View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

Learning to live with the New Economy…The tangible manifestations of the current U.S. economic slump have reinvigorated the Old Economy/New Economy debate.
The Old Economy’s champions, pointing to stock market woes, consumer sentiment worries, declining manufacturing activity, and corporate layoffs, see familiar patterns at work. New Economy advocates argue that even
as the economy endures an adjustment period, it does so
in different ways and will emerge in a different place than
it used to.
Does this Old Economy/New Economy dichotomy
offer us anything useful from which to learn, or is it a
distinction without a difference?
First, let’s define the Old Economy paradigm. In this
world, business cycles are endemic to the economy’s operations because it is so hard to coordinate production and
sales. Inventory buffers are stockpiled at links in the supply
chain between manufacturers and consumers to smooth
out normal imbalances between supply and demand, but
these same stockpiles can create large disturbances if they
swell just before demand shrinks. When that happens,
manufacturers are forced to scale back sharply or shut
down completelywhile the stockpiles areworked off, usuallyat deep price discounts.
The resulting declines in profitability feed back
through financial markets, impairing firms’ ability to
raise funds when they need them most. Labor markets
slacken, the unemployment rate rises, and hiring cost
pressures ease. Economic activity remains at low ebb
until excess inventories are cleared out, marginally profitable operations are sold or improved, and balance
sheets are repaired. Hiring and investment spending resume only after firms are forced to expand capacity once
again, and when banks are able to finance more projects.
The New Economy, its advocates say, is less fragile.
Where the Old Economy was rooted in manufacturing
industries constrained by decreasing returns to scale in
production, the New Economy is built on information
and technology industries that show increasing returns
to scale in production and positiveexternalities. Waves of
innovation guarantee that firms can constantly lower
their cost structure and promise consumers a continuously improving array of choices. Living standards tangibly rise, as does the quality of life. The dynamism associated with these innovations also ensures new and
profitable investment opportunities and a steady supply
of rewarding jobs. People accept change because they
see it as a bridge to a better future.

The New Economy is also free of the boomand-bust pattern that plagues the Old Economy. Inventory rebalancing, such a prominent source of transmission
in the Old Economy paradigm, is far less important in the
New Economy of advanced supply-chain management.
New Economy firms directly tie their information systems together, enabling them to continuously match orders to sales.
Moreover, New Economy firms and their
investors have long planning horizons. They see the merits of increasing market share, expanding globally, and
acquiring smaller competitors. With new technologies to
power their businesses and sell to others, the entire New
Economy has a solid underpinning that is impervious to
cyclical fluctuations. Its financing comes not just from
banks, but from global capital markets. While the Old
Economy was about job security and Social Security, the
New Economy is about creative destruction and the privatization of retirement wealth.
But just how profound is the change? High-tech investment, the lynchpin of our decade-long
expansion, has nearly stopped growing, while the NASDAQ’s much-vaunted invincibility has crumbled. One
Blue Chip firm after another has fallen short of its earnings projections. An old-fashioned inventory correction
seems to be under way, with especially severe repercussions echoing through the transportation equipment industry. Lenders are applying tighter credit standards to
their customers. Consumer and business sentiment has
been poor. Certainly none of these conditions fit with the
beguiling portrait that ardent New Economy advocates
have been painting. Yet, something does seem different.
Productivity has improved significantly during the past
several decades, especially in manufacturing industries.
New technologies are surely important, but there are other
important factors to consider. Businesses invest in new
technologies when they can put them to use profitably.
Those circumstances are far more likely to prevail in an
environment of low inflation and increasingly open borders—conditions that have prevailed for the last decade.
Competition and property rights are just as important to
intellectual property as they are to physical assets. The
New Economy is new, not only because of its application
of new ideas, but because it relies on some sound old
ideas as well.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
8 CPI AND PPI

January Price Statistics

7
Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

2000
5 yr.a avg.

Consumer prices
All items

6
5

7.8

4.2

3.7

2.6

CPI

3.4
4

Less food
and energy
Medianb

4.0

2.9

2.6

2.4

2.5

3.6

3.6

3.2

2.8

3.2

Producer prices

2
1

Finished goods 14.6

6.2

4.8

1.8

3.6

3.3

2.0

1.1

1.2

Less food
and energy

3

8.4

PPI
0
–1
–2
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND MEDIAN CPI

12-month percent change
5.0 CPI AND YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS

3.75
4.5
3.50
4.0

3.25

Year-ahead inflation expectations c

Median CPI b

3.00

3.5

2.75
3.0
2.50
2.5

2.25

CPI

CPI

2.00

2.0

1.75
1.5
1.50
1.25

1.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and University of Michigan.

Inflation worsened unexpectedly in January. The Consumer Price Index (CPI)
rose at a decade-high 7.8% annual rate,
helping to push its 12-month growth
trend to 3.7%, the highest level in nearly
nine years. Likewise, price increases at
the factory level were much larger in
January, up a whopping 14.6% (annual
rate). Energy and tobacco price increases
were especially prominent, building on a
year-long sequence of large advances in
these items.
Still, the breadth of recent price
increases clearly has extended well beyond a few volatile components, as

shown by core measures of inflation.
The CPI excluding food and energy, for
instance, was up 4.0% (annual rate) in
January, while the median CPI rose 3.6%
(annual rate). The median CPI corresponds to the price increase in a consumer’s market basket where half the
items show larger price increases and half
show smaller ones. The 12-month percent change in the median CPI has risen
sharply since the beginning of 2000.
Nevertheless, while the recent upward
inflation trend was accompanied by deteriorating household inflation expectations early in the process (1999), the pub-

lic’s inflationary sentiments seemingly
leveled off in 2000 and, so far, in 2001.
In other words, the higher inflation rates
recorded in recent months have apparently not fueled an inflation scare among
U.S. households.
The central bank faces an especially
difficult decision on how to
respond to these higher inflation
estimates, given the recent deceleration
in the rate of economic growth. The
Federal Reserve’s stated ultimate objective is to eliminate inflation’s corrosive
influence on the economy. A key ques(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Annualized quarterly percent change
5 CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECASTS a

