View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

July 2014 (June 13, 2014-July 16, 2014)

In This Issue:
Banking and Financial Markets

Monetary Policy

 Tracking Recent Levels of Financial Stress

 The Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth,
June 2014

Households and Consumers
 Households Ease Up on Adding New Debt

Inflation and Prices
 Cleveland Fed Estimates of Inflation
Expectations, June 2014
 European Inflation

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 A College Education Saddles Young Households
with Debt, but Still Pays Off

Regional Economics
 Neighborhood Gentrification during the Boom
and After

Banking and Financial Markets

Tracking Recent Levels of Financial Stress
07.01.14
by Amanda Janosko

Cleveland Financial Stress Index

The Cleveland Financial Stress Index (CFSI)
remained in Grade 2 or a “normal stress” period
throughout the early part of second quarter 2014.
More recently, the index has trended downward
into Grade 1 or a “low stress” period. As of June 27,
the index stands at −0.860, which is 3.966 standard
deviations below the historic high in December
2008 and 1.244 standard deviations above the
historical low in January 2014. The index is down
0.837 standard deviations from this time last year.

Standard deviation
3

April FOMC
meeting

June FOMC
meeting
Grade 4

2
1

Grade 3

0
Grade 2
-1
-2
-3
4/2014

Grade 1
5/2014

6/2014

7/2014

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Oet, Bianco, Gramlich, and Ong, 2012. "A Lens for Supervising the
Financial System," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper no. 1237.

Stress-Level Contributions
of Component Markets to CFSI

50

Credit
Funding

Equity
Securitization

Real estate
Foreign exchange

Equity Market Contribution to Stress
Units of stress

Points

20

2000
S&P 500
1950

15

40
1900

10
Equity Market
Component

30

10
0
4/2014

1850

5

20

0
4/2014
5/2014

1800
5/2014

6/2014

6/2014

Note: These contributions refer to levels of stress, where a value of 0 indicates the
least possible stress and a value of 100 indicates the most possible stress. The sum
of these contributions is the level of the CFSI, but this differs from the actual CFSI,
which is computed as the standardized distance from the mean, or the z-score.
Source: Source: Oet, Bianco, Gramlich, and Ong, 2012. "A Lens for Supervising the
Financial System," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland working paper no. 1237.

Note: These contributions refer to levels of stress, where a value of 0 indicates the
least possible stress and a value of 100 indicates the most possible stress. The sum
of these contributions is the level of the CFSI, but this differs from the actual CFSI,
which is computed as the standardized distance from the mean, or the z-score.
Sources: Author’s calculations; Haver Analytics.

The increased contributions of the equity and securitization markets to overall financial stress were
responsible for the index remaining in Grade 2 for
much of the quarter. The index moved back into
Grade 1 as the securitization and equity contributions waned and stock prices reached historic highs
in June. The CFSI’s credit, funding, real estate, and
foreign exchange markets remained relatively stable
over the quarter.
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

2

The Cleveland Financial Stress Index and all of
its accompanying data are posted to the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland’s website at 3 pm daily.
For a brief overview of how the index is constructed
see this page. The CFSI and its components are
also available on FRED (Federal Reserve Economic
Data), a service of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis. FRED allows users to download, graph, and
track more than 200,000 data series.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

3

Households and Consumers

Households Ease Up on Adding New Debt
07.01.14
by O. Emre Ergungor and Daniel Kolliner
A key question for the continued economic recovery is whether household deleveraging is over.
If households are beginning to add debt to their
balance sheets, it may be a sign that consumers’
confidence has returned and consumption might be
increasing.

Total Balance of Accounts is Rising:
Deleveraging is Over
Trillions of dollars

Billions of dollars

10

1500

9

Mortgages
(left axis)

8
7

1200

Auto
(right axis)

6

In response to the financial crisis in 2007, households cut back sharply on their borrowing, particularly in mortgages and bank cards. Lenders were
also part of the deleveraging process by tightening
up on credit standards and charging off bad loans.
After peaking in 2008:Q3 at $12.7 trillion, household debt declined for 17 out of the next 19 quarters. In the last three quarters, it has increased and
is currently at $11.7 trillion. Given that debt levels
and interest rates are so low, this additional debt is
not particularly burdensome, and it could support
consumption growth.

