View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

February 2012 (January 14, 2012-February 7, 2012)

In This Issue:
Banking and Financial Markets
 Loans and Leases in Bank Credit
Growth and Production
 Behind the Decline in Labor’s Share of Income
Households and Consumers
 Are Consumers More Eager to Borrow?
International Markets
 Pass-Through and the Renminbi’s Appreciation

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 Job Creation by Small and Large Firms over the
Business Cycle
Monetary Policy
 Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, January
2012
 More Transparency, But Not a Crystal Ball
Regional Economics
 Trends in Housing Prices per Square Foot

Banking and Financial Markets

Loans and Leases in Bank Credit
01.26.2012
by Ben R. Craig and Matthew Koepke
It has been two-and-a-half years since the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) declared
that the severe recession that began in early 2007
had ended. Since then, the U.S. has endured such
a slow recovery that many question if we are in a
recovery at all.

Loans and Leases in Bank Credit
12-month percent change
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Board of Governors; Haver Analytics.

One important measure of economic strength,
loans and leases in bank credit, confirms that the
current recovery has been relatively subdued compared to the recoveries after the 2001 and 1990 recessions. While loans and leases tend to be a lagging
indicator (due to the time it takes for old loans to
be paid off and for banks to reduce lending activity), balances in bank credit do serve as an important indicator of how quickly the general economy
is growing and, more importantly, what areas of the
economy are expanding.
Loans and leases in bank credit are recovering much
more slowly during this recovery than they did in
the previous two. One reason for the slower pace
this time around is simply the fact that the most
recent recession was more severe than the previous two. On a year-over-year basis, total loans and
leases declined in the recent recession an average
of 5.0 percent for 57 consecutive weeks. They fell
a full 9.7 percent in October 2009. Additionally,
on a year-over-year basis, they suffered a second
significant dip in March 2011 and then continued
to fall for an additional 25 weeks before recovering in September 2011. In comparison, total loans
and leases fell only 0.2 percent on average in the
2001 recession on a year-over-year basis. In the
1990 recession, the decline in loans and leases was
more prolonged (they fell 21 out of 26 weeks), but
the declines were never more than 0.8 percent on a
year-over-year basis.
Currently, loans and leases in bank credit remain
below their level at the trough of the recession.
Furthermore, the largest contributor to the current
growth in total loans and leases is likely to be a one-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

2

Total Loans and Leases as Percent of Trough
Level (trough = 100)
120
115

2007 recession
2001 recession
1990 recession

110
105
100
95

Consumer credit card
accounting change

90
0

20

40

60

80

100

120

time transfer of credit balances from off-balancesheet accounts to on-balance-sheet accounts, which
caused the level of consumer credit to increase 43.0
percent in March 2010 (week 40). Despite the
one-time accounting change, 132 weeks after the
recession trough, total balances of loans and leases
in bank credit stand at 98.8 percent of their level
at the recession trough. At the same point after the
1990 and 2001 recessions, total balances stood at
103 percent and 119 percent, respectively. However, while loan and lease balances have not grown
as quickly as they have in past recoveries, they are
following a similar trajectory as balances in the
recovery after the 1990 recession.

Weeks after trough

It is interesting to note that balances in one loan
category have grown faster during this recent recovery than in the two previous ones. Balances of commercial and industrial (C&I) loans 132 weeks after
the recession trough stand at 92.6 percent of the
recession trough level, which is approximately the
same level as balances after the 1990 recession and
significantly above the 84.8 percent level seen at the
same point after the 2001 recession. This is despite
the fact that C&I balances fell further after the recession trough of the 2007 recession (17.7 percent)
than after the troughs of the 1990 recession (8.0
percent) or the 2001 recession (16.0 percent).

Sources: Board of Governors; Haver Analytics.

C&I Lending as Percent of Trough
Level (trough = 100)
125

115

2007 recession
2001 recession
1990 recession

105

95

85

75
0
20
40
Weeks after trough

60

80

100

120

Sources: Board of Governors; Haver Analytics.

Also, while C&I lending fell by similar amounts
in the 2001 and 2007 recessions, C&I lending fell
faster after the 2007 recession, hitting bottom in
week 67 versus week 128 after the 2001 recession.
C&I balances began to increase much earlier in
this recovery than in the previous two as well. In
this recovery, they first increased around 70 weeks,
while after the 1990 recession it was around 145
weeks, and after the 2001 recession it was around
125 weeks. The relatively strong performance in
C&I lending likely reflects a rebalancing of bank
loan portfolios away from real estate loans into
C&I loans.
The rebalancing of portfolios is more apparent
when examining changes in real estate loan balances since the recession trough. With the exception of
a slight increase in November 2011, real estate balances—which include revolving home equity loans,
closed-end mortgages, and commercial real estate

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

3

Real Estate Lending as Percent of Trough
Level (trough = 100)
180
170
160

2007 recession
2001 recession
1990 recession

150
140
130
120
110
100
90

loans—have declined monotonically and currently
stand at 91.0 percent of their level at the recession
trough. Comparatively, at the same point after the
2001 recession (132 weeks), balances of real estate
loans were 1.4 times their recession trough level.
So, while C&I loan balances are increasing more
quickly than in past recessions, real estate loans,
which grew explosively after the 2001 recession,
remain stable to trending down. These two trends
together suggest that banks may be using the current recovery to rebalance their loan portfolios
toward higher levels of C&I loans and lower levels
of real estate loans.