Four-quarter percent change
7 CONSENSUS BLUE CHIP FORECAST OF CPI AND REAL GDP a
6

4
5

Highest 10
3
4
CPI

Average

Real GDP

3

2
CPI

2

Lowest 10
1
1

0

0

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2000

2001

2002

2003

Natural logs
0.12 P-STAR AND IMPLICIT GDP PRICE DEFLATOR

CPI, annual percent change
4.0 CPI AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE FORECASTS, 2001–02 a,b

0.10
3.5

P-star
0.08

3.0

0.06
0.04
Implicit GDP price deflator

2.5
0.02
2.0

0
–0.02

1.5
–0.04
1.0
3.5

4.0

4.5
Unemployment rate, percent

5.0

5.5

–0.06
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Blue Chip Panel of economists.
b. Individual economists’ forecasts, average for 2001 and 2002.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, February 10, 2001.

tion, then, is whether recent data are an
aberration or suggestive of a persistent
upward trend in the inflation rate.
Economists are divided on the outlook for the next few years. Pessimists
are projecting the rate of inflation to remain at or slightly above 3% through the
end of 2002; optimists see it falling back
below a fairly benign 2% during the same
period.
An argument for the optimists’ view is
that energy prices, which doubtless are

being incorporated into a wide range of
goods and services this year, will not
keep rising indefinitely. Slower growth in
economic activity might also relieve
some of the price pressure. Indeed, the
consensus forecast of economists shows
a pattern in which inflation is projected
to follow the economy’s growth rate
downward. But economists who use
such models have been unable to measure precisely the connection between
inflation and growth (witness the widely
scattered unemployment and inflation
rate expectations charted above).

The more pessimistic inflation
outlook is buttressed by an aboveaverage growth rate in the money supply
(as measured by M2) relative to estimates
of potential GDP, a model of future inflation that economists call P-star. When
P-star exceeds the price level (as it has
done since late 1998), inflation will likely
accelerate. Unfortunately, this model of
the inflation process has also proven
highly imprecise in recent practice.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent
6.25 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

Percent, weekly average
7.25 RESERVE MARKET RATES

6.00

6.75
January 3, 2001

Intended federal funds rate

5.75
6.25
Effective federal funds rate

5.50
5.75
5.25
February 13, 2001
5.25
5.00

January 31, 2001
February 26, 2001

Discount rate
4.75

4.75
February 22, 2001
4.50

4.25
Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

May

June
2001

July

Aug.

Sept.

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Billions of dollars
3.2 ADJUSTMENT CREDIT AND EFFECTIVE FEDERAL

Economic Indicators (percent)

2000
Actual

Oct.

Percent
8

FUNDS RATE–DISCOUNT RATE SPREAD e

Projections for 2001a
Central
Range
tendency

Nominal GDPb

5.9

3¾–5¼

4–5

Real GDPc

3.5

2–2¾

2–2½

PCE Chain-type
Price Indexb

2.4

1¾–2½

1¾–2¼

Civilian
unemployment
rated

4.0

4½–5

About 4½

6

2.4
Adjustment credit

1.6

4
Spread: Effective federal funds
rate minus discount rate

0.8

2

0

0

–0.8

–2
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. By Federal Reserve governors and Reserve Bank presidents.
b. Change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter.
c. Change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter, chain weighted.
d. Average level, fourth quarter.
e. Monthly, not seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

On February 13, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System submitted its semiannual Monetary
Policy Report to Congress, and Federal
Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
testified before the Senate Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs.
Chairman Greenspan expressed optimism about “the prospects for sustaining strong advances in productivity in the
years ahead,” but also noted that “downside risks predominate” over a shorter
horizon. Implied yields on federal funds
futures did not react strongly to his testimony. Market participants continue to

place a high probability on a further cut
of 50 basis points in the federal funds
rate by the end of March.
The report’s 2001 central tendencies
of projections for real GDP growth and
inflation (the Personal Consumption Expenditure Chain-type Price Index) were
revised downward from the July report’s
3¼–3¾% and 2–2½% to 2–2½% and
1¾–2¼%, respectively. Fourth-quarter
civilian unemployment rate projections
rose from 4–4¼% to about 4½%.
Banks’ borrowing through the Federal Reserve’s discount window has
fallen significantly in recent years. One

might expect a positive relationship between discount window borrowing and
the spread between the federal funds
rate and the discount rate. A larger
spread presumably would encourage
banks to exploit arbitrage possibilities by
borrowing more heavily from the Fed.
Before 1985, about 70% of changes in
adjustment credit could be accounted
for by changes in the federal funds–discount rate spread; since 1985, it is only
10%. Bank failures in the late 1980s may
have made banks hesitant to visit the discount window lest market participants
perceive its use as a sign of weakness.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Trillions of dollars
7.6 THE M3 AGGREGATE