900

5
4

Student loans
(right axis)

3

600

Bank card
accounts
(right axis)

2

300

1
0
1999

0
2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Total Balance of Accounts in 1999 Dollars:
A Better Indicator of the Toll of Deleveraging

Purchase Originations Are Slowing Down
Billions of dollars (seasonally adjusted)

Trillions of dollars

Billions of dollars

10

1500

80
70

9
Mortgages
(left axis)

8
7
6

1200

50
900

Auto
(right axis)

5
4

600

2

Bank card
accounts
(right axis)

1
0
1999

300

0
2001

2003

2005

40
30
20

Student loans
(right axis)

3

60

2007

2009

2011

10
0
2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

Note: Shaded bar indicates a recession.
Sources: Black Knight Financial Services; authors’ calculations.

4

Borrower Categories and Equifax Risk Scores
20%

49%

12%

Deep Subprime: Less than 600
Subprime: Between 600 and 650
Prime: Between 650 and 720

19%

Super Prime: 720 and above

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Average Number of Accounts
7

6

Super prime

5

Prime
4

3
1999

Subprime
Deep subprime

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Deep Subprime Eager to Borrow

5

4

3
Deep subprime
Subprime

2

Prime
Super prime

1

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

The recent growth in mortgage balances also seems
to be abating. Mortgage debt will continue to
increase as long as purchase originations are greater
than amortizations; however, purchases declined
sharply in early 2014. Compared to January and
February 2013, purchase originations for mortgages
declined 15.1 percent and 15.3 percent, respectively, and they have been declining year-over-year
since August 2013.
Not all households are adding debt at the same
pace. Those with strong credit scores seem to be
benefiting most from the low borrowing costs. A
“strong” score corresponds to an Equifax Risk Score
above 720. Nearly half of the population is in that
range, which we call the “super prime” category.
At the other extreme of the risk scale are the “deep
subprime” borrowers, whose Equifax Risk Scores
are below 600.
In general, individuals with higher credit scores are
also the most frequent users of credit. Currently, an
average super prime borrower has five open credit
accounts, but a deep subprime borrower has fewer
than four, which is still a significant improvement
relative to the post-crisis lows.

Average number of inquiries in previous 12 months

0
1999

By most accounts, household deleveraging appears to be over. Auto and student loans have been
strong throughout the recovery, and mortgage
lending is beginning to turn the corner. However,
after calculating the same data in inflation-adjusted
terms (1999 dollars), the weakness in consumer
credit looks more striking. For example, in nominal terms, mortgage balances are up to their 2007
level and increasing. In real terms, the balances are
still flat at their 2005 level. Also, while the recent
growth in auto loan balances looks strong in nominal terms, the balances are still below their pre-crisis
peak in real terms.

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

Yet the deep subprime borrowers apply for credit
most frequently, an indicator of the frequent denials they face and their pent-up credit demand.
During the crisis, they cut back on their credit applications significantly, which may be interpreted as
a sign of their discouragement at the credit market
conditions at the time. Since 2010, however, they
are once again getting their toes wet in the credit
markets, although they are still not as eager to seek
5

loans as they used to be. Their credit application
numbers are36 percent less than the prerecession
high.

Purchase Origination Slowdown
Affecting All Borrowers

In the mortgage market, prime and super prime
borrowers were responsible for most of the purchase
and refinance activity. Subprime and deep subprime
creditors no longer contribute a significant part of
mortgage originations.

Billions of dollars (seasonally adjusted)
40
35
30
25
20
15

Super prime

10
Prime
Subprime
Deep subprime

5
0
2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bar indicates a recession.
Sources: Black Knight Financial Services; authors’ calculations.

The Refinance Boom Benefited Prime Borrowers

The auto loan boom, on the other hand, has not
left anyone out. Although super prime borrowers
have been borrowing most aggressively, the auto
loan balances of the deep subprime individuals have
also been showing signs of life.
These credit measures suggest that the consumer
credit market is still weak outside select sectors and
for borrowers at the riskier end of the credit spectrum.