80
0
20
40
Weeks after trough

60

80

100

120

Sources: Board of Governors; Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

4

Growth and Production

Behind the Decline in Labor’s Share of Income
02.06.2012
by Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino
Labor income, which includes wages, salaries, and
benefits, has been declining as a share of total income earned in the U.S. Here, we look at the cyclical and long-run factors behind this development.
Labor and capital both contribute to the production of goods and services in the economy, and each
gets compensated with income in return. The share
of total income accruing to labor, the labor income
share, is a closely watched indicator because it
can affect a wide range of other important macroeconomic variables, such as income distribution,
human capital accumulation, the composition of
aggregate demand, and tax revenue.
For decades, the labor income share has been fluctuating around a long-run value of approximately
two-thirds. More recently, however, the share has
been trending down. In the nonfarm business sector, which accounts for roughly 74 percent of the
output produced in the U.S. economy, the share
has decreased from values around 65 percent before
1980 to the current level of 57.6 percent. This decline has accelerated during the last decade. Excluding the financial sector, the labor income share was
more stable up to the year 2000, but it has been
trending down since.

Labor Income Share
Compensation as a percent of output
70

Nonfinancial
corporate sector

68
66
64
62

Nonfarm business sector

60
58
56
54
1947

1957

1967

1977

1987

1997

2007

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

It is interesting to look at this decline from a different angle. When the share of income accruing
to labor declines, it means that labor income grows
at a lower rate than total income. In other words,
the compensation that workers receive in return for
their labor grows at a lower rate than the output
that they contributed to producing. Another way
of saying this is that workers’ compensation per
hour worked—the wage rate—grows at a lower rate
than the output produced per hour worked—labor
productivity. In short, when labor’s share of income
declines, the wage rate grows less than labor productivity. In the business sector, the gap between
compensation per hour and productivity—the
wage-productivity gap—remained quite stable
5

before 1980, began widening during the 1980s and
1990s, and opened up more visibly during the last
decade.

Real Wage and Productivity
Index, 1947=100
500
450
400
350
Real output per hour

300
250
200

Real compensation per hour

150
100
50
0
1947

1957

1967

1977

1987

1997

2007

Notes: Shaded bars indicate recessions. Data are for the nonfarm business
sector. Real calculations are based on the implicit output deflator.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Average Growth Rates in Select Periods
Annual percent change
3.0
Real output per hour
Real compensation per hour

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1948-1973

1974-1995

1996-2011

Notes: Data are for the nonfarm business sector. Real calculations are based
on the implicit output deflator.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Labor Income Share
Change from business cycle peak
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-2.5
-3.0

Current cycle
Average, all other cycles

-3.5
-12 -10 -8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10 12 14 16

Quarters from NBER peak

Productivity growth in the nonfarm business sector
averaged 2.7 percent before 1973, then 1.4 percent
during the 1974-1995 slowdown, and 2.5 percent
after the 1995 acceleration. Compensation per
hour lagged behind productivity during the slowdown and more so during the acceleration, when it
averaged 2 percent, almost half a percentage point
less than productivity.
Economists have identified three long-term factors
that can explain why the wage-productivity gap
has widened and the share of income accruing to
labor has declined. The first is the decrease in the
bargaining power of labor, due to changing labor
market policies and a decline of the more unionized
sectors. Another factor is increased globalization
and trade openness, with the resulting migration
of relatively more labor-intensive sectors from
advanced economies to emerging economies. As a
consequence, the sectors remaining in the advanced
economies are relatively less labor-intensive, and
the average share of labor income is lower. The
third factor is technological change connected with
improvements in information and communication
technologies, which has raised the marginal productivity and return to capital relative to labor.
In addition to these long-run factors, some cyclical factors are behind the current low level of
the labor income share. Over the cycle, the labor
income share tends to increase during the early
part of recessions, because businesses lower labor
compensation less than output, and compensation
per hour continues to increase even as productivity slows down. Then, after reaching a peak sometime during the recession, the labor income share
tends to decrease during the rest of the recession
and the early part of the recovery, as output picks
up at a faster pace than labor compensation, and
compensation per hour grows at a slower pace than
productivity. Only later in the recovery, as the labor
market tightens, does labor compensation catch up
with output and productivity, and the labor income
share recovers.

Note: Data are for the nonfarm business sector.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

6

Average Business Cycle
Percent change from business cycle peak
16
Real
Real
Real
Real

14
12
10

output per hour
compensation per hour
output
compensation

8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Quarters from NBER peak
Note: Data are for the nonfarm business sector. Real calculations are based
on the implicit output deflator.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The current cycle has followed a similar pattern,
with output initially falling more than compensation and then picking up at a faster pace. There
have been some notable differences though. This
time, the losses of output and compensation during the recession have been much larger, about 8
percent. It took four years for output to recover,
while compensation is still 5 percent below its prerecession peak. Productivity recently slowed down
and has barely grown in the past year. Compensation per hour slowed down even more and has been
roughly flat for two years. The weak labor market
may be one reason why compensation is growing
so slowly. The labor market needs to make further
progress before we see compensation growing at
rates more in line with past cycles.

Current Business Cycle
Percent change from business cycle peak
8

Real
Real
Real
Real

6
4

output per hour
compensation per hour
output
compensation

2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17

Quarters from NBER peak
Note: Data are for the nonfarm business sector. Real calculations are based
on the implicit output deflator.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

7

Households and Consumers

Are Consumers More Eager to Borrow?
01.25.2012
by Yuliya Demyanyk and Matthew Koepke
Consumer credit serves as an important indicator as
to where the economy is heading. Generally, consumers borrow more when they are more certain
about their financial prospects and less when they
are less certain. Consequently, changes in consumer
credit may indicate how confident consumers are
about the economy and their desire to consume in
the future.
Recent data from the Federal Reserve suggests that
consumers may be becoming more confident in the
economy and increasing their willingness to consume. According the Board of Governors’ November release, consumer credit grew 0.8 percent to an
inflation-adjusted level of $2.0 trillion. That is the
largest one-month increase since November 2001,
when total consumer credit grew 1.4 percent (note
that the Board’s measure does not take loans secured by real estate into account). November’s dramatic monthly increase was highlighted by many
news organizations as a sign that consumers are
quickly releveraging their balance sheets; however,
a closer examination of consumer credit, adjusted
for inflation, reveals that the level of total consumer
credit remains well below the June 2008 peak.

