View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Economic Trends
May 2007
(Covering April 13, 2007, to May 14, 2007)

In This Issue
Economy in Perspective
The more things change, the more they stay the same
Inflation and Prices
March Price Statistics
Money, Financial Markets, and Monetary Policy
Monetary Policy: No Surprise Here
Monetary Policy in the U.S., the Euro Area, and Japan
An Update from the Yield Curve
International Markets
Do Workers Benefit from Globalization?
Economic Activity and Labor Markets
Employment Flows and Firm Size
Real GDP Growth
Labor Costs
The Employment Situation
Business Investment
Subprime Statistics
Minimum Wage Earners
Household Wealth and Consumption
Construction Activity and Employment
Regional Activity
Fourth District Employment Conditions
Foreclosures in Ohio
Banking and Financial Institutions
FDIC Funds
Business Loan Markets

1

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

2

The Economy in Perspective
The More Things Change, the More They Stay the Same

...
05.14.07
by Mark S. Sniderman

The federal funds rate target has not budged since the Federal Open Market Committee set it at 5¼ percent in June
2006. The Committee’s statement announcing this action noted that economic growth was likely moderating from
its strong pace earlier that year, partly because housing markets were cooling. The statement also pointed out that
measures of core inflation had been elevated for some months and that, although inflation expectations had been
well-contained, high levels of resource utilization and of prices for energy and other commodities could sustain inflation pressures.
At the time, judging that some inflation risks remained, the Committee cautioned that some further policy firming
might be needed, but that the extent and timing of any actions would depend on incoming evidence about the outlook for inflation and economic growth. In financial markets, there were considerable differences of opinion about
whether the next rate movement would be up or down. Now, nearly a year later, the Committee has yet to adjust the
funds rate target one way or the other.
The uncertainty about the policy outlook last June grew primarily from uncertainty about the outlook for inflation and economic growth, the factors that the Committee said would shape their decisions. At the time, analysts’
prevailing opinion was that the housing sector would suffer a mild downturn through the end of the year. However,
their assessment deteriorated as the year progressed, and their growing expectation that policy would ease was reflected in the federal funds futures market. However, by early this year, many analysts thought they saw signs of stabilization, perhaps even of a turnaround, in the housing sector. So, since the rest of the economy seemed to be holding up
well, market expectations of a funds rate reduction began to return—though not all the way—to the view that the
rate would continue unchanged.
The inflation outlook has been equally difficult to discern. On one hand, the Committee’s June 2006 statement
explained that the cumulative effect of previous interest rate increases could be expected to slow, even to reverse,
inflation’s upward momentum. On the other hand, the Committee noted that resource utilization remained high
and that energy and commodity prices might still pose inflation risks.
Although financial market participants generally interpreted the Committee’s statement as an announcement of
a “pause,” it seems fair to say that few analysts expected the pause to last quite this long. Interestingly, the reasons
for the pause have changed over time, as incoming data caused the perception of risk to shuttle between economic
growth and inflation.
The Committee’s “wait and see” posture proved very durable in an environment that produced somewhat weaker
growth—but also more inflation—than anticipated. For their part, most financial market participants now expect
the economic outlook to evolve in such a way that the Committee will gradually lower the federal funds rate target
by 50 to 100 basis points beginning later this year. But analysts’ reactions to incoming data, the Committee’s press
statements, and speeches by Federal Reserve officials suggest that although the FOMC may still be “learning to talk,”
market participants understand fairly well what the Committee intends to accomplish and how it views the complex
workings of the global economy.
I remember a time, not so long ago, when monetary policymakers—and many academics too—thought policy
worked best when it caught markets by surprise. Today, exactly the opposite opinion prevails: Financial markets
3

should be able to predict what policymakers will do, even when circumstances change. At the moment, the Committee and the financial markets seem to understand one another well. That understanding is certain to be tested,
however , either when the Committee plans to move before the markets expect it to or when the markets tell the
Committee to move before it recognizes the need to do so. History provides examples of each.

Inflation and Prices

March Price Statistics
04.30.07
by Michael F. Bryan and Linsey Molloy

March Price Statistics
Percent change, last:
1
mo.a

3
mo.a

6
mo.a

All items

7.5

4.7

2.4

Less food and
energy

0.7

2.3

Medianb

3.3

16% trimmed
meanb

3.2

12
mo.

5
yr.a

2006
avg.

2.8

2.8

2.6

1.9

2.5

2.0

2.6

3.1

3.2

3.5

2.7

3.6

3.3

2.5

2.8

2.3

2.7

Consumer Price Index

Producer Price Index
Finished goods

12.5

6.9

5.2

3.2

3.4

1.7

Less food and
energy

0.0

2.3

2.3

1.7

1.4

2.1

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Sources: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

CPI Component Price-Change
Distributions, March 2007
Weighted frequency
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
<0

0 to 1

1 to 2

2 to 3

3 to 4

4 to 5

Annualized monthly price change distribution
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

>5

Retail price data revealed a relatively more favorable inflation report in March. The Consumer
Price Index (CPI) jumped 7.5 percent (annualized)
in March, reflecting dramatically rising energy
prices, which doubled over the month, but the CPI
excluding food and energy rose a mere 0.7 percent
(annualized).
The distribution of the price changes of individual
CPI components indicated that over half of the
index’s weighted components rose at a more moderate pace between 1 percent and 4 percent in
March, while a bit over one-quarter of the weighted
components rose at rates exceeding 4 percent. This
compares to the average price-change distribution
over the previous 12 months, in which roughly
one-quarter of the index’s weighted components
rose between 1 percent and 4 percent, while nearly
half rose at rates exceeding 4 percent.
On the other hand, alternative measures of core inflation, including the Median CPI and the 16 percent trimmed-mean CPI, were less sanguine, rising
a respective 3.3 and 3.2 percent in March. These
monthly increases were not markedly different from
the measures’ longer-term trends, which are now
between 2¾ and 3½ percent. This month’s modest
rise in the CPI excluding food and energy reflects
a deceleration in the prices of the services that are
included in this measure of core inflation (“core
services”), as well as deflation in the prices of the
goods that are included (“core goods”). The overall
price of core services, which account for over half
of the overall CPI, rose 1.4 percent (annualized) in
March, significantly below the longer-run trend,
which has fluctuated between 3½ and 4 percent
in recent months. This rise was modest despite the
rather persistently brisk monthly increases in rents
4

(including Owner’s Equivalent of Rent), which
constitute over half of core CPI services.

