View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

January 14, 2016

Does GDI Data Change Our
Understanding of the Business Cycle?
Mark Bognanni and Christian Garciga

The Bureau of Economic Analysis constructs two different measures of aggregate output: Gross Domestic
Product (GDP) and Gross Domestic Income (GDI).
As a matter of accounting, the expenditure-side GDP
measure should be identical to the income-side GDI
measure. In practice, however, it is difficult to measure nearly $17 trillion worth of value precisely, and
this measurement error always leaves a substantial
discrepancy between GDP and GDI. Recently, a
number of researchers have considered the possibility that GDI may contain useful information about the
true level of aggregate output beyond that in GDP
alone. For example, a substantial strain of research
has called attention to the potential value of combining GDP and GDI to gain a more accurate picture of
the state of the economy (see, for example, Nalewaik
(2010), Nalewaik (2012) and Aruoba, Diebold, Nalewaik, Schorfheide, and Song (2015)).
In light of the recent interest in GDI, we assess whether using GDI to measure output would change our
understanding of key features of the business cycle.
In particular, we look at whether GDP and GDI indicate the same business cycles with respect to output
and whether the cyclical components of GDP and

GDI move in the same way in relation to the cyclical component of a number of other macroeconomic
indicators. We form our assessment by revisiting the
canonical exercise of Stock and Watson (1999) in
which they document business cycle regularities, but
in addition to GDP, we also redo the calculations using
GDI as the measure of output.
Of course, the long-run trend of both real GDP and
real GDI is upwards, but since our interest is in movements corresponding to business cycles, we first strip
the trend out of the data. We follow the same method
as Stock and Watson (1999) and use the band-pass
filter of Baxter and King (1994). We filter each series
independently to extract the business cycle component of each, which we define as fluctuations in the
series lasting between six quarters and eight years.
To see how the cyclical components line up across
GDP and GDI, we plot the two detrended series from
1951 to 2012 and compare. We find that over this
period, cyclical fluctuations in both measures have
been broadly in line with one another, with two notable
exceptions: Before two of the last three recessions,
the cyclical component of GDI peaked substantially
earlier than did the cyclical component of GDP. Prior
to the early 1990s recession, cyclical GDI peaked
in 1988:Q4 compared to 1989:Q4 for cyclical GDP,
whereas before the Great Recession, cyclical GDI
peaked in 2006:Q3 versus 2007:Q4 for cyclical GDP.
These results suggest that GDI may hold particular
value for detecting business cycle turning points,
which supports the findings in Nalewaik (2012).
To compare how various macroeconomic indicators
move in relation to the cyclical components of GDP
and GDI, we repeat the cross-correlation exercise of
Stock and Watson (1999). We use the same filter as
before to extract the cyclical component of measures
of aggregate consumption and investment, unemployment, prices, and interest rates, as well as leading
indicators of economic activity.
In the table below, we report the correlation between
the cyclical component of each of these series and
lags and leads of the cyclical components of real GDP
and real GDI. For example, the large positive correlation between the cyclical components of CPI inflation

Cyclical Component of GDP and GDI, 1951-2012
Percent
4
3
2
1

GDI

0

GDP

-1
-2
-3
-4
-5

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Authors’ calculations using data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis.

and current and lagged GDP and GDI indicate that
economic expansions in the current and preceding quarters are associated with contemporaneous
increases in the cyclical component of inflation, and
contractions are associated with decreases. Correlations taken across the period 1953-1996 are very
close to those taken across 1953 to the present, and
so we follow Stock and Watson (1999) and report
results only for the former period. Most importantly for
our purposes, the correlations are relatively unaffected by which measure of aggregate output is used.

Cross Correlations with GDP and GDI, 1953-1996
(GDP in bold; GDI in italics )
Number of Lags or Leads
-6

-5

-4

-3

-2

-1

GDP

-0.27

-0.16

0.04

0.33

0.66

0.91

1

0.91

0.66

0.33

0.04

-0.16

-0.27

GDI

-0.27

-0.14

0.07

0.35

0.66

0.89

0.97

0.88

0.64

0.32

0.03

-0.18

-0.28

-0.31

-0.17

0.05

0.35

0.67

0.91

1.00

0.91

0.67

0.35

0.05

-0.17

-0.31

-0.38

-0.28

-0.09

0.18

0.48

0.74

0.90

0.90

0.77

0.54

0.30

0.10

-0.05

Consumption

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

-0.38

-0.28

-0.09

0.17

0.47

0.72

0.87

0.88

0.76

0.55

0.32

0.12

-0.03

Consumption
(nondurables + services)

-0.29

-0.17

0.01

0.24

0.50

0.73

0.86

0.87

0.74

0.53

0.28

0.05

-0.12

-0.28

-0.15

0.03

0.25

0.49

0.70

0.83

0.83

0.71

0.51

0.28

0.06

-0.12

Consumption (durables)

