View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

The Economy in Perspective
Recession…There, we said it! Not that we are predicting
one, mind you, but we’ve noticed that the R-word is
rarely used in Federal Reserve publications and we just
wanted to get it into print. Now that we have your
attention, we can discuss what recessions are and what
you should know about them.
Some working economists have adopted a quick-anddirty benchmark for gauging recessions: two consecutive
quarterly declines in the real value of the gross domestic
product. The most widely accepted arbiter of business
cycle peaks and troughs—the Business Cycle Dating
Committee of the National Bureau of Economic
Research, or NBER (a private, nonprofit, educational
organization)—defines a recession as “a recurring period
of decline in total output, income, employment, and
trade, usually lasting from six months to a year, and
marked by widespread contractions in many sectors of
the economy.”
Of necessity, the NBER’s cycle-dating deliberations
occur at some time after the period in question. Economic data are received after varying lag times and
undergo significant revisions as more complete
information becomes available. Experience with data
revisions shows that observers who rely on contemporary data alone can be very seriously misled about a
current situation’s true nature. Consequently, the
NBER’s cycle-dating process is designed less for
current economic policy purposes than for better
understanding business cycle dynamics.
The NBER’s definition of a recession should make
clear that the cycle-dating process requires two kinds
of judgments: First, has economic activity actually
declined? Second, can the aggregate decline be attributed to a broad range of industries and locations?
During the mid-1980s, for example, economic conditions in the Midwest were quite poor due to surging
imports of manufactured goods and declines in agricultural exports. Had the rest of the country been
struggling too, the NBER might well have labeled the
period a recession, but conditions elsewhere were
more buoyant. The early 1990s provided a nice counterpoint, in which the Midwest led the nation out of
recession because there was strong demand for its
manufactured products. The national recession might
have lasted longer had manufacturing conditions in
the Midwest not improved so quickly.
To reflect for a moment on the current situation, it is
not yet plain whether the pullbacks announced in certain industries will trigger declines in other sectors.
The structure of the U.S. economy has changed in the
10 years since the last recession. Fewer employees

work in manufacturing industries, import and export
activity are both more prominent, and high-tech
sectors account for a much greater share of overall
investment spending. In addition, supply-chain management has become more sophisticated, reducing the
risk of major, unintended stockpiling of inventory.
This development is significant because the process of
inventory buildup and liquidation has amplified
smaller disturbances leading to previous recessions.
The modern economy may not be recession-proof,
but future recessions could very well generate
different warnings and follow different patterns.
Recessions can be regarded as extreme versions of
a relatively common economic phenomenon, that is, a
temporary market mismatch between supply and
demand, caused by an unexpected disturbance. Left
unfettered, prices, wages, and interest rates generally
adjust quickly enough to clear out excess supply in
the affected markets without transmitting the initial
disturbance into other, unrelated markets. Recessions,
then, are those rare occasions on which many people
are unable to adjust and coordinate their plans
without serious disruptions.
How our economy’s evolving structure might affect
its ability to respond to disturbances remains to be
seen. Certainly it responded far better than most
analysts expected in 1998 to shocks emanating from
international capital markets. But history shows that
economic activity propelled by booms—which rely
heavily on widespread confidence and leverage
during the upsurge—can become similarly vulnerable
to decline when broad-based retrenchments set in.
Policymakers face difficult obstacles in heading off
recessions, whose seeds are often sown during the prior
boom. Experience shows how hard it is for policymakers
to counsel restraint during periods of exuberant growth,
let alone to take actions that are regarded as antigrowth.
The difficulties are compounded because no one can be
certain what the propagating impulse for a recession
might be or when it might occur.
The U.S. economy has demonstrated a remarkable
resilience during the past several decades, as its leaders
have relied on markets to deliver lasting noninflationary
growth. Whatever the economy’s short-term performance, the long-term benefits of this strategy should
not be forgotten.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent, weekly average
7.25 RESERVE MARKET RATES

Percent
6.6 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES
6.5
October 31, 2000

6.75
6.4
Intended federal funds rate

6.3

6.25

November 30, 2000

6.2

Effective federal funds rate
5.75

6.1
December 19, 2000
6.0

5.25

December 20, 2000

5.9
Discount rate

5.8

4.75

December 28, 2000
5.7

4.25

5.6

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Percent, weekly average
6.8 SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES

Oct.

Nov.
2000

Dec.

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

May

June

2001

Percent, weekly average
9 LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

6.3

Conventional mortgage

8

5.8
1-year T-bill a

7

5.3
30-year Treasury a
6
4.8
3-month T-bill a

5

4.3

10-year Treasury a

3.8

4
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Constant maturity.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) maintained the intended
federal funds rate at 6.5% on
December 19, its final regular meeting of 2000. However, as this issue
was going to press, the FOMC cut
the intended rate 50 basis points
(bp) to 6.0% in an intermeeting
move on January 3, 2001. In a
related action, the Board of Governors approved a 25 bp decrease in
the discount rate. The FOMC
maintained its stance, adopted in
December, that the balance of risks
facing the U.S. economy is

“weighted mainly toward conditions
that may generate economic weakness in the foreseeable future.”
Federal funds futures markets
began to build in the possibility of future rate cuts in September, causing
the implied yield curves to slope
downward. This slope has steepened
remarkably in recent weeks, vividly
illustrating market participants’
heightened expectations that policymakers would lower the intended
federal funds rate. On December 28,
the May contract was trading 71 bp
below the current target rate and