CPI, Core CPI, and
Trimmed-Mean CPI Measures
12-month percent change
4.75
4.50
4.25
4.00
3.75
3.50
3.25
3.00
2.75
2.50
2.25
2.00
1.75
1.50
1.25
1.00
1995

Median CPI a
CPI

16% trimmeda
mean
- CPI
1997

1999

2001

Core CPI
2003

2005

2007

a. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Core CPI Goods and Core CPI Services

Professional forecasters expect inflation, as measured by the CPI excluding food and energy, to
drop from 2.5 percent in 2006 to 2.4 percent in
2007, and to 2.3 percent in 2008. Meanwhile, the
year-ahead inflation expectations of households
continue to rise; households expect a 4.0 percent
rise in retail prices over the next year. Their longerterm inflation expectations, which are correlated
with movements in core inflation, ticked up to
3.6 percent in late April, a bit above the 3¼–3½
percent range in which they’ve fluctuated for nearly
one year.

Housing Prices

12-month percent change
8.00
Core services
7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
3.00
2.00
1.00
0.00
-1.00
-2.00
-3.00
Core goods
-4.00
-5.00
-6.00
1995
1997

1-month annualized percent change
1-month annualized
percent change
core services

1-month
annualized
percent change
core goods

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

a. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

4.0

CPI:
Owner’s equivalent rent
of primary residence
1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

Household Inflation Expectations*
Forecasts
Top 10
average

3.5

CPI: Rent of primary residence

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Core CPI and Forecasts
Annual percent change

7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1995

12-month percent change
6.0
5.5

One year ahead

5.0

3.0

4.5

2.5

Five to 10 years ahead

4.0
2.0
3.5
1.5
Bottom
10
average

1.0
0.5

3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5

0.0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
SOURCES: Blue Chip panel of economists, April 10, 2007.

1.0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
*Mean expected change as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of
Consumers.
SOURCES: University of Michigan.

5

Money, Financial Markets, and Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy: No Surprise Here
05.09.07
by John B. Carlson and Bethany Tinlin

Reserve Market Rates
Percent
8
Effective federal funds rate a

7

As widely anticipated, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) left the target level of the
federal funds rate unchanged at 5.25 percent this
afternoon. It was the seventh consecutive meeting
with no change. The inflation-adjusted fed funds
rate remains near 3 percent, or about 400 b.p.
above its low of June 2004.

6
5
Primary credit rate b

4
3
2
1

Discount rate b
0
2000 2001 2002

Intended federal funds rate b
2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

a. Weekly average of daily figures.
b. Daily observations.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest
Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15.

Real Federal Funds Rate*
Percent
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

*Defined as the effective federal funds rate deflated by the core PCE. Shaded bar
represents a period of recession.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia;
and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

Implied Probabilities of Alternative
Target Federal Funds Rates,
June Meeting Outcome*
Implied probability
1.0
0.9

Bernanke testifies

5.25%

FOMC statement

0.8

The FOMC’s assessment of risk was unchanged. It
kept the statement “the Committee’s predominant
policy concern remains the risk that inflation will
fail to moderate as expected.” This language, which
first surfaced in the March statement, seems to have
been slowly digested in markets over the intermeeting period. The initial market reaction after
the March meeting focused more on the previous
meeting’s changes in rationale, which were made to
give the Committee greater flexibility when writing
its post-meeting statements.

FOMC statement

0.7
0.6

Real GDP

0.5
Employment report
Minutes released
0.3
5.50%
4.50%
0.2
0.4

5.00%

4.75%

0.1
0.0
2/15

Changes in the FOMC’s post-meeting statement
language were minimal, largely reflecting information revealed since the March meeting. For
instance, in its rationale the FOMC acknowledged
the weak first-quarter GDP report, changing the
first sentence of the second paragraph to “Economic growth slowed in the first part of the year
…” from the March language, “Recent indicators
have been mixed ….” The statement maintained its
outlook that “the economy seems likely to expand
at a moderate pace over the coming quarters.”
The reference to inflation was made more concise,
replacing “Recent readings on core inflation have
been somewhat elevated,” with the statement “Core
inflation remains somewhat elevated.”

2/24

3/05

3/14

3/23

4/01

4/10

4/19

4/28

*Probabilities are calculated using trading-day settlement prices of July 2007
federal funds futures and options on that futures contract.
SOURCES: Chicago Board of Trade; and Bloomberg Financial Services.

5/07

At that time, the characterization of recent economic indicators was weaker than markets had
anticipated; hence, it seemed to signal to markets
that policy easing might occur sooner than they
had anticipated. Indeed, the probability of a rate
cut in July increased noticeably after the statement’s
release. This reaction was quickly reversed, however,
6

Implied Probabilities of Alternative
Target Federal Funds Rates,
August Meeting Outcome*

and market participants seemed to gradually put
greater focus on the inflation risk, especially after a
strong employment report. Accordingly, the prospect of a rate hike before summer’s end diminished.

Implied probability
1.0
FOMC statement

0.9

Bernanke
testifies

0.8

5.25%

0.7

Real GDP

0.6
0.4
0.3

Market reaction to today’s statement was limited,
consistent with the minimalist approach to today’s
changes. Prospects for a rate cut remain very unlikely according to implied probabilities of alternative outcomes for the August meeting.

Employment
report

0.5

Minutes
released

4.50%

0.2

5.00%

4.75%

0.1
5.50%
0.0
3/13 3/19

3/25

3/31

4/06

4/12

4/18

4/24

4/30

5/06

*Probabilities are calculated using trading-day settlement prices of July 2007 and
August 2007 federal funds futures and options on those futures.
SOURCES: Chicago Board of Trade; and Bloomberg Financial Services.

Money, Financial Markets, and Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy in the United States, the Euro Area, and Japan
05.01.07
by Guillaume Rocheteau and Bethany Tinlin

Overnight Rates
Percent
7
Intended federal funds rate

6
5

ECB minimum bid rate
4
3
2
1
Japanese overnight call money rate

a

0

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

a. Daily data.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected
Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; the European Central
Bank; and Bloomberg Financial Information services.

Estimated Response to a OnePercentage Point Change in
the Policy Rate, 1996–2006
Euro
area

Japan

U.S.

Core inflation

1.14

0.24

1.93

GDP growth

1.32

0.03

2.07

The conduct of monetary policy typically depends
on specific economic conditions within a country
such as its inflation, its level of production, and its
level of employment. It also depends on the mandate of its central bank and the bank’s objectives in
terms of price stability, employment, and growth
(among other things). For instance, the European
Central Bank pursues price stability as its primary
goal, while the Federal Reserve System seeks maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate
long-term interest rates. The Bank of Japan aims for
price stability and for the stability of the payments
and settlement system. Thus, in principle, different
countries should be expected to run different monetary policies. But when we focus on the United
States, the Euro area, and Japan, we see that while
monetary policies differ across those countries,
some general patterns in their approaches can be
identified.
Policy Instruments: Overnight Rates

To achieve their objectives, central banks set overnight interest rates: the federal funds rate in the
U.S., the minimum bid rate in the Euro area, and
the uncollateralized overnight call rate in Japan.
7

Since 2000, interest rates have followed a somewhat similar pattern in the US and the Euro area:
they declined substantially from 2001 to 2004
and gradually increased after 2004 ( U.S.) or 2005
(Euro area). The amplitude of the changes has been
higher in the U.S. than in Europe. In contrast,
overnight rates in Japan remained close to 0 percent, the minimum that is feasible to achieve, from
2001 to 2006.