Billions of dollars (seasonally adjusted)
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20

Super prime
Prime
Subprime
Deep subprime

10
0
2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bar indicates a recession.
Sources: Black Knight Financial Services; authors’ calculations.

Borrowers and the Auto Loan Boom
Billions of dollars
300
Super prime
250
200
Deep subprime
Prime
Subprime

150
100
50
0
1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Consumer Credit Panel/Equifax.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

6

Inflation and Prices

Cleveland Fed Estimates of Inflation Expectations, June 2014
News Release: June 17, 2014
The latest estimate of 10-year expected inflation
is 1.83 percent, according to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. In other words, the public currently expects the inflation rate to be less than 2
percent on average over the next decade.

Ten-Year Expected Inflation and
Inflation Risk Premium
Percent
7

The Cleveland Fed’s estimate of inflation expectations is based on a model that combines information from a number of sources to address the
shortcomings of other, commonly used measures,
such as the “break-even” rate derived from Treasury
inflation protected securities (TIPS) or surveybased estimates. The Cleveland Fed model can
produce estimates for many time horizons, and it
isolates not only inflation expectations, but several
other interesting variables, such as the real interest
rate and the inflation risk premium.

6
5
Expected inflation
4
3
2
Inflation risk premium

1
0
1982

1986

1990

1994

1998

2002

2006

2010

2014

Real Interest Rate

Expected Inflation Yield Curve

Percent

Percent
2.5

12

May 2014
June 2014

10
2.0

8
6

June 2013

1.5

4
2

1.0

0
-2

0.5

-4
-6
1982

0.0

1986

1990

1994

1998

2002

2006

2010

Source: Haubrich, Pennacchi, Ritchken (2012).

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

2014

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 910 12
15
20
Horizon (years)

25

30

Source: Haubrich, Pennacchi, Ritchken (2012).

7

Inflation and Prices

European Inflation
06.24.14
by Owen F. Humpage and Jessica Ice
At its most recent policy meeting, the European
Central Bank eased monetary policy because inflation had drifted well below the ECB’s target. With
economic activity weak, money growth slow, and
commercial-bank lending sluggish, the risk of slipping into a Japanese-style deflation seemed plausible. Prices in the euro area increased an unexpectedly low 0.5 percent on a year-over-year basis in
May, indicating that inflation has been moderating
for the past 2½ years. Absent the volatile food and
energy components, prices have risen just above
their lowest pace since the euro came into being.
Euro Area Harmonized Index of
Consumer Prices (HICP)
Year-over-year percentage change
6
5
4

Introduction
of euro

3

ECB
“target”
HCIP less
food and
energy
HCIP

2
1
0
-1
1993

1996

1999

2002

2005

2008

2011

2014

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: European Central Bank.

In response, the ECB lowered its key interest
rates, which resulted in a negative interest rate on
commercial-bank deposits at the ECB. The ECB
will also institute some long-term lending facilities
designed specifically to encourage bank lending to
households and nonfinancial businesses and may
initiate outright purchases of asset-backed securities. Hoping to keep inflation expectations anchored just below 2 percent, the ECB has promised
to maintain its accommodative monetary stance
until inflation moves close to that rate.
The ECB’s primary policy mandate is to maintain
price stability, which it defines as an inflation rate
below, but close to, 2 percent over the medium
term. In its assessment of price stability, the ECB
considers year-over-year changes in a weightedaverage consumer price index covering the entire
eighteen-country euro area. This is the Harmonized
Index of Consumer Prices (HICP), which apportions weights according to the relative size of countries’ consumer expenditures. While the ECB does
pursue other macroeconomic-policy objectives, like
full employment and economic growth, these economic goals remain secondary to price stability.
This ordering of policy objectives reflects the
view—one shared by most monetary economists—
that maintaining price stability is the chief way
that a central bank can contribute to long-term

