apparel
Paper
Printing/
publishing
Chemicals
Petroleum
Rubber/
misc. plastics
Leather

19491994

19491973

19741994

2.53
2.46
2.59
2.32
3.96
2.42
2.55

2.59
2.83
2.75
2.98
4.36
2.08
2.95

2.45
2.01
2.39
2.09
3.96
2.83
2.08

1.30
3.01
3.30

2.05
4.41
4.36

0.41
1.33
2.02

2.21
1.77

2.61
I .74

1.73
1.80

Average Annual Productivity Growth: Durables
(Percent)

Total mfg.
Durables
Lumber
Furniturelfixtures
Stone/clay/glass
Primary metals
Fabricated metals
Industrial
machinery
Electricalequip.
Transportation
equip.
Instruments
Misc. mfg.

19491994

19491973

19741994

2.53
2.69
2.54
1.89
1.96
1.92
1.63

2.59
2.66
3.38
1.97
2.54
2.19
1.93

2.45
2.73
1.54
1.79
1.27
1.59
1.26

3.20
3.77

2.22
2.89

4.37
4.83

2.22
3.76
2.43

2.80
3.52
3.43

1.53
4.05
1.22

a. Seasonally adjusted. Productivity is defined as output per labor hour.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

NIuch Iias Ixen rnade of the C.S.
proclucti\-ity slo\vdon.n, which began in the early 1970s. Procluctivity,
or o~ttputper labor hour; grew at an
average annual rate of about 2.3%)
fronl 195') to 1973. I,ut only around
0.8% from 1974 to 1993. The causes
of this slo\vdown are ~lnclear.Some
economists point to the oil shock of
1973, measurement error, sectoral
reallocation, :uncl technological innovation clue mainly to computers
(since it talies time for workers to
learn new techniclues).
A f ~ ~ r t h ecomplication
r
in pin-

pointing the source of the procluctivity slo\\rdo\\m is the lack of uniformity across sectors. For example,
:tnn~lalprod~~ctivity
g r o ~ in
h manufacturing senlairled steady, averaging
z ~ h o 2.6%
~ ~ t hetween 1949 ancl 1973
ancl 2.5% between 1974 anel 1994.
E\.en within that sector there ~ v a s
substantial variation. Nondur:~bles
manufacturing exhibited a slight decline in productivity across the t11~)
periocls. \vhile clurables showed a
nloclest increase. A further brealidon-n inclicates that large procluctivity gains occurred in industrial machinery, \vhich includes computer

equipment, ancl electrical equipment. 13y contrast, gro\\.th in printing
and p~~blishing,
chemicals, petsoleurn, anci lumt~erincreaseel by less
than half in the latter 1>eriocl cornp:md to the forrner.
Over the entire 44-year span,
there \\..as a s~~lxtantial
labor realloseccation ~vithinthe nx~nufiucti~ring
tor as well as an overall clo\v~lwarcl
trend in employment. A movement
of lal,or to less procluctive sectors
may partially explain the procluctivity slo\vclo\\-n.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

TheAuto Industry

Shaie 01 U S nonfaiiii employment

Share ol U S nonfarm employment

50

1982-84 dollars Der week

5

U.S. EMPLOYMENT

-1
30

-

20

-

10

-

-3

Motor veh~clesand equipment

0

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

1

0

a. Numbers indicate final assembly plants in state. Data are unavailablefor Alaska, Arizona, Colorado, Hawaii, Montana, Nevada, South Dakota, and Wyoming.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Ward's Automotive Reports, September 2, 1996.

With :tnothel- r o ~ ~ nol'
c l negotiations
l~enveenthe m:tjor auto~n:tkersanel
the unions wincling donin. a potelltially large shocli to Foilrth Fecle~xl
Reserve Ilistrict employment appears to h:lve l x e n a\;ertecl. &lost
auto procl~lctionin the 17.S. follo\\;s
Interstate 75 s o ~ ~ t lfrom
i
Iletroit
through Ohio. ICentncliy. Tennessee: ancl Georgia. blichigan ancl
O h i o ha\-e the most final assernbly
plants, :l~-idpans proclucers are typically locatecl ne:ut>y.

Like manuk~cturingemployment,
motor vehicle procluction represents
a decreasing share of the U.S. employment base. Despite this trend,
:ts of 19% about 968,000 workers
still liacl jolx in the inclustry, down
only slightly from 1978's peal< of
over I million. With foreign automakers espancling their U.S. procluctiotl :tncl clonlestic companies recovering some of their market share,
employment in the industry has ac-

tually expancleci each year since
1971. Over the 1773-94 ancl1994-75
periocls, 111otor vehicle manufacturers aclded to their payrolls at the
robust rates of 8.7% ancl 6.5%. respectively. Iluring the same time,
manufacturing employment remainecl
ahout even.
Despite the flat~lessin manuhtct~lringemploy~nentancl the clrop in
re:tl earnings in 120th nunufactusing
; ~ n dtotal nonfarm employment over
(cotztit7zle~lotz~ ~ e x t p u g e )

0

0

0

,

@

6

$

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

0

TheAuto industry (cont.)

