View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

On the policy trail…The Federal Open Market
Committee has maintained its federal funds rate target at 1% for almost a full year, by most reckonings a
considerable length of time. With inflation close to
1% and inflation expectations also very low, the real
federal funds rate has stayed in the neighborhood
of zero during that period. This situation is unusual
but not unprecedented—the FOMC set the real
funds rate near zero for a period in the aftermath of
the 1990–91 recession.
As of May, nonfarm payroll employment is still
1.6 million below its level at the peak of the last
business cycle in March 2001. The nation’s 5.6%
unemployment rate is above the 2000 peak of
roughly 4.0%. Similarly, many industries’ capacity
utilization rates lie well below their pre-recession
peaks. So, despite recent reports of accelerating
economic activity, it is not surprising that many
analysts think the economy is operating below its
full-employment potential.
Although the theoretical concept of full employment potential and its cousins—potential output,
the nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment
(NAIRU), and the natural rate of interest—variously
describe ideal economic conditions, policymakers
face challenges in determining how to implement
the concepts empirically and use them in real-time
situations. Theoretically, each of these concepts can
be thought of as indicating the output level, the rate
of unemployment, or the interest rate that would
prevail in an economy where supply and demand
are balanced in all markets. Generally, no more
resources could be employed without reducing
overall social welfare.
How can policymakers constructively contribute
to the attainment of ideal conditions? A central bank
could attempt, in effect, to keep its policy rate on a
path consistent with an economy evolving toward
full resource utilization with price stability. Unfortunately, even the wisest and best-intentioned central
banks are not omniscient. While trying to remain on
this so-called neutral policy path, policymakers necessarily must rely on a constellation of judgments
about economic structure and forecasts.
Why are policy rates not always characterized
as neutral? Why are they sometimes described as
“accommodating”? This terminology could mean

that policymakers are simply accommodating an
increased demand for liquidity by lowering the
price of bank reserves as the economy evolves
along its equilibrium path. Alternatively, the term
could connote a desire to foster a greater expansion
in real economic activity than would occur if the
policy rate were set higher, especially if a higher rate
were called for by the neutral policy path.
Policymakers might choose to be accommodating if they were uncertain about particular aspects
of their forecasts or were risk-averse regarding sluggish economic performance. However, if a central
bank underestimated its economy’s inflationary
potential by putting too much faith in its estimates
of economic slack, it could unwittingly “accommodate” an unwelcome acceleration in inflation.
Central bankers have learned that they can promote social welfare not only by achieving their goals,
but also by avoiding policy surprises along the way.
Consequently, central banks try to give the public
information about their goals, economic frameworks, and policy reaction functions (that is, how
they tend to respond to incoming data). People
move in markets as soon as relevant information
becomes available. When people are very well
informed about policymakers’ intentions and methods, they initiate transactions that make sense if the
central bank subsequently acts in ways that are
consistent. By the time the central bank actually
takes the conforming action, it will have been anticipated and “priced into” the financial markets.
A central bank can prevent some market turbulence
by providing information about what it does and
does not know.
Fortunately, just as people tend not to persist in
systematic errors, many central banks also have
proved to be quick learners. For if a central bank
continues too far down a policy trail that would
have undesirable consequences, chances are high
that the markets would provide cautionary signposts along the way. Like policymakers, markets are
not omniscient—they can make incorrect assumptions and judgements, and anticipate economic
conditions that never arise. Consequently, one of
the arts of central banking is knowing when to educate markets, and when to let markets educate you.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

March Price Statistics

3.75

Percent change, last:
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr.

2003
avg.

3.50
CPI

3.25

Consumer prices

3.00

All items

6.0

5.1

1.7

2.6

1.9

Less food
and energy

4.4

2.9

1.6

2.2

1.1

2.50

Medianb

3.3

2.6

2.2

2.9

2.1

2.25

2.75

2.00

Producer prices
Finished goods
Less food and
energy

6.8

5.1

1.4

2.2

4.4

1.75
CPI excluding
food and energy

1.50

2.4

2.1

0.7

0.9

1.1

1.25
1.00
1995

12-month percent change
4.25 CPI AND TRIMMED-MEAN MEASURES

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Annualized percent change
6.0 CORE CPI
5.5

4.00
3.75

Median CPI b

3.50

5.0

Three months

4.5
CPI

3.25

One month

4.0

3.00

3.5

2.75

3.0

2.50

2.5

2.25

2.0

2.00

1.5

1.75

1.0

1.50

0.5
CPI, 16% trimmed mean b

1.25
1.00
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

12 months

0
2003

2004

–0.5
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

March data reflect seemingly broadbased increases in retail prices. The
Consumer Price Index (CPI) rose an
additional 6.0% in March, significantly
exceeding its 12-month growth rate of
1.7%. The core CPI (which excludes
food and energy) surged an annualized 4.4% in March, its largest monthly
increase since November 2001, while
the median CPI was up an annualized
3.3%, its largest monthly increase in
more than a year.