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

8

economic growth and to full employment. Changes
in monetary policy, particularly unanticipated ones,
might alter real economic activity in the short run,
but not in the long run. The ECB’s current policy
actions, however, support both long-term price
stability and short-term economic growth.
The ECB is concerned that disinflation, if not
addressed, could lead to a Japanese-style deflation—an outright decline in the HICP—that
becomes imbedded in the public’s expectations and
harms economic growth. It is a connection with a
self-reinforcing potential. When individuals and
businesses expect prices to fall, for example, they
naturally postpone purchases and investments, if
possible, but that only weakens economic activity
and drives prices lower.
Deflation could also derail economic growth
through its effect on the debts of households, businesses, and governments. Deflation increases the
real burden of servicing debts, like credit cards,
mortgages, and commercial loans. If debtors sell
off assets to services these debts, asset prices can
fall, causing losses and a decline in real net worth.
Higher real debt burdens can also increase the incidence of default, which adversely affects financialsector balance sheets and credit allocation. These
developments, in turn, weaken economic activity,
slow or contract money growth, and induce further
declines in prices.
Fortunately, the ECB maintains a great deal of
credibility with respect to its inflation objective.
Over the 15½ years since eleven—now eighteen—
European countries adopted the euro and a common monetary policy, the ECB has consistently
delivered on its price stability pledge. Inflation
has averaged 2 percent and has generally remained
within a range of 1.2 percent to 2.8 percent.
Nevertheless, prices in the euro area have dfemonstrated some sharp, largely one-off, fluctuations,
particularly during the recent financial crisis.
Between late 2007 and early 2008, for example, the
euro area’s HICP increased sharply, reaching 4.1
percent in July 2008 primarily because of rising energy, agricultural, and other commodity prices. By
March 2009, commodity prices were declining, and
the recession was reducing other cost pressures. By
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

9

May 2009, prices began to fall, and in July 2009,
the HICP fell 0.6 percent on a year-over-year basis.
When a central bank has achieved a reputation for
price stability, deviations like these do little to damage credibility.

Distribution of Euro Area Inflation, May 2014
Number of countries
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-2.5

-2.0

-1.5

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

HCIP year-over-year change, percent

Price patterns among the 18 member states show
a wide divergence. In Greece, for example, prices
fell 2.1 percent (year over year) in May, continuing a decline that began in October 2012. Cyprus
and Portugal have also experienced deflation in
recent months. Price declines in these distressed
economies are part of the process through which
they regain their competitiveness vis-à-vis the other
euro-area countries. In Austria, at the other end
of the spectrum, prices have recently been rising
around 1.5 percent year over year.

Source: European Central Bank.

Prices in the Distressed European Economies
Index, December 2008=100
115
Italy
Spain
Portugal
Greece

110
105

Ireland

100
95
90
2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

Source: European Central Bank.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

10

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

A College Education Saddles Young Households with Debt, but Still Pays
Off
07.16.14
by Daniel Carroll and Amy Higgins

Average Student Loan Debt
Thousands of dollars (real dollars base year: 2010)
20
18
16
College degree

14
12

Some college

10
8
6
4

High school diploma/GED

2
0
1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer
Finances.

Median Wages: 22-29 Years of Age
Thousands of dollars (real dollars base year: 2010)
55
50
45

College degree

40
35

Some college

High school diploma/GED

30
25
20
15
1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer
Finances.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

Many parents believe their children must get a
college degree—especially if they want to have at
least as comfortable a lifestyle as their parents had;
yet the price of a college degree has been rising
rapidly over the past three decades. As costs have
risen, more and more students and their families
have turned to education loans for financing. This
trend, combined with the strong propensity for
households to form among individuals of similar
education levels, has led to much larger student
loan debt burdens for households headed by young
adults who have attended college. In the 1989 Survey of Consumer Finances, real (inflation-adjusted)
average student loan debt for young households
(those headed by someone between 22 and 29 years
of age) with a college degree was $3,420. In 2010,
the same average was $16,714, nearly a 400 percent
increase. For households with some college, but
without a college degree, average student loan debt
rose about 270 percent.
While it has become more costly to attend college,
the extra education typically awards a benefit in
the labor market. Households headed by an individual with a college degree earn, on average, a skill
premium relative to non-college households. Real
wage earnings for young households, for example,
have consistently been higher for households with
a college degree than for those without. In 2010,
the median young household headed by a college
graduate earned $42,693 in wage income while
the median non-college household earned only
$26,429, a premium of 61.5 percent. From 1989
to 2010, this premium averaged 45 percent. For
young households with exceptional labor market
outcomes—those in the 90th percentile of wage income within each level of educational attainment—
the wage-income premium averaged 39 percent. In
2010, the difference in the 90th percentile of wage
income between young college and non-college
households was $85,387 and $64,040, respectively.
11

