View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 2011 (February 8, 2011-March 8, 2011)

In This Issue:
Monetary Policy
 The Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth
 Economic Projections from the January FOMC
Meeting
Banking and Financial Markets
 Mortgage Originations—A Mixed Bag
Inflation and Prices
 Some Prices Are Up, but Is That Inflation?

Households and Consumers
 Educational Attainment and Employment
Growth and Production
 Household and Corporate Balance Sheets
Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 The U.S. Labor Market Experience in a Global
Context

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, February 2011
Highlights

Covering January 15, 2011–February 25, 2011
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Timothy Bianco

February

January

December

3-month Treasury bill rate
(percent)

0.11

0.15

0.14

Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures

10-year Treasury bond rate
(percent)

3.60

3.36

3.18

Yield curve slope
(basis points)

349

321

304

Prediction for GDP growth
(percent)

1.0

1.0

1.0

Probabilty of recession in 1
year (percent)

0.7

1.2

1.5

The yield curve twisted steeper over the past
month, as long rates once again increased substantially, moving up nearly one quarter of a percentage
point, while short rates edged down. The threemonth Treasury bill rate moved down to 0.11 percent, below January’s 0.15 percent and December’s
0.14 percent. The ten-year rate rose to 3.60 percent, up from January’s 3.36 percent, which itself
was up sharply from December’s 3.18 percent. The
slope rose by 28 basis points, staying above 300,
and remains a full 45 basis points above December’s
304.

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP
Growth
Percent
11
9

GDP g
growth
-o
ch
(year-over-year
change)

7
5
3
1
-1

Ten-yearr minus three-month
eyield spread
re

-3
-5
1953 1960

1966

1973

1980

1987

1994

2001

2003

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
11
One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

9
7
5
3
1
-1

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-3
-5
1953

1960

1966

1973

1980

1987

1994

2001

2003

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

Projecting forward using past values of the spread
and GDP growth suggests that real GDP will grow
at about a 1.0 percent rate over the next year, the
same numbers as November and December. Although the time horizons do not match exactly,
this comes in on the more pessimistic side of other
forecasts, although, like them, it does show moderate growth for the year.
Using the yield curve to predict whether or not
the economy will be in recession in the future, we
estimate that the expected chance of the economy
being in a recession next February is at 0.7 percent,
slightly down from both January’s at 1.2 percent
and December’s 1.5 percent.
The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth
The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
5

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4

Predicted
GDP growth

3

More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.

2
1
0
-1

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-2
-3
-4

-5
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
80

Probability of recession

70
Forecast

60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1960

1966 1972 1978 1984

2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.

1990 1996 2002 2008

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

Predicting GDP Growth
While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution.For more detail on these and other issues related to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” The Federal Reserve Bank of New York
also maintains a website with much useful information on the topic, including their own estimate of
recession probabilities.

3

Monetary Policy

Economic Projections from the January FOMC Meeting
02.17.11
by Brent Meyer
Economic forecasting at the Fed isn’t as simple
as trying to predict where the economy might be
heading. It also involves estimating how monetary
policy actions the Fed is considering will likely
affect the economy in ways that encourage full
employment and stable prices. Here, in layman’s
terms, is how and why forecasting is conducted at
the Fed. See all the Drawing Board videos
Four times a year, we get a glimpse of the Federal
Open Market Committee’s (FOMCs) forecasts for
economic growth, unemployment, and inflation.
The projections take into account all the available
data at the time, assumptions about key economic
factors, and each participant’s view of the appropriate monetary policy that will satisfy the Fed’s dual
mandate (maximum sustainable employment and
price stability).