17 bp lower than on the day before
the FOMC meeting.
Yields on government securities
also fell sharply over the last month.
For the week ending December 22,
yields on 3-month and 1-year T-bills
fell around 69 bp and 65 bp (to
5.67% and 5.44%, respectively) from
a month earlier. Despite this decline,
the spread between 3-month and
1-year T-bills held fairly stable, and
yields remained inverted. Long-term
interest rates also declined significantly (55 bp on the 10-year Treasury

(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
THE M2 AGGREGATE a

1997

1998

M2 VELOCITY AND OPPORTUNITY COST

1999

M2 AND M2 DEMAND

2000

2001
12-month percent change
3.9

Billions of dollars
120 EXCESS MONEY AND INFLATION

3.4

80
Actual M2 minus predicted M2, two quarters previous

40

2.9

0

2.4
CPI, all items

–40

1.9

–80
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

1.4
2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Last plot for M2 is estimated for December 2000. Dotted lines for M2 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges.
b. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2000 growth rate for M2 is calculated on an estimated
December over 1999:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

bond and 28 bp on the 30-year Treasury bond) through December 22.
Can policymakers extract any relevant information from the monetary
aggregates? Before the early 1990s,
changes in M2 velocity (the ratio of
nominal GDP to M2) were closely
related to M2 opportunity cost (the
difference between the rate of return
on M2-denominated assets and a
riskless alternative asset). This provided a basis for judging what money
target or interest rates would be
consistent with noninflationary economic growth. The relationship
between M2 velocity and opportunity

cost broke down in the early 1990s,
and standard models of money demand became less reliable.
Since 1993, the historical link
between velocity and opportunity
cost seems to have reasserted itself.
Indeed, when the money demand
relationship is adjusted to account for
the early 1990s, the model tracks
actual money about as well as before
the change. More intriguing, statistical evidence suggests that when
actual M2 exceeds (falls short of)
predicted M2, inflation rises (falls).
Some might point to the much
slower growth rates in the narrow

monetary aggregates, particularly
currency and the monetary base, as a
sign that policy has been too contractionary, but this would be somewhat
misleading. Currency, which accounts
for about 90% of the monetary base,
is supplied according to demand,
making it less useful as a policy indicator. In addition, year-to-date growth
rates are calculated relative to
elevated pre-Y2K levels, which
clearly were expected to decline once
the event had passed without
incident. Finally, seasonal adjustment
(the process of removing regular
fluctuations associated with recurring
(continued on next page)

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Billions of dollars
575 CURRENCY

CURRENCY GROWTH b

Currency growth, 1995–2000 a
12
9
525

Seasonally adjusted

6
3
0

475
Non-seasonally adjusted

425

375
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Index, January 1990 = 100
1,200 SELECTED STOCK INDEXES

Dollars per share
20 REAL S&P 500 RETURNS, FIVE-YEAR MOVING AVERAGE

Earnings
900
10

NASDAQ

600
Dividends
S&P 500
0
300
Wilshire 5000

0

–10
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2000 growth rate for currency is calculated on an estimated
December over 1999:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
b. One-year annualized year-to-date growth rates are calculated from the fourth quarter of the previous year through the given month. Two-year annualized
year-to-date growth rates are calculated from the fourth quarter two years previous.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Standard and Poors Corporation; and Wall Street Journal.

events such as holidays) is particularly difficult after a one-time event of
this magnitude. Annualized year-todate growth over a two-year horizon
arguably provides a less biased
picture of currency growth.
The stock market provided plenty
of thrills and chills in 2000, rising
sharply in the winter and staying relatively high through much of the
summer, then falling precipitously for
the rest of the year. Broad indexes
like the S&P 500 and the Wilshire
5000 ended the year down about
10% and 12%, respectively. Much of

the excitement focused on the technology sector, which dominates the
NASDAQ stock index. By year’s end,
the NASDAQ had fallen to around
half its March peak.
Despite the recent drop, stock
prices are still four times higher than
in 1990. And in retrospect, this year’s
experience is not so surprising. The
economy seems to be in transition
from a high—some say unsustainable—growth rate of near 5% to a
trend growth rate that is lower than
the recent pace but higher than the
trend rate experienced in 1973–95.

A transition was expected, but its
timing and the magnitude of the
slowdown remain highly uncertain.
Such details become known only in
retrospect and only then have clear
implications for near-term earnings
growth and stock prices.
The decade-long rise in broad
stock indexes like the S&P 500 was
largely supported by fundamental
factors such as earnings growth,
which showed persistently high
rates over much of the past 10 years.
Moreover, the index’s price/earnings
ratio (P/E) reached a peak of about
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percent
4.2 S&P 500 DIVIDEND YIELD

Ratio
35 S&P 500 PRICE/EARNINGS RATIO

30
3.4

25
2.6
20

1.8
15

1.0

10
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Dollars per million Btu b
6

Dollars per barrel
40 ENERGY PRICES a

Percent
275 FOREIGN ASSETS IN THE U.S.

Natural gas

175

30

4

20

2

Net capital inflows

75

Crude oil, spot
0

Non-Treasury securities

–25

10
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Oil prices are West Texas intermediate. Natural gas prices are from Henry Hub.
b. British thermal units.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Standard and Poors Corporation; and Wall Street Journal.