Trillions of dollars
5.25 THE M2 AGGREGATE

6%

5%
M2 growth, 1996–2001 a
12

M3 growth, 1996–2001 a
15

1%

2%

7.0
8

10

5%

4

4.75

6%

5
1%

0

6.4

2%

0

6%

5%

2%

1%

5.8
4.25

6%

5%

2%
6%

5.2

1%

2%

5%
1%

4.6

3.75
10/96

10/97

10/98

10/99

M2 COMPONENTS

10/00

10/96

10/01

10/97

10/98

10/99

10/00

10/01

Trillions of dollars
1.0 NON-M2 COMPONENTS OF M3

Large-denomination time deposits
0.8

Institutional money funds
0.5
Overnight and term repurchase agreements

0.3

Overnight and term eurodollars
0
10/96

10/97

10/98

10/99

10/00

10/01

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2001 growth rates for M2 and M3 are calculated on a
January over 2000:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
NOTE: Last plots for M2 and M3 are January 2001. Prior to November 2000, dotted lines for M2 and M3 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges. Subsequent
dotted lines represent growth rates and are for reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Growth in the broad monetary
aggregates accelerated sharply in January.
Annualized year-to-date M2 growth
reached 10.2% and annualized year-todate M3 growth hit a remarkable 13.2%.
The annualized monthly changes for
these aggregates were the largest posted
in the last 10 years (13.1% and 17.9%,
respectively).
The components of M2 reveal that
about 8.5 percentage points of the
13.1% January increase can be attributed
equally to demand deposits and retail

money market mutual funds. The recent
buildup in these components, however,
results primarily from transitory factors.
Much of the increase in demand deposits, for example, reflects a surge in
mortgage refinancings, which in turn enlarge custodial balances between the time
old mortgages are extinguished and the
time when payment is made to mortgage-backed securities holders.
Acceleration in retail money funds, on
the other hand, reflects the recent increase in stock market uncertainty.

Money market mutual funds give tentative investors a temporary parking lot for
funds. Even as temporary factors abate,
however, M2 growth will be sustained by
recent declines in interest rates, which
lower the opportunity cost of holding
money.
As for M3, about 11 percentage
points of its nearly 18% January increase
comes from institutional money market
mutual funds and large-denomination
certificates of deposit (CDs), with most
(continued on next page)

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Daily, 2001
1,500

Percent of income
16

Ratio
8 HOUSEHOLD FINANCIAL POSITION a

Index, January 31, 1981=100
2,400 STOCK MARKET INDEXES

NASDAQ

7

12

1,300

1,800

S&P 500

900
Jan.

1,200

Personal saving rate

NASDAQ

1,100

Feb.

6

8

5

4

Mar.

600

Wealth-to-income ratio

4

S&P 500

0

3

0
1980

1985

1990

1995

Percent of disposable personal income
10 HOUSEHOLD DEBT-SERVICE BURDENS

–4
1980

2000

1985

1990

1995

2000

Percent, weekly average
9 LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

9
8
Conventional mortgage
Consumer debt
8
7
7
30-year Treasury b
6
6
Mortgage
5

5

10-year Treasury b

4

4
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Wealth is defined as household net worth. Income is defined as personal disposable income. Data are not seasonally adjusted.
b. Constant maturity.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bloomberg Financial Information Services; and W allStreet Journal.

of the rest accounted for by the increase
in M2. Institutional money funds, like retail funds, swelled as many investors
headed for the sidelines. The increase in
large CDs mirrors the sudden January
rise in commercial and industrial loans,
for which CDs are a convenient source
of funding.
The stock market remains the big
story. The sharp ascent of equity prices,
especially in the late 1990s, greatly increased household wealth, pushing up
the ratio of wealth to income almost

50%. With stock prices four times their
1990 levels, many households have seen
less reason to save part of their current
income. Indeed, the personal saving rate
has dropped below zero as wealth-induced spending grew faster than income.
After rallying in January, stock prices
drifted downward in February, erasing all
gains on the year. A key element is participants’ uncertainty about the seriousness of the current economic slowdown.
Private economic projections—such as
those of the Reserve Bank presidents

and Board of Governors—anticipate
weakness in the first half of this year,
with economic activity beginning to accelerate again about midyear.
The major impetus for this projected
rebound in growth is a cessation of inventory rebalancing. Higher energy prices, another dampening factor, could also abate.
The recent decline in both spot and futures energy prices, if sustained, could
boost purchasing power and thereby become a key support for recovering demand over the rest of the year.
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent of total assets
50 COMPONENTS OF HOUSEHOLD ASSETS

COMPONENTS OF HOUSEHOLD LIABILITIES

Finanical non-equity-related assets
40

Real estate
30

20
Financial equity-related assets a

10
Tangible non–real estate
0
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Ratio
8.2 HOUSEHOLD ASSETS/LIABILITIES

Index, 1966:IQ =100
120 CONSUMER ATTITUDES b
Sentiment

7.8
100

7.4
80

7.0

60

6.6

Expectations

6.2

40

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Equity-related assets are defined as corporate equities, mutual fund shares, and pension fund reserves.
b. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and University of Michigan, Survey of Consumers.

Another likely contributor to household purchasing power in 2001 is the recent surge in mortgage refinancing. Refinancing reduces households’debt-service
burdens, freeing up funds for spending
on other goods and services. Moreover,
home equity financing has given households an important means of consolidating consumer debt. Because home equity
loan rates are substantially lower than
rates paid on credit card debt, such consolidation offers households another way
to reduce their overall debt burden.