FOMC Projections: Real GDP
Annualized percent change
6
November
January
5
4
3

Central
tendency

Range
2
1
0
2011 forecast

2012 forecast

2013 forecast

Longer-run

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

FOMC Projections: Unemployment Rate
Annualized percent change
10

November
January

9
8
Central
tendency

7
Range
6
5
4
2011 forecast

2012 forecast

2013 forecast

Longer-run

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

The newest forecasts were released with the minutes
of the January FOMC meeting. At the time of that
meeting, incoming data hinted that growth was on
firmer footing than had been previously suspected.
Notably, data on consumption and industrial
production came in stronger than expected. As a
result, the Committee shaded up its forecasts for
near-term output growth relative to the November
meeting, with the central tendency for 2011 real
GDP growth rising to a range of 3.4 percent—3.9
percent from November’s estimate of 3.0 percent—3.6 percent. However, forecasts for the medium term were largely unchanged, as Committee
members still expect solid above-trend growth for
2012 and 2013.
Despite slightly stronger expectations for near-term
growth, the Committee’s 2011 unemployment rate
forecasts improved only narrowly—with the central
tendency ticking down just 0.1 percentage point
from a range of 8.9 percent—9.1 percent in November to 8.8 percent—9.0 percent in January. The
unemployment rate projections for 2013 now range
from 6.8 percent to 7.2 percent, well above the
4

Committee’s longer-run “sustainable rate” projections. Many participants noted that the ongoing
(and gradual) labor market recovery may be further
restrained by “uneven recovery across sectors” leading to a mismatch between workers and jobs, and
relatively strong productivity gains (dampening the
need for robust hiring to fuel growth).

FOMC Projections: PCE Inflation
Annualized percent change
3.0
2.5

November
January

2.0
1.5
Central
tendency

1.0
Range
0.5
0.0
2011 forecast

2012 forecast

2013 forecast

Longer-run

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

FOMC Projections: Core PCE Inflation
Annualized percent change
3.0
2.5
2.0

November
January
Central
tendency

Committee members continue to expect that
inflation will remain at or below their longer-run
projections, as readings on underlying inflation
continue to come in soft. For example, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland’s Median CPI is up just
0.6 percent on a year-over-year basis. The release
noted that many participants expect that high levels
of resource slack should continue to apply downward pressure on prices. Moving toward the longerterm outlook, “appropriate monetary policy” combined with well-anchored inflation expectations
will likely result in modest inflation rates. Still, the
range of forecasts for both headline and core PCE
prices over the medium term is little changed from
November and remains relatively wide.

Range

1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
2011 Forecast

2012 Forecast

2012 Forecast

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Most participants continued to judge the uncertainty accompanying their projections for all
forecasted variables as “elevated” when compared
to historical norms. However, the Committee did
change its assessment of the risks to its growth and
inflation projections. The majority of Committee
members now judge the risks to be “balanced,”
whereas in November the majority weighted risks
to the “downside.” On the upside for growth, some
of the participants noted that the recent strength
in aggregate spending data might be evidence that
a sharper recovery was taking shape (one typical
of those that usually follow a deep recession). On
the downside, other Committee members noted
the continued fragility of the housing market may
still adversely affect household spending patterns
and bank lending. As for the inflation risks, several
participants put a lower probability on further disinflation or outright deflation outcomes, leading to
their view of a more balanced distribution of risks.
This article was released in conjunction with The Drawing Board
video on forecasting. To watch the video, please visit http://www.
clevelandfed.org/research/trends/2011/0311/01monpol.cfm.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

5

Banking and Financial Markets

Mortgage Originations—A Mixed Bag
02.28.11
by Yuliya Demyanyk and Matthew Koepke
The mortgage market ended 2010 on a high note,
with mortgage originations increasing for the
third consecutive quarter and reversing a trend of
three consecutive quarterly declines. According to
the January 28 issue of Inside Mortgage Finance,
fourth-quarter mortgage originations rose 22.0 percent to $500 billion, representing the highest level
of originations since the second quarter of 2009.
Additionally, the increase represents the first consecutive double-digit quarterly percentage increase
since the second quarter of 2009.

Total Mortgage Originations
Quarterly Percentage Change
30

10

-10

-30
2009:Q2 2009:Q3 2009:Q4 2010:Q1 2010:Q2 2010:Q3 2010:Q4
Source: Inside Mortgage Finance.

