View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

The Economy in Perspective

Hanging in the balance…According to Fed-watchers,
the Federal Reserve is nearing a crossroads in its
thinking about the need for further reductions in
the federal funds rate. On one hand, they say, the
economy remains weak despite the 2½ percentage
point reduction already made this year; on the other
hand, there are some signs that inflation and inflation expectations may be stirring. Since the Fed is
presumed to be sensitive to both inflation and the
pace of economic growth, it is reasonable for
Fed-watchers to assess carefully the balance
between the risks that pertain to each. Indeed, the
FOMC referred explicitly to the balance of risks
between economic activity and inflation in its
May 15 press release, which announced a reduction
of ½ percentage point in the funds rate.
The economy grew slowly in the last two
quarters and, judging by the little bit of hard data
available plus many anecdotal accounts, it is still
doing so. Employment, hours worked, and factory
orders all reflect a decline in activity from just six
months ago. Interest rates and credit terms reflect
the tighter standards lenders are applying to
borrowers in a broad array of financial markets.
Cash—not equity—is king. Earlier this year,
analysts looked for a quick inventory correction
and some thinning out of high-tech firms, but expected little extended damage. Now that personal
consumption spending has slowed from last year’s
torrid pace, observers have stretched out their
forecasts of stronger overall economic growth.
Those who spoke of a V-shaped recovery have
grudgingly begun to substitute the letter U.
The FOMC was certainly aware of current
conditions—and the possibility of continuing
sluggishness—when it met on May 15. Although
some aspects of the economy appeared to be
positive, its published statement indicated that
“[t]he Committee continues to believe that…the
risks are weighted mainly toward conditions that
may generate economic weakness in the foreseeable future.”
In arriving at this balance of risks, the Committee
also discussed inflation and the potential for it to
accelerate in the period ahead. Its published statement concluded that “[w]ith pressures on labor and
product markets easing, inflation is expected to
remain contained. Although measured productivity
growth stalled in the first quarter, the impressive
underlying rate of increase that developed in recent
years appears to be largely intact, supporting
longer-term prospects.”

Inflation should be thought of not as the monthly
or even yearly change in a price index, but as a persistent decline in the purchasing power of money.
Price indexes fluctuate at different rates from year to
year, and only by considering their movements over
several years can we form a clear picture of inflation. In an environment characterized by complete
price-level stability, people would expect their
money’s purchasing power to be constant over long
time horizons and would not be terribly concerned
about short periods of inflation and deflation.
Until recently, price stability in the United States
seemed a quaint notion; people’s only question
about inflation was how much of it there would be.
The FOMC has repeatedly stated its intention to
achieve price stability over time, although it has not
provided a precise numerical definition of that
goal. However, noting that the rate of increase in
the Consumer Price Index fell below 2% in 1997
and again in 1998—and recognizing possible upward biases in the index—many people believed
that price stability finally had arrived. Since that
time, price indexes generally have been rising at
greater rates, and inflation expectations have
picked up as well. Has price stability slipped away?
In reality, price stability may not truly have been
reached. A more accurate assessment of inflation in
the 1990s may be that not much progress
toward price stability was made at all. Between
1990 and the present, the CPI, the CPI excluding
food and energy, and the median CPI each increased about 3% annually on average, making a
cumulative gain of 40%. The bountiful years of 1997
and 1998 must be balanced against some of the
leaner years. The current performance of the CPI
and the median CPI, in the range of a 3.5% annual
rate, looks less aberrant when compared to the
decade-long trend than when measured against
the experience of 1997–98 alone.
As the economy regains some of its lost momentum and the effects of oil price shocks dissipate, we
will have additional opportunities to evaluate our
money’s purchasing power. Price stability remains a
laudable goal, and the FOMC has the ability to
achieve it over time. It appears, however, as though
its time has not yet come. Nevertheless, we understand that for now, inflationary pressures are expected
to remain contained.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
CPI ENERGY

April Price Statistics
Annualized percent
change, last:
2000
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr. avg.

Consumer prices
All items

3.5

2.5

3.3

2.5

3.4

Less food
and energy

2.6

3.1

2.7

2.4

2.5

Medianb

3.9

4.0

3.5

2.9

3.2

Finished goods

3.4

1.4

3.6

1.7

3.6

Less food
and energy

2.4

0

1.6

1.1

1.3

Producer prices

12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND MEDIAN CPI

3.75

3.75

3.50

3.50
3.25

3.25
CPI
3.00

3.00

2.75

2.75

2.50

2.50

2.25

2.25

Median CPI b

CPI excluding food and energy
2.00

2.00

1.75

1.75

1.50

1.50

CPI

1.25
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1.25
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Following a modest 0.1% increase in
March, the Consumer Price Index
(CPI) rose 0.3% in April. A 1.8%
surge in energy prices contributed to
the jump in retail prices. Energy
prices, which tend to behave erratically from month to month, have
been exceedingly volatile this year,
contributing to uncertainty about
where the inflation trend is headed.
Even within the energy components,
price behavior has been volatile and
mixed: In April, motor fuel prices registered an extreme increase (4.8%),

while household fuel oils posted one
of the month’s sharpest retail price
declines and natural gas and electricity prices also fell.
Energy prices aside, consumer
inflation has risen steadily since the
beginning of 2000. The 12-month
percent change in the CPI less
energy was 2.0% in January 2000,
compared to 2.8% in April 2001. The
upward pattern is essentially the
same for the CPI less food and
energy, while the median CPI, another measure of core prices, has

risen even more sharply over this
same period. In January 2000, the
12-month percent change in the median CPI was 2.4%; the reading for
the most recent 12 months was 3.5%.
The impact of recent price behavior
on consumers’ inflation psychology
has been muted. When energy prices
first spiked upward in early 1999,
households appear to have responded
by ratcheting up their inflation expectations a full percentage point. Since
then, inflation expectations have hovered around 3.5%, perhaps reflecting a
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
12-month percent change
5.0 HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS AND CPI