As stock prices soared in the late
1990s, equity-related assets approached
45% of total household assets, up from
about 15% in 1980. During the same period, the ratio of household assets to liabilities declined. This raises concerns
about households’ financial vulnerability
to the vagaries of the stock market. And,
as Chairman Greenspan noted in his
February 13 testimony, changes in stock
market wealth have become more important than changes in current household income when it comes to determining shifts in consumer spending.

Sharply lower equity prices seem to
affect consumer confidence as well. The
University of Michigan’s indexes on consumer sentiment and expectations both
fell in February but were revised up from
preliminary estimates. Although all measures of consumer confidence have
fallen precipitously in recent months,
their levels nonetheless remain higher
than those that formerly have been consistent with economic growth.

8
Unemployment in Canada and the U.S.
Percent
69 LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

Percent
14 UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

67

12
Canada

65

10

Canada
63

8

U.S.
61

6
59
U.S.
4

57

55

2
1/1/76

1/1/80

1/1/84

1/1/88

1/1/92

1/1/96

1/1/70

1/1/00

1/1/75

1/1/80

1/1/85

1/1/90

Percent
82 MALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

Percent
65 FEMALE LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION

80

60

1/1/95

1/1/00

1/1/95

1/1/00

U.S.
78

55

76

50
U.S.

74

45
Canada

Canada
72

40

70
1/1/70

35
1/1/75

1/1/80

1/1/85

1/1/90

1/1/95

1/1/00

1/1/70

1/1/75

1/1/80

1/1/85

1/1/90

FRB Cleveland

March 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics and Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; Bank of Canada; and Statistics Canada.

Since the early 1980s, the U.S. unemployment rate has been about two percentage
points lower than Canada’s. Before that
time, the two countries’ unemployment
rates were almost identical. The relative
strength of the U.S. economy can account for its lower unemployment in the
1990s, but what might explain the differences in the previous decade?
U.S. unemployment insurance benefits became taxable in the 1980s, while eligibility requirements became tougher
and benefits shrank. Over the same period, Canada’s unemployment insurance
system changed little, if at all. As a result,

the U.S. system became relatively less
generous. A less generous system gave
some unemployed U.S. workers an incentive to take jobs that were previously unacceptable, thus lowering the country’s
unemployment rate. But the story does
not end there. Other workers had an incentive to exit the labor market in the
1980s because of changes in the U.S. system, lowering U.S. participation rates relative to Canada’s.
The difference in the two countries’
participation rates did, in fact, narrow.
Before the 1980s, the U.S. rate was higher
than Canada’s but their positions reversed over the decade.

U.S. participation rates for both men
and women fell relative to Canada’s. Participation rates for males have generally
fallen over the past 30 years. During the
1980s, however, men’s rates fell to a
lesser degree in Canada than in the U.S.
Participation rates for females have generally risen over the past 30 years. Until
the early 1980s, U.S. females’ participation rates exceeded Canadian females’.
During the 1980s, female participation
rates were about the same for both countries, implying a relative decline for U.S.
women during that decade.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Canada/U.S. Exchange Rate
Canadian dollars per U.S. dollar
1.6 CANADA/U.S. EXCHANGE RATE

12-month percent change
16 CONSUMER PRICE INDEX
14

1.5

12
1.4
10
Canada
1.3

8

1.2

6
4

1.1
2
U.S.
1.0

0

0.9

–2
1/1/71

1/1/76

1/1/81

1/1/86

1/1/91

1/1/96

1/1/01

Percent
12 REAL TREASURY RATES

9/1/79

9/1/83

9/1/87

9/1/91

9/1/95

9/1/99

Percent of GDP
80 GOVERNMENT DEBT

10
Canada 3-month Treasury bill

8

70

6
60

4
2

Canada
50

0
U.S. 3-month Treasury bill

U.S.

–2

40

–4
–6

30

–8
–10

20
1/1/80

1/1/84

1/1/88

1/1/92

1/1/96

1/1/00

1/1/80

1/1/84

1/1/88

1/1/92

1/1/96

1/1/00

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics and Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; Bank of Canada; and Statistics Canada.

Before 1976, the exchange rate between
the U.S. and Canadian dollar was typically not far from one. The U.S. dollar
appreciated
significantly against
Canada’s in 1976–85 and again between
1991 and the present. The reasons behind these appreciations, especially the
present one, are a puzzle.
Currencies may appreciate or depreciate relative to one another for several
reasons. If one country’s inflation rate is
higher than another’s, then one might
expect the currency of the higher-inflation country to depreciate because its
real value is eroding faster. Although in-

flation rate differentials may explain the
initial run-up in the exchange rate, they
do a poor job of explaining the run-up
after 1991—Canada’s inflation rate has
been consistently lower than that of the
U.S. during this period.
If one country’s real interest rate is
lower than another’s, the currency
associated with the lower rate would be
expected to depreciate. Real interest rate
differentials in Canada and the U.S., measured by real Treasury bill rate differentials, cannot explain exchange rate movements. Canada’s real interest rate was
higher than the U.S.’s in 1984–86 and

from 1991 to the mid-1990s, periods
when the exchange rate appreciated.
A country with consistently higher
government deficits than another may
experience a currency depreciation, possibly because of fear that it will pay off
its debt by the inflationary method of
simply printing money. As a percent of
GDP, federal government debt in
Canada has closely tracked that of the
U.S. for the past 15 years. Hence, levels
of federal debt, like inflation and real interest rate differentials, fail to explain
Canada/U.S. exchange rate movements
after 1991.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Contribution to percent change in GDP
0.20 PERCENTAGE-POINT CHANGE FROM ADVANCE