Percent

Percent
6

5

4

3

2

1

0
1956

1961

1966

1971

1976

1981

1986

1991

1996

a. For some Fourth District counties, transportation equipment employment shares are based on the midpoint of the employment size class. Asterisks indicate
final assembly plant(s) located within county
b. Does not include medium or heavy trucks.
c. 1984-87 data for West V~rginiaare unavailable.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; County Business Patterns; and Ward's Automotive Reports, September 2, 1996.

the past 20 years, real earnings of
worlters in the motor \.chicle and
transpcxtation ecliiipment inclustries
have remainecl lul;~ti.i.ely
high. In fact,
average weelily earnings in motor
vchicles and cqciipment have esceedecl those in t~inspo~tation
equipment as a \z;hole. \.i;hicli inclucles aircraft procluction and shipl~uilding.
I n the Fourtll District, employment in the transportation equip-

111ent inclustry is heaviest along the
western border. Even though final
assembly plants are founcl in only
10 Ohio counties, automotive parts
suppliers are common ancl account
for a large share of the District's auto
industly employment.
Ohio leads the District in transportation equipment employment.
Lilce the U.S., the state has seen ernployment in the industry decline as a
share of total nonfarm employment,

I x i t it has been able to keep en~ploynlent levels stable at around 139,000.
Michigan follows a similar pattern:
Transpostation equipment accoc~ntecl
for nearly 17.5% of total employment
in 1956, but by 1995, that figure liad
plummetecl to 7%. States that have
been able to l ~ u c kthis trend, lilte
ICent~~cky
ancl Tennessee, have benefited from the automotive inticistry's
move southnrarcl.

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

Banking Conditions (cont.)
Percent

Boston

New York

Philadelphia

Cleveland

Richmond

Atlanta
Chicago
Federal Reserve District

St. Louis

Minneapolis Kansas City

Dallas

San Francisco

a. Horizontal lines represent the distribution of loans in each category for the U.S. as a whole
b. Totals may not sum due to rounding.
NOTE: Data are for commercial banks.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Call Reports, June 30, 1996.

Because large h:lnks are able to
make loans to. any customer while
s~llallbanlis x e limitetl to s~llallbusiness financing (l>ecaclseof their size
a n d regul:ttions go\.erning incliviclual
risk exposure), the clrop-off in the
n ~ l m h e r of slnall institutions has
raisecl concerns a l ~ o t the
~ t ax.ailal,ility
of small firm cr-eclit.
Av:lilal~lc cl:~taconfirm that most
of the commercial ancl inclustrial
(C&I) loans maclc by slnall banlts go
to sm;lll fir~ns.However. large banlts
account for a gre:lter share of small
b ~ ~ s i n e financing.
ss
For example, as

of June 1996, about 67% of U.S.
Ixnlis hacl assets helo~v$100 million.
These institutions were respollsible
for allout 25%) of C&I loans below
S1OO.OOO and for about 12% of loans
with original amounts between
S100,000 ancl S250.000. At the same
time. the comparable figures for
l,anl<s \vith assets above $1 billion
(less than 4% of the industry) were
about 41% ancl 56%. respectively.
Sirnilas patterns are present in
nonfr-lrm, nonresidential real estate
lenciing. S~ilallh;unlis hanclleci about
32% of loans below 6100,000 and

13% of loans bet\veen S1OO.OOO :111d
S250,OOO. For large banks. the comparable fig~lreswere 27% and 33%.
To a certain extent. these figures
should allay some of the concern
that banking consolidation will reduce the funcls avail:~hle for s~nall
I~usinessloans.
Finally, note that in the Fourth
Federal Reserve District, the proportion of C&I loans catagorizecl as
srllall is slightly below the U.S. average, but s~llallreal estate loans exceed the national norli1.

0

0

I

0

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

I

International Developments
Billions of U.S dollars

Output and Inflation
(Percent change, s.a.a.ca)
Real GDP: 1996.110

CPI: August 1996

Year
over
year

Change
from
previous
quarter

Year
over
year

Change
from
previous
month

2.7

4.7

2.8

0.2

Germany 1.2

6.1

1.8

-0.1

U.S.

Japan

2.6

-2.9

-0.1

-0.1

Canada

1.2

1.3

2.2

0.1

U.K.

1.7

1.5

3.4

-0.4~

France

0.4

-1.5

1.7

-0.3

Percent

a. Seasonally adjusted annual rate.
b. Change from June to July 1996.
c. Weekly average of daily rates.
d. The foreign G-10 countries comprise Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, and the U.K.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census: U.S.Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; the Federal Reserve Bank of New York; and Citibank.