Total Mortgages Serviced
Year-over-year percent change
16
12
8
4
0
-4
3/00

3/02

3/04

3/06

3/08

3/10

Source: Inside Mortgage Finance.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

Despite the improvement in mortgage originations,
the number of total mortgages serviced continued
to fall. According the February 4 issue of Inside
Mortgage Finance, total mortgages serviced by
the top mortgage servicers declined 2.0 percent in
2010, falling from $10.7 trillion in the first quarter to $10.5 trillion in the fourth quarter. While
mortgage originations were up, the majority of
the new originations were for mortgage refinances,
where existing loans are converted into new loans
at different rates or maturities, and not for new
home purchases. Consequently, few new loans have
been added to mortgage servicers’ portfolios. Additionally, the level of foreclosed homes has risen
dramatically, which reduces the total number of
mortgages serviced. The combination of the high
level of refinancing activity and the increase in
home foreclosures is likely causing total mortgages
serviced to decline despite the increase in mortgage
originations.
Refinancings have constituted the majority of mortgage originations since December 2008. Driven
by the low-interest-rate environment, refinancings
have averaged 68 percent of all originations since
March 2009, and by the fourth quarter of 2010
they had grown to 78 percent of all mortgages
originated. Such high proportions of refinancing
mean that banks are not creating many new loans.

6

Foreclosures are playing a big role in reducing the
number of mortgages serviced because they have
risen to such high levels. From 2000-2007, the
average number of foreclosed homes was 1.26 million, but since 2008, that number has ballooned
to 3.91 million. Given that foreclosures and delinquencies remain at an all-time high, it is unlikely
that the number of mortgages serviced will rise
without an increase in purchase originations.

Total Mortgages Originations
Dollars in billions
1,400
Total mortgage originations

1,200
1,000
800
600
400
200

Refinance originations

0
3/00

3/02

3/04

3/06

3/08

3/10

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Homes in Foreclosure and Distress Mortgages
Number of mortgages in millions

Number of homes in millions
6

12

Mortgage originations may have improved in 2010,
but the improvement has done little to raise the
number of mortgages serviced. Though activity
has picked up, high levels of refinancing originations and foreclosures have made it difficult for
the increased activity to fully offset the declines in
servicers’ existing portfolios. Looking ahead, total
mortgages serviced will continue to decline if low
demand for purchase originations persists or if
home foreclosures rise.

All mortgages past due
4

2

8

Inventory of foreclosed homes

0

4

0

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

7

Inflation and Prices

Some Prices Are Up, but Is That Inflation?
03.01.11
by Brent Meyer
The headline Consumer Price Index jumped up
at an annualized rate of 4.9 percent in January,
following a 5.3 percent increase in December. The
12-month growth rate is now 1.6 percent. Energy,
commodity, and food prices have been exerting significant upward price pressure lately—increases in
those items were responsible for roughly two-thirds
of the measure’s overall increase in January, according to the BLS. Food prices spiked in January (the
food at home index jumped up 9.3 percent—its
largest increase since July 2008—as all six major
food groupings posting increases). The price of motor fuel has risen at an annualized rate of 54 percent
over the past three months.

Consumer Price Index
12-month percent change
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

But are these recent price increases simply relative price movements brought about by changes in
supply and demand conditions, or are the increases
symptomatic of a monetary impulse working its
way through prices in general?
Headline inflation measures, such as the CPI, are
subject to short-term volatility brought about by
mismeasurement, the treatment of seasonal factors, and relative price changes that have little or
nothing to do with inflation. These transitory price
fluctuations may cause the CPI to give a misleading
monthly signal of the inflation trend.
Price statistics that attempt to distinguish the
inflation signal from noise are often called core or
underlying measures of inflation. One well-known
core inflation statistic excludes food and energy
prices from the CPI, a statistic most economists
refer to as the “core CPI.” Food and energy prices
tend to be the most volatile components and they
regularly cause fluctuations in the CPI that are not
characteristic of the inflation trend. However, the
“ex-food and energy” approach does not address
transitory price fluctuations in other components of
the retail market basket that is used to construct the
CPI. Such fluctuations can be caused by mismeasurement and idiosyncratic shocks (like excise taxes,
8