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IVQ

TO PRELIMINARY ESTIMATE, 2000:IVQ

(Preliminary estimate)
Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

Change,
billions
of 1996 $

Real GDP
Personal consumption
Durables
Nondurables
Services
Business fixed
investment
Equipment
Structures
Residential investment
Government spending
National defense
Net exports
Exports
Imports
Change in business
inventories

24.7
43.9
–6.5
3.8
44.0

1.1
2.8
–2.8
0.8
5.0

3.4
4.5
5.3
3.8
4.7

–2.3
–10.3
6.1
–3.2
10.7
7.4
–15.2
–18.1
–2.8

–0.6
–3.5
8.8
–3.5
2.7
8.8
—
–6.1
–0.7

10.3
9.7
12.3
–2.6
1.2
–2.0
—
6.8
11.5

–13.0

—

—

Business
fixed investment
0.10

Change in
inventories

0

Imports
Personal
consumption

Government
spending

Residential
investment

–0.10

–0.20
Exports

–0.30

Annualized percent change from previous quarter
6 GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST a

Contribution to percent change in GDP
2.5 COMPONENTS OF REAL GDP, 2000:IVQ
2.0
Advance estimate

Final percent change

5

Blue Chip forecast c
Advance estimate
Preliminary estimate

Preliminary estimate
1.5
4

30-year average
1.0
3
0.5

0

Business
fixed
investment
Personal
consumption

Change in
inventories

Imports

2
Government
spending

Residential
investment

1

–0.5
Exports

0

–1.0

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2001

IVQ

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
c. Blue Chip forecasts for current and future periods are based on Blue Chip Economic Indicators, February 10, 2001. Past-quarter predictions are based on
Blue Chip Economic Indicators three months prior to the end of a quarter.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, February 10, 2001.

According to the recently released preliminary estimate, real GDP growth in
2000:IVQ was somewhat weaker than reported in the advance estimate—1.1%
compared to 1.4%. Growth in inventory
investment and exports was revised downward substantially, while growth in business
investment and imports increased.
Declining exports and inventory investment were the largest contributors to relatively weak output growth in 2000:IVQ.
Residential investment, traditionally a leading indicator, also declined, albeit by less
than in the previous quarter. Business

fixedinvestment fell slightly, a result of the
first outright decline in the equipment and
software component in almost a decade.
One explanation for the U.S. economy’s
remarkable growth during the 1990s is
that it reaped the benefits of previous investments in information technology. If
this is true, the decline in equipment and
software investment may foreshadow
slower growth. Personal consumption
grew at a slower pace than in previous
quarters, and growth in government
spending increased relative to past quarters. The decline in exports accounted for

much of the fall in output growth.
The Blue Chip forecast suggests that
GDP mayweaken further in 2001:IQ, but
it is expected to regain strength later in the
year. By the end of 2001, forecasters predict output growth will return to its historical average. Forecasters, however, have
tended to predict a reversion to the historical mean output growth: They were surprised on the upside in the first half of
2000 and on the downside in the last half
of that year.
One of the major industries in the
Fourth District is steel production. Accord(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Billions of 1982 dollars
6.5

Index, 1982=100
125 STEEL IMPORTS

Percent
40 SOURCES OF U.S. STEEL IMPORTS

30
5.7

120

Asia

PPI, steel products

EU

20
115

4.9

Mexico

10
110

Oceania

4.1

0

Real steel imports

105

Canada

–10

2.5

Other
European a

Other
Western
Hemisphere
Year-over-year growth in U.S. imports

3.3

100

Africa

Share of total U.S. imports

–20

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Billions of dollars
4 ANNUAL PROFIT OF STEEL AND IRON PRODUCERS

150 STEEL CAPACITY AND UTILIZATION

3

140

2
130
1
120
0

Capacity (percent of 1992 production)
110

–1
Production Index, 1992=100 b
100

–2

–3

90
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Includes Russia.
b. Product of capacity-utilization rate and steel capacity.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and American Iron and Steel Institute.

ing to the American Iron and Steel Institute,
the U.S. industry “has been severelyweakened by high levels of dumped, subsidized
and disruptive steel imports.” Recently, the
Institute called for temporary import quotas to stabilize the industry.
Presumably, imports of foreign steel
drive down U.S. steel prices. Experience in
the 1990s lends some credibility to this
story: Steel prices rose sharply in 1995–96
as steel imports fell, and prices fell in
1997–99 as steel imports rose. There must
be more to the story, though, because prices
also increased in 1994–95, a period when
imports rose.

Asia, the European Union, and the rest
of Europe are the largest exporters of steel
to the U.S. Our NAFTA partners, Canada
and Mexico, are also important sources.
Growth of exports to the U.S. was
strongest in Europe, exclusive of the European Union.
After declining in the early 1990s, the
U.S. steel industry’s capacity has risen. Capacity utilization fluctuated throughout the
decade and appears to be positively correlated with steel prices. For the most part,
total U.S. steel production rose during the
1990s.

Profits in the steel industry appear to
move fairly closely with the price of steel.
Undoubtedly, the U.S. steel industry was
pleased when a U.S. trade panel recently
voted 6–0 to allow the Commerce Department to continue its investigations of
“dumping” (selling below cost) of hotrolled steel exports by 11 nations. The European Union, Brazil, Chile, India, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, and Thailand have
disputed these charges as being illegal under
international trade rules.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Variance
1.0 INEQUALITY OF INCOME AND CONSUMPTION

0.9
0.8
0.7
Income
0.6
0.5
Consumption
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
24

26

28

30

32

34

36

38

40

42

44

46

48
50
Age

52

54

56

58

60

62

64

66

68

70

72

74

72

74

Variance
1.0 INCOME INEQUALITY BY SCHOOLING
0.9
0.8

College degree

0.7
0.6
Some high school

High school diploma

0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
24

26

28

30

32

34

36

38

40

42

44

46

48
50
Age

52

54

56

58

60

62

64

66

68

70

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

SOURCE: Kjetil Storesletten, Chris I. Telmer, and Amir Yaron, “Consumption and Risk Sharing over the Life Cycle,” unpublished manuscript, September 2000.