12-month percent change
25 COMMODITY SPOT PRICES b

4.5

20
15

4.0
Year-ahead inflation expectations a

10

3.5

5

3.0

0

2.5

–5
CPI

–10

2.0
–15
1.5

–20

1.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

–25
1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

Annualized quarterly percent change
5 CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST d

12-month percent change
40 GOLD BULLION SPOT PRICE c
30

4
20
Highest 10%

CPI
10

3
Consensus

0
2

–10

–20

Lowest 10%
1

–30
0

–40
1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
b. As measured by the Knight–Ridder Commodity Research Bureau’s Composite Spot Index, all commodities.
c. London fix, p.m.
d. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Commodity Research Bureau; Wall Street Journal; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators,
May 10, 2001.

belief that most energy price changes
are unlikely to worsen from their
recent—but high—growth trend. Yet
the continued persistence of price
increases outside the energy area
(suggested by the core inflation
measures) may be undermining the
public’s inflation expectations; survey data show a modest increase in
households’ inflation expectations
for the next 12 months.
Not all indicators point to a worsening inflation trend. Industrial
commodity price movements, which

some economists consider a leading
indicator of inflation at the retail
level, have failed to show any sustained upward movement for almost
five years (although the rate at
which commodity prices are declining has clearly diminished). Nor
have gold prices, which some claim
are the harbinger of an inflationary
upturn, shown any convincing upward movement for many years.
Conflicting signals about the inflation
data are reflected in widely divergent
forecasts of inflation. Economists con-

tinue to disagree regarding the inflation
outlook: The consensus view shows
the CPI trend moderating at around
2½% over the next year and a half;
other economists, however, see the CPI
holding above 3%, as it has done for
the past year and a half. Inflation optimists see the inflation trend falling
below a 2% threshold this year and
next, nearly equaling the low inflation
readings of the late 1990s.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent
7.25 RESERVE MARKET RATES

Percent
5.00 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

6.75
Intended federal funds rate
6.25

4.75

Effective federal funds rate a

March 21, 2001
4.50

5.75

5.25

4.25
May 14, 2001

April 19, 2001

Discount rate

4.75

4.00
May 16, 2001
4.25
3.75
3.75

June 6, 2001

3.25

3.50
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Apr.

2001

Percent
SOMA PORTFOLIO OF GOVERNMENT BONDS BY MATURITY b

100

May

June

July

Aug.
2001

Sept.

Oct.

Nov.

Dec.

Jan.
2002

Percent of outstanding Treasury securities
35 SOMA SHARE BY MATURITY DATE c

30
More than 10 years
5–10 years

80

Treasury bills

1–5 years
Less than 1 year

25

60
Notes and bonds with maturities less than 1 year
20
Maturities 1–2 years

40

Maturities 2–5 years

15
Maturities 5–10 years

20

Maturities more than 10 years
10

0
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

July

Aug. Sept. Oct.
2000

Nov.

Dec.

Jan.

Feb. Mar. Apr.
2001

May June

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Weekly average.
b. Holdings for all years are as of the end of May.
c. Weighted average of the share of security issues held by SOMA.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Federal Reserve Bank of
New York; and Chicago Board of Trade.

The Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) lowered the intended federal
funds rate 50 basis points (bp) to 4% at
its May 15 meeting. Its press release
cited weakened business profitability
as a factor in reduced spending on
capital equipment. Separately, the
Board of Governors approved Reserve
Banks’ requests to lower the discount
rate 50 bp to 3.5%.
Implied yields on federal funds
futures across various maturities have
flattened since the year began, indicating reduced expectations of future

rate cuts. As of June 6, the December
contract traded at 3.8%.
In managing the System Open
Market Account (SOMA), the FOMC
attempts to maintain a relatively short,
liquid portfolio. To minimize distortions in the yield curve, the Trading
Desk has tended to spread its purchases evenly across the maturity
spectrum of Treasury securities. However, because issuance of Treasury
bills was reduced, the Desk curtailed
operations in bills from December
1997 to April 2000, increasing the
average maturity of SOMA’s portfolio.

In July 2000, the New York Fed
announced that instead of balancing
purchases across maturities, it would
make purchases consistent with shortening the portfolio’s average maturity.
It would limit holdings of each issue,
ranging from 35% of outstanding bills
and coupon securities with remaining
maturities of less than one year to 15%
of securities with maturities of more
than 10 years. Since the cap for many
Treasury bill issues currently is binding,
shortening the portfolio’s average maturity has meant buying coupon securities with maturities under two years.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Percent
1.8 INTENDED FEDERAL FUNDS RATE

Percent, weekly average
6.4 YIELD CURVES a

MINUS 2-YEAR TREASURY BOND YIELD
May 18, 2001

5.9

1.2

December 1, 2000
5.4
0.6

January 5, 2001
4.9

0

April 13, 2001
4.4

–0.6
3.9

–1.2

3.4
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Percent, daily
7.5 TREASURY SECURITIES AND SPREAD WITH TIIS

0

5

10

15
20
Years to maturity

25

30

35

Percent, weekly average
9.5 PRIVATE-SECTOR YIELDS
9.0
BAA corporate bond
8.5

5.0
10-year Treasury yield
8.0

7.5
2.5
7.0
AAA corporate bond
Yield spread: 10-year Treasury bond minus
10-year Treasury inflation-indexed securities
0
1997

Conventional mortgage

6.5

6.0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Constant maturity.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

Interest rates fell across the entire
maturity spectrum last winter, when
incoming data revealed an abrupt
weakening in economic conditions.
Initially, the yield curve remained
inverted at the low end because
investors anticipated an attenuated
response from the FOMC. This was
evident in the spread between the
intended federal funds rate and the
2-year Treasury rate, which exceeded 1 percentage point in early
March. But when the FOMC responded aggressively in early spring,
this spread fell precipitously.