Japanese Short-Term Interest and
Overnight Rates
Percent
1.0
0.8
0.6
Japanese short term interest rates

b

0.4
0.2

Short-term Interest Rates1

0.0

Japanese overnight call money rate a

-0.2
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

a. Daily data.
b. Monthly data.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest
Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development; European Central Bank; and Bloomberg
Financial Information Services.

Euro Area Short-Term Interest and
Overnight Rates
Percent
6
Euro area short-term interest rates
5
4
3
2
ECB minimum bid rate
1
0
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected
Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development; European Central Bank; and
Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

2007

By changing overnight rates, a central bank affects
interest rates at different maturities, thereby influencing the real economy and prices. For instance,
three-month interest rates closely follow overnight
rates closely.
Policy Rules

To understand changes in short-term interest rates,
it helps to look at the simple relationship that links
the policy rate to core inflation and output growth.
This relationship, which can be estimated with a
simple regression (known as the Taylor rule), aims
to capture in some crude way how policy reacts to
economic conditions.2 While it includes only a few
variables, it explains the path of short-term interest
rates in the U.S. and the euro area reasonably well.3
Note that from 1996 to 2006, the estimated
response of the monetary policy rate to a change
in GDP growth was larger than that of the euro
area’s. Such a result is consistent with the Federal
Reserve’s dual mandate. Note also that a change
in core inflation has a much larger effect on policy
rates in the euro area and in the U.S. than in Japan.
This response—known as the Taylor principle—is
considered essential for price stability. The idea is
that when inflation increases, the central bank must
raise its interest rate high enough to increase the
real interest rate and reduce inflationary pressures.
If inflation rises one percentage point, for example,
the central bank must raise rates by more than one
percentage point.
Over the last decade or so, the Bank of Japan has
faced a far different situation—deflationary, rather
than inflationary pressure—to which the relationship captured by the Taylor rule did not apply.
Interest rates varied minimally, hovering near their
lower bound of zero.
8

Inflation over the Past 25 Years

U.S. Short-Term Interest and
Overnight Rates
Percent
8
7

U.S. short-term interest rates

6
5
4
3
2
1
Intended federal funds rate
0
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest
Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development; European Central Bank; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

Short-Term Interest Rates and
Regressed Values*
Percent
8
7

U.S.

6
5
4
Euro area
3
2
Japan
1
0
1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

*Regressed values are represented by a thinner line.
SOURCES: The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development; the
Japanese Cabinet Office; Statistical Office of the European Communities; and the
Bureau of Economic Analysis.

As the regressions above illustrate, inflation is a key
explanatory variable of central banks’ behavior. It is
remarkable that the three economies under consideration here have experienced a common disinflationary process over the last 25 years. In the U.S.
and Europe, inflation has decreased from about 15
percent to about 2 percent–3 percent; in Japan it
has decreased from about 8 percent to 0 percent,
and even went negative between 2000 and 2004.
The phenomenon is the same for core inflation,
which excludes food and energy. This convergence
from two-digit inflation rates to very low inflation
rates reflects the common view that inflation, even
at relatively moderate levels, is costly for society.
Inflation since 2000

Over the past seven years, inflation has been stable
in the U.S. and Europe. Currently, the average
inflation rate is slightly higher in the U.S. (about
2.75 percent) than in the euro area (2 percent). The
difference between their core inflation rates (2.19
percent and 1.75 percent, respectively) is smaller.
Core (12-month) inflation in the U.S. decreased
from about 2.7 percent in January 2001 to a low
of 1 percent in November 2003, allowing the Fed
to cut its rate from 6.5 percent to 1 percent. U.S.
core inflation has rebounded since 2004, reaching almost 3 percent in January 2006. The Fed has
responded to this inflationary pressure by raising its
rate to 5.25 percent.
Compared to the U.S., the euro area’s inflation has
been less volatile; the maximum 12-month core
inflation rate in the euro area was 2.3 percent in
March 2002, and the minimum was 1.3 percent in
January 2006. This seems consistent with the fact
that the primary objective of monetary policy in
Europe is price stability, whereas the Fed has multiple objectives.
Japan’s recent inflation experience is entirely different from that of both the U.S. and Europe. Japan’s
core inflation rate has been consistently negative
over the last seven years. However, since January 2001 it has increased from about -1 percent
to nearly 0 percent. One reason for such inflation
rates is low output growth, which the country has
suffered since the beginning of the 1990s.
9

Global Disinflation: Consumer Prices,
All Items
12-month percent change
16
14
Euro area
12
10
8
6
U.S.

4
2
0
Japan

-2
-4
1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

SOURCE: The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

Global Disinflation: Consumer Prices,
Less Food and Energy
12-month percent change
16
14
12
10
Euro area
8

GDP Growth since 2000

As suggested our Taylor rule estimates suggest,
monetary authorities also care about output
growth. Since 2000, the U.S., the euro area, and
Japan have undergone a recession and a recovery.
In the U.S., the four-quarter growth rate of GDP
declined from 4.8 percent in April 2000 to 0.2
percent in October 2001. In the euro area, the corresponding decline was from 4.6 percent in April
2000 to 0.48 percent in April 2003. Although the
recovery was slower in the euro area, both it and the
U.S. posted a growth rate of slightly less than 3 percent in July 2006. As we noted earlier, the Fed and
the European Central Bank responded to the recession by cutting overnight interest rates and to the
recovery by gradually increasing rates. The recession
in Japan was much more severe than in the U.S.
and Europe, with GDP contracting 4.7 percent
from October 2000 to October 2001. Although the
country was facing deflationary pressures, the Bank
of Japan could not lower interest rates below zero
percent. This zero boundary limited the bank’s ability to counteract deflationary pressures or to stimulate growth. As a result, Japan’s policy rate does not
show a strong response to either inflation or growth
in the policy rule.

6
4

U.S.

2
Japan
0
-2
1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

2004

Footnotes

1. According to the OECD’s definition, short-term
rates are three-month rates for three categories of
instruments: interbank loans, Treasury bills, and
certificates of deposit or comparable instruments.
2. On the basis of quarterly observations, we regress
(using ordinary least squares) the three-month
interest rate on 12-month core inflation, the fourquarter GDP growth rate, and the lagged policy
interest rate.

SOURCE: The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

Consumer Prices, All Items
12-month percent change
5
U.S., average = 2.75

4

3. There is voluminous literature on estimating
monetary policy rules. See Charles T. Carlstrom
and Timothy S. Fuerst, “The Taylor Rule: A Guidepost for Monetary Policy,”the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland, Economic Commentary (July 2003).
The original Taylor rule is evaluated using the
output gap, that is, the difference between potential
and actual GDP, but we use GDP growth instead.

