View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

Caveat forecaster…The most remarkable aspect of
current economic conditions is that they are so unremarkable. Real GDP expanded at a 3.7 percent
rate during the last four quarters, the unemployment rate stands at 5.2 percent, and core CPI inflation registered 2.2 percent during the last 12
months. In other words, the economy is expanding
somewhat faster than its long-term average, unemployment is at its long-term average, and the inflation rate is low and stable. Many forecasters expect
real GDP to expand at a slightly slower rate in 2005
than in 2004, but still at a solid pace. Inflation is also
thought to be well anchored although inflation measures were slightly elevated during the past year.
Most analysts’ relatively sanguine picture of 2005
does not necessarily mean that it will turn out to be
a ho-hum year. First, any forecast is just that, a forecast subject to various risk factors. Some, like energy
prices, seem obvious. Others, like the pace of productivity growth, are more subtle. If productivity
growth slows significantly from its pace of the last
decade, might pressure on wages and inflation
going forward be stronger than what is built into the
average forecast? What about household consumption? If consumers decide to increase their personal
saving rates after a long period of decline, might that
not come at the expense of some of the consumption spending already built into the projections?
Professional forecasters, who know more about
these risks than the public does, use projections to
evaluate exposure to various possible scenarios—
they do not simply plan for the most likely one.
Another reason to be skeptical about forecasts
for 2005 is that economists have more talent for
describing the future than putting a date on it. The
U.S. current account deficit and the dollar provide a
good example: Several years ago, a number of economists pointed out that if our current account continued on its (then) present course, one might
reasonably expect the U.S. dollar to depreciate
against its trading partners’ currencies. The logic of
this prediction rested on the much-quoted observation that unsustainable events have a way of stopping. If the current account deficit ever stopped
growing in proportion to our GDP, economic

theory and historical precedent suggested that dollar depreciation would probably be part of the
adjustment process.
Some forecasters called for a little depreciation,
others for a lot. Some expected a sharp adjustment,
others a prolonged rebalancing. Whatever their
views, they all looked foolish as long as the current
account deficit continued to deepen without consequence for the dollar. Eventually, these forecasters’
main point proved correct—the dollar did depreciate on a trade-weighted basis against foreign currencies. Whether the amount has been large or
small, and the pace fast or slow, lies in the eyes of
the beholder. Moreover, the current account deficit
itself has not yet begun its predicted reversal, creating yet another opportunity for differences of opinion regarding the timing and magnitude of its doing
so.; it is also plausible that it will not occur at all.
Forecasters tackle even longer-term issues than
the current account, such as the solvency of the
Social Security system. In that debate, the Social Security trustees and the Congressional Budget
Office, respectively, estimate that the system will be
unable to pay its obligations in about 40 or 50 years.
Of course, some scenarios telescope that date
forward and others push it back even further, but
the indisputable fact is that something’s got to give.
Some people argue that 40 to 50 years is a long
time, and since anything can happen—including a
favorable economic future—why bother to press
for reforms now. Others contend that since anything can happen—including a less favorable financial future—it is prudent to plan for insolvency now.
One reason to plan ahead for insolvency arises
from another set of projections: Medicare and Medicaid deficits will increase rapidly as a share of GDP
at the same time that Social Security is headed
toward insolvency. Although many potential solutions could put these programs back on sustainable
financial paths, predicting when and how a solution
will be reached seems as useless today as forecasting when and how much the dollar would depreciate seemed a few years ago. But we are enriched by
the exercise.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.25 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

December Price Statistics

4.00

Percent change, last:
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr.

2004
avg.

3.75
3.50

Consumer prices
All items

3.25

–0.6

3.0

3.3

2.5

3.4

Less food
and energy

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.1

2.3

Medianb

2.1

1.8

2.4

2.9

2.4

CPI

3.00
2.75
2.50
2.25

Producer prices

2.00

Finished goods –7.6

6.3

4.1

2.2

4.4

Less food and
energy

2.6

2.2

1.0

2.2

CPI excluding
food and energy

1.75
1.50

1.6

1.25
1.00
1995 1996

1997

1998

1999

12-month percent change
4.25 CORE CPI AND TRIMMED-MEAN MEASURES

12-month percent change
3.50 CORE CPI AND CORE PCE

4.00

3.25

3.75

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2003

2004

3.00

Median CPI b

CPI excluding food and energy

3.50

2.75

3.25

2.50

3.00

2.25

2.75
2.00
2.50
1.75
2.25
1.50

2.00

1.25

1.75

16% trimmed mean b

PCE excluding food and energy

1.00

1.50
CPI excluding food and energy

1.25
1.00
1995 1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

0.75
2004

0.50
1995 1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland.

During December, the Consumer
Price Index (CPI) declined at a 0.6%
annualized rate, reflecting a 19.8%
drop in energy prices. The core CPI
rose 1.8% for the second straight
month, while the median CPI increased 2.1%.
Growth in retail price measures accelerated in 2004; however, core measures, which exclude the more volatile
food and energy prices, showed more
modest growth (between 1.5% and
2.5%). After rising 1.9% in 2003, the
CPI advanced 3.3% in 2004—its

largest annual increase since 2000.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics attributed about one-third of the rise to a
16.6% increase in energy prices over
the year. Growth in retail prices was
more subdued and consistent across
the alternative retail price measures.
The core CPI rose a more moderate
2.2% in 2004, but still doubled its
2003 growth rate of 1.1%. The Bureau
of Labor Statistics attributed threefourths of the acceleration to rising
prices for new and used vehicles and
shelter costs. In 2004, the median CPI

rose 2.4%, and the 16% trimmed-mean
CPI rose 2.2%. The core Personal Consumption Expenditure (PCE) price
index, which measures prices for an alternative consumer-goods market basket, rose a modest 1.5% over the year.
Looking ahead, survey data from
U.S. households indicate that retail
prices over the next 12 months are
1
expected to rise 3 /2%—about the
same inflation expectation that
households have held over most of
the past three years. In fact, if we exclude the sharp drop that followed
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
12-month percent change
16 CPI AND YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD

10-year moving average
7 12-MONTH CPI INFLATION

14

6

18

5

15

4

12

3

9

2

6

1

3

INFLATION EXPECTATIONS a

Variance over the past 10 years
21

CPI
12

10

8
Year-ahead household inflation expectations
6

4

2
0

0

0
1987

1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

1993

1990

1996

1998

2001

2004

Percent
40 IMPACT OF A CHANGE IN THE 12-MONTH INFLATION
TREND ON YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION
EXPECTATIONS b
35

Variance over the past 10 years
18 VARIANCE IN 12-MONTH CPI INFLATION AND
YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS a
16
14

30

12-month CPI inflation
12

25

10
8

20

6
15
4
Year-ahead household inflation expectations

10

2
5

0
1987

1990

1993

1996

1998

2001

2004

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
b. Estimated over 10-year intervals using an ordinary least-squares equation, which regressed the change in year-ahead household inflation expectations on
the change in the 12-month inflation trend during the previous month.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and University of Michigan.

September 11, 2001, household inflation expectations have fluctuated
within a rather narrow range over
much of the past 10 years. In other
words, households seem to accept
that inflation has been following a
rather steady course and they expect
moderate inflation to continue in
the future.
Clearly, as the trend rate of inflation has moderated over time, so too
has inflation’s year-to-year volatility.
Indeed, the trend’s volatility, which
decreased dramatically with the great

disinflation of the early 1980s, has
been reduced further as inflation has
moved even lower in the current
decade. The more stable inflation
environment has been accompanied
by reduced volatility in household
inflation expectations. That is, households’ inflation sentiment appears to
be more firmly “anchored” than in
the past.
A crude way to gauge that steadiness is to consider what impact a
change in the inflation trend has
on household predictions for future

inflation—are they likely to perceive
a change in the inflation trend as a
passing event or a persistent phenomenon? In the late 1970s to early
1980s, about 30% of any change in
the inflation trend stayed in household inflation predictions for the next
year. Over the past 10 years, changes
in the inflation trend seem to have
had considerably less influence on the
public’s outlook; during that period,
only about 9% of the change in an
observed trend became embedded in
year-ahead inflation expectations.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Billions of dollars
850 THE MONETARY BASE

6%

Sweep-adjusted base growth, 1999–2004 a
15
12
Sweep-adjusted base b
9

800

750

Trillions of dollars
2.2 THE M1 AGGREGATE

6

7%
7%

6

7%

4

1.8

3
0

700

Sweep-adjusted M1 growth, 1999–2004 a
10
8

2.0

6%

7%

2
0

8%

8%

1.6
2%

650

Sweep-adjusted M1 b

5%

2%
Monetary base

12%

1.4

600
M1
1.2

550

1.0

500
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Trillions of dollars
6.8 THE M2 AGGREGATE

7%

M2 growth, 1999–2005 a
12

4%
12%

5%
8%

8%

5.0
8%

5%
5%

4.4

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

Growth Rates of Monetary Components
(percent)

1999
Monetary
basec

3
0

2000

4%

10%

6

5.6

1999

7%

9

6.2

2005

2000

Annual
2001 2002

Average,
1999–
2003 2004 2003

12.7

2.1

8.8

7.8

6.2

5.9

7.5

M1d
5.0
M2
6.2
Currency
11.1
Total
reserves
–7.2
Check and
demande –4.8
Money market
funds
13.6
Small time
deposits –0.7
Savings
deposits 10.1

1.7
6.1
4.3

8.5
10.2
9.1

6.7
6.7
8.2

7.5
5.3
5.9

7.0
5.1
5.5

5.9
6.9
7.7

–6.2

8.7

–6.6

8.2

7.2

–0.6

–6.8

5.2

–1.5

7.3

5.4

–0.1

11.4

7.8

–6.6

–11.6 –12.0

2.9

9.6

–5.0

–9.1

–9.3

–0.4

–2.9

6.7

21.7

21.1

15.2

10.8

15.0

3.8
1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. The far-right bars refer to the most recent data available. Growth rates are calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis except for the far-right bar
for M2, which refers to the annualized year-to-date growth rate from 2004:IVQ to January 2005. All data are seasonally adjusted.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts. Sweepadjusted M1 contains an estimate of balances temporarily moved from M1 to non-M1 accounts.
c. Sweep-adjusted base.
d. Sweep-adjusted M1.
e. Demand deposits and other checkable deposits.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Money Stock Measures,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.6.

Growth in the sweep-adjusted monetary base (total currency in circulation
plus total reserves plus vault cash of
depository institutions not applied to
reserve requirements) has been fairly
constant for a couple of years. In 2004,
however, it showed an annual growth
rate of 5.9%, slower than its 7.5% average for 1999–2003. Base growth declined, primarily because currency
growth slowed. Currency growth
moderated to an annual rate of 5.5%,
in contrast with its five-year average
of 7.7%. On the other hand, total

reserves rose 7.2% in 2004 after falling
0.6% over the previous five years.
M1, which consists of currency in
the hands of the public plus demand
and other checkable deposits, is a
slightly broader monetary aggregate.
Like the monetary base, sweepadjusted M1 growth has been fairly
stable for a couple of years. Unlike
base growth, however, M1 growth was
slightly higher than its 1999–2003
average. Much of this acceleration
resulted from a sharp increase in the
sum of demand deposits and other

checkable deposits, which represent
roughly 48% of M1. After falling 0.1%
in 1999–2003, its growth rate rose
5.4% in 2004.
An even broader monetary aggregate, M2, grew 5.1% in 2004, 1.8 percentage points less than its 1999–2003
average. This slower growth resulted
from a 12% decline in retail money
market mutual funds and a slight
(0.4%) decline in small time deposits
in 2004. These declines partly offset
the 7% advance in M1 and the 10.8%
increase in savings deposits in 2004.
(continued on next page)