Over the past two months, the
Treasury yield curve—which depicts
yields on various Treasury securities
at different maturities—has steepened dramatically, largely because of
a fall in short-term interest rates.
Mounting signs of economic weakness fostered expectations that the
FOMC would engineer a more concentrated series of fed funds rate cuts
over the course of the spring, driving
down short-term yields.
The yield curve is widely viewed
as a useful economic indicator. Historically, a steep yield curve has

been associated with a strong economy, while an inverted yield curve
often presages a recession.
The recent period, however, is
somewhat unusual. Budget surplus
projections began to reveal that the
federal government could retire its
entire debt within the next decade.
Because Treasury debt is uniquely
desired as a benchmark risk-free
asset, the prospect of a diminished
supply probably distorted yields on
Treasury bonds, keeping them artificially low relative to private debt.
More recent projections of the deficit
(continued on next page)

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent, weekly average
Percent, quarterly average
7 SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES AND M2 OPPORTUNITY COST 6

Trillions of dollars
5.25 THE M2 AGGREGATE
M2 growth, 1996–2001 b
12
9

1-year T-bill a
5

6

1%
5%

6

4.75
5

5%

1%

3

4

0

5%

3-month T-bill a
1%
3

4

4.25

5%

M2 opportunity cost
3

1%

2
5%
1%

2

1
1997

1998

1999

2000

1997

2001

Trillions of dollars
5.1 THE MZM AGGREGATE

10%

MZM growth, 1996–2001 b
20

3.75
1999

2000

2001

2002

12-month percent change
7 CONTRIBUTION TO PERCENT CHANGE IN MZM c
Institutional money market funds

10%

5%

15

4.6

1998

Savings deposits
5%

10

5

10%

5
0

5%

4.1

10%

3

5%

3.6

10%
Retail money market funds
5%

3.1

1
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Constant maturity.
b. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2001 growth rates for M2 and MZM are calculated on an
estimated May over 2000:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
c. Weighted by share of MZM.
NOTE: Last plots for M2 and MZM are estimated for May 2001. Prior to November 2000, dotted lines for M2 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges.
Subsequent and dotted lines for MZM represent growth rates and are for reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

suggest that debt retirement is less
imminent. Nonetheless, the rise in
long-term Treasury rates since January has created some concern about
whether policy actions have become
too stimulatory. In particular, the
spread between the 10-year Treasury
bond and the Treasury inflationindexed bond suggests that inflationary pressures may be intensifying.
On the other hand, yields on corporate bonds and mortgages have
not risen as dramatically, despite
robust borrowing in these markets.
Mortgage rates have stayed relatively
low, inducing a substantial volume

of refinancing. For many households, refinancing has provided
liquidity, helping to sustain moderate consumer spending despite the
economic slowdown.
The fall in short-term interest rates
has lowered the opportunity cost of
holding monetary instruments, enhancing their attractiveness relative
to other financial assets. Increased
demand for monetary aggregates
such as M2 and MZM is reflected in
their acceleration this year.
MZM includes all instruments with
zero maturity such as checking
accounts, savings deposits, and money

market mutual funds, both retail and
institutional. The sharp rise in savings
deposits over the past year occurred
largely at the expense of retail money
funds, as several mutual fund
providers initiated sweep arrangements. This arrangement—which
provides FDIC insurance on such
funds—involves regular transfers from
money funds into savings deposits at
affiliated banks. It thus reduces retail
mutual fund balances and increases
savings deposits by a like amount, but
washes out in MZM and M2.
This year’s surge in liquid assets
also reflects equity market condi(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Index, 1941–43 = 100
1,600 THE S&P 500 INDEX

Ratio
35 S&P 500 PRICE/EARNINGS RATIO

30

1,200

25
22.2
20

800

15
13.3
10

400

5
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

1945

1955

1965

1975

Dollars per share
70 S&P 500 OPERATING EARNINGS a

Index, 1966:IQ = 100
120 CONSUMER EXPECTATIONS

60

100

50

80

40

60

30

1985

1995

40
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Dashed line shows earnings estimates provided by Standard and Poors.
SOURCES: Standard and Poors Corporation; University of Michigan, Survey of Consumers; and Wall Street Journal.

tions. During periods of heightened
uncertainty, investors often park
their balances in liquid assets, which
make up MZM and M2. Many analysts believe this “money on the
sidelines” has great potential for
financing an equity market recovery
should the economic outlook become more favorable.
Although S&P 500 firms’ earnings
are expected to decline this year relative to 2000, analysts forecast sharply
accelerated earnings beginning in late
2001 and continuing through 2002.
“By all evidence,” Federal Reserve
Chairman Alan Greenspan recently

noted, “we are not yet dealing with
maturing technologies that, after having sparkled for a half decade, are now
in the process of fizzling out.” Equity
prices have strengthened somewhat
since March, suggesting that investors
are still confident about longer-term
profitability in the corporate sector.
Also, consumer expectations stabilized
in late winter and appear to be drifting
up modestly.
Stock prices’ sharp fall since early
2000 was contained largely within the
technology sector. The S&P 500 price/
earnings ratio now stands near its
1990s average of 22.2.