-0.44

-0.36

-0.19

0.09

0.41

0.69

0.85

0.86

0.73

0.53

0.32

0.16

0.04

-0.44

-0.37

-0.19

0.08

0.39

0.67

0.83

0.85

0.74

0.55

0.36

0.19

0.06

-0.32

-0.17

0.06

0.34

0.62

0.83

0.90

0.84

0.66

0.41

0.18

-0.01

-0.14

-0.34

-0.18

0.05

0.33

0.60

0.81

0.88

0.83

0.66

0.43

0.20

0.00

-0.14

0.14

-0.03

-0.27

-0.56

-0.80

-0.93

-0.89

-0.69

-0.39

-0.07

0.17

0.31

0.35

0.17

-0.01

-0.26

-0.54

-0.80

-0.94

-0.91

-0.72

-0.42

-0.11

0.14

0.30

0.38

0.33

0.24

0.11

-0.04

-0.21

-0.38

-0.52

-0.64

-0.70

-0.69

-0.61

-0.50

-0.36

0.34

0.24

0.11

-0.05

-0.22

-0.39

-0.52

-0.64

-0.69

-0.68

-0.61

-0.50

-0.36

0.34

0.46

0.58

0.64

0.63

0.53

0.35

0.14

-0.07

-0.26

-0.40

-0.48

-0.51

Investment (total fixed)

Unemployment rate

CPI index

CPI inflation

0.36

0.49

0.59

0.64

0.62

0.51

0.34

0.15

-0.06

-0.25

-0.39

-0.48

-0.52

Federal funds rate

0.28

0.40

0.52

0.61

0.63

0.55

0.37

0.11

-0.18

-0.43

-0.62

-0.72

-0.72

0.26

0.39

0.51

0.61

0.65

0.58

0.41

0.16

-0.13

-0.39

-0.59

-0.71

-0.74

Consumer expectations

-0.63

-0.67

-0.63

-0.51

-0.30

-0.04

0.22

0.42

0.53

0.53

0.46

0.34

0.23

-0.65

-0.69

-0.64

-0.50

-0.28

-0.02

0.23

0.44

0.56

0.58

0.52

0.40

0.26

-0.49

-0.51

-0.48

-0.37

-0.17

0.10

0.38

0.62

0.75

0.76

0.66

0.51

0.35

-0.47

-0.49

-0.47

-0.37

-0.18

0.07

0.33

0.57

0.71

0.74

0.67

0.55

0.39

-0.40

-0.40

-0.32

-0.15

0.09

0.33

0.52

0.60

0.56

0.41

0.22

0.03

-0.11

-0.41

-0.42

-0.33

-0.15

0.09

0.35

0.54

0.63

0.58

0.44

0.24

0.06

-0.09

0.48

0.61

0.71

0.74

0.71

0.61

0.45

0.25

0.04

-0.16

-0.32

-0.43

-0.48

0.50

0.63

0.72

0.76

0.72

0.61

0.44

0.23

0.01

-0.19

-0.35

-0.46

-0.51

-0.02

0.18

0.40

0.61

0.78

0.86

0.84

0.70

0.48

0.23

-0.01

-0.20

-0.34

-0.02

0.19

0.41

0.63

0.80

0.88

0.86

0.72

0.49

0.23

-0.02

-0.23

-0.38

Building permits

Vendor performance

Unfilled orders

New orders

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics, the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, the Conference Board, and the Institute for Supply Management.

By revisiting the exercise of Stock and Watson (1999)
we can see that whether we examine GDP or GDI
makes little systematic difference to our understanding of how various indicators comove over the business cycle. However, the “GDI business cycle” has
notably turned downwards earlier than GDP in two
out of the three most recent official recessions, suggesting that further research exploiting the information
content of GDI is warranted.

References
Aruoba, S. Boragan, Francis X. Diebold, Jeremy J. Nalewaik,
Frank Schorfheide, and Dongho Song, 2015. “Improving GDP
Measurement: A Measurement-Error Perspective,” Journal of
Econometrics, forthcoming.
Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King, 1999. “Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time
Series,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81:4, 575-593.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson, 1999. “Business Cycle
Fluctuations in US Macroeconomic Time Series,” in Handbook of
Macroeconomics, Volume 1, edited by J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford. Elsevier Science B.V.
Nalewaik, Jeremy J., 2012. “Estimating Probabilities of Recession
in Real Time using GDP and GDI,” Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 44:1, 235-253.
Nalewaik, Jeremy J., 2010. “The Income- and Expenditure-Side
Estimates of U.S. Output Growth,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 1: 71–127.

.

Mark Bognanni is a research economist in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. His research focuses on
understanding the macroeconomic effects of monetary policies and fiscal policies.
Christian Garciga is a research analyst in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. His primary interests
include time series econometrics, Bayesian statistics, and macroeconomics.
Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted provided that the source is
credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to
econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922