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy (cont.)
Percent
8 RESERVE MARKET RATES
7

Anticipated Target Federal Funds Rates
(calculated January 27, 2004)

Effective federal funds rate a

February 1–2 meeting

Target federal funds rate

6

Implied probabilityc

2.25%

2.50%

2.75%

0.0%

98.5%

1.5%

5
Intended federal funds rate b

March 22 meeting

4

Target federal funds rate
Implied probabilityd

Discount rate b

2.25% 2.50% 2.75% 3.00%
0.4%

4.5% 85.3%

9.8%

3
Discount rate b

May 3 meeting

2

Target federal funds rate
Implied probabilitye

2.50% 2.75% 3.00% 3.25%
3.4% 13.3% 66.2% 17.1%

1
0
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005
Percent, monthly
4.0 TIPS-BASED INFLATION EXPECTATIONS

Percent, weekly
4.5 YIELD SPREAD: 10-YEAR TREASURY NOTE
4.0

MINUS THREE-MONTH TREASURY BILL
3.5

3.5
Yield spread: 10-year Treasury note minus 10-year corrected TIPS f,g
3.0

3.0

2.5
2.5

2.0
1.5

2.0

1.0
1.5

0.5

Yield spread: 10-year Treasury note minus 10-year TIPS

0
1.0
–0.5
–1.0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

0.5
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Weekly average of daily figures.
b. Daily observations.
c. Probabilities are calculated using trading-day closing prices from options on February 2005 federal funds futures that trade on the Chicago Board of Trade.
d. Probabilities are calculated using trading-day closing prices from options on April 2005 federal funds futures that trade on the Chicago Board of Trade.
e. Probabilities are calculated using trading-day closing prices from options on May 2005 federal funds futures that trade on the Chicago Board of Trade.
f. The corrected TIPS yield is adjusted for the liquidity premium.
g. The liquidity premium is calculated as the difference between yields of on-the-run versus off-the-run conventional Treasuries, using data from the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Chicago Board of Trade;
and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

At its meeting on December 14,
2004, the Federal Open Market Committee raised the target federal funds
rate 25 basis points (bp) to 2.25%, the
fifth such increase since the rate stood
at 1% in June 2003. Evidence from options on federal funds futures implies
that market participants expect a 25
bp rate increase at each of the next
three meetings, which would raise the
target federal funds rate to 3% after
the May meeting.
The yield curve has flattened continuously over the past few months.

The yield spread between the 10-year
Treasury note and the three-month
Treasury bill dropped from 343 bp
in June to 182 bp in late January.
Although an inversion of the yield
curve frequently portends a recession,
as it did in 2001, a flattening of the
yield curve is not necessarily bad news
for the economy. Flattening can result
from changes in economic fundamentals, inflation expectations, or both.
The yield curve can be expected to
flatten with increases in short-term
interest rates if long-term inflation

expectations remain well anchored.
If we use Treasury inflation-protected
securities (TIPS) to gauge inflation expectations over the next 10 years, we
see that both the raw TIPS numbers
and those adjusted for liquidity risk are
hovering around 2.6%. The five recent
hikes of 25 bp each in the target rate,
coupled with the market’s expectation
of gradual, continued tightening, seem
to have reinforced the public’s confidence that the Federal Reserve will not
let inflation accelerate.

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Business Cycles
2004 dollars per barrel
110 REAL OIL PRICES AND THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE a

Percent
22

100

20

Basis point change from previous peak
200 EFFECTIVE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
150
2001:IQ peak

100
90

18

80

16

0

70

14

–50

60

12

50

–100

Average c

–150
50

10
Federal funds rate

40
30

–200

8

–250

6

–300

Real oil prices b
20

4

10

2

–350
–400

0
1973

0
1977

1981

1985

1989

1993

1997

2001

2005

–450
–500
–8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Quarters from previous peak

Percent change from previous peak
16 REAL PRIVATE FIXED INVESTMENT d

Percent change from previous peak
14 REAL GDP

12

12
10

8

Average e
8

Average e

4
6

2001:IQ peak

0
4
–4
2
–8

0
2001:IQ peak

–12

–2

–16

–4
0

1

2

3

4

5 6 7
8 9 10
Quarters from previous peak

11 12

13

14

15

0

1

2

3

4

5 6 7 8 9 10
Quarters from previous peak

11 12

13

14

15

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Shaded bars indicate periods of recession.
b. Prices of West Texas intermediate crude oil, deflated by the Consumer Price Index.
c. Includes peaks in 1957:IIIQ, 1960:IIQ, 1969:IVQ, 1973:IVQ, 1980:IQ, 1981:IIIQ, and 1990:IIIQ.
d. Nonresidential.
e. Includes peaks in 1948:IVQ, 1953:IIQ, 1957:IIIQ, 1960:IIQ, 1969:IVQ, 1973:IVQ, 1980:IQ, 1981:IIIQ, and 1990:IIIQ.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Wall Street Journal.

Oil prices and the federal funds rate
typically spike before recessions. Both
are likely to be causal factors, although
the spikes’ timing and impact on the
economy vary. Oil prices spiked before
the 2001 downturn, but earlier than
they typically do. And although the fed
funds rate also jumped, the increase
was less pronounced than usual,
which suggests that policy changes
were not as influential as they sometimes have been.