33 in 1999, with the 18 largest tech
stocks hitting a P/E peak above 125.
The P/E implicitly measures the
prospect for future earnings growth.
When it is high, investors are willing
to pay high prices because they
expect that earnings will grow faster
than historical trends so that the P/E
will fall to some norm—now
thought to be somewhere between
15 and 25.
Analysts’ estimates of individual
firms’ earnings growth prospects have
confirmed this view. Recently, however, near-term earnings projections

have been revised downward because of evidence that the anticipated
transition is under way. Nevertheless,
earnings projections over three to five
years still exceed historical trends and
so remain broadly consistent with the
current P/E.
High U.S. stock prices in the late
1990s also reflected their attractiveness relative to assets abroad.
Foreign holdings of U.S. securities
jumped in 1998 after the Russian
default, when global investors sought
a safe haven. The dollar’s recent
weakness relative to the euro raises

concerns that foreign investors may
now seek better prospects outside
the U.S. And although oil prices
receded substantially in December
(not shown), the price of natural gas
accelerated late in 2000 when temperatures in North America dropped
well below normal. Earnings growth
prospects for some sectors could thus
be depressed further as households
cut discretionary expenditures to pay
their heating bills. Transition, a reality
of a market economy, is rarely an
unmixed blessing.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

International Developments
Index, November 1, 2000 = 100
105 TRADE-WEIGHTED DOLLAR INDEX

Index, November 1, 2000 = 100
106 SELECTED EXCHANGE RATES a

104

104

Japanese yen

British pound

103
102

102

Major Currency Index

101

100

100
98

99
98

Canadian dollar

96

Broad Dollar Index
97

Euro
94

96
95

92

8/1/00

9/1/00

10/1/00

11/1/00

12/1/00

8/1/00

9/1/00

10/1/00

11/1/00

12/1/00

Index, November 1, 2000 = 100
140 EQUITY PRICE INDEXES

Percent
7 REAL GDP GROWTH

130

6

Euro area
U.S.

120

5

110
4

100
S&P 500
3

90
2

80
NASDAQ composite

1

70
60

0
1998

1999

2000 b

2001 b

9/1/00

10/1/00

11/1/00

12/1/00

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Foreign currency per dollar, daily data.
b. Blue Chip forecast.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Blue Chip Economic Indicators; and Wall Street Journal.

The dollar’s trade-weighted value
has slipped in recent weeks. The
Major Currency Index is down
more than 4% and the Broad Dollar
Index more than 2% since their
peaks in late November. Depreciation against the British pound and
the Canadian dollar has been
consistent with the two indexes,
but the U.S. dollar has continued to
appreciate against the yen as the
outlook for the Japanese economy
seemed to soften a bit. More
dramatic has been the dollar’s
change relative to the euro, which
has appreciated 10.4% against the

dollar since its October low of
0.827. Changing expectations about
U.S. economic growth and financial
market performance are said to
be largely responsible for the
dollar’s depreciation.
The downward revision to thirdquarter U.S. GDP was small, but it
appeared to confirm market sentiment that growth is slowing more in
the U.S. than in Europe. Faster European growth could eventually pull
foreign investment away from the
U.S. Market participants appear to
have factored lower profit growth
into prices of U.S equities already.

Falling equity prices make American
assets less attractive to foreigners
and reduce capital inflows to
the U.S.
The dollar’s rise relative to the
euro over the past few years has
been associated with stronger-thanexpected U.S. economic growth,
stronger growth in the U.S. than in
Europe, and large inflows of foreign
capital. As U.S. growth slows relative
to Europe, inflows of foreign capital
may slacken and reduce demand for
the dollar relative to the euro.

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Interest Rates
Percent
6.75 YIELD CURVES a

Percent
4.50 TREASURY INFLATION-INDEXED SECURITIES a

6.50
4.25
December 24, 1999 b
6.25
4.00
6.00

5.75

30-year TIIS

3.75

December 1, 2000 b

10-year TIIS

5.50
3.50
5.25
3.25

December 29, 2000 b

5.00
4.75

3.00
0

5

10

15
20
Years to maturity

25

30

35

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Percent
10 REAL GDP GROWTH VS. 10-YEAR, 3-MONTH TREASURY SPREAD c
8
Real GDP growth d
6

4

2

0
10-year, 3-month Treasury spread
–2

–4
3/60

3/63

3/66

3/69

3/72

3/75

3/78

3/81

3/84

3/87

3/90

3/93

3/96

3/99

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
b. Average for the week ending on this date.
c. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
d. Real GDP growth for the succeeding four quarters.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

As 2000 closed, the yield curve was
inverted, with a 3-year, 3-month
spread of –78 basis points (bp) and
a 10-year, 3-month spread of
–74 bp. The inversion’s proximate
cause was an increase in short rates
combined with a decrease in long
rates. The curve starts sloping
upward again at five years, although
7-year yields continue to exceed
adjacent maturities somewhat.
Long-term real interest rates—as
measured by Treasury inflationindexed securities (TIIS), which

adjust both principal and interest
payments for inflation—show a
related pattern. Both 10-year and
30-year TIIS fell throughout most of
2000, although 30-year yields were
generally lower. This is evidence of
an inflation premium in nominal
rates, for which the 30-year premium
exceeds the 10-year.
An inverted yield curve is commonly thought to signal an incipient
recession. How valid is this claim?
One way to check is to plot the
10-year, 3-month spread (historically,

the best spread for predicting recessions) along with GDP growth for
the year ahead. The spread was
negative (even if only slightly)
before the past five recessions,
although the lag between inversion
and recession varied, and at least
once (in 1966) a negative spread was
not followed closely by a recession.
Generally, a wide spread indicates
high growth and a narrow spread indicates low growth, but this relation
was strained in two low-inflation
eras, the 1960s and the 1990s. While
(continued on next page)

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Interest Rates (cont.)
Percent
1.4 YIELD SPREAD: A2/P2 MINUS A1/P1 a