Total Consumer Credit Outstanding
(Monthly)
Dollars in trillions, SA (Dec. 1999 = 100)
2.4

2.2

6/2008

11/2011
2.0

1.8

1.6
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Sources: Federal Reserve Board; Haver Analytics.

Inflation-adjusted nonmortgage consumer credit
outstanding peaked in June 2008 at $2.2 trillion.
Since then, total real consumer credit has fallen
8.0 percent to just over $2.0 trillion. Revolving
accounts—credit card loans and unsecured lines of
credit—led the decline in consumer credit, falling
21.3 percent since the peak. On a year-over-year
basis, revolving accounts have fallen continuously
from February 2009 to October 2011—albeit at a
decreasing rate.
November’s flat performance was the first time in
nearly two years where revolving credit did not decline. It is clear from the Board of Governors’ data
that consumers’ holdings of revolving debt declined
far more dramatically in the wake of the financial
crisis than their holdings of nonrevolving debt. It is

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

8

unclear from the data, however, if those reductions
in revolving credit were driven by consumers seeking to deleverage or banks cutting limits on credit
cards and unsecured credit lines.

Home Mortgages (Quarterly)
Dollars in trillions
10.0

Nonrevolving credit—secured and unsecured loans
for automobile purchases, mobile homes, durable
goods, etc.—fell less significantly through the recession and subsequent recovery. Likely buoyed by
relatively strong auto sales, nonrevolving consumer
credit has fallen only 0.1 percent, to an inflationadjusted level of $1.4 trillion, since June 2008.
Moreover, while year-over-year revolving consumer
credit growth has declined persistently since the
financial crisis, nonrevolving credit growth hit an
inflection point in October 2010 and has grown
every month since then. Nevertheless, it is difficult
to know if consumers will be interested in increasing their leverage based on the Board of Governors’
data, since it does not include mortgage debt.

8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Note: Includes installment home equity lines of credit.
Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Equifax.

Bank Card Outstanding Balances
(Quarterly)
Dollars in trillions
1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

However, data from the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York’s Consumer Credit Panel suggests consumers may still be deleveraging. Those data show
that while consumers have been taking on nonrevolving debt, they have been reducing their balances of mortgage debt.
Moreover, the Panel confirms that consumers have
been dramatically reducing their revolving balances.
According to the Panel’s third-quarter results, the
amount of mortgage debt held by consumers has
fallen nearly 10 percent since September 2008, to
$8.4 trillion. Bank card debt (mostly credit cards)
has fallen even more dramatically, declining nearly
20.0 percent to $690 billion. Thus, while nonrevolving credit has been rising throughout the
economic recovery, consumers have been reducing
their holdings of mortgage and credit card debt.
While the growth in consumer credit in November
was impressive, it is difficult to tell if consumer
credit will be able to grow at a similar rate going
forward. One measure we can examine to gauge if
consumer credit growth is sustainable going forward is the household financial obligation ratio.
The household financial obligation ratio measures
the amount of debt service—including auto lease
payments, rental payments on tenant-occupied

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Equifax.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

9

property, homeowners’ insurance, and property
tax payments—relative to disposable income. The
average household financial obligation ratio over
the past 30 years has been 17.2 percent. For the
past decade, the average household obligation ratio
stood at 18.0 percent, 103 basis points higher than
the 30-year average. However, since the first quarter
of 2009, the ratio has dropped monotonically, falling from a high of 18.5 percent to its current level
of 16.2 percent. For now, it appears that the ratio
has stabilized. Moreover, given its relatively low
level, there may be some room for consumers to
grow their balance sheets going forward.

Household Financial Obligation Ratio
(Quarterly)
Percent, seasonally adjusted
20
19

Financial obligation ratio
Average historical financial obligation ratio

18
17
16
15
14
2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

Note: Financial obligation ratio includes automobile lease payments, rental
payments on tenant-occupied property, homeowners' insurance and property
tax payments.
Sources: Federal Reserve Board; Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

10

International Markets

Pass-Through and the Renminbi’s Appreciation
01.24.2012
by Owen Humpage and Margaret Jacobson

Renminbi Appreciation and Import
Prices: 2005-2008
Index, June 2005=100
125
120
115
110

U.S. dollar-renminbi exchange rate

105
100
Chinese import prices

95
90
6/2005

1/2006

8/2006

3/2007

10/2007

5/2008

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bloomberg, China National Bureau of
Statistics, and Haver Analytics.

Renminbi Appreciation and Import
Prices: 2010-2011
Index, June 2010=100
110
U.S. dollar-renminbi exchange rate
105
Chinese import prices
100

95

90
6/2010

9/2010

12/2010 3/2011

6/2011

9/2011 12/2011

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bloomberg, China National Bureau of
Statistics, and Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

Since mid-2010, the Chinese renminbi has steadily
appreciated against the dollar. Many here in the
United States hope that a more expensive renminbi
will induce a proportional rise in the prices of
Chinese goods and take some of the sting out of
China’s competitive bite. They may, however, be
disappointed. The relationship between exchangerate changes and import prices is often loose—
more like a swing dance than a tango.
Between 1995 and 2005, China pegged the renminbi at roughly 8.28 per dollar—a rate that
undervalued the renminbi and allowed China
to accumulate a substantial portfolio of dollardenominated assets. In July 2005, as complaints
about China’s exchange-rate practices mounted,
China undertook a controlled appreciation of the
renminbi. Over the next three years, the renminbi
appreciated 19.1 percent against the dollar, but the
dollar price of U.S. imports from China rose only
4.7 percent. Only one-quarter of the renminbi appreciation seemed to pass through to higher import
prices.
In mid-2008, as the global financial meltdown
chilled its economic activity, China once again
pegged the renminbi at roughly 6.83 per dollar.
Again, complaints about China’s exchange-rate
practices proliferated, and in mid-2010, when its
economic outlook brightened a little and inflationary pressures began to build, China once more
allowed the renminbi to appreciate. Since then,
the renminbi has appreciated 7.1 percent against
the dollar, a slightly slower pace than earlier. This
time around, import prices have risen 4.5 percent;
roughly 64 percent of the renminbi’s appreciation
has passed through to import prices.
This variation in the rate of pass-through results because renminbi appreciations can induce secondary
adjustments that offset their main price impacts. In
China’s case, the distinction between the “domestic
content” and the “foreign content” of exports to
11