3
2
Euro area, average = 2.08

1
0
-1

Japan, average = –0.37
-2
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

SOURCE: The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

10

Consumer Prices,
Less Food and Energy

GDP Growth since 2000

12-month percent change

6

4-quarter percent change

5

U.S.
4
Euro area

4
U.S., average = 2.19
3

2
0

2
1

-2
Euro area, average = 1.75
Japan

0

-4

-1
-6

Japan, average = –0.54

2000

-2
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

SOURCE: The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

SOURCES: The Japanese Cabinet Office; the Statistical Office of the European
Communities; and the U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Money, Financial Markets, and Monetary Policy

An Update from the Yield Curve
04.18.07
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Brent Meyer

Yield Spread and Real GDP Growth*
Percent
12
10

Real GDP growth (year-to-year percent change)

8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
1953

Yield spread:
10-year Treasury note minus 3-month Treasury bill
1963

1973

1983

1993

2003

*Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

As mentioned in recent months, the slope of the
yield curve has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year,
and yield curve inversions have preceded each of
the last six recessions (as defined by the NBER).
Very flat yield curves preceded the previous two,
and there have been two notable false positives: an
inversion in late 1966 and a very flat curve in late
1998. More generally, though, a flat curve indicates weak growth, and conversely, a steep curve
indicates strong growth. One measure of slope, the
spread between 10-year bonds and 3-month T-bills,
bears out this relation, particularly when real GDP
growth is lagged a year to line up growth with the
spread that predicts it.
The yield curve has been giving a rather pessimistic view of economic growth for a while now. The
spread is currently negative: With 10-year rate at
4.74 percent and the 3-month rate at 5.03 percent
(both for the week ending April 13), the spread
stands at a negative 29 basis points, the same as it
11

Yield Spread and
Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
12
10

One-year-lagged real GDP growth (year-to-year percent change)

8
6
4
2
0
-2

Yield spread:
10-year Treasury note minus 3-month Treasury bill

-4
1953

1963

1973

1983

1993

2003

While such an approach predicts when growth is
above or below average, it does not do so well in
predicting the actual number, especially in the case
of recessions. Thus, it is sometimes preferable to
focus on using the yield curve to predict a discrete
event: whether or not the economy is in recession.
Looking at that relationship, the expected chance
of a recession in the next year is 38 percent, down a
bit from last month’s value of 46 percent.

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis;
and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Predicted GDP Growth
and the Yield Spread
Percent
6
Real GDP growth
(year-to-year percent change)

5
4

Predicted
GDP growth

3
2
1
0
Yield spread: 10-year Treasury note
minus the 3-month Treasury bill

-1
-2
12/01

12/02

12/03

12/04

12/05

12/06

12/07

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and authors’ calculations.

Probability of Recession Based on the
Yield Spread*
Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50

was a month ago and, indeed, it has been in the
negative range since August. Projecting forward
using past values of the spread and GDP growth
suggests that real GDP will grow at about a 1.7 percent rate over the next year. This prediction is well
below many other forecasts. On the other hand,
the recent woes in the subprime mortgage industry
are making pessimism a bit more fashionable these
days.

Forecast

Probability
of recession

Of course, it might not be advisable to take this
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution.
For more detail on these and other issues related to
using the yield curve to predict recessions, see the
Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal Recession?”

40
30
20
10
0
1960

1966

1972

1978

1984

1990

1996

2002

2008

*Estimated using probit model. Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and authors’ calculations.

12

International Markets

Do Workers Benefit from Globalization?
05.03.07
by Owen F. Humpage and Michael Shenk

Income Share of Labor
Percent of GDP
70
68
66
Advanced economies
64
62
60
58
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

Income Share of Labor
Percent of GDP
75
73

Europe 2

71
69
Other
Anglo-Saxon 1

67
65
63
61

United States

59

Japan

57

55
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
1. Includes Australia, Canada, and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland,
Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

Income Share of Labor Unskilled Sector
Percent of economywide value added
36
34
32
30
28
26
24
22

Japan
Europe 2

Other Anglo-Saxon1

20
18

United States
16
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Ireland, Italy, Norway, Portugal, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook,April 2007.

Over the past 50 years or so, advances in transportation and communications, together with
a loosening of government barriers to trade and
financial flows, have greatly expanded the possibilities for international commerce. While countries
that embrace globalization can improve their overall standards of living, not all of their citizens may
share in the bounty. Rudimentary economic models suggest that when highly developed countries
open up their economies to developing countries,
whether through trade, the location of production,
or immigration, unskilled workers in the advanced
economies can find themselves worse off, if not
in terms of their absolute purchasing power, then
relative to their more highly skilled colleagues. Even
highly skilled workers, however, can find themselves
with a shrinking share of national income, leaving
business owners with the lion’s share.
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) recently
looked at the evidence bearing on this controversial
subject and concluded that globalization has generally given workers in advanced developed countries
a bigger piece, but a small share, of a growing economic pie. Unskilled workers bear the brunt of the
globalization burden, as theory suggests. Over the
past 25 years, the share of income going to skilled
workers in most advanced economies has increased,
but the share of income going to unskilled workers
has declined.
The real earnings of unskilled workers in most advanced economies have continued to grow; they are
receiving a bigger piece of the economic pie. Their
earnings are not growing as fast as those of their
skilled counterparts, however. In the United States,
the gap between the real earnings of skilled and
unskilled workers has widened by approximately
25 percent, according to IMF estimates. Two factors determine the real earnings of workers: employment and real compensation per worker. The
employment of unskilled workers in the United
States has expanded, but more slowly than the
13

Income Share of Labor Skilled Sector
Percent of economywide value added
45

Other Anglo-Saxon 1

43

Europe 2

United States
41
39

Japan
37
35
33
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Ireland, Italy, Norway, Portugal, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

Index of Unskilled Real Labor
Compensation per Worker
Index, 1980=100
140
Japan

130

Europe 2

120
110

Other Anglo-Saxon1

100
90

United States

80
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Norway, Portugal, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

Index of Unskilled Employment
Index, 1980=100
130
125

United States

120
115
110

Other Anglo-Saxon 1

105
100
Japan

95
90

employment of skilled workers. Real compensation
per unskilled worker in the United States, however,
fell until fairly recently and has since made only
meager gains. The situation is somewhat different
in most other advanced economies, where real compensation per unskilled worker has risen almost as
much as that of their skilled counterparts, but their
employment prospects have been rather dismal.
Globalization is not the only force behind these
labor patterns. Technological change and governmental policies can also have a big impact on
labor’s overall share of income and on the portions
of income going to the skilled and unskilled sectors. Of course, all of these factors are inter-related.
Isolating the individual impact of any particular
one is a tricky task, so one should always interpret
such attempts cautiously.
The IMF staff estimates that while globalization
and technological change both adversely affected
the share of income going to unskilled workers,
technological change had the bigger impact. This
is not all that surprising because business investments associated with advances in information and
communication technology often substitute for
unskilled labor, while enhancing the productivity of their skilled counterparts. Even though the
share of income going to skilled workers rose over
the past 25 years, globalization held it back. This
probably reflects the influence of offshoring. Firms
in advanced economies often outsource the production of intermediate inputs and services that then
fit into a more highly skilled production process.
The manufacture of these offshored intermediate
goods and services frequently involves a higher skill
set than the fabrication of imported final goods.
Consequently, offshoring tends to affect the income
share of workers higher up on the skill spectrum
than do final goods imports. In any event, offshoring remains a small part of the overall production
in advanced economies.