Percent
8.0 COMMERCIAL PAPER YIELDS a

1.2

7.5

1.0

7.0

0.8

6.5

30-day A2/P2

90-day A2/P2
90-day
6.0

0.6

5.5

0.4
30-day

30-day A1/P1

90-day A1/P1
5.0

0.2

4.5

0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

1996

2001

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Percent
7 YIELD SPREAD: 10-YEAR B3 CORPORATE BOND

Percent
3.0 YIELD SPREAD: 10-YEAR BAA CORPORATE BOND

MINUS 10-YEAR BAA CORPORATE BOND

MINUS 10-YEAR TREASURY BOND

6

2.5

5
2.0

4
1.5

3
1.0

2
0.5

1

0

0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Bloomberg composite rate for dealer-placed commercial paper.
NOTE: For all charts on this page, the last data point is December 29, 2000.
SOURCE: Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

a cause for concern then, the current
inversion should not be taken as a
definitive indicator.
Another recent source of concern
has been risk spreads—spreads between bonds of different riskiness.
The commercial paper market has
seen a particularly large spike in the
spread between paper rated A1/P1
(the highest grade) and A2/P2. This
spike tops levels that were reached in
earlier times of financial concern,
such as the Long Term Capital Management crisis and Russian default of
late 1998 and the Y2K preparations
of a year ago.

Although spreads on both 30- and
90-day commercial paper have risen,
higher A2/P2 rates account for most
of the rise in the 30-day spread,
whereas declines in the safe A1/P1
rate also contribute to the 90-day
spread. Perhaps less noticeable, both
spreads have recently fallen as
sharply as they had risen: From their
peaks of 119 bp and 107 bp for the
week of December 22, 2000, 30- and
90-day spreads dropped to 22 bp and
38 bp as of January 2, 2001.

Other sorts of risk spreads also
have increased recently: The spread
of BAA corporate bonds over Treasuries has reached high levels, as has
the spread of B3 corporates over
BAAs. Along with commercial paper
rates, this may signal some tightness
in the lending market: A decline in
outstanding federal debt might
account for the increasing spread
over Treasuries, but it cannot explain
the spread between different grades
of corporate bonds.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 PCE CHAIN-TYPE PRICE INDEX AND CPI

November Price Statistics

3.75

Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

5 yr.a

1999
avg.

3.25
CPI

Consumer prices
All items

3.50

3.00

2.1

3.5

3.4

2.5

2.7

3.3

2.9

2.6

2.4

1.9

3.7

3.5

3.2

2.8

2.3

Less food

2.75
2.50

and energy
Median b
Producer prices

2.25
2.00
1.75
PCE Chain-Type Price Index

Finished goods

1.7

5.6

3.7

1.7

2.9

1.50
1.25

Less food
and energy

0.0

1.1

1.0

1.0

0.8

1.00
0.75
1995

12-month percent change
5.0 CPI AND YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1998

1999

2000

2001

12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND MEDIAN CPI
3.75

4.5
Year-ahead inflation expectations b

3.50

4.0

Median CPI c

3.25
3.00

3.5

2.75
3.0
2.50
CPI
2.5

2.25
CPI
2.00

2.0

1.75
1.5

1.50
1.25

1.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
c. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and University of Michigan.

The Consumer Price Index rose 2.1%
(annualized) in November, replicating the growth rate for October.
Despite two consecutive months of
moderate growth, CPI has grown at
3.5% (annualized) since September,
just above the 3.4% average rate for
the past 12 months. Consumer prices
for 2000 are expected to register a
substantially larger increase than the
annual advances experienced in
1995–99.

Two months of relatively modest
price growth have helped to
moderate
household
inflation
expectations. From a peak of more
than 4% in October, the latest Survey
of Consumers showed the mean
year-ahead anticipation of pricelevel growth at the year’s lowest; it is
now just below the actual
12-month growth rate of the
measured price index.

CPI volatility over the course of
2000 intensifies uncertainty about the
price outlook. Despite recent moderation in the growth of the overall
index, the median CPI and the CPI
excluding food and energy components—both alternative measures of
so-called “core” inflation—have
continued to drift upward, with the
trend in the median especially
noticeable. Furthermore, an increasing number of components registered
annualized growth rates above 3%.

(continued on next page)

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
Share of index (percent)
40 DISTRIBUTION OF CPI COMPONENT PRICE CHANGES

Percent of forecasts
70 DISTRIBUTION OF 2001 CPI FORECASTS b

35

60

1999

January 2000

2000 a

December 2000

30
50
25
40
20
30
15
20
10
10

5
0

0
Less
than 0

0–1

1–2

2–3

3–4

4–5

More
than 5

Annualized percent change

12-month percent change
16
CPI AND CPI ENERGY COMPONENT c

Less than 1.5

12-month percent change
60

14

50

12

40

10

30

1.5–1.9
2.0–2.4
2.5–3.0
Expected CPI growth, percent

More than 3.0

12-month percent change
15 MEDIAN CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY c

12

9

20

8

CPI excluding food and energy

CPI energy
CPI

6

10

6

0

4

3
2

Median CPI d

–10
–20

0
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

0
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Through November 2000.
b. Blue Chip panel of economists.
c. Shaded areas show economic recessions.
d. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 2000,
and December 10, 2000.

The dynamics of prices in 2000
clearly have been influenced by
energy developments, and the
recent reversal of oil prices has
contributed to the decline in both
measured inflation and inflation
expectations. However, the overall
energy price outlook is far from settled: Rapid accelerations in oil and
energy prices have been a characteristic of most downturns in the past
25-plus years (especially if 1980–82
is considered a single episode).
Some observers interpret current

signs of softening in real activity as a
classic energy-related supply shock.
If this is true, we should not jump
to the conclusion that any developing weakness in the economy will
inevitably bring a quick diminution
in long-term price pressures. It is true
that CPI growth tends to fall sharply
in recessions, along with oil price inflation. Core measures of inflation,
however, do not typically improve
prior to the recovery phases of the
business cycle.