Exchange-Rate Movements against
the Chinese Renminbi
Percent of depreciation

Percent of appreciation

Japanese yen
South Korean won

June 2005–July 2008
June 2010–
December 2011

Taiwan dollar
United States dollar
Germany euro
Australian dollar
Malasian ringgit

the United States is important. The former refers
to the value of Chinese goods that directly emanates from Chinese economic activity. This would
include such things as the wages of Chinese labor,
the cost of Chinese resources, and the depreciation
of Chinese capital used in the production process.
China, however, produces many of the goods that it
exports to the United States with hefty amounts of
foreign content, that is, with goods imported from
other countries, even from the United States. While
very difficult to estimate, the domestic content of
Chinese exports to the United States is probably no
more than 60 percent.

Brazil real
Thailand baht
-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

Source: Haver Analytics.

30

A renminbi appreciation against the dollar would
raise the dollar cost of the domestic content of China’s exports to the United States. This appreciation,
however, could simultaneously lower the renminbi
price of the foreign content of those same goods,
if the appropriate foreign exchange rates remained
unchanged vis-à-vis the dollar. This seems unlikely.
In the end, the net effect of a renminbi appreciation
on the price of Chinese exports to the United States
depends largely on how those other foreign currencies might change against the renminbi. Between
June 2005 and July 2008, the currencies of those
countries that supply the lion’s share of China’s
imports depreciated by 10.3 percent against the
renminbi overall, or about 0.3 percent per month.
This lowered the renminbi price of China’s foreign
content and helped China maintain its competitive
edge. Since June 2010, those key foreign currencies
depreciated 0.4 percent, or about 0.02 percent per
month. So the offset effect of the current renminbi
appreciation has been smaller than the previous
renminbi appreciation, and more of the renminbi’s
strength has now passed through to higher import
prices.
Besides exchange-rate changes, the U.S. price of
imports from China reflects underlying inflation
trends in that country and the pricing strategies
of Chinese exporters. Since June 2005, China’s
inflation rate has generally outpaced inflation in
the United States. While productivity in the trade
goods sector is undoubtedly higher than in other
sectors of the Chinese economy, the higher overall
rate of inflation is still corrosive to China’s competi-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

12

tiveness. China’s exporters also might respond by
cutting profit margins as the renminbi appreciates,
but the scope for this type of adjustment is probably narrow.

Inflation Rates
Four quarter percent change in CPI
10.0
8.0
6.0

China
United States

4.0
2.0
0.0
-2.0
-4.0
1/2005 2/2006

3/2007

4/2008 5/2009 6/2010 7/2011

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bloomberg, China National Bureau of
Statistics, and Haver Analytics.

Even if all of the renminbi appreciation passed
through to Chinese export prices, the development
might only reshuffle competitive pressures instead
of damping them. The Congressional Budget Office conservatively estimates that one-third of the
Chinese import penetration into the United States
between 1998 and 2005 came at the expense of
imports from other—mostly Asian—countries
and not at the expense of U.S. manufacturers. In
many cases, firms moved final assembly operations
into China from their home countries. If China’s
competitive position should deteriorate because of
higher domestic price pressures or from a renminbi
revaluation, these firms might shift operations out
of China, say, to Viet Nam or Mexico or to other
low-wage countries. A renminbi appreciation might
then only change the source of U.S. imports, not
the level.
So to those relying on appreciation, here’s a tip:
Many’s the slip twixt cup and lip.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

13

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

Job Creation by Small and Large Firms over the Business Cycle
02.06.2012
by Murat Tasci and Emily Burgen
The Great Recession caused establishments of all
sizes to make significant cuts in their employment. To get a picture of those losses, we turn to
the Business Employment Dynamics (BED) data
collected by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS),
the best data to look at for employment gains and
losses at the establishment level. BED data provides
gross job gains and losses at the establishment level
going back to the early 1990s and breaks down the
data to several size categories. We aggregate those
categories into three classes to simplify our analysis:
small firms (1-49 employees), medium size firms
(50-499), and large firms (500 and more employees).

Payroll Employment Quarterly Change
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
1500
1000
500
0
-500
-1000
-1500
-2000
-2500
-3000
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

Between the first quarter of 2008 and the second
quarter of 2009, firms in every size class destroyed
more jobs than they created, implying negative rates of job creation throughout the recession. Small firms, on net, cut their workforces by
485,000 per quarter on average. Medium size firms
cut theirs by 329,000, and large firms cut theirs by
538,000. These net job losses contrast sharply with
the average quarterly net gains in the years leading
up to the recession (2003:Q2 to 2007:Q4): small
firms added 124,000 new jobs over this period,
medium size firms added 118,000, and large establishments added 145,000. The subsequent negative
trend in net job creation did not stop until further
into the recovery. It was not until mid-2010 that
firms of all size classes started to report positive
quarterly net job creation figures.
Net job creation did vary somewhat across establishments of different size over time, but the divergence was never significant. What is more striking
is that the net job creation levels of all three sizes
of establishment moved together over the business
cycle, especially during the recessions.
It would be useful to know whether a specific size
class leads the employment loss during the recession
or the overall job gains during the recoveries, but
14

it is not possible to determine this from the chart
above. Looking at the underlying gross job gains
and losses separately for different size firms sheds
more light on the question.
Looking at gross job gains from 1994 to 2011
reveals that in any given quarter, U.S. establishments generated millions of jobs. Even during the
worst-performing period—the Great Recession—
establishments created around 5.3 million jobs per
quarter. This is significantly less than the average of
6.3 million jobs per quarter over the entire period.
Nevertheless, it clearly shows the underlying dynamism in the U.S. labor market.