The 2001 recession was driven
primarily by investment, which fell
nearly twice as far from its peak as it
typically does. One reason for this,
distinct from both oil prices and
interest rates, may have been excess
investment or “capital overhang”
leading into the recession. But the
real anomaly was not how the economy behaved going into the recession but how it behaved coming out.
Now, nearly four years after the National Bureau of Economic Research

declared the recession officially over,
employment is just approaching its
prerecession level; in a typical recovery, it would be 6% higher than
it was before the downturn. Some
researchers believe that the persistently weak employment numbers
reflect a fundamental restructuring in
the economy. They point out that
almost all the layoffs in this recession
were permanent; temporary layoffs,
which generally increase during a
recession, were unusually flat.
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Business Cycles (cont.)
Percent change from previous peak
8 NONFARM EMPLOYMENT

Percent
2.50 TEMPORARY LAYOFF RATE b

7

2.25

6

2.00

5

1.75

Average a
4

1.50
3
1.25
2
1.00
1
0.75

0

0.50

–1
2001:IQ peak

0.25

–2
–3
0

1

2

3

4

5 6 7 8 9 10
Quarters from previous peak

11 12

13

14

15

Percent change from previous peak
18 NONFARM PRODUCTIVITY

0
1967

1972

1977

1982

1987

1992

1997

2002

Percent change from previous quarter
40 REAL OIL PRICES c

16
30
Average d

14
2001:IQ peak
20

12
10

10

8
0

6
Average a
4

–10

2

2001:IQ peak
–20

0
–2

–30
0

1

2

3

4

5 6 7 8 9 10
Quarters from previous peak

11 12

13

14

15

–8 –7 –6 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Quarters from previous peak

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Includes peaks in 1948:IVQ, 1953:IIQ, 1957:IIIQ, 1960:IIQ, 1969:IVQ, 1973:IVQ, 1980:IQ, 1981:IIIQ, and 1990:IIIQ.
b. Shaded bars indicate periods of recession.
c. Prices of West Texas intermediate crude oil, deflated by the Consumer Price Index, 2004 dollars per barrel.
d. Includes peaks that started in 1973:IVQ, 1980:IQ, 1981:IIIQ, and 1990:IIIQ.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Wall Street Journal.

Yet using the recession to explain
what has been going on in the recovery may be misleading. The recession, which ended almost four years
ago, is in many ways a distant memory. While the recovery has been
atypical, the terminology unfortunately causes us to focus on the recession for what was, and to some
extent still is, happening. But the
cause of the “job-loss recovery” may
be independent of what originally
caused the 2001 downturn. If that is

so, what explains the labor market’s
sluggishness?
Productivity growth doesn’t seem
to be the answer. It has been robust,
so that one would expect firms to
have hired more workers. Perhaps
the causes of labor’s feeble recovery
are the usual ones: interest rates, oil
prices, or a combination of the two.
Interest rates, however, were cut as
aggressively and consistently as after
a typical recession. Oil, however, is a
likely culprit. At the end of 2001,
crude oil sold for $20 per barrel;

a year later a barrel was going for
$30. After a short pause, oil prices
continued their near-relentless climb,
peaking at nearly $50 per barrel at
the close of 2004. This strongly suggests that oil has been a major cause
of employment’s inability to recover
from the recession. Yet high oil prices
have not translated into another
recession; the economy seems to
be healthy otherwise. Productivity’s
steady advance has allowed output to
continue growing.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Chinese Renminbi
Billions of dollars
180 U.S. GOODS DEFICIT WITH CHINA

Percent of total goods deficit
30

Percent of GDP
15 CHINA'S BALANCE OF PAYMENTS b
12

150

25

120

20

9

Current account

Portfolio and other financial flows c

Net direct investment

Reserve accumulation

6
3
90

15

60

10

30

5

0
–3
–6
–9
–12

0

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

–15

2004 a

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

12-month percent change
30 CONSUMER PRICE INDEX

Index, June 1995=100
120 RENMINBI/DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE

25

110

20

100
China

15

Real

90
Nominal

10

80

5

70
U.S.

0

60

–5

50
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Covers December 2003 through November 2004.
b. Data for 2004 and 2005 are International Monetary Fund forecasts.
c. Includes other errors and omissions through 2003.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; International Monetary Fund,
International Financial Statistics, IMF Country Report No. 04/351 November 2004; and National Bureau of Statistics of China.

During the 12 months ending in November 2004, the U.S. registered a
$157.6 billion deficit in goods trade
with China, a shortfall that accounts
for nearly 25% of the total U.S. trade
deficit. In recent years, China generally has run a current account surplus
equal to approximately 3% of its GDP
and has experienced direct investment inflows of a similar magnitude.
Contrary to the claims of many analysts, China’s exchange rate policies
do not seem to explain much of its
trade performance.
In 1995, China pegged its currency,
the renminbi, to the U.S. dollar at

approximately Rmb 8.3 per dollar.
This peg, however, tells us nothing
about China’s competitiveness relative
to the U.S. because it ignores price
patterns. The real renminbi–dollar
exchange rate adjusts the exchange
rate peg for changes in relative inflation rates, thereby providing a clearer
picture of China’s competitiveness.
On a real basis, the dollar has appreciated only 2.5% against the renminbi
since the beginning of the peg; that
movement cannot confer much of
a trade advantage on China. The real
exchange rate has, however, undergone some large swings. Between

June 1995 and October 1997, the dollar depreciated 11.4% against the renminbi because China’s inflation rate
exceeded that of the U.S. Between
October 1997 and October 2003, however, the dollar appreciated 17.3%
against the renminbi on a real basis
because China’s inflation rate was
lower than that of the U.S. Since
October 2003, China’s inflation rate
has generally exceeded ours, and the
dollar has again depreciated 1.4%
against the renminbi on a real basis.
To keep the renminbi pegged at
Rmb 8.3 per dollar in the face of an
overall balance-of-payments surplus,
(continued on next page)

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Chinese Renminbi (cont.)
Billions of dollars, end of quarter
600 CHINA'S FOREIGN EXCHANGE RESERVES

Factors Determining the Monetary Base

500

Billions of renminbi
Monetary Foreign Domestic Misc.
base
assets
assets liabilities