inclement weather, government programs to stimulate demand for certain items, and so on).
A couple of measures of underlying inflation produced by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland—
the median CPI and 16 percent trimmed-mean
CPI—attempt to “amplify” the inflation signal by
eliminating the most volatile monthly price swings
(hence, decreasing the noise). What have these
measures been telling us lately?

Consumer Price Index
12-month percent change
7
6
5
4

CPI
Median CPI

3
2
1

Well, the median CPI rose 2.0 percent in January,
while the 16 percent trimmed-mean CPI increased
2.7 percent. These increases are roughly in line with
the statistics’ longer-run (5-year) averages of about
2.0 percent. The latest numbers are somewhat of an
uptick compared to recent months, however. Over
the past 12 months, the median and trimmedmean measures are hovering just above series lows
set back in 1968—up just 0.8 percent and 1.0
percent, respectively.

16% trimmed-mean CPI

0
-1
-2
-3
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Another way to analyze the incoming data is to
look at where the price increases are coming from.
Bryan and Meyer (2010) separate the consumer
market basket into “flexible” and “sticky” prices.
Flexible-priced items (like gasoline) are free to
adjust quickly to changing market conditions,
while sticky-priced items (like prices at the laundromat) are subject to some impediment or cost
that causes them to change prices infrequently. As
their research shows, sticky prices appear to have an
embedded inflation expectations component that is
useful in forecasting future inflation.
As is evident in the figure below, the flexible price
series is definitely more volatile, and does appear
to vary with changing economic conditions. The
sticky price series has been relatively stable since
1983, usually hovering between 2.0 percent and 3.0
percent. However, over the past two years the sticky
CPI has experienced a sizeable disinflation—slowing from a year-over-year growth rate of 2.8 percent
in December 2007 to a low of 0.7 percent in September 2010. Since then, the sticky CPI has edged
back up slightly and is now trending at a 12-month
growth rate of 1.0 percent. The flexible CPI, which
fell to a year-over-year growth rate of -10 percent

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

9

during the depths of the last recession, has popped
back up to a 12-month growth rate of 3.4 percent
through January.

Disaggregated CPI
12-month percent change
20
15

The flexible CPI is intriguing in that, by design,
it is likely to show evidence of pricing pressure
ahead of the sticky CPI. However, the series is very
volatile relative to its sticky-price counterpart and
likely dominated by relative price changes. As a
result, inflation forecasts based on the flexible CPI
perform rather poorly.

Sticky CPI

10
5
0
Flexible CPI
-5
-10
-15
1968

1973

1978

1983

1988

1993

1998

2003

2008

While rapid price increases in a few categories seem
to have pushed up the headline CPI lately, underlying measures of inflation are relatively low and have
only ticked up slightly in the past few months.

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bryan and Meyer (2010).

“Are Some Prices in the CPI More Forward Looking than Others?
We Think So.” Michael F. Bryan and Brent Meyer. Economic Commentary, May 19, 2010. http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/commentary/2010/2010-2.pdf

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

10

Households and Consumers

Educational Attainment and Employment
03.02.11
by Dionissi Aliprantis and Mary Zenker
Labor market experiences can be highly varied for
individuals with different levels of educational attainment. Higher levels of educational attainment
tend to be associated with higher wages, and there
is evidence that the benefits of a degree have been
increasing in recent decades in the United States.
For example, the wages of high school dropouts
have dropped since the early 1970s, while the wages
of college graduates relative to high school graduates have increased. Empirical facts like these make
it unsurprising that a great deal of attention has
recently been focused on the relative performance
of American students in terms of both educational
attainment and achievement.
Given this changing wage structure, a natural issue
to investigate is whether other employment outcomes have also changed by education levels over
time. A look at labor force participation rates and
unemployment patterns using data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics shows they have.