In the U.S., inequality among individuals
in both consumption and income increases with age, although it is unclear
how large a role income inequality plays
in consumption inequality. The question
is important because the design of public
policy programs, such as welfare reform
and unemployment insurance, could benefit greatly from identifying the sources
of individuals’ risk and uncertainty.
At least some progress is being made
in narrowing the range of explanations
for age-related income inequality. Some

inequality, predictable even before a person is old enough to enter the labor market, is determined by preconditions, like
family background and schooling, that
affect individuals’ incomes throughout
their working lives. Programs like unemployment insurance would have only a
minor effect if the dominant sources of
inequality were fixed early in life.
Evidently, such preconditions do not
loom large in explaining why
income inequality increases with age;

variations among individuals at a given
age do not differ substantially across
schooling groups, leaving little variance
to be explained by preconditions. It appears that random but persistent shocks
over workers’ lifetimes, perhaps from
plant closings, technological change, and
so on, must lead to the observed increase
in inequality with age. Recent research
suggests that roughly 40% of the age-related increase in income inequality can be
explained by such shocks.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Production Workers’ Earnings
Annual percent change
12 GROWTH IN REAL EARNINGS AND INFLATION

Hourly earnings in 2000 dollars
16.50 REAL AVERAGE HOURLY EARNINGS

Inflation

16.00
9

15.50
15.00
Manufacturing

Private nonfarm

6

14.50
14.00
3
13.50

Average hourly earnings
Private service-producing

13.00

0

12.50
Real average hourly earnings
–3

12.00
1970

1974

1978

1982

1986

1990

1994

1970

1998

1974

1978

1982

1986

1990

1994

1998

Thousands of 1999 dollars
65 FAMILY INCOME

Annual percent change
5.0 OTHER MEASURES OF REAL COMPENSATION
4.0

60

3.0
Mean family income

Employment Cost Index

2.0

55

1.0
50

0

Median family income

–1.0
45

Compensation per hour

–2.0
40

–3.0
1979

1983

1987

1991

1995

1999

1975

1979

1983

1987

1991

1995

1999

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

The American economy has experienced
a 60% increase in real per capita output
since 1970. However, this has not translated into large gains in private production workers’ real average hourly earnings, which consist of their hourly
compensation (wages and benefits) as reported by employers. In fact, private production workers’ real hourly earnings,
after falling nearly $2 an hour between
1972 and the mid-1990s, only recently
returned to the mid-1980s level (about
$14 an hour in 2000 dollars). Production

(or nonsupervisory) workers, as
defined here, comprise slightly more
than 80% of the private labor force, a
share that has remained roughly constant
for 30 years.
Much research has focused on
explaining why production workers’ average real hourly earnings have fallen in
an expanding economy. Measurement
flaws with this series is one such explanation. But there is little doubt that the
three major spikes in the inflation rate in
the 1970s and 1980s contributed to erosion in hourly earnings.

Other measures of compensation,
however, such as total compensation
from the Employment Cost Index and
real compensation per hour from productivity data, which cover a different
subset of the labor force and employ different methodologies, have shown overall growth since the late 1970s.
In addition, despite some intermittent
declines, overall family income has risen
since 1975. Much of this growth, however, may result from the increasing
number of two-worker families.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Automobile Industry
Units, seasonally adjusted
3.20 INVENTORY/SALES RATIO FOR

Millions of units
19 AUTOMOBILE AND TRUCK SALES

DOMESTICALLY PRODUCED AUTOS

Actual

Forecast

2.95

18

2.70

17
2.45

16
2.20

15
1.95

14

1.70

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Index, 1992=100
185 PRODUCTION OF MOTOR VEHICLES AND PARTS

01/96

01/97

01/98

01/99

01/00

01/01

AUTO WORKERS IN THE FOURTH DISTRICT

165

145

Areas with 1,000 or more auto workers
125

105
01/96

01/97

01/98

01/99

01/00

01/01

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
and Blue Chip Economic Indicators.

U.S. motor vehicle sales reached new highs
in 1999 and 2000, but forecasters do not
expect
this
trend
to
continue. The February 2001 edition of
Blue
Chip
Economic
Indicators
reported a consensus forecast that sales
would fall to 16.0 million in 2001 (a drop
of roughly 10%) and rebound slightly to
16.3 million in 2002.
Evidence of this slowdown in
automobile and truck sales has
already appeared in auto industry data.
Although sales were strong for last year
as a whole, the inventory-to-sales ratio

for domestically produced autos rose
fairly steadily from April to November
and then jumped precipitously in December.
As unit sales of domestic automobiles
fell from a seasonally adjusted annual
rate of 6.8 million in August 2000 to 5.7
million in December (a drop of 16%),
manufacturers of motor vehicles and
parts cut production to keep their inventories from rising further. In December
2000, production of motor vehicles and
parts hit the lowest level seen since June
and July 1998, when work stoppages at

two General Motors plants in Flint,
Michigan, idled more than 71,000 workers at assembly plants across the country.
The slowdown in the auto industry will
have a noticeable effect on the economy of
the Fourth District; in the metropolitan statistical areas of Cleveland–Akron, Dayton–Springfield, Pittsburgh, Toledo, and
Youngstown– Warren, large numbers of
workers are employed by auto makers or
suppliers.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Steel Industry
Annualized percent change
60 SALES OF IRON AND STEEL