What is most troubling is that core
inflation since the 1981–82 downturn has not generally responded to
energy-related declines in the overall CPI, except during the 1990–91
recession. In fact, evidence from this
period suggests an asymmetric relationship: Declines in the relative
price of energy have no effect on
trend inflation—except, it seems,
when they follow an acceleration
prior to short-run economic decline.
Not a pretty picture.

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Contribution to percent change in GDP
0.06 CHANGE FROM PRELIMINARY TO FINAL GDP ESTIMATE

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IIIQ
(Final estimate)
Change,
billions
of 1996 $

Real GDP
50.6
Consumer spending
69.2
Durables
16.5
Nondurables
21.5
Services
32.6
Business fixed
investment
26.3
Equipment
15.8
Structures
9.6
Residential investment –10.3
Government spending
–5.5
National defense
–8.9
Net exports
–24.3
Exports
37.0
Imports
61.2
Change in private
inventories
–6.1

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

2.2
4.5
7.7
4.7
3.7

5.2
5.3
9.3
5.4
4.3

7.7
5.6
14.6
–10.6
–1.4
–9.7
—
13.9
17.0

13.1
13.2
12.6
–1.5
2.6
–1.2
—
11.1
14.5

—

—

Annualized percent change from previous quarter
9 GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST a

–0.03

–0.06

Imports
Residential
investment
Personal
consumption
expenditure

Change in
inventories

–0.09

–0.12

–0.15

Exports

–0.18

4.0

Advance estimate
Preliminary estimate
Blue Chip forecast, December 10, 2000

7

Business
investment
0

Percent change from previous year
4.5 ANNUAL REAL GDP GROWTH

Final estimate

8

Government
spending

0.03

Actual
December Blue
Chip forecast

3.5
3.0

6

2.5
5
2.0

30-year average
4

1.5
3
1.0
2

0.5

1

0

0

–0.5
IVQ
1999

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
NOTE: All data are annualized and seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, December 10, 2000.

In 2000:IIIQ, gross domestic product
(GDP) grew at a 2.2% annual rate, its
slowest in four years. This final
estimate, released late in December,
is 0.2 percentage point below the
preliminary estimate of a month
earlier and fully 0.5 percentage point
lower than October’s advance estimate. Downward revisions were
common to all sectors except imports
and government, with a major contribution (–0.15 percentage point) from
a lower export estimate. The slowdown in real GDP from the second
quarter to the third primarily reflected

lower inventory investment and less
federal government spending, as well
as deceleration in nonresidential fixed
investment. These negative changes
were partly offset by a noticeable
rebound in personal consumption
expenditures. After slowing markedly
in the second quarter, personal consumption spending rose at a healthy
4.5% annualized rate in the third.
Disposable personal income is still
growing more slowly than consumption expenditures, and the personal
saving rate dipped below zero in the
third quarter.

Blue Chip forecasters expect GDP
growth to rebound only slightly and
to remain below the 30-year average
throughout 2001. Of course, Blue
Chip forecasters have a history of
underprediction. December Blue
Chip median forecasts of the next
year’s annual GDP growth rate underestimated actual GDP growth in
eight of the past 11 years; in each of
the last five years, they were more
than a full percentage point too low.
Despite ever-smaller personal saving rates over the last decade, the
household sector’s ratio of net worth
(continued on next page)

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Ratio
Percent of disposable income
10
6.33 PERSONAL SAVINGS AND NET WORTH a

Percent change from previous quarter
8 PERSONAL CONSUMPTION AND DISPOSABLE INCOME
7

8

6.00

Personal consumption

Personal saving rate
6
5.66

6

5.33

4

5.00

2

5

4

3
Disposable income

4.66

2

0
Net worth/disposable income

1
9/95

4.33
9/96

9/97

9/98

CHANGES IN NET WORTH a

9/99

9/00

–2
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

Change from previous quarter c
7.5
NONFINANCIAL CORPORATE PROFITS b

2000

Change from previous quarter c
30

20

5.0
Transportation

Nondurables
Other

2.5

10

Metals

0

0

–10

–2.5
Motor vehicles
Machinery

Electrical equipment
–20

–5.0
9/99

12/99

3/00

6/00

9/00

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Annual data excluding the last observation, which is for 2000:IIIQ.
b. Profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.
c. Billions of current dollars.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

to disposable income has increased
dramatically. The National Income
and Product Account’s measure of
personal savings is simply the difference between disposable personal
income and total personal consumption of all outputs except residential
construction. By this measure, personal savings have fallen significantly
over the decade. However, if
consumers’ purchases of durable
investment-type goods such as automobiles and household appliances
are included, the drop in personal
savings is less pronounced. But even

this would not account for the rapid
increase in household net worth.
Holding gains on investments in
equities and real estate reached
extraordinary levels between 1994
and 1999. These capital gains,
whether realized or not, are responsible for the swift rise in the net
worth/disposable income ratio. The
stock market retrenchment of the
past year may eliminate holding
gains as a dominant source of
increased net worth in 2000, but the
level of the net worth ratio is likely to
remain high. There should be little
question why consumers have had

no apparent qualms about choosing
negative personal saving rates.
Growth in nonfinancial corporate
profits (with inventory and capitalconsumption adjustments) came to a
halt during the third quarter. While
profit growth rates typically are volatile,
declining profits were widespread.
Profits fell in transportation, nondurable
goods, and four of five durable-goods
sectors. Only the machinery sector
showed an increase in profits. Such a
widespread drop has not occurred
since the first quarter of 1997.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
350 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT GROWTH