Europe 2

85
80
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Norway, Portugal, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

The IMF study presents a quandary to the antiglobalization crowd. Should society care about the
absolute well-being of workers, which globalization
enhances, or should it worry about their relative
well-being? If it is the latter, do you want to stop
technological changes as well?
14

Index of Skilled to Unskilled Real
Labor Compensation per Worker

Index of Skilled to
Unskilled Employment

Index, 1980=100

Index, 1980=100

130

170
160

125

Europe 2

United States

120

150

115

140
Other Anglo-Saxon1

110
105

Europe 2

100

Other Anglo-Saxon1

130
120

Japan
United States

110

95

Japan

90
85
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Norway, Portugal, and Sweden
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

100
90
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
1. Includes Canada and the United Kingdom.
2. Includes Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy,
Norway, Portugal, and Sweden.
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, April 2007.

Economic Activity and Labor

The Employment Situation
05.07.07
By Peter Rupert and Cara Stepanczuk

Average Monthly Nonfarm
Employment Change
Change, thousands of workers
300
270

Revised
Previous estimate

240
210
180
150
120
90
60
30
0
2004 2005 2006 2007 IIQ

IIIQ IVQ IQ Feb Mar Apr
2006
2007

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Nonfarm payroll employment increased by 88,000
in April, much lower than the first-quarter average
monthly gain of 143,000 jobs and the 2006 average
monthly gain of 189,000 jobs. In addition, February and March payrolls were revised down –26,000.
The report was weaker than the expected 110,000
increase and had the lowest increase since November 2004.
Goods-producing industries continued to soften
after last month’s spike, as April’s loss of 28,000
jobs nearly reversed the 36,000 gain in March. The
manufacturing sector accounted for most of the
decline (–19,000). The construction sector also
hurt the headline number by failing to maintain
its strength from March: The construction sector lost 11,000 jobs in April after having provided
28.2 percent of March’s job growth (+50,000).
Construction payroll growth has been flat since the
beginning of the year.
Service-providing industry job growth (+116,000)
was subpar, as well, compared to the first-quarter
average montly gain (+149,000) and the 2006
average montly gain (+179,000). The payroll
15

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees, NAICS)
2004

2005

2006

Jan-Mar
2007

Payroll employment

Apr
2007

172

212

189

143

88

Goods-producing

28

32

9

–17

–28

Construction

26

35

11

2

–11

Manufacturing

0

–7

–7

–12

–19

Durable goods
Nondurable goods
Service-providing
Retail Trade
activitiesa

8

2

0

–14

–13

–9

–9

–6

2

–6

144

180

179

149

116

16

19

–3

25

–26

8

14

16

3

–11

PBSb

38

57

42

18

24

Temporary help services

11

18

–1

–4

-6

Education and health
services

33

36

41

41

53

Financial

Leisure and Hospitality

25

23

38

24

22

Government

14

14

20

27

25

4.5

4.5

Average for period (percent)
Civilian unemployment rate

5.5

5.1

4.6

a.Financial activities include the finance, insurance, and real estate sector and
the rental and leasing sector.
b. PBS is professional business services (professional, scientific, and technical
services, management of companies and enterprises, administrative and support, and waste management and remediation services.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Percent Change in Average
Nonfarm Hourly Earnings

numbers are still suffering from the lack of strength
in the professional business services sector, which
increased only by 24,000 jobs this month. Retail
trade and financial activities also put a damper on
the report by losing 28,000 and 11,000 jobs, respectively. The financial activities sector experienced
its weakest growth in over two years.
The driver for job growth this month was education
and health services, with an increase of 53,000 jobs
that accounted for almost half of the growth in the
service sector. The government sector helped pick
up some of the slack, adding 25,000 jobs.
Average hourly earnings slowed, and the 0.2 percent increase in the series was the lowest monthly
change since the beginning of the year. Earnings
were up 3.7 percent from 12 months ago, but
down from March’s 4.0 percent rate. Private service-providing industries influenced the easing of
wage pressures more than goods-producing industries this month, but the two have varied widely
since the beginning of 2006. Employees earn an
average $17.25 per hour.
Real average nonfarm earnings—both weekly and
hourly rates—have moderated, as well. However,
the dollars per hour and per week remain high
relative to recent trends. In real terms, nonfarm
employees earn an average $8.32 per hour and
$281.92 per week (1982 dollars).

Monthly percent change
0.6

Real Average Nonfarm Earnings

Private service producing
0.5

Dollars per hour
0.4

8.35

0.3

284
Hourly earnings

0.2
0.1
Goods producing
0.0
1/06

Dollars per week
286

8.40

Total

3/06

5/06

7/06

9/06

11/06

8.30

282

8.25

280

8.20

278

8.15
1/07

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

3/07

276
Weekly earnings

8.10

274

8.05

272

8.00
1/01

10/01 7/02

4/03

1/04

10/04 7/05

4/06

1/07

270

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

16

Economic Activity and Labor

Employment Flows and Firm Size
05.02.07
by Tim Dunne and Brent Meyer

Job Creation and Destruction
by Firm Size, 2006:IIQ
Creation as % of employment

Destruction as % of employment
1000+
500-999
250-499
100-249
50-99
20-49
10-19
5-9

1-4 employees
-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Business Employment Dynamics.

Employment Shares by Firm Size,
2006:IIQ
8%

9%

1–4

34%

5–9
1000+
employees

9%
10–19
20–49

6%

500–
999 250–
499
7%

8%

11%

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Business Employment Dynamics.

Job Creation and Destruction by
Firm Size, 2006:IIQ
Job creation, thousands*

Job destruction, thousands*

While all of this labor market churning is driven by
differences between companies and the unique set
of circumstances that each faces, generally speaking,
job creation and job destruction rates decline sharply as firm size increases. For instance, job creation
and destruction rates for firms with more than a
thousand employees were 2.5 percent and 2.3 percent in the second quarter of 2006. Corresponding
rates for the smallest firms—those with one to four
employees—were 16.4 percent and 16.3 percent.
Does this mean that large firms are unimportant in
accounting for overall job flows? No, it doesn’t.
Large firms may create and destroy jobs at low
rates, but they employ a large percentage of all
private sector workers (34 percent), which makes
them an important source of aggregate employment
flows. Firms with more one to four workers, in contrast, employ 8 percent of all private sector workers.