Asset price bubbles, like those in
the tech stocks, can be recognized
only after they burst. Nevertheless,
policymakers can and often do lean
against the economic winds that
generally accompany speculative
excesses. When stock prices correct
abruptly, policymakers may act aggressively to keep asset-price deflation
from threatening economic stability.
But monetary policy takes effect only
after long and variable lags. Given the
concentration of policy rate reductions
already taken in 2001, one might expect that future cuts, if needed, will be
more attenuated.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Saving, Investment, and International Financial Flows
Billions of dollars
200 CURRENT ACCOUNT AND COMPONENTS

Percent of GDP
1 CURRENT ACCOUNT

100

0

Income receipts
0

–1
Unilateral transfers
–100
–2
–200

Balance on goods and services

–3
–300
Current account
–400

–500
1981

–4

–5
1984

1987

1990

1993

1996

1999

1981

1984

1987

1990

1993

1996

1999

Broad Index, March 1973 = 100
130 REAL TRADE-WEIGHTED DOLLAR

Percent of GDP
23 SAVING AND INVESTMENT

125

22
Gross domestic investment

120

21
115
20

110
105

19

100

18

95
17
90
Gross domestic saving
16

85

15
1981

1984

1987

1990

1993

1996

1999

80
1/81

1/84

1/87

1/90

1/93

1/96

1/99

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The necessary counterpart to our
enormous current account deficit is
an inflow of foreign savings. Over the
past decade, our current account
deficit has generally reflected strong
U.S. investment opportunities rather
than American consumers’ profligacy.
Each year since 1991, more financial funds have flowed into the U.S.
than out of it. This net inflow of
foreign funds has helped to finance
U.S. investments at far higher levels
than domestic savings alone could

have supported. Since 1991, gross
domestic investment in the U.S. has
risen from 17% of GDP to 21.8%.
Over the same period, gross domestic saving has increased to 18.3%
of GDP.
To invest in this country, foreigners
must first acquire dollars—a process
that bids up the dollar’s foreignexchange price. Since 1996, the dollar
has appreciated 25.6% on a real tradeweighted basis. The dollar’s appreciation, however, raises the foreign

currency price of U.S. exports and
lowers the dollar price of foreign
goods and services. The current
account deficit expands until it exactly matches the dollar value of our
country’s net inflow of foreign funds.
An expanding current account deficit,
together with an appreciating dollar,
indicates that our international
accounts are driven by investment
inflows, not consumption spending.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

International Transactions and Statistical Discrepancy
Billions of dollars
100 STATISTICAL DISCREPANCY

Correlation with Statistical Discrepancya
Correlation
coefficient

50

Current account items

–0.21

0

–50

–100

Exports of goods and services

0

Imports of goods and services

0

Income receipts

0

Income payments

0

Unilateral transfers

–0.20

–150
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Correlation between Statistical Discrepancy and Financial Transactionsa

U.S.-owned assets abroad

Correlation
coefficient

Official reserve assets

–0.41

Official reserve assets

Other U.S. government assets

–0.29

Direct investments

Direct investments abroad

–0.59

U.S. Treasury securities

–0.41

Foreign securities investments

–0.29

Other U.S. securities

–0.06

Other private investments

–0.72

Other private investments

0.57

Foreign-owned assets in the U.S.

Correlation
coefficient

–0.50
0.36

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. All correlations are calculated using the first difference of published annual data, 1961–2000.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

No current account deficit can exist
without an equal inflow of foreign
investment funds. Practically speaking,
however, the measurement of trade
and financial flows is difficult and
often incomplete. Consequently, the
ledger of U.S. international transactions
contains a statistical-discrepancy term
to ensure that the current account
deficit (or surplus) is balanced against
net foreign financial flows.
The statistical discrepancy has
grown significantly since the 1960s.

Its average annual size, in absolutevalue terms, was $3.8 billion during
1960–79, but it rose to $30.7 billion
during 1980–99. Over the five years
ending in 2000, the average annual
statistical discrepancy amounted to
$47.4 billion.
Although the statistical discrepancy
aggregates measurement errors from all
components of international accounts,
economists believe that changes in the
statistical discrepancy primarily reflect
errors in the measurement of financial

flows (investors can accomplish such
transactions electronically, whereas
traders must carry goods through
ports of entry). The data seem to support this impression: The correlation
between year-to-year changes in the
statistical discrepancy and components of the financial accounts is
typically higher than the correlation
between year-to-year changes in the
statistical discrepancy and components of the trade accounts.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Contribution to percent change in GDP
0.2 PERCENTAGE POINT CHANGE FROM

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2001:IQ
Change,
billions
of 1996 $

Real GDP
30.8
Personal consumption 45.5
Durables
26.3
Nondurables
7.0
Services
16.0
Business fixed
investment
7.5
Equipment
–7.5
Structures
11.9
Residential investment
2.5
Government spending 18.5
National defense
4.7
Net exports
29.8
Exports
–7.7
Imports
–37.5
Change in business
inventories
–74.6

Government
spending

ADVANCE TO PRELIMINARY ESTIMATE

(Preliminary estimate)
Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

1.3
2.9
12.3
1.5
1.8

2.5
3.3
2.7
2.7
3.8

2.1
–2.6
17.2
2.8
4.7
5.4
—
–2.7
–9.2

5.9
4.1
11.6
–2.7
2.7
4.9
—
4.4
5.6

—

—

0.1
Change in
inventories

0

Business
fixed Residential
investment investment

Exports

–0.1
Personal
–0.2 consumption

Imports

–0.3

–0.4

–0.5

Billions of dollars
3 CHANGE IN INVENTORY LEVELS

Annualized percent change from previous quarter
4.0 GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST

2

3.5

30-year average

Manufacturing

Final percent change

3.0

1

Advance estimate
Preliminary estimate
2.5

0

Blue Chip forecast c

2.0

–1
Wholesalers
Retailers
–2

1.5

–3

1.0

–4
Oct.

0.5
Nov.
2000

Dec.

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.
2001

Apr.

IIIQ

IVQ
2000

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

2001

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
c. Blue Chip forecasts based on Blue Chip Economic Indicators, May 10, 2001.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, May 10, 2001.