400

Change,
1995:IIQ–
2004:IIIQ

3,979.69

3,413.09

1,037.33

470.73

Change,
2000:IVQ–
2004:IIIQ

1,918.01

2,387.07

–92.18

376.87

300

200

100

0
1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

CHINA’S MAJOR SOURCES OF IMPORTS, 2003

2002

2004

MAJOR RECIPIENTS OF CHINA’S EXPORTS, 2003
South Korea
5%

Malaysia
3%

Other
43%

Taiwan
12%

Hong Kong
17%
South Korea
10%

U.S.
8%
Japan
18%

Netherlands
3%

Japan
14%

Other
36%

U.S.
21%

Germany
4%

Germany
6%

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

SOURCE: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, Direction of Trade Statistics Yearbook 2004.

the People’s Bank of China, the country’s central bank, buys dollars on
the foreign exchange market. The
process expands China’s monetary
base and risks generating inflation. In
fact, this mechanism will prevent
China from realizing a long-term
trade advantage from its peg, because a rising inflation rate will dull
China’s competitive edge.
The People’s Bank of China can
frustrate the impact of its dollar
acquisitions on its monetary base
and inflation by selling domestic
assets from its portfolio or by increasing nonmonetary liabilities on

its balance sheet, but since the inception of the peg in 1995, the bank
has generally not done so. Between
1995:IIQ and 2004:IIIQ, China’s central bank acquired the equivalent of
Rmb 3.4 trillion in foreign exchange,
and its monetary base grew nearly
Rmb 4 trillion.
Since the end of 2000, however, the
picture has changed. The People’s
Bank has acquired nearly Rmb 2.4 trillion in foreign assets, but the monetary base has grown only Rmb1.9 trillion. The bank has offset the effect of
reserve growth on its monetary base
by reducing its holdings of domestic

assets slightly and by increasing
other, nonmonetary liabilities on its
balance sheet. Overall, since 2000,
the bank has neutralized 20% of the
increase in its foreign reserves. It has
also raised reserve requirements,
another anti-inflation measure, and
the government has tried to slow
investment spending.
To be sure, China has many artificial
barriers to trade and financial flows
that help it sustain an overall balanceof-payments surplus, but the contribution of its exchange rate policies
seems to have been overstated.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Percentage points
4 CONTRIBUTION TO PERCENT CHANGE IN REAL GDP c

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2004:IVQ
(Advance estimate)

Annualized
percent change
Current
Four
quarter
quarters

Change,
billions
of 2000 $

Real GDP
84.7
Personal consumption 87.6
Durables
18.3
Nondurables
31.5
Services
39.4
Business fixed
investment
31.0
Equipment
35.9
Structures
–2.5
Residential investment
0.4
Government spending
4.6
National defense
0.0
Net exports
–48.7
Exports
–11.1
Imports
37.6
Change in business
inventories
11.3

3.1
4.6
6.7
5.8
3.7

3.7
3.9
6.3
4.3
3.2

10.3
14.9
–4.1
0.3
0.9
0.0
__
–3.9
9.1

9.9
13.6
–1.6
5.7
1.6
5.5
__
4.1
9.2

__

__

3

Last four quarters

Personal
consumption

2004:IIIQ
2004:IVQ

2

1

Exports

Residential
investment
0

Government
spending

Business fixed
investment

–1

Change in
inventories
Imports

–2

Annualized quarterly percent change
5.0 GDP AND OTHER INDICATORS c

Annualized quarterly percent change
5.0 REAL GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST c

4.5
4.5

Final percent change
Advance estimate
Blue Chip forecast d

Real GDP
Capacity utilization
Hours of employment
Nonfarm employment
Industrial production

4.0
3.5

4.0
30-year average

3.0
2.5

3.5

2.0
3.0

1.5
1.0

2.5
0.5
0

2.0
IVQ
2003

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2004

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2005

IVQ

2004:IIIQ

2004:IVQ

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 2000 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to the total because the total and all components are deflated using independent chain-weighted price indexes.
c. Data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
d. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; National Bureau of Economic
Research, National Income and Product Accounts; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 2004.

Real GDP grew at an annual rate of
3.1% in 2004:IVQ, according to the
U.S. Commerce Department’s advance estimate. This was 0.9 percentage point (pp) lower than the
2004:IIIQ growth rate of 4.0%. The
growth rate slowed for most subcomponents, most notably exports,
which decreased at an annualized
rate of 3.9% in the fourth quarter
after increasing 6.0% in the third.
Durable goods increased 6.7% in
2004:IVQ, compared with an increase
of 17.2% the previous quarter, and

national defense spending was unchanged after growing at an annualized rate of 10.0%.
Unlike 2004:IIIQ, when changes in
private inventories subtracted 1.0 pp
(pp), they contributed 0.4 pp to real
GDP growth in 2004:IVQ. However,
this was offset by net exports, which
subtracted 1.7 pp.
Blue Chip forecasters had predicted growth of 3.7% for 2004:IVQ,
0.6 pp higher than the advance estimate of 3.1%. It was also 0.1 pp lower
than the 30-year average and the

lowest annual growth rate since
2003:IQ, when the economy grew at
1.9%. However, Blue Chip forecasters estimate that growth will average
3.5% in 2005.
There are often substantial revisions
to the National Income and Product
Accounts between the advance and
final estimates. Supply-side components give some hint of the likely
direction of these revisions. Growth in
capacity utilization was up 1.4 pp.
Hours were down 1.0 pp, while employment was up more than 0.6 pp.
(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Hours of employment, annualized quarterly percent change a
9 HOURS OF EMPLOYMENT AND REAL GDP GROWTH

Capacity utilization, annualized quarterly percent change
10 CAPACITY UTILIZATION AND REAL GDP GROWTH
8

7
6
5

4
2

3
0
1

–2
–4

–1

–6
–3
–8
–10

–5
–2

0

6
2
4
Real GDP, annualized quarterly percent change

8

Nonfarm employees, annualized quarterly percent change a
5 NONFARM EMPLOYEE AND REAL GDP GROWTH

–2

0

6
2
4
Real GDP, annualized quarterly percent change

8

Industrial production, annualized quarterly percent change
15 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION AND REAL GDP GROWTH

4
10
3

2

5

1
0

0

–1
–5
–2
–10

–3
–2

0

6
2
4
Real GDP, annualized quarterly percent change

8

–2

0

6
2
4
Real GDP, annualized quarterly percent change

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
a. Establishment survey.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.