Hours per week, seasonally adjusted
46.0 WORKERS’ AVERAGE WEEKLY HOURS:
BLAST FURNACES AND STEEL MILLS
45.5

40

45.0
20
44.5
0
44.0

–20
43.5

–40

43.0
I

II III IV
1996

I

II III IV
1997

I

II III IV
1998

I

II III IV
1999

I

I I III
2000

Billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted
21.0 NEW ORDERS: BLAST FURNACES AND STEEL MILLS

1/99

7/99

1/00

7/00

1/01

STEEL WORKERS IN THE FOURTH DISTRICT

19.5

18.0

Areas with 1,000 or more steel workers
16.5

15.0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The recent troubles of Cleveland’s LTV
Steel Corporation have brought regional
focus to the health of the U.S. steel industry. Sales of iron and steel decelerated
steadily in terms of annualized growth
rates during the first two quarters of
2000, then declined abruptly in the third
quarter. Although the third-quarter decline in growth was not remarkable, having become a regular feature of iron and
steel sales in recent years, the secondquarter growth decline was. Even during
the last recession, growth in the iron and
steel industry accelerated during the sec-

ond quarter. The industry has not experienced a second-quarter slowdown in
growth since 1989.
Decelerating sales have been
accompanied by a decline in the average
weekly hours of workers at blast furnaces and steel mills: Except for a very
small increase in September (0.1 hours),
workers’ average hours have been falling
since July 2000.
The decrease in sales and average
weekly hours, not surprisingly, coincides
with a decline in new orders for blast furnaces and steel mills, which began after

2000:IQ and persisted through the end
of the year. New orders declined from
June to December of last year, with only
a modest increase (0.7%) in September.
The industry’s slowdown will affect
several Fourth District areas where large
numbers of workers are employed in
producing iron and steel. Areas that are
sensitive to changes in the industry include the Cleveland–Akron, Huntington–Ashland, Pittsburgh, Steubenville–
Weirton, and Youngstown–Warren metropolitan statistical areas.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Lending by Depository Institutions
Percent of domestic respondents, net a
60 INSTITUTIONS REPORTING STRONGER DEMAND

Percent of domestic respondents, net a
80 INSTITUTIONS TIGHTENING STANDARDS

FOR COMMERCIAL AND INDUSTRIAL LOANS b

FOR COMMERCIAL AND INDUSTRIAL LOANS b
40
60

Large and middle-market firms
20
40
Small firms
0

Large and middle-market firms
20

–20
Small firms
0

–40

–60

–20
IQ

IIQ IIIQ
1998

IVQ

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IQ
2001

Billions of dollars
Billions of dollars
1,150 COMMERCIAL AND INDUSTRIAL LENDING, 1999–2001
20

IIQ IIIQ
1998

IVQ

IQ

10

1,050

IVQ

IQ

IIQ IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ
2001

Billions of dollars
Billions of dollars
1,200 COMMERCIAL AND INDUSTRIAL LENDING, 1994–2001
40
Loan volume

1,100
1,100

IIQ IIIQ
1999

1,000

20

900

10

800

0

700

–10

0

1,000

Trend

–10
Loan volume
600
Variation from trend

950
6/99

8/99 10/99 12/99 2/00

4/00

6/00

8/00 10/00 12/00

Trend

–20
Variation from trend

–20
4/99

–30
500
1/94 7/94 1/95 7/95 1/96 7/96 1/97 7/97 1/98 7/98 1/99 7/99 1/00 7/00 1/01

2001

a. Net percent, excluding respondents reporting no change.
b. The quarters indicated correspond to the publication dates of the survey and include data from the previous quarter.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,” Federal Reserve Surveys and
Reports; and “Assets and Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the United States,” Federal Reserve Statistical Release, H.8.

FRB Cleveland•March

30

In the last quarter of 2000, the net share of
commercial banks’ senior loan officers
(domestic and foreign) who reported
tightening their lending standards on commercial and industrial loans reached 60%
for loans to large and middle-market firms
and 45% for loans to small firms. This is
the latest and largest addition to the tightening trend that loan officers have been reporting since 1998:IVQ. Parallel to tighter
standards, senior loan officers reported declining demand for commercial and industrial loans; 50% (net) reported weaker loan

demand from large and middle-market
firms and 30% reported weaker demand
from small firms.
Commercial and industrial lending data
for 1999–2001 seem to support the declining-demand argument. Although the
dollar volume of commercial and industrial loans reached its highest-ever level of
$1,104 billion in January 2001, it has been
below trend since October 2000. The
shortfall was $11 billion in December
2000 and is currently about $3 billion.
However, it is not clear whether these

facts should be interpreted as signs of
weak bank lending or merely a myopic
comparison of current performance to
the most recent data. When we compare
the commercial and industrial loan volume
in January 2001 to the trend over a longer
period of time (1994–2001, for example)
rather than just the last two years, the current volume is $17 billion above trend.
From this longer-range perspective, the
decline in loan demand in 2000:IVQ may
(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Lending by Depository Institutions (cont.)
Percent of domestic respondents, net a
20 INSTITUTIONS INDICATING MORE WILLINGNESS