Labor Force Participation by Educational
Attainment
Seasonally adjusted, percent
85
75
65
55
45
Less than a high school diploma
High school diploma, no college degree
Some college, no degree
Associate’s degree
College degree and higher

35
25
1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Note: Age 25 years and older.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

First we see that high school dropouts have actually increased their labor force participation slightly
since the early nineties, despite their decreasing
wages. This contrasts with all other education
groups, which all experienced gradual decreases in
labor force participation rates. What may be most
striking about this picture is the huge gap between
high school dropouts and all other groups, which is
very gradually closing.
Once individuals decide to participate in the labor
market, how do their experiences differ by educational attainment? We see the expected differences
in unemployment rate: Those with a college degree
or higher have the lowest unemployment rates
over time, and the unemployment rate increases
as attainment decreases. The unemployment rate
approximately doubled for each group during the
recent recession. Since those with low educational
attainment already started out with higher unemployment rates, this doubling translates into larger
11

absolute changes for these attainment groups. That
is, while we see similar patterns for all groups,
higher educational attainment is associated with
smaller changes in unemployment.

Unemployment Rates by Educational
Attainment
Seasonally adjusted, percent
16

Less than a high school diploma
High school diploma, no college degree
Some college, no degree
Associate’s degree
College degree and higher

14
12

The story of unemployment duration is quite different. The recent recession caused a very large spike
in the length of time workers remain unemployed,
and spells of unemployment are now similar for
workers at all levels of educational attainment. It is
interesting that the differences in labor force participation and unemployment rates do not translate
into differences for duration.

10
8
6
4
2
0
1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Notes: Age 25 years and older.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Unemployment Duration by Educational
Attainment

Many factors influence the labor market, and thus
it is difficult to conclude that educational attainment alone drives labor market outcomes. Nevertheless, the evidence examined here suggests important relationships between educational attainment
and labor market outcomes.

Average number of weeks unemployed
40
Less than a high school diploma
High school diploma, no college degree
Some college, no degree
Associate’s degree
College degree and higher

35
30
25
20
15
10
1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

Note: Age 25 years and older.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

12

Growth and Production

Household and Corporate Balance Sheets
Household Leverage

03.07.11
by Tim Bianco and Filippo Occhino

Change from beginning of recession
0.08
2007 recession
0.06
0.04
Range
0.02
0.00
-0.02
Average of previous 8 cycles
-0.04
-12 -10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Quarters from beginning of recession
Note: Range refers to the minimum or maximum values over the 8 previous cycles.
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds
Accounts of the United States and authors’ calculations.

Corporate Leverage
Change from beginning of recession
0.4
2007 recession
0.3
0.2
Range
0.1
0.0
-0.1
Average of previous 8 cycles
-0.2
-12 -10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Quarters from beginning of recession
Notes: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over the previous 8 cycles.
Data are for nonfarm nonfinancial corporate businesses.
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds
Accounts of the United States; authors' calculations.

Household and Corporate Leverage
2.5

1.5
Corporate leverage

1.4

2.2

1.3

1.9

1.2

1.6
Household leverage

1.1
1.0
1952

1.3
1.0

1962

1972

1982

1992

2002

Notes: Shaded bars indicate recessions. Data for the corporate sector are for
nonfarm nonfinancial corporate businesses.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds
Accounts of the United States; authors' calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