Given capital and labor shares for the
U.S. economy, this evidence suggests a
more modest fall in GDP than the advance estimate. The increase in industrial production lends further support
to this conclusion.
A relationship between GDP and inputs (which generally are measured
more frequently) allows inferences
about what the final GDP might be.
There is a positive correlation of 0.63
between growth in capacity utilization
and real GDP growth. Capacity utilization refers to how intensively capital is

being used. Capital’s share of income
is roughly 30%, so an increase of 1 pp
in capacity utilization should raise
GDP 0.3 pp.
Labor input is probably best measured by hours of work. The correlation between growth in hours and
growth in real GDP is 0.57, showing
that these series are also positively
associated. Labor’s share of income
is around 70%, so a 1 pp increase in
the growth of hours should translate
into a 0.7 pp increase in the growth
of real GDP.

Employment is an alternative measure of the labor input. Employment
growth is also positively correlated
with real GDP (0.50), although less
closely than hours.
Industrial production is an output
measure that is less inclusive than
GDP. An advantage of looking at this
series is that it is available monthly,
whereas GDP is available only on a
quarterly basis. The correlation between the growth in these two series
is relatively strong at 0.69.

8

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
400 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT CHANGE

Labor Market Conditions

350

Average monthly change
(thousands of employees, NAICS)

Preliminary estimate

300

Revised

250

Payroll employment

200

Goods producing
Construction
Manufacturing
Durable goods
Nondurable goods

150
100

Service providing
Retail trade
Financial activitiesa
PBSb
Temporary help svcs.
Education & health svcs.
Leisure and hospitality

50
0
–50

2002
–45

2003
8

–124
–1
–123
–88
–35

–76
–7
–67
–48
–19

–42
10
–51
–32
–19

27
22
3
8
–5

–31
–9
–25
–12
–13

–25
–24
8
–63
–37
50
46

30
–10
6
–17
2
40
21

50
–5
7
22
12
30
–4

154
13
12
43
16
34
22

177
19
21
25
18
35
20

–100

2004
181

Jan.
2005
146

2001
–148

Average for period (percent)
Civilian unemployment
rate

–150

4.8

5.8

6.0

5.5

5.2

–200
2001 2002 2003 2004

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2004

IVQ

Nov. Dec. Jan.
2004
2005

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS

Percent
6.5

Employment-to-population ratio

12-month percent change, quarterly
8 EMPLOYMENT COST INDEX c
7

6.0

64.5

6
5.5

64.0

5
Compensation
63.5

5.0

63.0

4.5

4

3
Wages and salaries
2
Employer costs for employee benefits

4.0

62.5

1

Civilian unemployment rate
62.0
1995 1996

3.5
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

0
1990

1993

1996

1999

2002

2005

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted unless otherwise noted.
a. Financial activities include the finance, insurance, and real estate sector and the rental and leasing sector.
b. Professional and business services include professional, scientific, and technical services, management of companies and enterprises, administrative and
support, and waste management and remediation services.
c. Data not seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Nonfarm payroll employment increased 146,000 in January. December’s growth was revised down
24,000, although the employment
level was raised 161,000 after the
benchmark revision and updating of
seasonal factors. Payroll employment
declined by 2.7 million from February
2001 to May 2003, but has increased
by the same number since then.
Service-providing industries increased by 177,000 jobs in January;
education and health services contributed 35,000, approximating the
monthly gain in 2004. Manufacturing

jobs fell by 25,000 in January, nearly
half in the transportation equipment
industry. After increasing 85,000 from
January through August of last year,
manufacturing payrolls have fallen by
61,000. Construction jobs fell 9,000,
the first decline since February 2004,
possibly because of adverse weather.
In January, the unemployment rate
fell 0.2 percentage point (pp) to 5.2%,
mostly the result of lower labor force
participation. The unemployment rate
has fallen more than 1 pp from its 6.3%
peak in June 2003. The employmentto-population ratio, which changed

little during the same period, remained at 62.4% in January.
The Employment Cost Index, which
measures changes in compensation
costs not influenced by employment
shifts across industries or occupations,
rose 0.7% from 2004:IIIQ to 2004:IV; its
components, wages/salaries and benefits costs, increased 0.4% and 1.4%,
respectively; benefits accounted for
more than 60% of the total compensation increase, continuing recent years’
trends of accelerating benefits costs
and declining wage and salary growth.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Job Reallocation in the Recovery
Percent of labor force
12 UNEMPLOYMENT AND JOB LOSERS a

Millions
Percent still unemployed at beginning of following year c
10 WORKER DISPLACEMENT c
30
Durable goods manufacturing

10
8

24
Nonmanufacturing
Nondurable goods manufacturing

Unemployed
8

Durable goods manufacturing
6

18
Nondurable goods manufacturing

6

Nonmanufacturing
Job losers on
temporary layoff

4

2

0
1967

4

12

2

6

Job losers not on
temporary layoff b

0
1971

1975

1979

1983

1987

1991

1995

1999

2003

0
1/93–12/95

1/95–12/97

1/97–12/99

1/99–12/01

1/01–12/03

Percent of employment in sector
9 QUARTERLY GROSS JOB GAINS AND LOSSES f

12-month employment growth after business cycle
25 INDUSTY EMPLOYMENT GROWTH
DURING AND AFTER RECESSIONS a,e
20