The labor market bonus for completing a college
degree is not fully realized in the early years of
working. Looking at the wage income of households headed by an individual between 30 and 65
years of age reveals a much larger premium, both
at the median and the 90th percentile. In many
professions, a college degree combined with work
experience opens the door to senior-level administrative positions and higher salaries. The average
wage-income premium among these older households was 88 percent for degree-holding median
earners and 93 percent for 90th percentile earners.

Skill Premium: 22-29 Years of Age
Percentage points
80
70
60
Median
50
90th percentile

40
30
20
10
0
1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer
Finances.

Median Wages: 30-65 Years of Age
Thousands of dollars (real dollars base year: 2010)
95
85

College degree

75
65
55

Some college

45
35

High school diploma/GED

25
15
1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

In light of these data, the tradeoff seems clear. By
going to college, one is likely to end up in a household that earns a considerable wage income premium throughout its working life but which also has
a sizeable amount of college debt early on. There
is one education group for which this does not
hold: those with some college but no degree. These
households, which on average make up 32 percent
of those 22 to 29 years of age and 25 percent of
those 30 to 65 years of age, have some college debt
but get little to no labor market benefit.
For young households with some college but no
degree, the wage income premium is virtually zero,
averaging -3 percent for median earners and 5 percent for 90th percentile earners. Only a very small
premium emerges later in life. Among older households, the average premium was 22 percent at the
median and 17 percent at the 90th percentile.

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer
Finances.

Skill Premium: 30-65 Years of Age
Percentage points
130
120
110
100
90th percentile
90
80
70
Median

60
50
1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System’s Survey of Consumer
Finances.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

12

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, June 2014
Covering May 24, 2014–June 20, 2014
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Sara Millington
Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures

Highlights
June

May

April

Three-month Treasury bill rate (percent)

0.03

0.03

0.03

Ten-year Treasury bond rate (percent)

2.63

2.54

2.71

Yield curve slope (basis points)

260

251

268

Prediction for GDP growth (percent)

1.4

1.5

1.5

Probability of recession in one year (percent)

1.99

2.31

1.78

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; authors’ calculations.

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
Predicted
GDP growth

4
2
0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

GDP growth
(year-over-year
change)

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, authors’ calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

Since last month, the yield curve pivoted back
upward around the short end. The three-month
(constant maturity) Treasury bill rate stayed fixed
at 0.03 percent (for the week ending June 20), even
with April and May’s 0.03 percent. . The ten-year
rate (also constant maturity) increased to 2.63
percent, up 9 basis points from May’s 2.54 percent,
but still down from April’s level of 2.71 percent.
The pivot increased the slope back up to 260 basis
points, above May’s 251 basis points, though down
from the April level of 268 basis points. By recent
standards, the yield curve remains steep, as the
mean slope since 2000 has been 193 basis points
(median of 218).
The steeper slope had a small impact on projected
future growth. Projecting forward using past values
of the spread and GDP growth suggests that real
GDP will grow at about a 1.4 percentage rate over
the next year, even with May’s rate and just down
from April’s rate of 1.5 percent. The influence of
the past recession continues to push towards relatively low growth rates. Although the time horizons
do not match exactly, the forecast comes in slightly
more pessimistic than some other predictions, but
like them, it does show moderate growth for the
year.
The slope change had only a slight impact on the
probability of a recession. Using the yield curve to
predict whether or not the economy will be in a recession in the future, we estimate that the expected
chance of the economy being in a recession next
June at 1.99 percent, down a bit from May’s reading of 2.31 percent, but up a bit from April’s probability of 1.78 percent. So although our approach
is somewhat pessimistic with regard to the level
of growth over the next year, it is quite optimistic
about the recovery continuing.