Net Job Creation
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
800
600
400
200

Another feature we observe in the data is that small
firms account for more than half of the gross job
gains in every period. Medium-size and large establishments each contribute about a quarter of total
gains.

0
-200
-400
-600

1-49 employees

-800

50-499 employees
499+ employees

-1000
-1200

1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Gross Job Gains
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
2500

4000

2100

3600

1700

3200

1300

2800

900

1-50 employees (right axis)
50-499 employees
500+ employees

500

2400

2000

1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Finally, it is clear that all establishments experienced significant declines in gross job gains over the
course of the last recession. Large establishments
cut the most, reducing gross job gains by about
43 percent from their pre-recession peak to their
recession trough. The relative decline was almost 30
percent for medium-size firms and only 17 percent
for small firms. The rebound in gross job gains after
the recession seems to also differ by establishment
size: Large firms recovered much faster than the
others.
On the flip side, we observe that small firms also
account for slightly more than half of the aggregate
job losses at the establishment level over time—
about 3.3 million of the 6.1 million jobs destroyed
every quarter since 1994. Once again, the sheer size
of the gross job losses highlights the significant degree of churning that goes on at the establishment
level in the United States. Even in good times, for
instance, between the second quarter of 2003 and
the fourth quarter of 2007, job losses averaged
around 5.9 million per quarter.
Finally, the pattern of gross job losses for different
size firms resembles the picture of gross job gains:
Large firms led the pack with a relatively large
increase of around 50 percent of their pre-recession
trough to their recession peak.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

15

Gross Job Losses
Seasonally adjusted, thousands
2500

4000

2100

3600

1700

3200

1300

2800

900

1-50 employees (right axis)
50-499 employees
500+ employees

500
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Contribution to Job Gains
Relative to Job Losses
Seasonally adjusted
1.3
1.2
1.1
1.0
0.9
0.8
0.7

1-50 employees
50-499 employees
500+ employees

0.6
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

2400

2000

The overall picture of gross job flows shows that
behind the relatively small numbers of net job
creation there are large gross flows with a lot of
labor market churn. Moreover, there are cyclical
changes that affect every establishment regardless
of size. Even though small firms in general account
for more than half of the total job gains and losses
each quarter, large firms seem to lead the timing of
employment adjustment, contributing significantly
to gross job losses early in recessions and rebounding relatively quickly afterwards.
However, all these differences are not immediately
clear from the data on net employment changes
across establishments. This is due to the fact that
the contribution of job gains and losses by each size
class to the overall gains and losses is remarkably
constant over time. For instance, while small firms
create a lot of jobs, they also tend to shed a lot at
the same time, implying that their contribution to
net job creation stays proportionately the same relative to large and medium size firms.
One alternative way of looking at this issue is to
compare the share of job gains in each size class
relative to the class’s share of losses. If the ratio is
more than one, it means that establishments of
that size are contributing more to gross gains than
to gross losses. Looking at this ratio over time for
the three size classes shows that small firms in fact
contribute a lot more toward gross job gains during recessions, implying that they are dampening
overall net losses during downturns. However, this
role turns around during recoveries, when they tend
to contribute more to losses. This relationship has
held so far during the current recovery.
The fact that small firms are not rebounding as
much in terms of gross job gains does not seem to
be due to weak demand for labor. For information
on this aspect of the labor market, we look at the
establishment level data on job openings from the
Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS).
The number of job openings declined sharply in the
aggregate economy over the course of the recession, and it is still far below its pre-recession levels.
However, labor demand measured this way behaved somewhat differently across size classes. Even
though size is classified slightly differently than
16

Contributions to Job Openings
Seasonally adjusted
0.45
0.43
0.41

1-49 employees
50-249 employees
250+ employees

0.39
0.37
0.35
0.33

in the BED data, we can see that small firms have
been consistently accounting for more than onethird of the overall job openings since mid-2006,
higher than the other size classes. More interestingly, however, is that their demand for labor did
not decline (relative to others) until the recession
was over. Since then, their share has been declining,
whereas the share of large firms has risen significantly.

0.31
0.29
0.27
0.25
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: JOLTS.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

17

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, January 2012
Covering December 17, 2011–January 20, 2012
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Margaret Jacobson
Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures

Highlights
January

December

November

3-month Treasury bill rate
(percent)

0.04

0.01

0.01

10-year Treasury bond rate
(percent)

1.96

1.94

2.02

Yield curve slope
(basis points)

192

193

201

Prediction for GDP growth
(percent)

0.7

0.7

0.7

Probability of recession in
1 year (percent)

6.4

6.5

5.8

Starting the new year, the yield curve rose, with
both long and short rates rising slightly. The threemonth Treasury bill rate rose to 0.04 percent (for
the week ending January 20), up from the 0.01
percent seen in November and December. The tenyear rate stayed below 2 percent but rose slightly
to 1.96 percent, which is up from December’s
1.94 percent, but below November’s 2.02 percent.
The slope barely decreased, coming in at 192 basis
points, a decrease of 1 basis point from December’s
193 basis points and 9 basis points below November’s 201 basis points.
Projecting forward using past values of the spread
and GDP growth suggests that real GDP will grow
at about a 0.7 percent rate over the next year, the
same estimate as in the prior two months. The
strong influence of the recent recession is leading
toward relatively low growth rates. Although the
time horizons do not match exactly, the forecast
comes in on the more pessimistic side of other
predictions but like them, it does show moderate
growth for the year.