Gross job gains, private sector
8

15
10

Gross job losses, private sector

7

5
6

0

Gross job losses, manufacturing sector
–5
5

–10
1981–82 recession
2001 recession

–15

4
Gross job gains, manufacturing sector

–20
3

–25
–25

–20

–15 –10
–5
0
5
10
15
Annualized employment growth during recession

20

25

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Recession periods dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
b. Job losers not on temporary layoff include permanent job losers or persons who completed temporary jobs.
c. Displaced workers are those who had three or more years-tenure on a job they lost or left because of plant or company closings or moves, insufficient work,
or elimination of their positions or shifts. Includes only private nonfarm wage and salary workers 20 years and older.
d. For example, for workers displaced in the January 2001–December 2003 period, measures the percent unemployed in January 2004.
e. The bubble area is proportional to industry employment (two-digit SIC) at business cycle peak. Omits metals mining and includes only commercial banks, not all
depository institutions. See Erica L. Groshen and Simon Potter, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economic and Finance, August 2003.
f. Gross job gains are net gains at expanding or opening firms. Gross job losses are net losses at contracting or closing firms.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The labor market recovery after the
November 2001 business cycle trough
has been unusually weak. Has increased sectoral reallocation (a permanent shift in the way employment is
distributed among economic sectors)
been a factor in this slow transition?
The recessions of the 1970s and
1980s had a feature that the 1990–91
and 2001 episodes lacked: a spike in
the percentage of labor force participants on temporary layoff. The decrease in temporary layoffs compared to other layoffs during the last

recession is consistent with the idea
of increased sectoral reallocation.
What is more likely to be seen in
sectoral reallocations is increased
worker displacement. The years covered by the two most recent Displaced
Worker Surveys (DWS) showed spikes
in displacements. And researchers
have found that worker displacement
rates fell less in the 1990s than one
might have expected, given the strong
labor market conditions.
A less roundabout way to identify
sectoral reallocation, suggested by several researchers, is seeing how many

industries have employment increases
both during and after a recession or
employment decreases in both phases.
According to these researchers, increased sectoral reallocation is suggested by the larger proportion of industries in one of these two categories
for the 2001 recession than for previous episodes. Others take issue with
this methodology. They note that
both job creation and job destruction
have fallen since the last business
cycle peak and contend that this is less
consistent with the hypothesis of
increased sectoral reallocation.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Fourth District Employment
Index, March 2001=100
102 PAYROLL EMPLOYMENT SINCE PEAK,
FOURTH DISTRICT AND U.S.

Index, March 2001=100
110 OHIO PAYROLL EMPLOYMENT SINCE PEAK

101

105
WV

100

Nonmanufacturing, U.S.

100
99

Nonmanufacturing, OH

KY
95
U.S.

98

PA

90
Manufacturing, OH

97

Manufacturing, U.S.

OH
85

96

95

80
2001

2002

2003

2004

2001

2002

2003

2004

Index, March 2001=100
110 PENNSYLVANIA PAYROLL EMPLOYMENT SINCE PEAK

Index, March 2001=100
110 KENTUCKY PAYROLL EMPLOYMENT SINCE PEAK

105

105
Nonmanufacturing, PA

Nonmanufacturing, KY

100

100
Nonmanufacturing, U.S.

Nonmanufacturing, U.S.

95

95
Manufacturing, KY

90

90
Manufacturing, U.S.
Manufacturing, PA

85

85
Manufacturing, U.S.

80
2001

2002

2003

2004

80
2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

By some measures, Ohio’s economic
performance during the current recovery has been disappointing. Ohio
trails the other Fourth District states
in employment growth. Kentucky,
Pennsylvania, and West Virginia have
tracked the nation, more or less,
since the last business cycle peak.
Ohio employment, on the other
hand, lags the national average by
more than four percentage points.

Why is Ohio’s employment growth
so slow? Many have cited weakness in
manufacturing jobs, which account
for 15.3% of the state’s employment.
Since the last business cycle peak,
Ohio has lost 1.6% more manufacturing jobs than the nation.
But Pennsylvania, whose industrial
makeup is 12.2% manufacturing, has
lost an even greater percentage of its
manufacturing jobs than Ohio—
about 2% more.

Weakness in nonmanufacturing industries is what makes Ohio employment remarkable. Since the last peak,
nonmanufacturing jobs increased by
2% nationwide; in Ohio, they decreased by 1.6%.Nonmanufacturing
employment has fared much better in
Pennsylvania and Kentucky, where it
never fell more than 1% from its 2001
levels. These two states have tracked
U.S. nonmanufacturing employment
almost exactly.

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Education in the U.S. and Fourth District States
Percent
100 EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT IN 2003: HIGH SCHOOL DIPLOMA OR HIGHER

95

90

85

80

75

70
TX WV LA AL SC AR RI TN CA MS NC NM KY AZ NY FL GA NV OK IL DC PA NJ IN ME OR MA OH CT MD MI VA ID MO HI KS WI CO DE SD VT WA UT IA ND MT AK NE WY MN NH

Percent
50 EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT IN 2003: BACHELOR'S DEGREE OR HIGHER

40

30

20

10

0
WV AR MS WY NV KY IN LA SC ID AL MI TN ME NM NC SD AK WI OK IA TX PA MT GA OH ND FL AZ OR MO NE HI RI DE IL UT WA NY CA KS VT MN NJ CT NH VA CO MD MA DC

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

Very few people would deny that
there is a positive relationship between economic development and
education. How does the Fourth Federal Reserve District stack up against
the nation? It depends on the state.
Of the four states in the District,
West Virginia had the nation’s secondlowest share (78.7%) of residents 25
or older with at least a high school
diploma in 2003, less than every state

except Texas. West Virginia was about
10 percentage points lower than
Ohio, the Fourth District leader.
Kentucky was in between, with
82.8% of adults obtaining a high
school diploma. The national average was 84.6%.
Not surprisingly, educational attainment at the college level shows a
similar pattern. Of the 50 states, West
Virginia had the lowest rate of adults
(people 25 or older) with at least a

bachelor’s degree (15.3%). This rate
was one-third as high as Washington
D.C., the area where the highest
share of residents held at least a
bachelor’s degree. Massachusetts, at
37.6%, led every other state. In Kentucky, 21.3% of the adult population
had a bachelor’s degree or higher.
Ohio and Pennsylvania, the other
Fourth District states, were near the
national average of 27.2%.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Bankruptcies in the Fourth District
Index, 1991=100
225 BANKRUPTCIES, FOURTH DISTRICT AND U.S.