Real gross domestic product (GDP)
growth was revised down 0.7 percentage point from the advance estimate to
an annualized rate of 1.3% in 2001:IQ.
The estimate of personal consumption
growth was lowered slightly but remains healthy at nearly 3%. Business
fixed investment growth was revised
up a full percentage point to 2.1%,
primarily because stronger growth in
structures more than offset a slight
drop in equipment investment. Residential investment and exports were
also off modestly, while government
spending growth was higher than originally estimated. Private inventories

made the biggest contribution to the
difference between the advance
and the preliminary estimate. During
2001:IQ, changes in private inventories
contributed –2.9 percentage points to
real GDP growth, nearly 0.5 point less
than the advance estimate of –2.4%.
The large, sudden drop in inventory
accumulation and levels may offer
hope for the still-ailing manufacturing
sector. In 2001:IQ, retailers and wholesalers cleared much of the inventory
they had accumulated when the economy weakened last year. Manufacturers were slower to start reducing
inventories but made aggressive cuts

in the last part of the quarter. Many left
their plants idle in February and
March. With excess inventory cleared
out, plants may start ramping up production again if consumer spending
stays healthy.
This was the third consecutive quarter to post real GDP growth below the
30-year average of 3.2%. Blue Chip
forecasters expect GDP growth to increase slightly in 2001:IIQ, with more
substantial recovery coming in the
third and fourth quarters, but they do
not expect quarterly growth to surpass
the 30-year average before year’s end.
(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Millions of units
6

Thousands of units
1,000 HOME SALES a
900

5

Percent of U.S. households
68 HOME OWNERSHIP b

67

New
800
66
4

700

65
600

3
64

500
2
400

63

Existing

300
1965

1
1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

62

2000

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Thousands of 1999 dollars
50 MEDIAN REAL FAMILY INCOME

Percent
12 INFLATION-ADJUSTED MORTGAGE RATES c

47
9

44
6
41
3
38

0

35

–3
1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

32
1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Single-family homes.
b. Not seasonally adjusted.
c. Contract rate for the purchase of new, single-family homes minus the year-over-year percent change in the CPI.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and
National Association of Realtors.

Since the economy began slowing
last year, housing and residential
investment have been consistently
strong sectors; in fact, they were
unusually strong throughout the most
recent expansion. New and existing
home sales have trended upward
since 1991 and now stand at nearrecord levels, despite last summer’s
slowdown and higher mortgage rates.
The result has been record rates of
home ownership. After falling in the
first half of the 1980s and staying flat
for nearly a decade, home ownership
took off after 1995. The record of
nearly 66%, set in 1980, was broken;

the rate currently stands near 68%.
While this sudden jump is unprecedented, ownership rates also rose
rapidly in the late 1960s.
Some have credited the rise in
ownership rates during the 1990s to
years of stable inflation and low
mortgage rates. The sudden rise in
mortgage rates during the early 1980s
clearly slowed home sales and probably contributed to the decrease in
home ownership. Mortgage rates
have been more stable since 1990,
though the rapid rise in ownership
did not occur until 1995. Furthermore, in the 1965–70 period of rapidly

rising ownership, mortgage rates,
though stable, were not necessarily
falling or unusually low.
Real family income seems more
directly correlated with home ownership. Median real family income grew
rapidly between 1965 and 1973, just
as ownership rates were rising. As income growth faltered in the late 1970s
and became erratic during the 1980s
and early 1990s, growth in home
ownership slowed. Once family incomes began rising steadily and consistently after 1993, ownership growth
took off again.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
350 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT GROWTH

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

300
Revised a

250

Preliminary

200
150
100
50
0
–50
–100

May
2001

1997

1998

1999

2000

Payroll employment
280
Goods-producing
47
Mining
2
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
26
Nondurable goods –2
Service-producing
232
16
TPUb
Retail trade
24
c
21
FIRE
141
Servicesd
Government
17

251
22
–3
37
–13
–2
–11
230
20
30
22
120
28

257
7
–3
26
–16
–5
–11
250
18
49
7
131
35

167 –19
8 –89
1
4
18
31
–12 –124
1 –95
–13 –29
159
70
14
12
26
–5
0
22
93
42
18
13

–150

Average for period (percent)

Civilian unemployment
rate

–200

4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

4.4

–250
1996 1997 1998 1999

2000

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.
2001

Apr.

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS

May

Percent
8.2

64.5

Thousands of jobs
Thousands of jobs
19,000 EMPLOYMENT IN MANUFACTURING AND SERVICES
42,000
Manufacturing

7.6
Employment-to-population ratio

64.0

7.0

63.5

6.4

63.0

5.8

62.5

5.2

18,750

40,600

18,500

39,200

18,250

37,800
Services d

Civilian unemployment rate
62.0

4.6
18,000

61.5

36,400

4.0

61.0
1994

3.4
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

17,750

35,000
6/97

3/98

12/98

9/99

6/00

3/01

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. The Bureau of Labor Statistics revisions to monthly employment data for March 2000 through April 2001 were released this month.
b. Transportation and public utilities
c. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
d. Services include travel, business support, recreation and entertainment, private and/or parochial education, personal services, and health services.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The downward trend in payroll employment continued in May, with a net
loss of 19,000 jobs, but this was a considerable improvement over April’s
loss of 182,000 jobs. After Bureau of
Labor Statistics revisions to previous
monthly figures, May was the second
consecutive month of net job losses.
Manufacturing’s large job losses
continued, bringing that industry’s
year-to-date net loss to 470,000. The
slowdown in services seems to have
moderated in May, with a net gain
of 70,000 jobs. Losses in business

services (due to areas other than
help supply services) persisted, as
did weakness in hotel and lodging
employment. Growth in social,
health, and educational services remained strong. Growth in finance,
insurance, and real estate (a net gain
of 22,000 jobs) was concentrated in
commercial and mortgage banking.
The unemployment rate fell 0.1
percentage point in May, leaving the
employment-to-population ratio virtually unchanged. The civilian labor
force dropped a modest 485,000 jobs

to 141.3 million, and the labor force
participation rate fell to 66.8%.
Manufacturing employment has
fallen almaost continuously since
April 1998, when it reached its peak
for the current expansion. Over the
same period, services employment
has grown at an average annualized
rate of 3.4%. Services employment
growth has moderated in recent
months, presumably reflecting the
loss of jobs that formerly supported
the manufacturing sector.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Migration of Graduates
Percent
50 MIGRATION OF GRADUATES a