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP
Growth
Percent
10
8

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6
4
2

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth

0
-2

Using the yield curve to predict whether or not
the economy will be in recession in the future, we
estimate that the expected chance of the economy
being in a recession next January is 6.4 percent, just
down from December’s 6.5 percent, though up a
bit from November’s 5.8 percent. So although our
approach is somewhat pessimistic as regards the
level of growth over the next year, it is quite optimistic about the recovery continuing.

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-4
-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
8

One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6
4
2
0

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-2
-4

-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth

long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.
More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.
Predicting GDP Growth

Percent
Predicted
GDP growth

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4
2

We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.

0
-2

Predicting the Probability of Recession

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Recession Probability from Yield Curve

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.

Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
80

Probability of recession

70
60

Forecast

50
40
30
20
10
0
1960 1966 1972 1978 1984 1990 1996 2002 2008
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First, this
probability is itself subject to error, as is the case
with all statistical estimates. Second, other researchers have postulated that the underlying determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated yield
spreads during prior decades. Differences could
arise from changes in international capital flows
and inflation expectations, for example. The bottom line is that yield curves contain important information for business cycle analysis, but, like other
indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For

more detail on these and other issues related to
using the yield curve to predict recessions, see the
Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal Recession?” Our friends at the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York also maintain a website with much useful
information on the topic, including their own estimate of recession probabilities.

Monetary Policy

More Transparency, But Not a Crystal Ball
01.26.2012
by John B. Carlson and John Lindner
On January 3, the Fed released the minutes from
the December Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) meeting and revealed that it will begin
publishing the Committee’s interest rate projections. The goal of this action is to provide more
transparency in the policymaking process. However, there are limitations to the information these
types of projections provide. Examining the experiences of some foreign central banks illustrates what
conclusions might and might not be drawn from
the new data.
FOMC participants included three new pieces of
information when they submitted their Summary
of Economic Projections for January’s meeting. In
addition to projections for real GDP, the unemployment rate, PCE inflation, and core PCE inflation, participants included projections for the target
federal funds rate, a projection of the likely timing
of the first increase in the target rate, and a narrative explaining their assessment. Each participant’s
projections were based on his or her view of the
appropriate course of monetary policy.
How these projections would be presented was
specified in a press release the week prior to the
January meeting. Since participants submitted
their interest rate projection for the fourth quarter
of each of the next few years, and the longer run,
a histogram illustrates the number of participants
that expect the initial target federal funds rate
increase to occur by the fourth quarter of a given
year. In addition, each participant’s projected path
of the fed funds rate shows the spectrum of appropriate policy views. Perhaps more importantly,
though, the summaries that will be released with
January’s meeting minutes will include a narrative
describing how committee participants made their
assessments. This should, as we will discuss shortly,
provide some of the most meaningful information
about the participants’ preferences in determining
policy.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

21

By publishing interest rate projections, the Fed is
continuing its recent trend of increased transparency, as well as following in the footsteps of several
other central banks. The Reserve Bank of New
Zealand began publishing future interest rates in
1997, and Sweden’s Riksbank and Norway’s Norges
Bank followed suit in the mid 2000s. However, it
is expected that the FOMC has at least one distinct
advantage in providing its projections.
With the other central banks mentioned, the
policymaking group (their versions of the FOMC)
must come to a consensus on the projected path
of policy interest rates. Forming a consensus is a
hurdle, and it is one of the main arguments against
providing forward guidance on interest rates—and
based on the recent dissents within the FOMC for
policy decisions, it would seem that forming consensus projections might be difficult. But by asking
each participant to provide his or her own projections, this problem is avoided.
A larger concern is that the public will misinterpret the meaning of the projections. For one thing,
the projections are not the FOMC’s planned path
for interest rates, as the December minutes make
clear. But that misinterpretation has already been
made in the press and pointed out by Dave Altig of
Macroblog.
Also, the interest rate projections are based on
current projections of future economic conditions,
and as we know too well, the future can be pretty
unpredictable. Take, for example, the recent experiences of New Zealand, Sweden, and Norway.
Each of these countries’ central banks released
projections that turned out to be wide of the mark
because the bank’s expectations for future economic
conditions were not met. The first and most glaring
instance was heading into the recession in the fall
of 2008. All three banks made several projections
that severely underestimated the decline in economic output that was soon to occur. As a result, in
March 2008, New Zealand had projected an official
cash rate for March 2009 of nearly 9.0 percent, but
the rate was set at 3.0 percent by the time March
2009 arrived. Over the same period, Norway had
projected 5.5 percent for its sight deposit rate but
instead set a rate of 2.5 percent, and Sweden had
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

22

projected 4.3 percent for its repo rate but set a rate
of 1.5 percent.

Norway’s Sight Deposit Rate
Percent
7
Baseline projections

6
5
4
3
2

October 2011
projections

1
0
6/2004

9/2005

3/2007

9/2008

3/2010

9/2011

3/2011

9/2014

Source: Norges Bank.

Sweden’s Repo Rate
Percent
6
Baseline projections
5
4
3
2
December 2011
projections

1
0
6/2004

9/2005

3/2007

9/2008

3/2010

9/2011

3/2011

9/2014

Source: Sveriges Riksbank.