Because monthly retail price measures are extremely volatile, it is often
difficult to extrapolate an accurate
inflation trend from just a few
months’ data. But all of the 12-month
CPI growth rates are trending
upward: the core rate by 1.6%, the
median by 2.2%, and the trimmed
mean by 1.8%. The core CPI also
reveals substantial price acceleration
over the past three months.
One pertinent question is whether
the CPI’s recent rise reflects an

increase in the prices of particular,
perhaps isolated, components or a
broad-based shift in the inflation
trend. CPI variance measures the dispersion of consumer price changes:
The relatively low variance across the
CPI market basket over the past two
months is a sign of the broad-based
nature of recent retail price changes.
Indeed, prices for core services
and core goods have both contributed to acceleration in the core

(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Percent
5.5 CROSS-SECTIONAL VARIANCE OF
MONTHLY CPI PRICE CHANGES
5.0

12-month percent change
6.0 CORE CPI GOODS AND SERVICES

4.5

4.0

4.0

3.0

3.5

2.0

3.0

1.0

2.5

0

2.0

–1.0

1.5

–2.0

1.0

–3.0

0.5

–4.0

5.0

CPI core services a

CPI core services

CPI core goods a

CPI core goods

–5.0

0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2002

2003

2004

12-month percent change
5.0 HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS b

Percent
100 SHARE OF CPI WITH ANNUALIZED MONTHLY
GROWTH RATE EQUAL TO OR GREATER THAN 2%
90

4.5
Five to 10 years ahead

80

4.0

70

3.5

60

3.0

50

2.5

40

2.0

30

1.5

One year ahead

20
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Three-month annualized.
b. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; University of Michigan; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

CPI. The year-over-year deflation in
core goods prices has slowed since
December, perhaps because the
weaker dollar created upward pressure on consumer import prices.
However, core goods prices have
increased over the past three months.
There has also been a recent acceleration of core service prices, which
account for more than half of all
CPI components. In fact, in the past

month, about two-thirds of the total
CPI (four-fifths in February) rose 2%
or more, another sign of how broadbased recent price increases are.
These readings are similar to 2000,
when year-over-year CPI inflation averaged about 3.4%, (the highest rate
since the early 1990s).
Meanwhile, the University of
Michigan’s Survey of Consumers
reveals that inflation expectations for

the next year have substantially
increased to 4.0%. This outlook anticipates the highest inflation rate
since mid-2001. However, long-term
inflation expectations remain steady,
with households anticipating a 31/4%
rise in prices over the next five to 10
years, perhaps an expression of their
confidence in the maintenance of
long-run price stability.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent
8 RESERVE MARKET RATES

Percent
6 REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE c,d

7

5

Effective federal funds rate a

6

4

5
3

Intended federal funds rate b
4

2
3
Primary credit rate b
2

1

Discount rate b
0

1

–1
1988

0
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

Percent
1.750 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

Percent, quarterly
9 FEDERAL FUNDS RATE AND INFLATION TARGETS
8

1.625
April 26, 2004

7
1.500

6
1.375

5

December 10, 2003 f

4

January 29, 2004 f

1.250
February 13, 2004
November 11, 2003

3
1.125

2

March 17, 2004 f

Inflation targets: 4% 3% 2% 1% 0%
1.000

(Federal funds rates implied by the Taylor rule) e

1

Federal funds rate

0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

0.875
Nov.

Jan.
2003

Mar.

May

July
2004

Sept.

Nov.

Jan.
2005

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Weekly average of daily figures.
b. Daily observations.
c. Defined as the effective federal funds rate deflated by the core PCE Chain Price Index.
d. Shaded bars indicate periods of recession.
e. The formula for the implied funds rate is taken from Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Monetary Trends, January 2002, which is adapted from John B. Taylor, “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (1993), pp. 195–214.
f. One day after the FOMC meeting.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Congressional Budget Office; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
“Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

As of this writing, the target federal
funds rate remains at 1%, where it
has been since June 2003. A low rate
in itself does not necessarily signify
easy money or an accommodative
policy stance, but other measures
currently support that interpretation.
The real federal funds rate (calculated as the actual funds rate minus
the inflation rate) has hovered
around zero since late 2001. The fed
funds rate has also stayed well below
a popular benchmark provided by

the Taylor rule, which posits that the
Federal Open Market Committee
chooses the target rate as a balanced
response to weakness and inflation.
The form of this rule depends on the
weights assigned to inflation and output and on the assumed inflation target, but since mid-2002, the rate has
fallen well below what the rule would
have predicted, even assuming the
rather high inflation target of 4%.
Financial markets have certainly
been behaving as if low rates will not

last forever. The implied yield on fed
funds futures now reflects the market’s belief that an upward move is
likely at the June meeting and nearly
certain after that. Information about
longer-term expectations can be inferred from eurodollar futures; these
extend further than fed funds futures
contracts, which currently extend only
until November. Eurodollar futures
suggest that the markets expect further increases in 2005, although comparisons must be made cautiously
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Implied probability b
1.0 ALTERNATIVE TARGET FEDERAL FUNDS RATES FOR JULY
(AS OF APRIL 27)
0.9

Percent
8 IMPLIED YIELDS ON EURODOLLAR FUTURES
7
April 26, 2004

0.8

6
0.7
0.6092

5

0.6

January 29, 2004 a
4

0.5
March 17, 2004 a

0.4

3

0.3228
0.3

2
0.2
1

0.0680

0.1

0

0
2003

2006

2009

No change

2012

25-basis-point rate
increase

50-basis-point rate
increase

Percent, daily
2.0 EFFECTIVE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE MINUS
INTENDED FEDERAL FUNDS RATE

Federal Funds Rate Policies, 1983–2004

1.5

Average

Maximum

Minimum
1.0

Increase
Number of months
Percent change

3.7
1.09

12.1
3.25

0.7
0.125

0.5

0

Decrease
Number of months
Percent change

Stationary
Number of months

8.4
1.66

40.4
6.75

1.4
0.25

–0.5

–1.0

8.4

18.4

0.9
–1.5
–2.0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. One day after the FOMC meeting.
b. Probabilities are calculated by using prices from options on July 2004 federal funds futures that trade on the Chicago Board of Trade.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Chicago Board of Trade;
and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

because eurodollars are not federal
funds.
Even given the caveats, futures markets can be used to back out an
expectation from the market, but this
tells us nothing about the uncertainty
surrounding that expectation. It’s
tempting to infer, when looking at a
12.5 basis point (bp) change in fed
funds futures, that the market sees a
50% chance of a 25 bp move; however,
the market’s expectation often includes the views of participants who
expect larger and smaller changes.