13

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90

Probability of recession

80
70
60

Forecast

50
40
30
20
10
0
1960 1966 1972 1978 1984 1990 1996 2002 2008

2014

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, authors’ calculations.

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP Growth

10
8
GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

Predicting GDP Growth

Predicting the Probability of Recession

4
2
0
-2

10-year minus
three-month yield spread

-4
-6
1953

More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.

We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.

Percent

6

The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year,
and yield curve inversions have preceeded each of
the last seven recessions (as defined by the NBER).
One of the recessions predicted by the yield curve
was the most recent one. The yield curve inverted
in August 2006, a bit more than a year before the
current recession started in December 2007. There
have been two notable false positives: an inversion
in late 1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.

1965

1977

1989

2001

2013

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
numbers quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
14

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP
Growth
Percent
10
8

One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6
4
2
0

Ten-year minus
three-month yield spread

-2
-4
-6
1953

1965

1977

1989

2001

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For more detail on these and other issues related to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” Our friends at the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York also maintain a website with
much useful information on the topic, including
their own estimate of recession probabilities.

2013

15

Regional Economics

Neighborhood Gentrification during the Boom and After
07.16.14
by Daniel Hartley and Daniel Kolliner
During the housing boom, a number of large cities
in the United States experienced redevelopment
in their lower-income neighborhoods as higherincome residents moved in, a process known as
gentrification. Looser lending standards, which
were prevalent at the time, may have contributed to
the trend. Since lending standards have tightened
with the onset of the housing bust and the financial crisis, we wondered whether gentrification has
continued after the recession in places where it was
happening before.
To answer this question, we examined how the
income rankings of neighborhoods in the centers of
metropolitan areas have changed relative to those
in the suburbs since 2000. Looking at how average incomes have shifted in city neighborhoods
compared to the suburbs allows us to see which
metropolitan areas are experiencing income growth
in their core relative to their periphery. We find
that for the cities with the largest gains, the growth
is driven primarily by lower-income city neighborhoods moving up in the income distribution of the
metropolitan area. Such a pattern is consistent with
gentrification, where higher-income residents move
in to formerly low-income neighborhoods.
We selected a set of 59 large cities, all of which had
a population above 250,000 in the year 2000 and
the largest population of their respective metropolitan area (many metro areas include more than
one city). Then we ranked the census tracts of each
metropolitan area by the average income of residents in the tracts. The rankings are percentiles,
running from 1 to 100. Finally, we took the mean
of these rankings for the tracts that are located in
the largest city of the metropolitan area (referred to
as the principal city in the charts below). This mean
gives a sense of where the tracts of the largest city as
a whole fall in the income distribution of the metropolitan area. For example, the average tract in the
city of Virginia Beach was at the 66th percentile of
all of the tracts in the Virginia Beach-Norfolk-NewFederal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

16

port News metropolitan statistical area, while the
average tract in the city of Newark was at the 18th
percentile in the Newark, NJ-PA metropolitan division. This means that the average tract in Virginia
Beach is higher income than the average suburban
tract, while the opposite is true in Newark.

Changes in Mean Income
Change in income ranking, 2000−2007
10
Atlanta

5

Washington DC
St. Louis

Newark

0

Denver
Seattle
Minneapolis
Portland
Buffalo
Tampa
Chicago
Miami
Boston
Sacramento
San Francisco
Baltimore
Oakland Kansas City New Orleans
DallasAustin
San Diego
Cincinnati
Pittsburgh
Philadelphia
New York
Milwaukee Los Angeles
Cleveland
Louisville
Lexington−Fayette
Houston
Colorado Springs
Fort Worth
Memphis
Virginia Beach
Tucson
Las Vegas
San Jose San Antonio
Toledo
Albuquerque
Detroit
Indianapolis
Santa Ana
Oklahoma
El Paso
Columbus
City
Omaha
Tulsa

−5
10

20

30

40

50

60

Mean principal city tract income ranking in 2000
Source: Census 2000, American Community Survey 2005-2009 estimates.