Migration Rates

Educational
attainment

Percent migrating to another
state between event and 1996
High
school
College
Birth
Age 14 graduation graduation

Some high
school

34.8

23.2

—

—

High school
diploma

34.1

23.4

18.8

—

Some college 38.5

26.8

24.1

—

College
degree

45.8

36.7

35.1

29.6

More than
college

55.5

46.2

43.7

40.0

College graduates living in a different state than their high school
40

30

College graduates living in a different state than their college
20

10
Non–college graduates living in a different state than their high school
0
1

Migration Rates by High School Location
(Percent)
Census regionb

Inmigration

New England
Middle Atlantic
East North Central
West North
Central
South Atlantic
East South
Central
West South
Central
Mountain
Pacific

Outmigration

Net
migration

19.5
19.3
9.8

2.9
20.5
25.6

–10.4
–1.2
–15.8

13.2
32.9

27.4
19.2

–14.2
13.7

23.5

35.3

–11.8

23.6
69.4
52.6

19.4
36.1
10.5

4.2
33.3
42.1

2

3

4

5
7
6
8
Years after highest degree attained

9

10

Migration Rates by College Location
(Percent)
Census regionb

Inmigration

New England
Middle Atlantic
East North Central
West North
Central
South Atlantic
East South
Central
West South
Central
Mountain
Pacific

Outmigration

Net
migration

16.4
15.6
17.3

20.5
13.8
23.2

–4.1
1.8
–5.9

14.7
27.5

25.5
15.0

–10.8
12.6

21.3

25.5

–4.3

10.9
42.5
26.3

28.3
25.0
11.6

–17.4
17.5
14.7

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. The sample comprises all high school graduates. Non–college graduates are individuals who did not complete a four-year degree program.
b. New England: CT, ME, MA, NH, RI, VT. Middle Atlantic: NJ, NY, PA. East North Central: IL, IN, MI, OH, WI. West North Central: IA, KS, MN, MO, NE, ND, SD.
South Atlantic: DE, DC, FL, GA, MD, NC, SC, VA, WV. East South Central: AL, KY, MS, TN. West South Central: AR, LA, OK, TX. Mountain: AZ, CO, ID, MT,
NV, NM, UT, WY. Pacific: AK, CA, HI, OR, WA.
NOTE: Based on a study of the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, a sample of 6,000 people who were 14–22 years old in 1979. Survey participants were
reinterviewed every year until 1994 and again in 1996, the last year of survey data available. All migration is within the U.S.
SOURCE: Yolanda K. Kodrzycki, “Migration of Recent College Graduates: Evidence from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, New England Economic Review, January/February 2001, pp. 13–34.

Developing a highly skilled workforce
is often the justification for state spending on high school and higher education programs, but those education
dollars do not necessarily translate
directly into a better-educated workforce in that state. The migratory
pattern of recent college graduates
suggests that Ohio and the surrounding states are not retaining the students
they educate.
The higher a person’s educational
attainment, the more likely he or she

is to migrate. Indeed, those who have
attended graduate school have the
highest migration rates: More than
55% of them move from their state of
birth, and more than 43% move some
time after graduating from high
school. Most moves occur within
10 years of graduation.
In-migration rates are highest in
the South and West. The Mountain
and Pacific regions are gaining more
than one high school graduate
through in-migration for every three

they educate. In sharp contrast, the
East North Central region (which includes Ohio) is losing its high school
graduates the fastest: Roughly one in
six leaves the region.
College graduates more frequently
remain in the census region where
they attended college. The Mountain,
Pacific, and South Atlantic states
enjoy positive net migration rates of
college graduates, while the West
South Central and West North Central
states sustain the largest net losses.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Electricity Generation and Consumption
Index, 1980 = 100
125 ENERGY CONSUMPTION

Billions of kilowatt hours
400 ELECTRICITY GENERATION AND CONSUMPTION a

120

375

350

115
California

Generation
325

110
U.S.
105

300

100

275

95

250

Consumption
Ohio
225

90
85
1985

200
1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

Jan.

Apr.

July

Oct.

Jan.

1999

Capacity of Electric Utilities (Megawatts), 1997
Energy
source
Coal

Summer
California
Ohio
22,626

—

22,863

526

891

548

1,039

5,397

1,271

5,472

1,456

Hydroelectric 13,568

164

13,554

170

4,310

2,042

4,310

2,077

24,323

27,083

24,406

27,695

Petroleum

Gas

Nuclear
Totala

July

Jan.
2001

Oct.

2000

Electricity Statistics by State, 1997

Winter
California
Ohio

—

Apr.

Importer/
exporter

Primary
Average
energy utility price
source (cents/kWh)

Utility
price
ranking
(1=lowest)

California

Importer

Water

9.03

41

Kentucky

Exporter

Coal

4.16

3

Ohio

Importer

Coal

6.38

29

Pennsylvania

Exporter

Coal

7.86

40

West Virginia

Exporter

Coal

5.07

7

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Electricity generated does not equal electricity consumed, primarily because of losses during transmission and distribution.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Energy.