Information about those views can
be derived from another financial
instrument, options on fed funds
futures. These suggest that market
participants see a slight chance of a
50 bp increase by July.
Has the FOMC kept rates low for
longer than usual, irrespective of the
justification? And is there any historical evidence to suggest how extensive the increases will be when they
come? Since 1983, the FOMC has
kept rates constant for a mean
length of 8.4 months; the current

hold pattern has lasted 10 months.
Increases averaged a bit less than four
months, but the average decrease
lasted more than eight months and
some lasted far longer.
The emphasis on the target fed
funds rate makes sense only if the
actual, effective fed funds rate stays
close; that is, if the target is hit. Here
the Fed’s marksmanship looks good:
On a daily basis, the average difference between target and actual is less
than 1 bp, although on rare occasions it is appreciably higher.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Change in three-month Treasury bill, basis points
30
ACTUAL RATE CHANGE VERSUS ONE-DAY CHANGE
IN THREE-MONTH TREASURY BILL a
25

Change in 10-year Treasury note, basis points
30
ACTUAL RATE CHANGE VERSUS ONE-DAY CHANGE
IN 10-YEAR TREASURY NOTE a
25

20

20

15

15

10

10

5

5

0

0

–5

–5

–10

–10

–15

–15

–20

–20

–25

–25

–30

–30

–35

–35

–40

–40
–75

–50

–25

0
25
Target change, basis points

50

75

100

–75

–50

–25

0
25
Target change, basis points

50

75

100

Percent, weekly average
1.5
TREASURY-TO-EURODOLLAR (TED) SPREAD d

Percent, weekly average
6.0
YIELD CURVE b,c
5.5
April 23, 2004

5.0

1.2

4.5
December 12, 2003
4.0
0.9

3.5
March 19, 2004
3.0
0.6

2.5
2.0
0.3

1.5
1.0
0.5
0

5

10
Years to maturity

15

20

0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Observations are included if there was a change in the target rate starting June 6, 1989. The calculated change is the yield on the day of the target rate
change minus the previous day’s yield.
b. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
c. Average for the week ending on the date shown.
d. Yield spread: three-month Eurodollar deposit minus three-month, constant-maturity Treasury bill.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15.

One reason the federal funds rate gets
such intense scrutiny, even though
few people directly borrow and lend
at that rate, is that Federal Reserve policy affects other rates as well. But the
connection is not as tight as is often
supposed. Since 1989, lowering the
fed funds target has usually been accompanied by lower interest rates in
other markets, but not always. Even
the three-month Treasury bill, thought
to be quite sensitive to monetary policy, increased 20% of the time when
the target rate fell 25 basis points (bp).

The 10-year rate shows an even higher
proportion of such opposite moves.
Digging deeper into the data may
reveal more consistent patterns, depending on whether the change was
anticipated or unanticipated, which
part of business cycle the economy is
in, or the slope of the yield curve.
Since March, an already steep
yield curve has gotten even steeper.
The bellwether 10-year, three-month
spread has increased from 281 bp
to 346 bp, well above the historical
average of 120 bp. This rise has been

driven almost exclusively by increases
in long rates because short rates have
been restrained by the steady fed
funds rate. Historically, such a steep
yield curve has foretold robust economic growth for the following year.
Supporting that, the spread between
Treasury bonds and eurodollar deposits (the TED spread), which is
often thought to reflect concern over
international tensions, remains low
by recent historical standards.
Some observers believe inflation
fears caused the increase in long
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent, weekly
3.00 TREASURY-BASED INFLATION INDICATOR

Percent
8 PENNACCHI MODEL b

2.75
2.50

6
30-day Treasury bill

2.25
2.00

4

1.75
1.50

2

1.25

Estimated expected inflation rate
Yield spread: 10-year Treasury minus 10-year TIIS a

1.00

0

0.75

Estimated real interest rate

0.50

–2
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percent, weekly
7 BERK RATE c

Percent
4.0 TERM STRUCTURE OF INFLATION EXPECTATIONS
3.5

6
3.0

2.5

5

2.0
4

1.5

1.0
3
0.5
0
2004

2
2009

2014

2019

2024

2029

2034

1998

1999

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Treasury inflation-indexed securities.
b. The estimated expected inflation rate and the estimated real interest rate are calculated using the Pennacchi model of inflation estimation and the median
forecast for the GDP implicit price deflator from the Survey of Professional Forecasters. Monthly data.
c. The Berk rate is calculated as the 30-year GNMA yield plus the 10-year Treasury inflation-indexed securities yield minus the 10-year Treasury yield.
SOURCES: Chicago Mercantile Exchange; Bloomberg Financial Information Services; and Wall Street Journal.

rates, but more direct measures of
inflationary expectations give a different view. The “break-even” inflation
rate, defined as the difference between
a 10-year nominal Treasury bond and a
10-year TIIS bond (which is protected
against inflation), stands at 2.38%,
almost exactly where it stood in January. But because of tax, liquidity, and
different risk characteristics (particularly regarding inflation) this may overstate expectations by anywhere from
35 bp to 120 bp. Still, the lack of an
upward trend this year is encouraging.