New Zealand’s Official Cash Rate
Percent
10
9
8

Baseline projections
(90-day rate)

7
6
5
4
3

December 2011
projections (90-day rate)

2
3/1999 3/2001 3/2003 3/2005 3/2007 3/2009 3/2011 3/2013
Source: Reserve Bank of New Zealand.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

Even more recently, all three countries had projected stronger growth rates of GDP following their
recessions. As their recoveries wore on, much like
in the United States, it became clear that economic
growth was slower than expected, and thus interest
rates would need to remain lower than projected.
By March 2010, New Zealand was projecting an
official cash rate of 5.0 percent at the end of 2011,
but the rate was actually set at 2.3 percent. Similarly, the target interest rate projections of 3.3 percent
and 2.4 percent outdid the actual policy interest
rates of 2.0 percent and 1.8 percent in Norway and
Sweden, respectively.
The obvious conclusion to be drawn is that these
projections do not represent any sort of definitive
path of future policy interest rates. These projections are based on the current set of economic
conditions and the way central bankers believe
economic conditions will evolve in the future. That
means that if the state of the global economy does
not follow the path that the central bankers expect,
they would likely project an altogether different
path of policy interest rates. This is already apparent in the structure of the FOMC’s summary of
projections, which includes the qualification that
the projections presented are the expectations of
policymakers “in the absence of further shocks and
under appropriate monetary policy.” So, any largescale event, like a sovereign debt crisis, will alter the
expectations of FOMC participants, and in turn
the path of their projections.
Still, projections of the federal funds rate should
provide a guide as to how the FOMC is thinking about economic conditions and how those
conditions influence its policy choices. One might
characterize this as a basis for the public to infer a
policy reaction function. The idea is that the public
could see what the participants expect to happen in
the economy, and then based on those expectations,
how they would respond in their policy decisions.
In some respects, the submitted projections will be
a set of hypothetical situations, with each element
of the set providing an insight into how the FOMC
participant would respond to that situation.
23

By providing these viewpoints, the goal is to inform
the public about how the FOMC thinks about the
economy. If the public can better predict how the
FOMC will respond to changes in economic conditions, people can better incorporate that information into their economic decisions. In a research paper, the economists Glenn D. Rudebusch and John
C. Williams showed that this alignment of public
and central bank expectations reduced the magnitude of fluctuations in output and the difference
between the inflation rate and its target (“Revealing
the Secrets of the Temple: The Value of Publishing
Central Bank Interest Rate Projections”).

Norway’s March 2007 Projection
Percent
9
8
7

30% probability
50% probability
70% probability
90% probability

Projected sight
deposit rate path

6
5
4
3
2

Actual sight
deposit rate path

1
0
3/2005

3/2006

3/2007

3/2008

3/2009

3/2010

Source: Norges Bank.

Other central banks have tried to communicate
the conditionality of these projections by producing fan charts, or probability distributions. Below
is a chart from the Norges Bank in March 2007.
At that time, it predicted that its sight deposit rate
would reach 5.0 percent by March 2007 and then
level off between 5.5 percent and 5.0 percent until
the end of 2010. By the time December 2008 arrived, economic conditions had worsened, so the
Norges Bank began lowering its target interest rate.
The rate fell below 2.5 percent by March 2009 and
eventually settled at 2.0 percent. When the projections were made in March 2008, they were conditional on economic conditions developing according to policymakers’ estimations, but policymakers
were also uncertain that their expectations would
be met. Thus, they included a probability distribution around their projection, which outlines a range
of possible monetary policy responses to unexpected changes in economic conditions.
This example may not be illustrative of what the
FOMC has provided because the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections comprises a collection of participants’ projections. But based on the
practices of other central banks, an observer might
expect that each FOMC member is thinking about
their projections in a way similar to this fan chart.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

24

Regional Economics

Trends in Housing Prices per Square Foot
01.19.2012
by Stephan Whitaker
To attract job candidates and firms to a region like
the Fourth District, recruiters routinely point out
the affordability of living in their area, especially
the cost of housing. The pitch that “you can get
more house for your dollar here,” is aimed especially at growing families with mid-range incomes.
The large coastal metros have long had housing
costs above those of inland cities. In 1997, the
median price per square foot for a home in the San
Francisco area was $158 and the figure for Boston
was $104. That same year, homes sold at $76 per
square foot in Columbus and $56 in Pittsburgh.
These regional price differences widened over the
next 10 years until a family’s housing budget in
San Francisco bought them only a quarter of the
square footage that it could buy in Columbus.
Rapid appreciation took housing prices in the other
“sand states” (Florida, Arizona, Nevada) up over 50
percent above those in the Fourth District.

Twelve-Month Moving Average Median
Sale Price per Square Foot
Median sale price per square foot
110

Akron
Canton
Cleveland

105
100

Columbus
Dayton
Toledo
Pittsburgh

95
90
85
80
75
70
65
60
2007

2008

2009

2010

Where are these trends heading in the wake of the
housing bust? The states and metro areas of the
Fourth District still enjoy an advantage over places
like San Francisco and New York on a price-persquare-foot basis. However, the post-boom prices in
formerly expensive cities like Tampa and Las Vegas
are now below those of Columbus and Cleveland.
While median sale prices are the most commonly
cited measure of housing costs, prices usually are
not adjusted for differences in the housing stocks
between regions. The median house sold on Long
Island will be much smaller (and older, with fewer
amenities) than the median home sold near Phoenix, even if their sale prices are similar. As a first
step toward seeing how far a housing dollar goes
in an area, one can look at the median price per
square foot. Looking at trends in this measure also
reveals if residential properties are maintaining their
value, and if housing demand is high enough

2011

Source: Zillow via Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

25

to support a normal level of construction activity.
Both questions are important for economic growth
prospects in a region.
The median sale price per square foot is charted
below for the states of the Fourth District and the
nation. The decline from the high of the housing
market is clearly visible in the national trend. In
the middle of the last decade, the Fourth District
was not greatly affected by the run-up in housing prices, and therefore it enjoyed a competitive
advantage on this measure. However, as prices have
come down nationally, Pennsylvania is now just at
the national average. Housing in Ohio is becoming
more affordable. This may be good for attracting
new residents from outside the state, but it is not
good for the Ohio homeowners losing equity. West
Virginia’s housing costs have remained among the
most affordable in the nation on a per-square-foot
basis.