High gasoline prices and California’s
electricity shortages have focused
attention on electricity generation
and energy conservation. Throughout the current expansion, U.S. energy consumption has increased, although improved conservation and
energy efficiency efforts have
slowed its growth rate. Ohio’s energy consumption patterns follow
U.S. trends, but at a slower rate.
During the recessions of 1981–82
and 1990–91, energy consumption
in Ohio slowed considerably,

presumably because of the state’s
heavy manufacturing base.
U.S. electricity generation and
consumption are seasonal: Plants
adjust their production schedules to
follow peaks and troughs in demand.
Electricity demand peaks in the summer and drops to its lowest levels in
March and April. One might expect
excess electricity supply to be greatest when demand is weakest; however, the excess is greatest when
demand is strongest.

The seasonal nature of electricity
generation and consumption is also
reflected in the reporting of states’ generation capacities. Although California
has three times the population of Ohio,
Ohio’s utilities are capable of generating more electricity year-round. Like
California, Ohio is a net importer of
electricity, mainly because its utilities
are not allowed to export electricity to
other states. Deregulation, which will
be complete in 2006, will allow out-ofstate sales of electricity.
(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Electricity Generation and Consumption (cont.)
ELECTRICITY GENERATION BY PRIMARY ENERGY SOURCE, 1998

U.S.

Coal
Natural gas

Ohio

California

Nuclear
Hydroelectric
Other

Year-over-year percent change
4.5 ELECTRICITY CONSUMPTION BY SECTOR

MAJOR ELECTRICITY PLANTS IN OHIO, 2000 a

4.0

2000
2001

Toledo
Cleveland Youngstown
Lima
Mansfield

Akron
Canton

3.5

2002

3.0
2.5

Columbus
2.0

Dayton

1.5
Cincinnati

Coal

1.0

Natural Gas
Nuclear

0.5

Petroleum
0
Residential

Commercial

Industrial

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. A major electricity plant is one whose generation capacity is at least 100 megawatts.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Energy.

Each Fourth District state depends
on coal as its primary energy source
for generating electricity. Electricity
prices among the District’s states
varied widely in 1997, with Kentucky
posting the third-lowest price of any
U.S. state, and Pennsylvania—with
prices approaching California’s—
ranking in the highest quartile.
California’s energy situation is
unlikely to occur elsewhere. States’
deregulation strategies vary, and
California’s mix of energy sources is
unusual: It generates less than 1% of

its electricity from coal (the U.S.
average is 57%). California is one of
only six states where hydroelectric
power is the primary source of
energy for generating electricity.
Ohio, on the other hand, generates almost 90% of its electricity
from coal. Two nuclear plants, Davis
Besse and Perry, are located in the
northern part of the state. Most of
Ohio’s electricity plants are located
near large metropolitan areas and
along the Ohio River valley, where
coal mining predominates. The
state’s natural gas production is

centered in the southwest, between
Dayton and Cincinnati.
The pace of energy demand
growth in all sectors is expected
to slow in 2001, although forecasted
growth for 2002 differs among
sectors. While industrial energy consumption growth is expected to
remain roughly the same in 2002,
commercial electricity demand is
expected to accelerate. Growth in
residential energy consumption is
expected to fall roughly 50% from
2001 to 2002.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Commercial Banks
Percent
30 NET SHARE OF RESPONDENTS REPORTING

Percent
70 NET SHARE OF RESPONDENTS REPORTING

Billions of dollars
1,300

STRONGER DEMAND FOR C&I LOANS

TIGHTER STANDARDS FOR C&I LOANS

1,250

20

60

Outstanding C&I loans
Large and medium firms

1,200

10

50

Small firms
1,150

0
Large and medium firms

40

–10

30

–20

1,050

–30

1,000

–40

950

–50

900

Small firms

1,100

20

10

–60

0
IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ a
2001

Percent
25 NET SHARE OF RESPONDENTS REPORTING

850
IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

Percent
60 NET SHARE OF RESPONDENTS REPORTING

TIGHTER STANDARDS FOR CONSUMER LOANS

IIQ a
2001
Billions of dollars
560

STRONGER DEMAND FOR CONSUMER LOANS
40

20

540

Outstanding consumer loans
Residential mortgages

Other consumer loans

20

520

15

Consumer loans
Credit cards

0

500

–20

480

–40

460

–60

440

10

5

0

–5

–80
IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ a
2001

420
IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
1999

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ a
2001

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. As of May 2001.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,” Federal Reserve Surveys
and Reports, May 2001.

In May 2001, the net share of domestic
and foreign commercial banks’ senior
loan officers who reported tightening
standards for commercial and industrial loans in 2001:IIQ fell to 50.9% for
large and mid-size firms and 36.4%
for small ones, the first slowdown in
the tightening trend since 1999:IIIQ.
This year’s first-quarter tightening was
mostly reflected in higher spreads on
riskier loans. Collateralization requirements and credit-line limits were
affected least. The three most important reasons respondents gave for
tightening their lending standards

were a less favorable and more uncertain economic outlook, worsening of
industry-specific problems, and lower
risk tolerance.
Along with tightening in the commercial and industrial loan markets,
loan demand has weakened since
1999:IIIQ. Senior loan officers, on
balance, again reported moderately
weaker demand for commercial and
industrial loans this May, but this is
good news compared to the substantial decline cited in January. The
amount of outstanding seasonally adjusted commercial and industrial loans

(around $1,116 billion) has been flat
for the last five months.
The tightening trend is less significant on the consumer side: Only 20%
of respondents tightened, compared
to more than double that share for
commercial loans, and 80% did not
change their standards for consumer
lending. The reasons most often given
for tightening were a recent or expected increase in delinquency rates
and consumers’ worrisome debt service burden. Even so, consumer loan
demand has strengthened moderately
since May, when 46% of the senior
(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Commercial Banks (cont.)
Percent of all banks
8 BANK PROFITABILITY a