The Pennacchi model, which combines Treasury-bill rates and survey
measures of inflation, has also stayed
relatively flat in 2004.
Inflation expectations can be inferred from the recently introduced
CPI futures contracts. With a shorter
maturity than TIIS, these contracts
help fill out an overview of the “term
structure” of inflation expectations
because people may have different
views of inflation in the short versus
the long term. Because the market is
new, (trading in CPI futures at the

Chicago Mercantile Exchange only
began in February), the inflation
numbers look quite volatile.
Perhaps inflationary expectations
have held steady because monetary
policy has found the right balance between ease and tightness. In fact,
some real rates have been increasing
lately. The Berk rate, which measures
the real rate with an adjustment for a
firm’s ability to delay investment, has
risen almost 70 bp since mid-March.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Japan’s Economy
Index, March 31, 2000 = 100
200

Index, May 16, 1949 = 1
500 ASSET PRICES

Percent change, year-over-year
5 MEASURES OF INFLATION
4

160

400

3
CPI

National land prices

2
120

300

1
0

80

200

–1
GDP private consumption deflator
–2

NIKKEI 225

GDP deflator
40

100

–3
–4

0
1984 1986

0
1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

Percent of GDP
180

Percent of GDP
6 FISCAL BALANCES a

160

4

–5
1984 1986

2004

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

12-month percent change
25

Trillions of yen, fiscal year
25 MEASURES OF BANKING HEALTH
20

20
Loans b,d

Primary budget balance
2

0

140

15

15

120

10

10

100

5

Gross government debt
–2

Losses on disposal of
nonperforming loans c

Net income c

5

–4

80

0

0

–6

60

–5

–5

–8
1987

40
1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

–10
1984

–10
1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Data for 2003–05 are OECD forecasts.
b. Includes overdrafts beginning 1993:IIQ. The exception is Shinkin Bank overdrafts, which are included beginning in 1994:IIQ.
c. All banks holding current accounts.
d. Domestically licensed banks.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Foreign Exchange Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.1; Bank of Japan;
Japanese Ministry of Finance; Japanese Economic and Social Research Institute; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and Bloomberg
Financial Information Services.

When its stock and land price bubbles
burst in the early 1990s, Japan entered
a period of weak economic growth
and disinflation (now deflation) from
which it has not yet recovered. Falling
asset prices have reduced investment’s share of GDP from 19% in the
early 1990s to roughly 16% now and
have discouraged lending by reducing
the value of both banks’ capital and
the collateral required to promote
favorable lending terms.
Government spending stabilized in
the second half of the 1990s, but the
continued revenue declines caused by

economic weakness and deflation
have created a primary budget deficit
of about 5% of GDP. Because of structural reforms designed to enhance
growth prospects, government authorities have deferred moving the
budget to surplus status until the early
2010s. Low inflation has helped keep
long-term interest rates and debt
financing costs low. If interest rates
increase, it may become difficult to
maintain fiscal stability over the
medium term.
Inefficiencies in the banking sector,
such as the evergreening of loans,

have produced a large number of
nonperforming loans. Low (and now
negative) inflation levels have exacerbated the problem by discouraging
spending and increasing the real value
of debt payments. Nonperforming
loans have significantly reduced bank
profitability and discouraged the new
lending needed to spur economic
growth. In October 2002, the government announced its goal of halving
the stock of such loans by March
2005, and it has made some progress
toward this goal.
(continued on next page)

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Japan’s Economy (cont.)
Trillions of yen
40

Year-over-year percent change
40 MONETARY AGGREGATE

Percentage points
8 CONTRIBUTIONS TO YEAR-OVER-YEAR GDP GROWTH a

35

35
Monetary base
30

30

25

25

6

GDP

4
20

20

15

15

10

10

5

5
Current account reserves

0

Government

2

0
Net exports

0
–2
–5

–5

–10

–10
1994 1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001 2002

2003

Trillions of yen, monthly b
6 FOREIGN EXCHANGE RATES AND INTERVENTIONS

–4

2004

1990

Yen/dollars
160

5

150

4

140

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Annual percent change
8 PRODUCTIVITY AND LABOR GROWTH

6

Exchange rate
3

130

Productivity
4

2

120

1

110

0

100

–1

90

–2

2

0

80

Dollar purchases

–2

–3

Hours worked

70
60

–4
1994 1995 1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001 2002 2003

2004

–4
1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Recession bars are dated by the Economic and Social Research Institute.
b. Data through 2003.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Foreign Exchange Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.1; Bank of Japan;
Japanese Ministry of Finance; Japanese Economic and Social Research Institute; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and Bloomberg
Financial Information Services.

To reduce deflationary expectations, the Bank of Japan committed
itself to a program of quantitative
easing in March 2001 by targeting current account balances that banks hold
at the central bank. This has led to
dramatic growth in the monetary
base and has slowed disinflation, perhaps even reversing it. However, the
program has not yet solved either the
deflation problem or the problem of
declining loans.
Economic activity has picked up recently, with real GDP growing 2.7% in
2003, and the International Monetary

Fund has increased its forecast of
2004 real GDP growth from 0.8% last
September to 3.4% this March. Unlike
Japan’s two previous recoveries, this
one has benefited significantly from
net exports’ contribution to real GDP
growth. To promote export growth,
the Ministry of Finance has been selling yen through foreign exchange
interventions. Although the yen has
appreciated against the dollar over
the past two years, it has done so less
than the euro.
Japan’s recent growth is heartening. However, productivity growth has
fallen from the levels reached in the

late 1980s and early 1990s, and hours
worked have generally been declining
over the past 14 years. The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development now forecasts that
hours worked in 2003–08, adjusted
for cyclical factors, will fall 0.3% annually, and that during this period, Japan
will have the lowest potential GDP
growth of any country in the OECD.
This underscores the importance of
success with structural reforms and
antideflation strategies to the nation’s
growth prospects.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Changes in the GDP
Real GDP and Components, 2004:IQ

Percentage points
3.5 CONTRIBUTION TO PERCENT CHANGE IN REAL GDP b

(Advance estimate)

3.0

a

Annualized
Change, percent change, last:
billions
Four
of 2000 $
Quarter
quarters