9%

50–99
100–
249

In the second quarter of 2006, private business employment grew by 466 thousand jobs. Underlying
this net gain of 466 thousand jobs was the creation
of 7.76 million jobs and the concurrent destruction of 7.30 million jobs. The amount of gross job
creation and destruction always greatly exceeds the
net flows, as some firms expand their employment
levels while other firms are contracting theirs.

1000+ employees
500-999
250-499
100-249

One significant difference between large and small
firms is in the way jobs are created and destroyed.
For the smallest firms, over half of job creation and
job destruction comes through firm openings and
closings, whereas in larger firms almost all job creation and job destruction occurs through changes
in firm size.

50-99
20-49
10-19
5-9
1-4
-1200

-800

-400

0

400

800

1200

*Seasonally adjusted.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Business Employment Dynamics.

17

Openings and Closings as a Share
of Job Changes, 2006:IIQ
Percent of job creation or destruction
70
Openings’ share of creation
Closings’ share of destruction

60
50
40
30
20
10
0

1–4

5–9

10–19

20–49

50–99 100–249 250–499 500–999 1000+

Size of firm (number of employees)
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Business Employment Dynamics.

Economic Activity and Labor

Real GDP Growth
05.01.07
by David E. Altig and Brent Meyer

Real GDP and Components, 2007:QI
(advance estimate)
Annualized percent change
Change,
billions of
2000 $
Real GDP
Personal consumption

36.1

Over same
period 1
year ago

Current
quarter
1.3

2.1

77.7

3.8

3.4

Durables

21.6

7.3

4.5

Nondurables

17.2

2.9

2.9

Services

41.6

3.7

3.4

6.5

2.0

3.2

Equipment

4.9

1.9

0.8

Structures

1.5

2.1

9.4

Residential investment

-24.6

-17.0

-16.7

Government spending

4.7

0.9

1.7

Business fixed investment

National defense

-8.5

-6.6

0.4

Net exports

-15.2

—

—

Exports

-4.2

-1.2

5.5

Imports

10.9

2.3

1.6

-7.6

—

—

Change in business
inventories

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Real GDP grew 1.3 percent (annualized) in the first
quarter of 2007, according to the advance release
by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. This was a
substantial decline from last quarter’s 2.5 percent
(annualized) growth, and the slowest pace of expansion in the U.S. economy since the first quarter of
2003.
International trade was a big part of the story, as
exports fell considerably, from 10.6 percent (annualized) growth in the fourth quarter of 2006 to
–1.2 percent (annualized) in the first three months
of this year. (That decline represents the weakest quarterly growth rate since the second quarter
of 2003). Import growth compounded the issue,
increasing at an annual rate of 2.3 percent after
posting a decrease of 2.6 percent last quarter.
Real personal consumption expenditures (PCE)
growth decelerated slightly from 4.2 percent (annualized) last quarter to 3.8 percent, as growth
in nondurables fell 3 percentage points (from 5.9
percent to 2.9 percent). In contrast, PCE durables
increased from 4.4 percent (annualized) last quarter
to 7.3 percent.
While up slightly from last month, residential
investment continues to contract. In contrast, business fixed investment posted growth 15 out of the
18

last 16 months. That includes the first quarter of
this year, though the pace of nonresidential investment was sluggish.

Contribution to Percent Change in
Real GDP
Percentage points
4
3

Last four quarters
2006:IVQ
2007:IQ

Personal
consumption

2
Exports
1
0
-1

Government
spending

Residential
investment
Business
fixed
investment

Imports
Change in
inventories

-2

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

While a deceleration in GDP growth was expected,
consensus expectations from Moody’s.com were for
GDP to grow at an annual rate of 1.9 percent. The
Blue Chip panel of economists also overshot the
advance estimate, forecasting first-quarter real GDP
growth at 2.1 percent in their April 10 report.
Looking forward, the Blue Chip panel remains
optimistic: The consensus view as of April 10 had
GDP growth returning to 3 percent by the end of
the year.

Fixed Investment
Percent of GDP

Real GDP Growth

14

Annualized quarterly percent change
Forecast

12

6

Business
5

10

Current estimate
Advance estimate
Blue Chip forecast

4
8

3
Residential

6

2
1

4
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007

0
IQ

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

IIQ IIIQ IVQ IQ
2005

IIQ IIIQ IVQ IQ
2006

IIQ IIIQ IVQ IQ
2007
2008

Source: Blue Chip Economic Indicators, April 2007; U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Economic Activity and Labor

Labor Costs
05.01.07
by Murat Tasci and Cara Stepanczuk

Employment Cost and Inflation
Four-quarter percent change
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
3/00

Employment Cost Index, private

Average hourly
earnings of
production workers
3/01

3/02

3/03

Core CPI
3/04

3/05

3/06

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

3/07

Compensation costs, as measured by the Employment Cost Index (ECI), had been rising at a slower
pace since early 2005, but since the first quarter
of 2006, this slowdown reversed itself; during the
entire course of 2006, the pace of ECI growth sped
up. Data on production workers’ hourly earnings
suggest that the ECI’s wages and salaries component is responsible for the acceleration: this component has been increasing relatively faster since
the first quarter of 2006. Economists usually worry
that higher growth rates in the cost of employment
might increase inflationary pressures. Indeed, a
19

faster pace of core CPI growth has accompanied
the higher growth rates of both the ECI and hourly
earnings.

Productivity and Unit Costs
Four-quarter percent change
7.0
6.0
Output per hour,
nonfarm

5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
-1.0
Unit labor cost,
nonfarm

-2.0
-3.0
3/00

3/01

3/02

3/03

3/04

3/05

3/06

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Distribution of Total Compensation,
2006
Legally required benefits
5.9%
Retirement and savings benefits
7.0%
Insurance benefits
11.0%
Supplemental pay
0.9%
Paid leave 7.8%

Wages and salaries
67.5%
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Components of Employment
Compensation and Inflation

Of course, workers might be compensated more
just because they are producing more, but this
does not appear to have been the case over the past
couple years. While unit labor costs (a productivity-adjusted measure of employment costs), have
gained some momentum since the second half of
2004, the changes have been negatively correlated
with changes in output per hour in the nonfarm
business sector. This has been especially true since
2000. Hence, relatively higher growth in unit labor
costs has coincided with relatively smaller gains in
output per hour in the nonfarm business sector.
In 2006, almost 68 percent of the total compensation costs for service-providing workers consisted
of wages and salaries. (This was very similar in the
goods-producing sector.) The next-largest components were insurance benefits (11 percent), paid
leave (7.8 percent), and retirement and savings
benefits (7 percent). Growth in benefits was usually so high that it led to a greater increase in total
compensation even when wages and salaries did not
grow at a faster pace. This was the story between
the fourth quarter of 2002 and the first quarter of
2006. But even though benefits have historically
increased at a rate higher than wages and salaries,
since the first quarter of 2006, all components of
compensation have grown at a similar pace.