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

300

250

200

150

100

1997

1998

1999

2000

Dec.
2000

Payroll employment 280
Goods-producing
48
Mining
1
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
27
Nondurable goods –2
Service-producing
232
TPUa
16
Retail trade
24
b
FIRE
21
Services
141
Government
17

251
22
–3
37
–12
–2
–11
229
20
30
22
120
28

229
4
–3
25
–18
–6
–12
225
16
36
10
124
28

160
0
1
14
–15
–5
–10
159
14
25
4
95
13

105
–78
–3
–13
–62
–36
–26
183
23
8
19
81
56

50

Average for period (percent)

Civilian unemployment 4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

4.0

0
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS c

IVQ Oct. Nov. Dec.
2000
Percent
8.2

64.5

Year-over-year percent change
50 TEMPORARY HELP EMPLOYMENT

7.6
40

64.0

7.0

63.5

6.4

63.0

5.8

30

20

Civilian unemployment rate
62.5

5.2
10

Employment-topopulation ratio
62.0

4.6

61.5

4.0

0

61.0

3.4
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

–10
1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Transportation and public utilities.
b. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
c. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Despite signs of weakening in the
overall economy, labor markets held
steady, albeit with slower job growth
than earlier in 2000. In December,
nonfarm payrolls rose 105,000, which
exceeds the downwardly revised
figures for October (66,000) and
November (59,000), but is much lower
than the average monthly gain for the
first nine months of the year (187,000).
Other labor market measures remained strong: The unemployment
rate was unchanged at 4.0%, and the
employment-to-population ratio increased 0.1% to 64.5%.

The aggregate labor market’s apparent stability masked wide variations in
payroll growth across industries. The
private sector’s weak employment
growth in December resulted in a net
gain of only 49,000 jobs. Moreover,
there were significant net losses in
goods-producing industries such as
construction (–13,000) and manufacturing (–62,000), as well as in temporary
help services (–58,000). On the other
hand, many service industries, notably
computers and data processing and
health services, registered strong gains.
Also, a large gain in government
employment (56,000) reversed a
similar-sized loss in November.

Why has the unemployment rate
remained low when other economic
indicators have deteriorated rapidly?
The unemployment rate is generally
considered to be a lagging indicator,
which means that it takes awhile for
slowing economic activity to affect it
adversely. However, declining employment in temporary help over the
last 15 years seems to have led—not
lagged—weakening in overall economic activity. Indeed, the data show
that temporary help employment has
declined precipitously since April
2000 and is now at its lowest level
since the 1991 recession.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Long-Term Federal Budget Projections
Percent of GDP
10 FEDERAL BUDGET SURPLUS/DEFICIT

PROJECTED FEDERAL REVENUES AND EXPENDITURES

5

0

–5

–10

–15
2000

2010

2020

2030

2040

2050

2060

2070

2060

2070

Percent of GDP
10 PROJECTED MEDICARE, MEDICAID,

Percent of GDP
140 FEDERAL DEBT

& SOCIAL SECURITY OUTLAYS
120
8

100
80

6

60

Social Security
40
Medicare
4

20
0

2

–20

Medicaid

–40
0

–60
2000

2010

2020

2030

2040

2050

2060

2070

2000

2010

2020

2030

2040

2050

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

NOTE: All data are for calendar years.
SOURCE: Congressional Budget Office.

The Congressional Budget Office’s
projections suggest that, if current
policies remain in place, federal
revenues will grow at the same pace
as GDP and will stay at just below
20% of GDP through 2070 (under
mid-range economic and demographic assumptions). However, federal expenditures as a percent of
GDP will begin to rise after 2013.
The increase will be sustained over
several decades, reaching one-third
of GDP by 2070.
This means that near-term surpluses, however large, will be

converted into long-term deficits that
are larger still. As a result, it is projected that federal debt will be paid
off by 2010 and the Treasury will
hold positive cash balances through
the year 2050—again assuming that
current policies remain unchanged.
The chief reason for the projected
growth in federal expenditures
relative to GDP is baby boomers’ transition from middle age to retirement,
which will swell outlays on Social
Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.
Among these, Social Security is
expected to have the slowest growth

in outlays as a percent of GDP (from
4% now to nearly 6% by 2070).
Medicare and Medicaid will grow
faster relative to GDP. For example,
Medicare expenditures, currently at
just over 2% of GDP, are expected to
escalate to 9.6% by 2070.
The more rapid rise in health care
outlays may be explained by
increases in the unit costs of providing care, which are likely to occur as
better but more expensive procedures become available and the use
of health care services intensifies
over time.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Defined-Contribution Pension Plans
Percent of full-time employees
100 COVERAGE AND PARTICIPATION

Percent of plans
100 INVESTMENT CHOICES AVAILABLE b

All plans a
Defined benefit
Defined contribution

80

80

More than 10
5–10
1–4
60

60

40

40

20

20

0

0
1991

1993

1995

Employee contributions

1997

Employer contributions

Percent of plans
60 EMPLOYERS’ MAXIMUM PRETAX CONTRIBUTION

Percent of plans
60 WITHDRAWALS FROM DEFINED-CONTRIBUTION PLANS

50

50

40

40

30

30

20

20

10

10

Total
Any reason
Hardship only

0

0
5 or less

6–10
11–15
16–20
More than 20 c
Maximum contribution (percent of earnings) d

Withdrawals permitted

Withdrawals not permitted

Not determinable

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Includes defined-contribution and defined-benefit plans. Employees covered by both types are counted only once in the “all plans” category.
b. For plans not accounted for, the number of choices was either zero or indeterminable.
c. Or up to the IRS dollar limit.
d. Contribution limits were indeterminable for 2% of plans.
NOTE: All data are for 1997.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Employee Benefits Research Institute.