Real GDP
108.5
Personal consumption 69.4
Durables
–12.7
Nondurables
34.1
Services
44.7
Business fixed
investment
20.4
Equipment
25.8
Structures
–4.0
Residential investment
2.7
Government spending
9.6
National defense
17.0
Net exports
0.6
Exports
8.5
Imports
7.9
Change in business
inventories
6.3

4.2
3.8
–4.7
6.5
4.3

4.9
4.3
9.6
5.1
2.9

7.2
11.4
–6.6
2.1
2.0
15.1
__
3.2
2.0

9.4
12.9
–1.5
8.8
2.7
13.5
__
7.8
6.9

__

__

Personal
consumption

Last four quarters

2.5

2004:IQ

2.0
1.5
1.0

Exports

Residential
investment

0.5
0

Business fixed
investment

–0.5
–1.0

Government
spending

Change in
inventories

Imports

–1.5

Percent change from previous quarter
9 REAL GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST b

Percent change
16 REAL GDP GROWTH d

8

14

Final percent change
Blue Chip forecast c

7

12

Advance estimate

Average

10

6

2001
8

5

6

30-year average
4

1990–2001

4
3

2
2

0

1

–2

0

–4
IVQ
2002

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2003

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

0

1

2

2004

3

4
5
6
8
9 10 11
7
Quarters from previous business cycle peak

12

13

14

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 2000 dollars. Components of real GDP need not add to the total because the total and all components are deflated using
independent chain-weighted price indexes.
b. Data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
c. Blue Chip panel of economists.
d. The shaded band represents the average for the nine previous business cycles, plus or minus two standard errors.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; National Bureau of Economic Research; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators,
April 10, 2004

The advance estimate for real GDP
growth in 2004:IQ was 4.2%, slightly
above the previous quarter’s 4.1%
final estimate but below the Blue
Chip economists’ forecast of 4.3%.
Nonetheless, most observers remain
upbeat because the growth was fairly
broad based. Personal consumption
expenditures, the largest contributor
to real GDP growth in 2003:IVQ, rose
3.8%, led by nondurables (up 6.5%)
and services (up 4.3%). Spending on
durables dipped 4.7%, but was still up
9.6% from the previous four quarters.

Business fixed investment, the second
largest contributor to growth, was up
7.2%. Investment in equipment rose
11.4%, but investment in structures fell
6.6%. Residential investment also
slowed, up only 2.1%, far less than the
8.8% of the previous four quarters.
Net exports improved for the third
straight quarter; although exports
grew only 3.2%, imports slowed even
more, increasing just 2.0%. Government spending growth slowed to 2.0%
overall, but growth in national defense
spending continued at a strong clip,

up 15.1%. The 2.5% increase in the implicit GDP deflator and the 2.0% rise in
core CPI caused concern for some.
Looking forward, Blue Chip forecasters expect that real GDP growth
will stay close its the current rate,
well above the 30-year average of
3.1%, through the end of the year. If
that occurs, the current expansion
will continue to be fairly typical of
expansions of similar duration.
The beginning of the economy’s
third year of expansion is a good time
(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Changes in the GDP (cont.)
Percent
30 PERSONAL CONSUMPTION

Percent
30 BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT

25

20
Durables

20

Residential investment
10
Personal consumption

15

0
10
–10
5

Equipment

Business fixed investment

–20
0
Nondurables

Structures

Services
–30

–5
–10

–40
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percent
45 GOVERNMENT SPENDING

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percent
25

Billions of dollars
–300 FOREIGN TRADE
–325

20

35
–350

National defense

15
Imports

25

–375
Nondefense

15

5

–5
Government spending

10

Net exports

–400

5

–425

0

–450

–5

–475

–10

–500

–15

Exports

–15

–20

–525
–25

–25

–550
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis

to ask how the GDP’s components
have been performing. Since
2001:IIIQ, when real GDP began growing again, higher personal consumption expenditures, currently comprising about 71% of GDP, have accounted
for much of its 3.5% average annual
growth. About 57% of personal consumption came from services, its most
stable component, which has grown at
an annual average rate of 2.7%. Nondurable spending, about 29% of consumption and its next most stable
component, grew at a brisker 4.2%

rate over the same period. The smallest component (14%) of consumption was durable goods, which grew
at the highest rate (7.1%), but was by
far the most volatile.
Investment, 16% of GDP, grew at an
annual rate of 4.2% over this period.
Growth in equipment and software
(5.3%) and residential investment
(6.5%) were both fairly strong. Investment in structures suffered most in
the last downturn; even in the current
recovery period, when overall real
GDP was growing, this component
still fell at an annualized rate of 11.1%.

Federal, state, and local government
expenditures account for about 18% of
GDP. Overall government spending
has grown 3.6% since 2001:IIIQ; national defense spending, currently
26% of government spending, grew
10.5%. In contrast, nondefense government spending grew a mere 1.5%.
Over the same period, net exports
seem to have stabilized at around
–$515 billion. Growth rates for exports
and imports have tracked each other
quite closely, but the trade deficit persists because the level of imports is so
much higher than that of exports.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
400 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT CHANGE

Labor Market Conditions

350

Average monthly change
(thousands of employees, NAICS)

300
Preliminary

250

Revised

Payroll employment

200

Goods producing
Construction
Manufacturing
Durable goods
Nondurable goods

150
100

Service providing
Retail trade
Financial activitiesa
PBSb
Temporary help svcs.
Education & health svcs.
Leisure and hospitality