Median Sale Price per Square Foot
U.S. dollars (thousands)
450
2006
2011

400
350
300
250
200
150
100

0

San Francisco
Los Angeles
New York
Baltimore
Denver
Portland
Chicago
Sacramento
Raleigh
St. Louis
Columbus
Charlotte
Pittsburgh
Little Rock
Cleveland
Oklahoma
Akron
Atlanta
Phoenix
Tampa
Las Vegas
Memphis
Dayton
Orlando
Toledo
Mobile
Canton

50

Source: Zillow via Haver Analytics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

Housing prices vary with the season, with higher
prices during the spring and summer months,
when more buyers are in the market. It is difficult
to see past this seasonality at the metro level, so it
helps to look at 12-month moving averages. The
national figure’s recent lows are still above $105
per square foot, and the Fourth District metro area
with the highest median, Columbus, is below that
level. Prices per square foot are trending down in all
the metro areas except Pittsburgh. Canton, Dayton,
and Toledo all offer very affordable housing. Residential space in these areas costs around $30 less
than the national median.
Where the Fourth District metro areas stand relative to other metro areas has changed since the
height of the housing boom in 2006. The median
cost of housing, on a per-square-foot basis, was
more than twice as high in the expensive coastal
metro areas in 2006 as in the Fourth District. The
gap has narrowed considerably in the last five years.
The Fourth District metro areas are on par with cities such as Atlanta, Charlotte, and Oklahoma City.
Several boomtown metro areas, such as Phoenix,
Orlando, and Tampa, had significantly higher costs
per square foot in 2006. These markets now have
inventories of new large homes coming out of fore

26

to support a normal level of construction activity.
Both questions are important for economic growth
prospects in a region.

Median Sale Price and Estimated
Construction Cost for New, Single-family
Homes
Median sale price per square foot
300

SF

LA

250
NY

200
BLT

150

DNV
PL
CHI
SAC

100
LV

RAL
STL
COL Homes
CHR
PIT -family
LR OKC
ATLAKR
PHXCLE
MEM
ORLCAN
TOL
MOB

TMP
DYT

50
60

80

100

120

140

Estimated construction costs per square foot
Note: Construction costs per square foot are estimated using data from the U.S.
Census Bureau, which gathers information on new homes from building permits and
interviews with developers. To get the average value for new, single-family homes in
each metro area, I take the total value of new homes from the permits and divide it by
the number of permits. To calculate the construction cost per square foot, I divide the
average new-home cost by the 2008-2010 average square footage of new homes in
the metro area’s census region. (2011 estimates are not yet available).
Sources: Zillow via Haver Analytics, U.S. Census Survey of Construction, and
author’s calculations.

The median sale price per square foot is charted
below for the states of the Fourth District and the
nation. The decline from the high of the housing
market is clearly visible in the national trend. In
the middle of the last decade, the Fourth District
was not greatly affected by the run-up in housing prices, and therefore it enjoyed a competitive
advantage on this measure. However, as prices have
come down nationally, Pennsylvania is now just at
the national average. Housing in Ohio is becoming
more affordable. This may be good for attracting
new residents from outside the state, but it is not
good for the Ohio homeowners losing equity. West
Virginia’s housing costs have remained among the
most affordable in the nation on a per-square-foot
basis.
Housing prices vary with the season, with higher
prices during the spring and summer months,
when more buyers are in the market. It is difficult
to see past this seasonality at the metro level, so it
helps to look at 12-month moving averages. The
national figure’s recent lows are still above $105
per square foot, and the Fourth District metro area
with the highest median, Columbus, is below that
level. Prices per square foot are trending down in all
the metro areas except Pittsburgh. Canton, Dayton,
and Toledo all offer very affordable housing. Residential space in these areas costs around $30 less
than the national median.
Where the Fourth District metro areas stand relative to other metro areas has changed since the
height of the housing boom in 2006. The median
cost of housing, on a per-square-foot basis, was
more than twice as high in the expensive coastal
metro areas in 2006 as in the Fourth District. The
gap has narrowed considerably in the last five years.
The Fourth District metro areas are on par with cities such as Atlanta, Charlotte, and Oklahoma City.
Several boomtown metro areas, such as Phoenix,
Orlando, and Tampa, had significantly higher costs
per square foot in 2006. These markets now have
inventories of new large homes coming out of fore

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

27

closure, which has lowered their price per square
foot below that of Cleveland and Akron.
One of greatest economic challenges to come out
of the recent recession was the dramatic decline
in residential construction activity. Under normal
conditions, residential construction is a substantial
employer and a contributor to the gross regional
product. But if existing homes are selling for low
prices, it will be more difficult for builders to market new homes.
To shed some light on the relative costs of new and
existing homes, we plot the costs for both against
each other in the chart below. If the square footage of existing homes and new homes is similarly
priced in a region, then it will show up near the red
dashed line. In these areas, new construction should
be able to compete with existing homes, especially
because home buyers will pay extra for the latest
amenities, greater efficiency, lower maintenance,
and exclusive locations that new homes can provide. In Dayton, Canton, Toledo, and Cleveland,
new construction may have difficulty competing
with low-priced existing homes. Likewise, residential space is inexpensive relative to new construction
in Phoenix, Orlando, and Tampa. New construction should be able to continue at a normal pace in
Columbus and Pittsburgh.
The data we have used here have some limitations.
The median price-per-square-foot (like the median
price) can be pulled down by unusually frequent
turnover of low-value properties. The flipping of
foreclosed homes may have a strong influence on
recent data in weak housing markets. Also, estimates are not available for all regions. Data are not
available for the Cincinnati and Lexington metro
areas and the last three months of West Virginia’s
series.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

28

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | February 2012

29