For 25 years, employers increasingly
have turned to defined-contribution
(DC) pension plans, partly because
they are cheaper to administer and
reduce their risks of funding pension
coverage. But DC plans benefit
employees as well. In nominal terms
they provide a less stable replacement
of preretirement earnings than do
defined-benefit (DB) plans, but they
offer more flexible funding methods—
for example, they can protect against
real-income erosion through inflationhedged portfolios. Because DC plans
are fully funded and have simpler
benefit-payout rules, they make
annual pension wealth accrual more

transparent and predictable than do
DB plans. In addition, DC plans can
more easily allocate assets according to
workers’ desires to make bequests and
buy annuities.
Almost 80% of U.S. workers have
some type of pension. In the 1990s, as
the share of full-time employees covered by DC plans rose, the share
covered by DB plans fell. Most DC
plans offer five or more investment
choices. The law caps total contributions (employer plus employee) at
$30,000 or 25% of compensation,
whichever is less, and caps employees’
(elective) contributions at $10,500.
Limits imposed by employers tend to

be more restrictive; most allow maximum contributions of 15% of earnings
or less; only 10% permit contributions
to exceed 20% of earnings.
DC plans can be a flexible way to
seek retirement security, but their
success depends on how they are
used. Penalty-free withdrawals before
age 59.5 are legally permissible only if
based on a long-term schedule. Most
plans permit discretionary withdrawals
before age 59.5, albeit with a penalty.
Many accept only hardship reasons
(like home purchases, medical costs,
or unexpected legal expenses), but a
significant fraction accept any reason.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

401(k)-Type Plans
Percent of participants
100 FAMILY INCOME AND PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION

Percent of participants
100 FAMILY INCOME AND PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION

80

80

$10,000–$24,999
$25,000–$49,999
$50,000–$99,999
$100,000 or more

60

$10,000–$24,999
$25,000–$49,999
$50,000–$99,999
$100,000 or more

60

40

40

20

20

0

0
Mostly stock

Mostly interest-bearing

Mostly stock

Mixed

Percent of participants
100 RACE AND PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION

Mostly interest-bearing

Mixed

Percent of participants
100 AGE AND PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION

80

80

Younger than 35
35–44
45–54
55–64
65–74
Older than 75

White non-Hispanic
Nonwhite
60

60

40

40

20

20

0

0
Mostly stock

Mostly interest-bearing

Mixed

Mostly stock

Mostly interest-bearing

Mixed

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

NOTE: All data are for 1997. They combine 401(k) plans with 403(b) plans and supplemental retirement annuities.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Employee Benefits Research Institute.

Redressing Social Security’s funding
shortfall by cutting benefits or hiking
payroll taxes is likely to make returns
on past contributions barely, if at all,
positive. Workers with access to
defined-contribution (DC) pension
plans, however, might improve their
retirement income by investing more
in stocks than in bonds. Historical
experience suggests that over
investment horizons of 20 years or
longer, stocks in general are likely to
yield much higher returns than
bonds with only modest (or no) increased risk of capital loss. How
much an individual in a DC plan can

invest in stocks rather than bonds depends on the number and scope of
investment choices the plan offers.
Investment patterns among people
with access to 401(k)-type plans show
that a large fraction of those in lowincome families invest primarily in
bonds rather than stocks. The opposite is true for high-income families.
One explanation is that low-income
families are more risk averse or have
less access to information about the
risk–return trade-offs for stocks versus
bonds over longer horizons. Alternatively, they may be aware that they are
more likely to withdraw 401(k)-type

accumulations over shorter horizons
and may rationally invest more heavily
in bonds than stocks. Or high earners
may work for larger firms that offer
401(k)-type plans with a sufficiently
wide range of investment choices.
This permits better portfolio diversification and therefore greater exposure
to stocks.
The data suggest that more educated individuals and whites tend to
invest more heavily in stocks than
others do. Except for those older
than 75, there is little evidence that
the fraction invested in stocks varies
significantly by age.

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions
Billions of dollars
24 NET INCOME OF BANKS a

Percent of net operating revenue b
50 NONINTEREST INCOME OF BANKS

18

47

12

44

24

6

41

21

38

18

0

Percent of net operating revenue b
30

Assets under $1 billion

27

Securities and other gains/losses
Net operating income

Assets over $1 billion

–6
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

35
1990

15
1992

1994

1996

1998

Billions of dollars
35 CREDIT QUALITY OF COMMERCIAL

Percent
5.5 NET INTEREST MARGIN OF BANKS c

2000

Billions of dollars
5

AND INDUSTRIAL LOANS BY BANKS

28

4

5.0
Assets under $1 billion

Noncurrent loans and leases
21

3

14

2

4.5

4.0

Net charge-offs
7

1

Assets over $1 billion
3.5
1990

0
1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
b. Net operating revenue equals net interest income plus noninterest income.
c. Interest and dividends earned on interest-bearing assets minus interest paid to creditors, expressed as a percent of average earning assets.
NOTE: All charts refer to FDIC-insured institutions.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2000:IIIQ.