Four-quarter percent change
8.0
7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
Core CPI
2.0
1.5
1.0
3/00
3/01

Benefits

Total
compensation

Salary and wages
3/02

3/03

3/04

3/05

3/06

3/07

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

20

Regional Activity

Foreclosures in Ohio
05.11.07
by Yoonsoo Lee and Brian Rudick
The fourth quarter of 2006 saw a record number of
new foreclosures in the United States, according to
the latest National Delinquency Survey from the
Mortgage Bankers Association. Nationally, 0.57
percent of all outstanding loans were foreclosed in
the last three months of the year, up from 0.42 percent a year ago and resulting in 1.19 percent of all
mortgages in the U.S. currently in foreclosure. The
increase was driven by all major loan types, although
subprime (high-risk) and FHA loans stood out.

All Loans in Foreclosure, 2006:QIV

Note: Data not seasonally adjusted.
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

All Loans in Foreclosure
Percent
4
OH
3

2

1

KY
PA
U.S.
WV

0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Note: Data not seasonally adjusted. Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

All Loans Past Due, 2006:QIV

Note: Data not seasonally adjusted.
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Ohio, with 3.38 percent of all loans in foreclosure,
has the highest percentage of foreclosures of any
state in the nation. In addition, Ohio’s percentage
of loans in foreclosure is almost three times as high
as the national average (1.19 percent) and is well
above that of any other state in the Fourth Federal
Reserve District. Of all the 50 states, only Ohio,
Michigan, Mississippi, and Indiana have more than
2 percent of loans in foreclosure.
Ohio hasn’t always led the pack in foreclosures. In
fact, Ohio had a smaller percentage of them than
the nation as recently as 1998. But foreclosures
across the U.S., including Fourth District states
other than Ohio, have been falling since the last recession, while Ohio’s have stayed substantially higher.
Delinquencies, or loans past due, are related to
foreclosures, but not perfectly correlated. This is
because not all delinquencies turn into foreclosures,
and those that do take time to make the transition.
With 7.25 percent of all loans past due, Ohio had
the ninth highest percentage of delinquencies of all
U.S. states in the fourth quarter of 2006. This was
up from 6.67 percent a year ago.
In the mid-1990s, Ohio had a smaller percentage of
loans past due than the U.S. and most Fourth District
states. Currently, however, Ohio has a higher percentage of delinquent loans than any other District state.
Note that West Virginia had a higher percentage of
delinquencies than Ohio over the past few years, but
this did not result in a higher percentage of foreclosures.
21

Ohio Delinquencies and Foreclosures Higher in all Loan
Categories

All Loans Past Due
Percent
8

OH
WV
6
PA
KY
U.S.
4

2
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

Note: Data not seasonally adjusted. Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Share of Total Loans, 2006
Prime
71%

Prime
76%

FHA
11%

FHA
7%

VA
3%

VA
3%
Subprime
16%

Subprime
14%
United States

Ohio

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Home Price Appreciation
Index, 2000:QI = 100
200

175

As foreclosures have increased over the past year, a
lot of attention has focused on the subprime market. Subprime mortgages are more prone to delinquent payments and foreclosure due to their risky
nature. In addition, if interest rates increase, subprime loans are more likely to be severely affected,
because a higher percentage of subprime loans have
adjustable rates. Ohio’s share of subprime loans
(16 percent) was the fifth highest of all the states in
2006, behind states such as Nevada, Arizona, and
Florida. Despite this small share, subprime loans
accounted for about half of all foreclosures in Ohio,
and the U.S. in 2006. If measured in dollar value,
however, the percentage would be smaller.
That said, Ohio’s foreclosure and delinquency problems may not just be due to the subprime market.
Indeed, Ohio has higher delinquencies and foreclosures in every loan category (prime, subprime,
adjustable, fixed) compared to the U.S as a whole.
Economic fundamentals, such as housing trends
and labor market conditions, also play a large part
in the number of loans that go into foreclosure and
delinquency. When home values fall, borrowers
who need to sell or refinance to avoid foreclosure
have a harder time doing so because their property
is not worth what is owed. If people lose their jobs
and are out of work, they may have a hard time
keeping up with their mortgage payments. In Ohio,
home prices haven’t appreciated as fast as they have
nationally, and in many metro areas lately, values
have even declined. Ohio’s unemployment rate has
been higher than the nation’s since 2003 as well.

U.S.
150
OH
125

100
2000

Delinquencies and Foreclosures,
2006:QIV
Loans past due (%)

2002

2004

Source: Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight.

2006

Ohio

U.S.

All loans in
foreclosure (%)
Ohio

U.S.

Prime ARM

5.0

3.7

2.9

0.9

Prime FRM

3.7

2.5

1.3

0.4

Subprime ARM

18.9

15.5

14.1

5.6

Subprime FRM

13.1

10.8

9.0

3.2

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

22

Regional Activity

Fourth District Employment Conditions
04.10.07
by Christian Miller and Paul Bauer

Unemployment Rates*
Percent
8

7

6

United States

5
Fourth District a
4

3
1990

1992

1994 1996

1998

2000 2002

2004

2006

*Shaded bars represent recessions.
a. Seasonally adjusted using the Census Bureau’s X-11procedure.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Unemployment Rates, February 2007*
U.S. unemployment rate = 4.5%

3.4% - 4.4%
4.5% - 5.4%
5.5% - 6.4%
6.5% - 7.4%
7.5% - 8.4%
8.5% - 12.7%
*Data are seasonally adjusted using the Census Bureau’s
X-11 procedure.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The Fourth District unemployment rate stayed at
5.4 percent in January 2007, the same as in the previous month. Though the rate did not change, the
number of unemployed workers crept up slightly
(0.57 percent). Because the unemployment rate is
the ratio of unemployed workers divided by workers in the labor force, one would expect this outcome if the number of those in the labor force had
risen as well. However, the labor force participation
rate actually fell slightly (-0.12 percent) in January. What explains this month’s odd outcome is a
byproduct of rounding: the changes in the numbers
of those in the labor force and those working were
relatively small, and after rounding the resulting
rate was the same in December and January. Nationally, the unemployment rate rose to 4.6 percent
in January, up a bit from 4.4 percent in the previous month.
Most counties in the Fourth District reported unemployment rates above the national average (145
out of 169). Unemployment rates rose in 83 counties since December 2006 but fell in 76 counties
and remained the same in 10 counties. In comparison with a year ago at this time, 85 counties now
have higher rates of unemployment, 65 have lower
rates, and 19 have approximately unchanged rates.
Holmes County, Ohio, had the lowest unemployment rate at 3.7 percent; on the opposite end of the
field, Jackson County, Kentucky, had the highest
rate with 12.7 percent unemployment.
Over the past year, payroll employment levels fell in
Cleveland, Dayton, and Toledo, but in Pittsburgh
and Lexington, they posted gains of 1 percent or
more. Goods-producing industries continued to
slow employment growth in the Ohio MSAs. In
service-providing industries, on the other hand,
employment was either flat or positive. Education
and health services registered positive employment
growth across the board, while the other service
industries had more mixed growth across MSAs.
Information and leisure and hospitality grew more
23

than 6 percent in Lexington. The greatest growth in
the number of jobs created occurred in Pittsburgh
in the education and health services industry, which
added 6,100 jobs over the past year.