The econo~nicsof the 1J.S.. Can:lda,
Japan. ancl their m:~jor Eiiropean
tracling partners grebv at a slow to
moclel.ate pace over the past year.
The 1I.S. fr~reclIxst n.itli a n annual
growth r:lte of 2.7?4. while France
saw the slo\vest growth at 0.4%).
Consumer. prices z11so appear to
e lt~oth
y the
be increasing ~ n o c l e ~ ~ tin
Europe:in ancl North Americzln
countries. I~lflation over the past
year langccl from 1.7%)in France to
3.4%)in the 1J.Ii.l'hc bunching of
long-term interest rates froin 6% to
7%) in these nations suggests that
nlarlcet ~ , I tlc1p~lnt4
I
expect long-

term int1;ttion to remain in the 3% to

4% range. Collsutner prices in Japan
were nearly unchangecl, falling a
slight O.l(Yii since last year. Japan's
long-term interest rate is nearly three
percentage points below that of its
tracling partners, suggesting that consclrner price increases will rernain
relatively lo\\; tl~ere.
In August, the U.S. trade cleficit fell
by $0.7 I,illion, to $15.6 billion. This
slight clecline was caused by :I surge
in exports of nearly $1.8billion. Imports continued their steacly march
iip~vv~rcl,
increasing nearly $1 billion.
I)c\p~tetile nioclerate nallon lng In

the tracle deficit over the past month,
the long-term trencl to~v\ircl everlarger clef'icits contin~~es.
On a tradeweighted basis, the clollar appreciated slightly in micl-Octol,er (up
0.3%), remaining little cha~igeclfrom
Janua~y.
Thro~ighthe first two quarters of
1996, the I1.S. current account
deficit was riinning at a $147 billion
an11~1alrate. A country running a
current account deficit essentially
borrows output from the rest of the
world to finance its own consutnption ancl investment. To finance its
(~ol2rlil~le
01d
2 tze.~tpc[ge)

http://clevelandfed.org/research/trends
November 1996
Best available copy

International Developments (cont.)
U S oollars
[u.s. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Bill~onsof
40

B~lltonsof U S dollars
150

I OFFICIAL CAPITAL F L O W S ~

1

Pr~vatecap~talilowsa

Current account

Billions of U S dollars

U.S. Current Account: Saving and Investment
(Percent of GDP)

1993

1994

1995

1996

14.3

15.2

15.6

16.4

Private

14.7

14.5

14.5

15.1

Government

-0.4

0.7

1.1

1.4

Gross saving

Foreign capital
inflowC

1.5

2.1

2.0

2.0

Gross domestic
investment

16.5

17.7

17.4

17.6

Statistical
discrepancy

-0.7

-0.4

0.2

0.8

a. Private capital flows have signs reversed and include the statistical discrepancy as unrecorded capital flows. Positive values represent a capital outflow.
b. Positive vaiues represent a capital inflow.
c. Foreign cap~talinflows are the current account deficit with the sign reversed.
NOTE: All 1996 data are annualized averages of the first two quarters.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

imports, tlle L.S. 111~1st
export finanliving clepends o n whether it borcial assets-claims o n ~ L I nS ; ~ t i o ~ ~ ' srows to finance consumption or inf ~ i t u r e1~roductivity-resulting in a
vestment. The ctralllatic clifferellce
hetween the current account cleficit
n e t inflo~vof foreign capital. Incleecl, a net pri\;:ltc c:lpit:il inflo\v of
and private capital inflows suggests
thxt ~ L I current
S
accoullt cleficit is
$17.8 I,illion h:is accompaniecl this
year's t > ~ ~ i l di11
~ ~the
j ) current acnot supporting higher U.S. private
investment. Insteacl, the rate at
count elelicit. I-Io\ve\.er, the majority
which foreign governments have
of the reclc~isite net capitzll inflow
;~clcledto their holdings of L.S. govhas occurred as foreign goverllernment securities indicates that our
Inents 11ar.c :~clclecl$130 I~illion(211tlacle cleficit is primarily supporting
nualized) to their official holclings.
domestic government spencling.
A co~lntry's al3ility to service
Whether this results in a decline in
these f ~ t u r cclaims without sufferour fi~tureliving star-iclarcl hinges on
ing a clecline in its onin stanclarcl of

whether the increasecl government
borrowing is financing government
consumption or investment, such as
public infr-~~str~lcture.
Despite years of increasecl I3orro\ving fro111al~roatl.total net investIlleIlt income \\?\;aspositive prior to
1994: that is, we e:lmecl more from
our offshore investments than foreigners earnecl from their investments in the L.S. Recently, however,
the long-awaited payhacl< has
started, as total net investment incolile has turnecl slightly negative.

1