Consistent with the slowing economy, conditions for the nation’s
FDIC-insured depository institutions
remained mixed in the third quarter.
After a disappointing second quarter,
commercial banks’ earnings rebounded in the third, approaching
the record-setting levels reached in
the first quarter. Third-quarter net income totaled $19.3 billion, up 31.6%
from the second quarter, but still
1.32% off the $19.5 billion posted in
the first. Gone were large banks’ sizable restructuring and credit-related

charges, which sapped the industry’s
second-quarter results.
Average return on assets (ROA)
tells a similar story. Third-quarter
ROA recovered to 1.28%, following
0.99% in the second quarter, but
remained significantly lower than the
1999:IIIQ peak of 1.41%. Higher
short-term rates caused commercial
banks’ net income to slip 1.4%
below that of a year ago. Earnings
strength remained widespread, however, with 62.9% of commercial
banks reporting an ROA of 1% or
more for the third quarter.

Although securities losses and
other gains and losses narrowed,
some signs pointed to the possibility
of lower profits to come. Noninterest
income as a percent of net operating
revenue, which has grown robustly
over much of the last four years, has
stalled of late, particularly for small
banks. Furthermore, net interest margins continued their long decline,
which began in 1993.
In addition, loan quality seems to
be slipping. Noncurrent loans and
leases and net charge-offs have
(continued on next page)

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions (cont.)
RESERVE STATUS OF BANKS

250

Percent of assets
65 NET LOANS AND LEASES OF BANKS

200

62

150

59

100

56

50

53

0

50
1990

NET INCOME OF SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS c

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

NONINTEREST INCOME OF SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Ratio of prudential reserves to total loans and leases.
b. Ratio of prudential reserves to noncurrent loans and leases.
c. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
d. A major cause of the sharp decline in 1996 was a special insurance assessment on savings institutions’ deposits.
e. Net operating revenue equals net interest income plus noninterest income.
NOTE: All charts refer to FDIC-insured institutions.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2000:IIIQ.

been rising since 1998, increasing
$2.2 billion and $0.4 billion in
2000:IIIQ. Unfortunately, prudential
reserves continue to grow more
slowly than noncurrent loans and
total loans. The reserve ratio (prudential reserves as a percent of total
loans and leases) and the coverage
ratio (those same reserves as a percent of noncurrent loans and leases)
have edged downward. Net chargeoffs of banks’ credit-card loans
caused the largest loan losses, with

net charge-offs of $2.4 billion
(4.27%) in the last quarter.
Banks have been able to offset
some of the decline in loan quality by
boosting the ratio of net loans and
leases to total assets, thus generating
more earnings per asset dollar. Also,
assets rose $80.9 billion during the
third quarter, topping $6 trillion for the
first time and giving banks more to
lend. They found willing borrowers
for the additional capital, much of
which has gone to depository institutions (up 12.5%), home equity lines of

credit (up 5.8%), and real estate construction and development loans (up
4.6%). In sum, the nation’s banks
remained fairly healthy. This is reflected in their equity capital, which
increased to 8.59% of assets because
of profit retention arising from securities holdings’ improved market value
and higher retained earnings.
Conditions for FDIC-insured
savings institutions weakened as
earnings fell for the second consecutive quarter to $2.6 billion, down $186
million from the second quarter and
(continued on next page)

19
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Conditions (cont.)
Percent
4.5 NET INTEREST MARGIN OF SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS a

Millions of dollars
400

Millions of dollars
4,000 CREDIT QUALITY OF COMMERCIAL

AND INDUSTRIAL LOANS BY SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS
4.0

3,200

320

Assets under $1 billion
3.5

Noncurrent loans
2,400

240

1,600

160

3.0

2.5
Assets over $1 billion

800

2.0

80
Net charge-offs

1.5

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

Billions of dollars
30 RESERVE STATUS OF SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS

Percent
150

25

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

1998

2000

Percent of assets
70 NET LOANS OF SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS

125

68

100

66

15

75

64

10

50

62

25

60

Noncurrent loans
20

Coverage ratio b

Loan-loss reserves
5
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

1990

1992

1994

1996

FRB Cleveland • January 2001

a. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
b. Ratio of loan-loss reserves to noncurrent loans.
NOTE: All charts refer to FDIC-insured institutions.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, 2000:IIIQ.

down $273 million from a year ago.
Profitability remains a concern
because almost 10% of savings institutions reported losses in 2000:IIIQ and
just 27% had an ROA higher than
1%. Their average ROA fell to 0.86%
from 1.00% a year ago.
As with banks, the inverted yield
curve has put downward pressure on
thrifts’ net interest margins. Higher
short-term rates have increased funding costs, but the yield on earning
assets has not kept pace. Unlike
banks, thrifts’ noninterest income
continues to rise at a fairly stable rate.

Savings associations’ credit quality,
while still far better than it was during
the savings and loan crisis, has been
slipping since 1998. For the first time
in a year, loan-loss reserves did not
keep pace with the increase in noncurrent loans. Noncurrent loans rose
$253 million in the third quarter, while
reserves increased only $239 million,
lowering the coverage ratio to 132%.
The percent of loans that were noncurrent increased for commercial and
industrial loans (up 13 basis points to
1.39%), credit cards (up 10 bp to
1.33%), and real estate construction
and land loans (up 5 bp to 0.79%).

Savings associations’ assets rose
$25 billion over the quarter, led by a
$16 billion increase in home mortgages. Securities were the only major
asset category to decline. Although
deposits grew a robust $13.6 billion,
one-third of this increase came from
a single institution that completed the
purchase of a large branch network
from a commercial bank. On another
positive note, equity capital climbed
to 8.32% of assets from 8.16% in
2000:IIQ as a result of capital infusions, retained earnings, and lower
losses on available-for-sale securities.