7

Percent of all banks
80

CHANGES IN THE SHARE OF UNPROFITABLE BANKS,
2000:IQ TO 2001:IIQ

Institutions showing earning gains

6

60

5

Unprofitable institutions
40

4

Share fell (22)

3

No change (5)
Share rose (24)

2
1993

1995

1997

1999

Percent
16.5 BANK EARNINGS a

20
2001

Percent
1.6

16.0

Percent
1.8 RISK-WEIGHTED ASSETS a

Percent
85

1.5
80

1.7

Return on equity
15.5

1.4
Return on risk-weighted assets

15.0

1.3

1.6

75

1.5

70

Return on assets
14.5

1.2

14.0

1.1
Risk-weighted assets/total assets

13.5

1.0
1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

1.4
1993

1995

1997

1999

65
2001

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. Only first quarter of each year is presented.
SOURCES: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council, Report of Condition and Income, various issues; and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

loan officers surveyed reported
stronger demand for residential mortgages and 10% reported stronger
demand for consumer loans.
In 2001:IQ, the share of unprofitable FDIC-insured commercial banks
rose to 7.1%, continuing an upward
trend that began in 1996. Compared
with 2000:IQ, the share of unprofitable
banks increased in 24 states, remained
unchanged in five, and decreased in
21 states and the District of Columbia.
The most significant deterioration occurred in Arizona, where unprofitable
institutions’ share jumped from 16% to

31%. No significant change occurred in
Fourth District states.
Parallel to deterioration in the
share of profitable institutions over
the last five years, commercial banks’
annualized 2001:IQ return on assets
and return on equity show that their
profitability declined relative to 2000.
Return on equity dropped from
16.0% in 2000 to 14.7% in 2001:IQ.
Return on assets was 1.27%, down
from 1.35% in 2000. The return on
risk-weighted assets also indicates a
decline in bank profitability. Focusing solely on first-quarter results, the

return on risk-weighted assets showed
its first decline since 1994 and currently
stands at 1.61%.
The ratio of risk-weighted assets
to total assets shows that commercial banks’ risk exposure lessened.
As of 2001:IQ, this ratio stood at
78.1%, down from its all-time high
of 80% in September 2000. One factor in this decline may be the tighter
lending standards that senior loan
officers have reported.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks
Percent, daily
6.5 EURO ZONE MONETARY POLICY RATES

Percent
Billions of euros, weekly
12 EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK MONETARY POLICY STATISTICS 6.0
Euro overnight interbank average a
5.5

6.0

10

Marginal lending facility

Marginal lending facility

5.0

5.5
8

4.5
5.0
4.0

6
4.5
Euro overnight interbank average a

Main refinancing operations

Deposit facility

3.5

4
4.0
3.0
Deposit facility

3.5

2
2.5

3.0

0
1/1/01

1/29/01

2/26/01

3/26/01

4/23/01

5/21/01

Percent, daily
8 MONETARY POLICY TARGET RATES b

2.0
1/7/99

7/7/99

1/7/00

Percent, monthly
6 REAL EFFECTIVE RATES

7

7/7/00

1/7/01

Sterling overnight interbank average d

5
Federal Reserve

6
4

Bank of England
5

3
U.S. federal funds rate e

4
European Central Bank

2

3

Euro overnight interbank average a
1

2
Bank of Japan call money rate

0

1
Bank of Japan c
0
1/7/99

7/7/99

1/7/00

7/7/00

1/7/01

–1
1/99

7/99

1/00

7/00

1/01

FRB Cleveland • June 2001

a. The weighted rate on all overnight unsecured lending transactions in the interbank market, initiated within the euro area by contributing panel banks.
b. Overnight interbank rates except for the European Central Bank, whose main refinancing rate is shown.
c. On March 19, the Bank of Japan shifted to a target for the quantity of current account balances at BOJ that is expected to be consistent with a zero rate.
d. The weighted average rate of all brokered, unsecured sterling overnight deals between money market institutions and their overseas branches, transacted
between midnight and 3:30 p.m. GMT.
e. The weighted average rate on trades made through New York City brokers.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; European Central Bank; Bank of Japan; and Wholesale Markets Brokers Association.

On May 11, the European Central
Bank (ECB) cut its main refinancing
rate target 25 basis points (bp) to
4.5%. It was the last major central
bank to respond to the current global
economic slowdown. The move
came while the M3 monetary aggregate was slightly above its 4.5%
target. The ECB noted, however, that
M3 growth “has been on a gradual
downward trend since spring 2000,”
and M3 growth now is distorted
upward by non-euro-area residents’
holdings. Measured inflation also is
above target, but the ECB explained
that “upward risks to price stability

over the medium term have diminished somewhat,” a view “supported
by all forecasts.”
In the ECB’s February 14 and
April 11 main refinancing operations,
bidding at rates at or above the ECB
minimum was weakened by expectations of an imminent cut in that rate.
The resulting shortage of reserves
caused the overnight market rate to
spike, driving banks to borrow unusually large amounts from the marginal
lending facility at a 100 bp premium
over the minimum rate. In the week
following, bidding and allotments in
refinancing operations reached the

highest levels in the ECB’s brief history, compensating for the previous
week’s shortage.
European and U.S. policy rates
now are clustered within a 125 bp
range, while Japanese policy is consistent with a zero rate. A rough reading
of real policy rates might be derived
by assuming that the past year’s actual
inflation rate approximates expected
inflation. On this basis, policy rates are
more evenly spread, between 0.4% in
Japan (zero nominal rate plus 0.4%
deflation rate) and about 4.2% in the
U.K. (5.25% nominal rate minus about
1.1% inflation).