50
0
–1
–50

YTD
217

Apr.
2004
288

–42
7
–48
–30
–18

35
25
7
10
–4

42
18
21
20
1

37
–5
6
23
15
28
8

182
39
5
54
16
26
27

246
23
8
123
35
31
36

2001
–149

2002
–47

2003
–5

–124
–1
–123
–88
–35

–76
–8
–67
–48
–19

–25
–24
8
–63
–37
50
–1

29
–11
6
–17
2
40
–11

–100

Average for period (percent)
Civilian unemployment
rate

–150

4.8

5.8

6.0

5.6

5.6

–200
2000 2001 2002 2003

IIQ

Feb. Mar. Apr.
IIIQ IVQ IQ
2003
2004
2004

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS

Percent
6.5

Employment-to-population ratio

Continuing claims,
four-week moving average

6.0

64.5

Percent
4

Millions of persons
4 UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE

3
64.0

5.5

63.5

5.0

63.0

4.5

3

Insured unemployment rate
2

2

1

1

4.0

62.5
Civilian unemployment rate
62.0
1995

3.5
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

0

0
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
a. Financial activities include the finance, insurance, and real estate sector and the rental and leasing sector.
b. Professional and business services include professional, scientific, and technical services, management of companies and enterprises, administrative and
support, and waste management and remediation services.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration and Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Nonfarm payroll employment registered a net increase of 288,000 jobs in
April. At the same time, net gains for
the previous two months were revised
up a total of 66,000 jobs to 420,000.
After a net increase of almost 250,000
jobs over the last four months of 2003,
nonfarm payroll employment has
added more than 850,000 net jobs
thus far in 2004.
Services accounted for much of
the employment growth in March
and April, gaining about 250,000 net
jobs each month. Professional and
business services accounted for half
of April’s employment increase in

service-providing industries. Temporary help services, often a leading indicator of total employment, posted a
net gain of 35,300 jobs for the month.
The sector has added 260,500 net jobs
over the past 12 months, the largest
such gain in four years. Manufacturing gained 21,000 net jobs in April,
its third straight monthly increase
following 42 consecutive months of
decline. Recent net job gains in the
sector continued to be concentrated
in durable manufacturing.
The civilian unemployment rate fell
0.1 percentage point and has largely
been flat so far in 2004 after dropping

0.6 percentage point in the second
half of 2003. However, the number
unemployed for 15 weeks or more
declined by 350,000, dropping below
3 million for the first time since September 2002. The four-week moving
average of continuing unemployment
claims has fallen steadily since the
beginning of October, declining more
than 600,000 to under 3 million for the
first time since July 2001. The insured
unemployment rate also began trending downward in October, three
months after the civilian unemployment rate began to fall.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Employment Conditions in the OECD
Index, December 2002 = 100
105 EMPLOYMENT INDEX

Percent
14 UNEMPLOYMENT RATES

U.S.
12

100
Euro zone

Germany

10
Canada

France

95
U.K.

8

Australia

Australia
90
U.K.

6

Canada

U.S.
85
4
Japan
2
1994

80
1996

1998

2000

2002

Unemployment rate
50 UNEMPLOYMENT AND LABOR FORCE
PARTICIPATION BY AGE GROUP, 2002

1994

2004

Labor force participation rate
100

80
50

55–64
30

15–24

60

20

40

15–24
25–54
55–64

1998

2000

2002

2004

Percent of total unemployment
70 DURATION OF UNEMPLOYMENT, 2002
60

25–54
40

1996

More than six months
and less than one year
One year or longer

40

30

20

10

20
10

0

0
Australia Canada

France Germany

Italy

Japan

U.K.

U.S.

0
Australia Canada

France Germany

Italy

Japan

U.K.

U.S.

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Australian Bureau of Statistics; Statistics Canada; Deutsche Bundesbank; Eurostat; French
National Institute for Statistics and Economic Studies; Japanese Ministry of Public Management, Home Affairs, Post, and Telecommunications; U.K. Office for
National Statistics; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Labor Force Statistics; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

Unemployment rates fell and employment rose in most nations of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) from 1997
to 2001. For countries like Australia
and the U.K., the drop in unemployment was spectacular and persistent,
thanks to sustained growth and the
structural reforms of the 1980s. Then,
from 2001 to 2003, unemployment
rates steadily rose from 8.0% to 9.1%
in the euro zone and from 4.8% to
6.0% in the U.S. In Japan, unemployment trended up from 2.3% in 1993 to
more than 5.0% in 2002–03; however,

in the second half of 2003, it dropped
back from 5.4% to 5.0% as the country’s growth gathered momentum.
Differences in unemployment
rates among OECD countries are particularly pronounced when they are
broken down by age categories.
Young people (those aged 15 to 24)
have the highest unemployment; in
the U.S., for example, the rate is 12%.
But this age group fares worst in
countries with high overall unemployment: Young people’s jobless
rates run to 20% in France and 26%
in Italy. Moreover, the rate of labor

market participation for this age
group is low—30% in France and
36% in Italy, compared to 69% in the
U.K. and 63% in the U.S.
Long-term unemployment, measured as the share of unemployed
people who have been jobless for at
least a year, differs dramatically between Europe and North America. In
European countries, this proportion is
high (32% in France, 47% in Germany,
and 59% in Italy); in North America,
long-term unemployment shares are
relatively low (8.5% in the U.S. and 9%
in Canada).

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Pennsylvania State Budget
TOTAL STATE REVENUES
Lottery fund
2%
Motor license
fund 4%

GENERAL FUND REVENUES

Corporate net
income tax 7%

Cigarette
tax 4%
All other
funds 10%

Gross receipts
tax 5%

Tobacco
settlement
fund 1%

Other taxes
8%

Capital stock
and franchise
tax 4%

General fund
45%

Personal income
tax 36%

Federal funds
34%
Sales and use tax
34%

Augmentations
and fees 4%

Non-tax
revenues 2%

Total: $50.1 billion

Millions of dollars
1,400 RAINY DAY FUND, YEAR-END BALANCE

GENERAL FUND APPROPRIATIONS
Debt service
3%

1,200
Actual
Projected

Corrections
6%

1,000

All other
15%

Higher
education
8%

800
Pre-K to grade 12
education
34%

Other welfare
16%
Medical
assistance
18%

600

400

200

0
94–95 95–96 96–97 97–98 98–99 99–00 00–01 01–02 02–03 03–04 04–05

Fiscal year

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

NOTE: Budget figures are for Pennsylvania’s fiscal year 2004–05, which begins July 1, 2004.
SOURCE: Commonwealth of Pennsylvania, Office of the Budget.