Changes in City of Atlanta Income
Ranking, 2000 to 2007
Greater than 10%
6% to 10%
-4% to 5%
-9% to -5%
Less than -10%

Source: Census 2000, American Community Survey 2005-2009 estimates.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

To get a sense of the degree to which center-city
neighborhoods are moving up in income rankings
compared to their suburbs, we look at how these
means have changed over time. We use tractlevel data from the 2000 Census, the 2005-2009
American Community Survey, and the 2008-2012
American Community Survey, though for simplicity we refer to the periods these data cover as 2000,
2007, and 2010.
From 2000 to 2007 Atlanta showed the largest increase in mean income ranking of all the 59 cities,
moving up 8.7 percentiles. Washington was second
with an increase of 5.0 percentiles. The biggest
drops were in Tulsa (−3.6) and Omaha (−2.7).
From a map of income rankings in the city we can
gather where the income shifts are occurring. In Atlanta, income is rising, relative to the metropolitan
area, near the central business district, in midtown,
and on the east side.
To examine whether the gentrification trends of
the pre-recession boom period extended into the
bust and recovery, we plot the changes in the mean
income ranking from 2007 to 2010 against the
changes in the mean income ranking from 2000 to
2007. It should be noted that we might expect to
see smaller changes in income from 2007 to 2010
since it is a period of only three years, while 2000
to 2007 is seven years. We must make do with the
shorter post-boom period, since that is the extent of
the tract-level data that is available.
For a few cities (Denver, Minneapolis, Portland,
Seattle, and Washington), the increase in income
ranking continued after the boom, rising 2 to 3
percentiles from 2007 to 2010. By contrast, the
large increases in income ranking in the city of
Atlanta during the boom years were not matched in
the subsequent period. Another interesting case is
Cincinnati, which barely changed in income rank17

ing from 2000 to 2007 but has increased at a pace
similar to Denver or Washington during the 2007
to 2010 period.

Changes in Mean Income
Change in income ranking, 2007−2010

In Washington, the city center’s income growth is
more pronounced from 2000-2007; however, the
same general trend occurs from 2007-2010. The
tracts located in the middle of the city have had
larger changes in income ranking for both periods.
Surrounding the middle of the city are areas where
the income ranking has declined or grown slowly.

3
Portland
Minneapolis
Seattle
Denver

2

Washington DC
Cincinnati

San Diego
Louisville
Lexington−Fayette
Charlotte
Oakland

1

Tampa

St. Louis

Fort Worth
Chicago
Houston
Columbus
Tulsa
Miami
Philadelphia
Sacramento
Pittsburgh
Austin
El Paso
Boston
Wichita Raleigh
Dallas
Detroit
Cleveland
Indianapolis
Baltimore
Milwaukee
Memphis
San Francisco
Corpus Christi
Nashville−Davidson
Omaha Virginia Beach
New
Orleans
Fresno
Las Vegas
Phoenix
Buffalo
Colorado Springs
Santa Ana

0

Tucson

San Jose
San Antonio

−1

Atlanta

Newark

Albuquerque

−5

0

5

10

Change in income ranking, 2000−2007
Source: Census 2000, American Community Survey 2005-2009 Estimates,
American Community Survey 2008-2012 Estimates.

Changes in Income Rank: Washington, DC
2000-2007

2007-2010

Greater than 10%
6% to 10%
-4% to 5%
-9% to -5%
Less than -10%

In order to get a sense of whether the changes in
income rankings of the center cities that we observe
are being driven by neighborhoods that were initially lower income or initially higher income, we also
looked at the changes in income ranking using only
low-income census tracts (those that were in the
bottom half of the metropolitan-area distribution).
Much of the mean change in income rankings in
the large cities we studied is being driven by lowerincome neighborhoods moving up in the distribution, a pattern consistent with gentrification.
It appears that gentrification continued despite the
bust in cities such as Denver, Minneapolis, Portland, Seattle, and Washington, while in Atlanta it
ground to halt. The variation may be due to the
fact that that the financial crisis and housing bust
had different effects on different industries. Since
metropolitan areas specialize in different things, the
effects of the crisis and bust played out in different
ways across regions.

Sources: Census 2000, American Community Survey 2005-2009 estimates; American
Community Survey 2008-2012 estimates.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

18

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | July 2014

19