One reason for the striking severity of the last recession is the double whammy that struck household
and corporate balance sheets. Balance sheets deteriorated sharply when the values of both financial
and real estate assets plunged. The resulting increase
in leverage (the ratio of assets to net worth) was
much larger than in any of the previous eight recessions. Weak balance sheets depress real activity in a
number of ways: they raise the cost of credit, they
reduce its availability, and they constrain consumption and investment demand.
Household leverage reached record high levels, and
corporate leverage hit near-high levels. Leverage ratios in both sectors have since decreased but remain
close to their peaks, and this is likely one factor
slowing the current recovery down.
A closer look at the balance sheets of the two sectors reveals some interesting differences. Households have been reducing their liabilities in the past
two years, lowering the large home mortgage and
consumer credit components. During the same
period, however, firms have steadily accumulated
liabilities, especially by raising the corporate bond
component.
Each sector suffered a substantial loss of assets
during the recession. Both financial assets and real
estate assets experienced their largest percentage
drop on record. Moreover, the contractionary effects of the losses on leverage and real activity were
compounded by the simultaneous drops in the two
kinds of assets. Financial asset values have since
rebounded, and assets for both sectors recovered as
a result, but the recovery has been only partial.
Household financial assets were hit harder by the
crisis than corporate financial assets, which suggests
that households were relatively more exposed to the
type of financial shock that hit the economy. While
corporate financial assets decreased by 6 percent,
household financial assets decreased by 22 percent.
After the recession, corporate financial assets have
13

fully recovered and surpassed the previous peak, but
household financial assets are still well below their
pre-crisis levels.

Household Financial Assets

Corporate Financial Assets

Percentage change from beginning of recession

Percentage change from beginning of recession

40

60
50

Average of previous
8 cycles

30

Average of previous
8 cycles

40

20

30
20

10
0

10
0

-10

-10
-20

-20
Range

-30

2007 recession

2007 recession
Range

-30

-40
-12 -10

-40
-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

-12 -10

Note: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over the previous 8 cycles.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts
of the United States; authors' calculations.

Percentage change from beginning of recession
40
Average of previous
8 cycles

20
10
0
2007 recession

-20
Range

-30
-40
-12 -10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

6

8

Notes: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over the previous 8 cycles.
Data are for nonfarm nonfinancial corporate businesses.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts
of the United States; authors' calculations.

Household and corporate real estate assets began
to fall, respectively, four and two quarters prior to
the beginning of the 2007 recession. When the
recession started, they had already decreased by
7 percent and 3 percent, respectively. The overall
percentage drop in real estate assets was by far the
largest on record for both sectors, −27 percent for
households and −35 percent for corporations. For
both sectors, real estate assets are currently close to
their post-crisis lows.

Household Real Estate

-10

-6

Quarters from beginning of recession

Quarters from beginning of recession

30

-8

10

12

Quarters from beginning of recession
Note: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over the previous 8 cycles.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts
of the United States; authors' calculations.

One reason the corporate sector experienced a
larger percentage decrease in real estate assets is that
it was relatively more exposed to commercial real
estate prices than residential real estate prices. The
percentage drop in commercial real estate prices
was larger than in residential real estate prices. Depending on the price index considered, commercial
real estate prices dropped by between 40 percent
and 45 percent, while residential real estate prices
dropped by between 11 percent and 32 percent.
Although real estate prices seem to have bottomed
out, they are not showing any clear sign of recovery
yet. Consequently, leverage in both sectors continues to be high and close to peak, likely weighing on
the current recovery.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

14

Corporate Real Estate

Real Estate Price Indexes

Percentage change from beginning of recession

500

50
40

400

Average of previous
8 cycles

30
20

300

10
0
-10
-20
Range

-30

S&P/Case-Shiller home price index
Commercial real estate:
transactions-based index: all properties
FHFA house price index
Commercial real estate:
RCA-based national
aggregate index (right axis)

2.5
2.0
1.5

200

1.0

100

0.5

2007 recession

-40
-50
-12 -10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Quarters from beginning of recession
Notes: Range refers to the minimum and maximum values over the previous 8 cycles.
Data are for nonfarm nonfinancial corporate businesses.
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts
of the United States; authors' calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

0.0
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: S&P, Fiserv, and Macroeconomics LLC; FHFA; Moody’s, MIT Center for
Real Estate.