In February, Pennsylvania governor
Edward G. Rendell presented his
annual budget proposal for fiscal year
2004–05. Only about half of the
state’s revenues are available for
discretionary appropriations; the rest
are subject to spending restrictions.
For example, dollars from the motor
license fund and other special funds
have specific, predetermined uses.
Most federal funds are also restricted,
but some of those earmarked for
social welfare improvement are not
associated with specific programs

and can be allocated by the state
legislature.
The 2004–05 budget focuses
primarily on expenditures from
general fund revenues, which comprise about 45% of the state’s total
revenues. Governor Rendell has
devoted about three-quarters of his
proposed general fund appropriations to education, health, and
human services. General fund dollars
are derived primarily from personal
income taxes and sales taxes, which
account for about 70% of general
fund revenues.

Pennsylvania’s constitution mandates a balanced budget, so the general fund’s revenues must meet or
exceed appropriations. They are projected to exceed appropriations by
approximately $2 million in fiscal year
2004–05. According to current law,
25% of the general fund’s projected
year-end balance must be transferred
to a rainy day fund so that the state will
be able to maintain its service level
despite any revenue shortfalls. Additional revenues for the upcoming fiscal
year are projected to put the rainy day
fund at just under $100 million.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Kentucky State Budget
GENERAL FUND REVENUES

TOTAL STATE REVENUES
Road fund
6%

Lottery
2%

Coal
severance
tax 2%
Property
tax
6%

Restricted
funds
21%
Individual
income tax
41%

General fund
40%
Federal funds
33%

Other taxes
and revenues
7%

Sales and
use taxes
36%

Corporate income tax
and licensing 6%

Total: $38.0 billion

Millions of dollars
300 BUDGET RESERVE TRUST FUND BALANCE

GENERAL FUND APPROPRIATIONS

250
Actual
Projected
Postsecondary
education
16%

Education
43%

200

Medicaid
11%

All other
18%

Corrections
4%

150

100
Health and
family services
(net medicate)
8%

50

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998
2000
Fiscal year

2002

2004

2006

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

NOTE: Biennial budget figures are for Kentucky’s fiscal years 2005 and 2006, which begin July 1, 2004.
SOURCE: State of Kentucky, Office of the Budget.

In January, Kentucky governor Ernie
Fletcher presented his proposed budget for the state’s fiscal years 2005 and
2006, (The biennial budget process
generally occurs in every even-numbered year.) The governor’s budget focuses primarily on expenditures from
the general fund. That fund accounts
for nearly 40% of the state’s total revenues, most of which are collected
from sales taxes and individual income
taxes. The remaining 60% of revenues
are restricted in various ways. For instance, fuel tax receipts are earmarked
primarily for constructing and main-

taining state highways and interstates;
most federal government dollars are
used for social welfare programs.
Governor Fletcher has said that the
proposed budget is aimed at improving the state’s competitiveness by
“resolving budgetary shortfalls without burdening the people and businesses of Kentucky with higher taxes.”
His proposed appropriations allocate about 80% of the general fund
revenues to education, health, and
human services.
For the 2004 fiscal year, which ends
June 30, Kentucky had expected to

have a budgetary shortfall, something
prohibited by the state’s constitution.
But because of a series of spending restraints (some enacted as early as the
end of 2002) and, to a lesser degree,
federal fiscal relief, the state expects to
end the fiscal year in the black. Moreover, it expects to achieve this without
drawing down its budget reserve trust
fund, which fell nearly to zero in 2002
and 2003. Instead, Kentucky is working to build this fund back up and projects a reserve of almost 1% of general
fund revenues in each of the next two
fiscal years.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Institutions
Billions of dollars
26 SOURCES OF INCOME

Billions of dollars
5 NET INCOME a

4

Billions of dollars
6

5

24
Net operating income
Total noninterest income

3
22

4
Total interest income

2
20

3

18

2

1
Securities and other gains/losses
0

16

–1
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Percent
14 NET INTEREST MARGIN AND ASSET GROWTH

1
1998

2003

Percent
3.5

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Percent
1.5 EARNINGS

Percent
15

3.4

12
Net interest margin
10

3.3

8

3.2

6

3.1

4

3.0

1.3

13
Return on equity

11

1.1

Asset growth rate
2

2.9

0

2.8

–2

2.7
2.6

–4
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Return on assets
0.9

9

0.7

7

0.5

5
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

FDIC-insured savings institutions
(S&Ls) reported net income of $4.53
billion for 2003:IVQ. This was $544 million higher than a year earlier but $33
million lower than the third quarter.
One-time gains on securities sales
were only $0.30 billion in 2003:IVQ,
compared to $1.13 billion in 2003:IIIQ.
S&Ls’ noninterest (fee) income
stood at $5.17 billion, up 80.7% from
a year earlier. Their total interest income of $17.2 billion is far below the
recent high of $22.3 billion reached

in 2001:IQ and 4.8% lower than a
year earlier. However, they seem to
have completed the process of repricing their loan portfolios around
the end of 2003:IQ. In the face of this
portfolio adjustment, net interest income has increased only 4.8% over
the past year because reductions in
interest income from lending were
nearly matched by declines in borrowing between 2002:IVQ and
2003:IVQ.
Although the net interest margin
declined slightly to 3.27% from the

recent peak of 3.35% reached at the
end of 2002, overall earnings performance continued to be strong. (The
net interest margin is calculated as
interest and dividends earned on
interest-bearing assets minus interest
paid to depositors and creditors; it is
expressed as a percentage of average
earning assets.) S&Ls’ net income
grew at a 13.6% rate on a year-overyear basis, outstripping the relatively
robust asset growth of 8.49% for the
same period. As a result, S&Ls’ return