Percent of domestic respondents, net a
40 INSTITUTIONS REPORTING STRONGER

TO MAKE CONSUMER INSTALLMENT LOANS b

DEMAND FOR LOANS TO HOUSEHOLDS b

15

20

10

0
Consumer loans

5

–20
Residential mortgages

0

–40

–5

–60

–10

–80
IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

1999

IIIQ

IVQ

2000

Billions of dollars
540 OUTSTANDING CONSUMER LOANS

IQ
2001

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

1999

Billions of dollars
60

IIIQ

IVQ

2000

Billions of dollars
1,600 TOTAL CONSUMER CREDIT OUTSTANDING

IQ
2001

Billions of dollars
80

BY COMMERCIAL BANKS

30

1,400

440

0

1,200

390

–30

1,000

490

40

Trend

Trend

Loan volume

0

–40
Loan volume

Variation from trend

340
–60
1/94 7/94 1/95 7/95 1/96 7/96 1/97 7/97 1/98 7/98 1/99 7/99 1/00 7/00 1/01

Variation from trend

800

–80
1/94 7/94 1/95 7/95 1/96 7/96 1/97 7/97 1/98 7/98 1/99 7/99 1/00 7/00 1/01

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. Net percent, excluding respondents reporting no change.
b. The quarters indicated correspond to the publication dates of the survey and include data from the previous quarter.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,” Federal Reserve Surveys and
Reports; and “Consumer Credit,” Federal Reserve Statistical Release, G.19.

be interpreted as a return to trend from
the exuberance of early 2000.
On the consumer lending side, 6%
(net) of senior loan officers surveyed in
January 2001 reported that they are less
willing to make consumer loans than they
were in previous quarters. Their pessimism parallels the weakness in consumer loan demand that they have been
reporting since 1999:IVQ. In 2000:IVQ,
36% (net) of the senior loan officers surveyed said that they faced a weaker consumer loan market. There has been no

change in the demand for residential
mortgages.
Supporting the reported decline in
consumer loan demand, the dollar volume of consumer lending by commercial banks declined steadily from a high
of $514 billion in August 1997 to a low
of $482 billion in October 1999. The
good news is that the volume of outstanding consumer loans by commercial
banks has been increasing ever since. As
of December 2000, commercial banks
had $535 billion in outstanding con-

sumer loans, which was $7 billion above
trend.
It may be helpful to look at the size of
the entire consumer loan market (such as
commercial banks, finance companies,
and credit unions) to understand why consumer lending by commercial banks
dropped in 1998 and 1999. The data show
that the size of outstanding loans has been
increasing steadily in recent years. Therefore, the decline in commercial bank lending may be partly attributable to a loss of
market share. As of December 2000, the
dollar volume of total outstanding consumer loans was $15 billion above trend.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

International Monetary Policy Rates
Percent
8 UNITED STATES

Percent
8 EURO ZONE

7

7
Target rate

6

Marginal lending facility

6
Discount rate

5

5
Euro overnight interbank average b

Federal funds rate a
4

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

Main refinancing operations

0

Deposit facility

0
1/1/99

5/1/99

9/1/99

1/1/00

5/1/00

9/1/00

1/1/01

Percent
8 UNITED KINGDOM

1/1/99

5/1/99

9/1/99

1/1/00

5/1/00

9/1/00

1/1/01

Percent
0.55 JAPAN
0.50

7

Discount rate
0.45

6

0.40
0.35

5

Call money rate

0.30
4

Bank of England repo rate
Sterling overnight interbank average c

3

0.25
Target rate

0.20
0.15

2

0.10
1
0.05
0

0
1/1/99

5/1/99

9/1/99

1/1/00

5/1/00

9/1/00

1/1/01

1/1/99

5/1/99

9/1/99

1/1/00

5/1/00

9/1/00

1/1/01

FRB Cleveland • March 2001

a. The weighted average rate on trades made through New York City brokers.
b. The weighted average rate on all overnight, unsecured lending transactions in the interbank market, initiated within the euro area by contributing panel banks.
c. The weighted average rate of all brokered, unsecured sterling overnight deals between money market institutions and their overseas branches, transacted
between midnight and 3:30 p.m. GMT.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Wholesale Markets Brokers Association.

The central banks of other major countries have not imitated the Federal Open
Market Committee’s 100 basis point (bp)
easing of the federal funds rate target in
January. The Governing Council of the
European Central Bank kept rates unchanged at its February 1 meeting, but
acknowledged that “risks to price stability in the medium term nowappear more
balanced than at the end of last year.”
At its February 8 meeting, the Bank
of England’s Monetary Policy Committee, seeing “inflation most likely to continue below the 2.5% target for quite a
while,” adopted a precautionary or grad-

ualist reduction of 25 bp in the Bank’s
repo (repurchase) rate. The inflation rate
of 1.8% for the year ending in January
remained within the allowable symmetrical 1.0% band around the 2.5% target.
An inflation rate below this band would
trigger a compulsory letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining the
divergence from target.
The Bank of Japan left the overnight
call rate target (0.25%) unchanged at its
February 9 meeting. While maintaining
its scenario of “moderate recovery led
by private demand,” the Bank noted
more pronounced risk elements

“involving U.S. economic developments
and stock markets.” The Bank did adopt
a new Lombard-type lending facility,
designed to help stabilize short-term interest rates. Starting in March 2001,
overnight loans will be extended at the
request of eligible counterparties (banks,
securities companies, tanshi money market dealers, and securities finance dealers) at the basic discount rate, which was
reduced from 0.50% to 0.35%. The intention is to cap the overnight call loan
rate when market disturbances otherwise
would push it more than 10 bp above the
current target.