Payroll Employment by Metropolitan Statistical Area
12-month percent change, January 2007
Cleveland
Total nonfarm
Goods-producing

Columbus

Cincinnati

Dayton

Toledo

Pittsburgh

-0.2

0.7

0.1

-0.7

-0.3

1.0

Lexington
2.2

U.S.
1.7

-1.7

-1.4

-1.3

-4.5

-1.6

1.1

0.0

0.3

Manufacturing

-2.6

-1.5

-1.6

-5.3

-1.4

0.1

-0.3

-0.6

Natural resources, mining, and construction

1.6

-1.1

-0.6

-1.4

-2.1

5.6

0.8

2.1

Service-providing

0.1

1.0

0.4

0.1

0.0

1.0

2.7

1.9

-0.4

0.6

-0.3

-2.4

-0.6

-0.6

-2.6

0.8

Information

-2.6

-3.7

-2.5

-0.9

0.0

0.0

6.5

0.7

Financial activities

-0.1

-0.1

0.0

1.5

-3.1

-0.9

3.7

2.1

Professional and business services

0.3

2.5

0.7

0.6

-1.5

2.1

5.4

3.0

Education and health services

2.3

1.4

2.6

-0.2

0.8

2.8

1.3

2.7

Leisure and hospitality

0.7

2.3

-0.4

3.9

2.0

1.5

7.6

3.6

Other services

0.2

-0.3

0.0

0.6

0.7

0.2

-3.0

0.4

Government

-1.7

0.4

0.1

0.3

0.6

0.6

5.3

1.3

5.5

4.6

5.0

6.1

6.8

4.7

4.2

4.6

Trade, transportation, and utilities

January unemployment rate,
seasonally adjusted (percent)

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

24

Banking and Financial Institutions

FDIC Funds
04.18.07
by O. Emre Ergungor and Cara Stepanczuk

FDIC-Insured Deposits
Billions of dollars

FDIC-insured deposits grew 6.7 percent in 2006.
The fund’s reserve-to-deposit ratio fell to 1.21
percent, partly because insured deposits increased
after the retirement account ceiling was raised from
$100,000 to $250,000 in April. The reserve-todeposit ratio remained in the target range, which
changed to 1.15 percent–1.5 percent that month.

4,400
4,000
3,600
3,200
2,800
2,400

Bank failures since 1995 have been miniscule in
terms of both the number of institutions and their
total assets. No FDIC-insured institution failed in
2006; in fact, the fourth quarter of 2006 was the
tenth consecutive quarter without any failures, the
longest such period in the history of federal deposit
insurance.

2,000
1,600
1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

Fund Reserve Ratio
Percent of insured deposits

By the end of 2006, the number of problem institutions (those with substandard examination ratings) had dropped to 50, the lowest in the 36 years
for which data are available. However, their total
assets increased from $7 billion to $8.3 billion over
the same period. Still, the low number of problem
institutions and the low value of their assets suggest
that the FDIC’s losses will remain low in the near
future.

2.00
1.75

Target

Target range

1.50
1.25
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

Failed Institutions*
Number of institutions

Problem Institutions
Total assets, billions of dollars

Number of institutions

Total assets, billions of dollars

11

5.0

180

45

10

4.5

160

40

9

4.0

140

35

3.5

120

30

100

25

80

20

60

15

40

10
5

8
7

3.0

6
2.5

5

2.0

4
3

1.5

2

1.0

1

0.5

20

0.0

0

0
1995

1998

2001

2004

*A bank with $16 million in total assets and $12 million in deposits failed in
February 2007.
Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

0
1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

25

Banking and Financial Institutions

Business Loan Markets
04.18.07
by O. Emre Ergungor and Cara Stepanczuk

Domestic Banks Reporting
Stronger Demand
Net percent
45
30

Small firms

15
0
-15
Medium and large firms

-30
-45
-60
-75
1/00

10/00

7/01

4/02

1/03

10/03

7/04

4/05

1/06

10/06

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Senior Loan
Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices, December 2006.

Domestic Banks Reporting
Tighter Credit Standards
Net percent
60
Medium and large firms
50
40
30
20
Small firms
10
0
-10

The Federal Reserve Board’s January 2007 survey of
senior loan officers (covering the months of November, December, and January), found essentially
no change in credit availability for businesses. After
three years of easing standards, domestic banks reported that their lending standards for commercial
and industrial loans (for borrowers of all sizes) had
changed little over the period surveyed. Banks continued to narrow their lending spreads of loan rates
over the cost of funds, attributing their decisions to
more aggressive competition from other banks and
nonbank lenders, and a more favorable economic
outlook. By contrast, foreign banks increased the
maximum size of credit lines, eased loan covenants,
and narrowed spreads of loan rates over their cost
of funds. They reported that their decisions were
based on increased liquidity of business loans due
to a deeper secondary market and increased tolerance for risk.
Demand for commercial and industrial loans has
continued to weaken over the past three months,
albeit at a slower rate than reported in the October
survey. Those who reported weaker demand said
decreased financing needs for accounts receivable
and competition from other credit sources were
responsible, while those who reported stronger demand cited an increase in mergers and acquisitions.
The effect of companies’ investment in plants and
equipment was mixed, as it was implicated in both
increased and decreased loan demand.

-20
-30
1/00

10/00 07/01 04/02 01/03 10/03

07/04 04/05 01/06 10/06

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Senior Loan
Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices, December 2006.

Banks’ increasing unwillingness to further ease their
lending standards and businesses’ declining appetite for bank loans have yet to be reflected on bank
balance sheets. The $33 billion increase in bank
and thrift holdings of business loans in the fourth
quarter of 2006 marks the eleventh consecutive
quarter of increases in bank and thrift holdings of
commercial and industrial loans. The sharp reversal
in the trend of quarterly declines in commercial
and industrial loan balances on the books of FDIC26

insured institutions prior to the second quarter of
2004 is still going strong.

Quarterly Change in
Commercial and Industrial Loans

The utilization rate of business loan commitments
(drawdowns on prearranged credit lines extended
by banks to commercial and industrial borrowers)
edged down to 36.1 percent of total commitments,
potentially indicating the declining importance
of bank credit to commercial borrowers as a result
of easier access to capital markets. This is another
piece of evidence suggesting that business credit is
readily available.

Billions of dollars
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
09/01

06/02

03/03

12/03

09/04

06/05

03/06

12/06

Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

Utilization Rate of Commercial and
Industrial Loan Commitments
Percent of loan commitments
41
40
39
38
37
36
35
34
09/01

06/02

03/03

12/03

09/04

06/05

03/06

12/06

Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile,
fourth quarter 2006.

27