(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Institutions (cont.)
Percent of total assets
70 NET LOANS AND LEASES

Percent
0.5 ASSET QUALITY

68

0.4

1.0

66

0.3

0.8

64

0.2

Percent
1.2

Problem assets
0.6
Net charge-offs

62

0.1

60
1998

0.4

0
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Percent
10 HEALTH

0.2
1998

Percent
1.4

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Ratio
8.3 CAPITAL

Ratio
1.4

Problem S&Ls
9

1.2

8

1.0

7

0.8

6

0.6

0.2

4

3

0
1999

2000

1.2

8.0

1.1

7.9

1.0

0.9

Core capital (leverage) ratio

0.4

Unprofitable S&Ls

1998

Coverage ratio

8.1

7.8
5

1.3

8.2

2001

2002

2003

7.7

0.8

7.6

0.7

7.5
1998

0.6
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

on assets continued its recent upward
trend, rising to 1.28% in 2003:IVQ. A
similar picture emerges for return on
equity, which reached 13.66% for the
quarter.
In 2003:IVQ, net loans and leases
as a share of total assets reached
67.6%, up slightly from the previous
quarter. This share was very close to
its recent high of 67.9% in 2000:IIIQ,
however, suggesting an end to the
decline in savings institutions’ direct
holdings of loans.

Asset quality showed mixed signs
in 2003:IVQ. Net charge-offs (gross
charge-offs minus recoveries) rose to
0.30%. Problem assets (noncurrents
assets plus other real estate) made
up 0.62% of total assets for the quarter, which represented only a slight
decrease in the problem asset ratio
from its 2002 level of 0.69%.
However, asset quality is not currently a significant problem. Problem
S&Ls (those with substandard exam
ratings) declined significantly from
1.16% in 2002 to 0.71% in 2003:IVQ.

The share of unprofitable institutions
continued to fall, reaching 5.7%. The
coverage ratio stands at $1.05 in loan
loss reserves for every dollar of noncurrent loans. The slight increase in
the coverage ratio between 2002 and
2003:IVQ resulted from a $185 million
increase in loan loss reserves and a
$307 million decrease in noncurrent
loans during that period. In 2003:IVQ,
core capital, which protects savings institutions against unexpected losses,
decreased very slightly to 8.05% from
8.06% in 2002.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks
Percent, daily
7 MONETARY POLICY TARGETS a

Trillions of yen
–35
–30

6

CHANGES IN POLICY RATES SINCE NOVEMBER 6, 2003 b

–25

5
Bank of England
3

European Central Bank

2

–15

Mexico

–10

New Zealand

–5

Federal Reserve

1

Hungary

–20

4

Latvia

0

0
–1
Bank of Japan

–2

5

Australia

10

Lithuania

15

–3

Bulgaria

20
Singapore

–4

25

–5

30

Peru

–6

35
40

Argentina

–7
4/1

9/28

3/27

2001

9/23

3/22

2002

9/18
2003

3/16
2004

Colombia
South Africa

Trillions of yen
39 BANK OF JAPAN c

Sweden

36
Norway

33
Current account balances (daily)

Canada

30
27

Venezuela

Current account
balances

24

Chile

21

Indonesia

18

Israel

15

Slovenia

12

Excess reserve balances

Russia

9

Brazil

6

Turkey

Current account less required reserves

3
0
4/1

10/1
2001

4/1

10/1

4/1

2002

10/1
2003

4/1
2004

–4

–3

–2

–1

0
Percent

1

2

3

4

FRB Cleveland • May 2004

a. Federal Reserve: overnight interbank rate. Bank of Japan: a quantity of current account balances (since December 19, 2001, a range of quantity of current
account balances). Bank of England and European Central Bank: repo rate.
b. Date of the first of the Bank of England’s recent rate increases.
c. Current account balances at the Bank of Japan are required and excess reserve balances at depository institutions subject to reserve requirements plus the
balances of certain other financial institutions not subject to reserve requirements. Reserve requirements are satisfied on the basis of the average of a bank’s
daily balances at the Bank of Japan starting the sixteenth of one month and ending the fifteenth of the next.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bank of Japan; European Central Bank; Bank of England; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

Public discussion of expected monetary tightening has begun to spread
around the globe, although the four
major central banks left their policy
settings unchanged in April. In
Europe, the Governing Council of
the European Central Bank concluded that an unchanged policy rate
was “in line with the maintenance of
price stability over the medium
term,” while officials outside the bank
continued to press for a cut in its
main refinancing rate.

The Bank of England’s Monetary
Policy Committee, noting that “global
economic recovery still seemed to be
developing broadly as expected,” left
its policy rate unchanged in April after
raising it 50 basis points since October.
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan
Greenspan’s remark that deflation
“was no longer an issue” in the U.S.
triggered spirited public speculation
about the timing of potential future
increases in the policy rate.
Economic recovery and lower excess reserves led to talk of an end to

the Bank of Japan’s policy of quantitative easing. Governor Fukui, however,
reiterated that for this to happen, the
bank would need to see both past and
prospective core CPI measures at or
above zero and might continue the
policy “even if these two conditions
are fulfilled.”
The Bank of China continued to
battle rapid growth and potential
inflationary pressures in April by
raising reserve requirements for the
second consecutive month.