15

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

The U.S. Labor Market Experience in a Global Context
03.07.11
by Murat Tasci and Mary Zenker
The recent recession was felt around the globe.
Most advanced economies and some developing
countries experienced a significant contraction in
real output sometime after 2007, and this widespread slowdown translated into exceptionally bad
performance in world output. According to the
IMF, after growing at a rate of 4.2 percent every
year between 2000 and 2007, world output grew
only 2.8 percent in 2008 and contracted by 0.5
percent in 2009. This might be the first time since
World War II that the world economy actually
shrank.

Changes in GDP and Unemployment
Percent point change
10

Percent change
15
Ireland

8

10

6

5 Canada

U.K.

4
2

Germany

0

0

-2
-5
-10
-15

France

Spain

U.S. -4
-6

Italy
Unemployment rate
GDP

While the major industrialized countries led this
decline with sizeable contractions in their GDP,
the effects of the downturn on labor markets differed across countries. When we looked at a set of
developed countries that experienced similarly sized
shocks to GDP—about 5 percent on average from
peak to trough—along with Ireland and Japan,
which saw much larger declines, we found a wide
range of unemployment responses across countries.
For example, GDP fell about as much in the United States as it did in Spain, but the unemployment
rate increase in Spain was double that of the U.S.

Japan

-8
-10

Notes: GDP is measured
from country-specific peak to country-specific trough;
.
.
unemployment is measured over
the same period as GDP.
Source: International Monetary Fund; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Germany is unusual in that its 7 percent decline
in GDP was accompanied by a decrease in its
unemployment rate! It’s impossible to tell from
the unemployment rate alone, however, what else
might be happening in the labor market to explain
such data. It could be that in Germany the unemployment rate declined but those who are employed
worked less. That response would not be captured
explicitly in the unemployment rate and unfortunately, we lack data robust enough to allow us to
compare hours worked across countries.
While the extent of the increase in unemployment
varied across countries, the underlying pattern of
unemployment over the course of the recession was
remarkably uniform. Looking at the unemployment rate increases starting from the beginning

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

16

Increase in Unemployment Rate
Percentage points
12

Spain

10

Ireland

8
6

U.S.

4
U.K.

Italy
France

2
Japan

0

Canada

Germany
-2
0

4

8
12
16
20
24
28
Months from beginning of recession

32

36

Note: The beginning of the recession is the country-specific GDP peak.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Employment Protection and
Unemployment
Percentage point change in unemployment rate
12
10

Spain
Ireland

8
6
U.S.

4

All sample countries

U.K.
Canada

2
0
-2
0

Sweden
Italy
Finland
Japan
Germany

France
Portugal
Excluding Ireland
and Spain

1
2
3
Overall strictness of employment protection

4

Notes: Unemployment is measured over country-specific GDP peaks and troughs.
Strictness (x axis) refers to the average protection level in 2005-2008.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; OECD.

of the contraction in real output, we see that the
response was gradual and persistent almost everywhere. Unemployment started to show significant
signs of an upward trend a couple of months after
the start of the recession in each country, and it
stayed elevated long after GDP began to pick up.
In the case of Ireland and Spain, peak unemployment rate levels were observed only recently. Again,
Germany is the exception.
So far, we have assumed that labor markets respond to aggregate economic activity, with higher
unemployment rates following contractions in real
output. But all economies might not respond to aggregate conditions in the same way. One potential
reason is that labor market institutions differ across
countries. For instance, continental European
countries have very strict laws against firing employees and hiring temporary workers. It is conceivable that employers in those countries might
not have as much flexibility as they would like to
adjust their workforces in the face of a recession.
Anticipating the restriction, firms might be hesitant
to hire in the first place, even when times are good.
Such conditions would imply muted change in the
unemployment rate as it responds to business cycles
fluctuations.
We can explore this issue with an index computed
by the OECD. The Overall Strictness of Employment Protection index provides a measure of the
overall strictness of the labor market in a country
with respect to the processes and costs involved
when firing workers or hiring temporary employees. The measure can help us determine whether
rigid labor markets (economies with strict employment protection) responded differently than more
flexible labor markets during the Great Recession.
In a sense, employment protection handicaps the
ability of the labor market to adjust at the extensive
margin as output falls. Plotting the unemployment
rate change over the recession and the overall strictness indicator in the figure below shows us how the
relationship plays out.
Even though all of the countries in this extended
sample are among the major advanced economies,
they range widely in the strictness of their employment protections, with values between 0.2 and

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

17

3.4 (the OECD average is 1.9). The United States
has the lowest employment protection score of the
countries in the sample. Correspondingly, the unemployment rate response in the U.S. labor market
was one of the strongest we see on the chart. Spain
and Ireland stand out as major outliers in terms of
their unemployment rate response, and they blur
the relationship between employment protection
and rising unemployment. Indeed if one ignores
these two outliers, the trend line suggests a somewhat significant negative relationship: as employment protection increases, the unemployment rate
response becomes increasingly muted. However,
this relationship ignores the variance in the severity
of the recession across countries.

Changes in GDP and Unemployment
Percentage point change in unemployment rate
12
10

Strict countries
Less strict countries

Spain

8

Ireland
Less strict countries

6

All countries

U.S.

4
Canada

2
0

U.K. Sweden
Italy
France
Finland
Japan
Portugal
Germany

-2
0

5
10
Percent decline in GDP

15

Notes: GDP is measured from country-specific peaks to country-specific troughs;
unemployment is measured over the same period as GDP.
Source: International Monetary Fund; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Unemployment Rate Change 2007 to 2009
Percentage points
12
Men
10
Women

Ireland

8
U.S.

6
4
2
0

U.K.
France
Canada

-2

Italy

Japan
Spain

Germany

-4
Source: OECD.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

To understand how the severity of the recession
interacted with the degree of employment protection, we split countries into a “less strict” group and
a “strict” group. The strict group includes Spain,
France, Portugal, Sweden, Italy, Germany, and Finland, while the less strict group consists of the United States, the United Kingdom, Canada, Ireland,
and Japan. The less strict countries exhibit a labor
market whose response varies with the depth of the
GDP decline. Deeper recessions are associated with
larger increases in the observed unemployment
rate. In the strict countries, even as the declines in
GDP increase in severity, the labor market does not
calibrate accordingly. Spain’s outsized increase in
unemployment influences this relationship for the
group of strict countries and makes the relationship
relatively insignificant.
One needs to exercise caution when interpreting these results, as our very small sample for one
particular episode may not necessarily generalize.
Nevertheless, this casual correlation suggests that
increasingly large declines in GDP fail to yield
additional changes in the labor market on the
extensive margin in countries with relatively strict
employment protection.
Another pattern shared across countries concerned
the unemployment experiences of men and women.
In all of the countries in our sample, women fared
better than men throughout the recession.
The different experiences of men and women make
sense considering male-dominated industries
18

Importance of Housing Downturns
Contribution to change in total employment 2007:Q4 to 2009:Q4
2
France

Spain

Italy

U.K.

U.S.

0
Germany
Canada
-2

like construction and finance were hit hard by
the recent recession. Housing downturns were an
important factor in the recessions of about half of
the countries in our sample. Construction was an
especially large contributor to employment declines
in Ireland and Spain, as in the United States. Correspondingly, males experienced dramatic increases
in unemployment in those countries.

Japan
-4

-6
Ireland

Construction
All other sectors

-8
Source: OECD.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

The U.S. experience in the Great Recession has
been characterized by persistently high unemployment despite a modest recovery in GDP. Looking
at that experience in a global context, we see that
while the shock experienced by some of the major
industrialized countries was relatively uniform in
size, the labor market responses of the group exhibited a lot of variation as well as some similarities.
Countries with less strict employment protection
and those with significant housing market problems
experienced larger increases in their unemployment
rate when the recession hit. Among almost all of
them, however, unemployment rate increases were
gradual and persistent, and they disproportionately
affected men.

19

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | March 2011

20