Year-over-year percent change
60

Thousands
30 OHIO BANKRUPTCIES

200

25

Fourth District

45
Percent change

175
20

30

15

15

10

0

150

125
U.S.
100
Number of filings
5

75

50
1991

–15

–30

0
1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

1991

Year-over-year percent change
60

Thousands
24 PENNSYLVANIA BANKRUPTCIES

1994

1997

2000

2003

Year-over-year percent change
45

Thousands
10 KENTUCKY BANKRUPTCIES
Percent change

20

45

8

30

6

15

4

0

Percent change
30

16

12

15

8

0
Number of filings
Number of filings

–15

2
–15

4

–30

0
1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

0
1991

–30
1994

1997

2000

2003

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

SOURCE: Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts.

Bankruptcies cost businesses and
consumers billions of dollars every
year, but they also offer essential protection for debtors. The two main
types of bankruptcies are Chapter 7
and Chapter 13. In a Chapter 7 bankruptcy, individuals’ or businesses’
debts are abolished, but their nonexempt assets are liquidated. Nonexempt assets (property that creditors
can take as compensation) differ
from state to state. In a Chapter 13
bankruptcy (Chapter 11 for businesses), the debtor, creditors, and

court agree on a plan for repayment,
usually within three to five years.
Bankruptcies in the Fourth District
have tracked the national average
closely over the past decade. Although it is true that the number of
bankruptcies filed is influenced primarily by economic conditions, such
as consumer debt and labor market
changes, it is also a function of legislation. For example, large year-overyear increases in bankruptcy filings in
2001 were caused by both economic
conditions and proposed bankruptcy

reform legislation that would have
made it more difficult to file after
2001. Although the reform never
passed into law, talk of it caused an
increase in filings, designed to beat
the proposed legislation. As economic conditions improved and talk
of reform quieted, the acceleration in
bankruptcy filings fell off a bit.
Bankruptcy filings in the Fourth
District states generally rose throughout the last decade. For all four of
these states, bankruptcy levels are at
about the same level as a year ago.

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Banking Structure
Number, thousands
100 BANKING OFFICES

Number, thousands
20 SAVINGS ASSOCIATIONS OFFICES
Branches
Banks

Branches
Savings and loans

80

16

60

12

40

8

20

4

0

0
1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

INTERSTATE BRANCHES AS A PERCENT OF TOTAL OFFICES

More than 30%
15% to 30%
1% to 15%

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

NOTE: All 2004 data are as of the end of the third quarter.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile and QBP Graph Book, September 30, 2004.

Passage of the 1994 Reigle–Neal Act,
which regulates interstate banking,
spurred consolidation of depository
institutions. The number of FDICinsured commercial banks fell from
10,998 at the end of 1993 to 7,672 at
the end of 2004:IIIQ, a decline of
more than 30%. Over the same
period, the number of FDIC-insured
savings associations fell nearly 40%,
from 2,262 in 1993 to 1,365 at the
end of 2004:IIIQ.
The number of savings associations
offices also declined, but less sharply

than the number of institutions (only
around 20%, from 16,953 in 1993 to
13,571 at the end of 2004:IIIQ). Total
banking offices, however, increased
nearly 20% over that period, from
63,622 to 76,102. From the end of
1993 to September 30, 2004, the total
number of FDIC-insured depository
institutions’ offices increased 11%,
from 80,575 to 89,673. This count does
not include other channels for delivering banking services, such as automated teller machines, telephone
banking, and online banking. Hence,

the reduction in the number of insured depository institutions has not
decreased the availability of bank services for the average consumer.
Finally, the effects of interstate
consolidation of the banking industry are evident: All but seven states
now report that more than 15% of
depository institutions’ branches are
part of an out-of-state bank or savings association. And in over half the
states, 30% or more of all branches
are offices of out-of-state depository
institutions.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks
Percent, daily
7 MONETARY POLICY TARGETS a

Trillions of yen
–35
–30

6

–25

5
Bank of England

4

–20

3

European Central Bank
Federal Reserve

1

United States: Eight regularly scheduled Federal
Open Market Committee meetings during a year, at
intervals of six to eight weeks.

–15
–10

2

Frequency of Monetary Policy Meetings

–5

0

0

–1

5

–2

10

European Union: Twelve regularly scheduled
Governing Council meetings during a year, normally
on the first Thursday of each month.
United Kingdom: Twelve regularly scheduled meetings during a year, normally the Wednesday and
Thursday following the first Monday of each month.

15

–3
Bank of Japan

–4

20

–5

25

–6

30

–7

35

–8
4/1/01

40
5/6/02

6/10/03

Japan: “In principle,” 24 monetary policy meetings
during a year. Typically, meetings are held monthly on
a schedule announced at the end of each quarter for
the following six months.

7/14/04

Minutes of Monetary Policy Meetings

Other Releases

United States: Minutes of scheduled meetings
released three weeks after the policy decision.

United States: Press release announcing the policy
decision immediately after the meeting. No press
conference. Meeting transcripts published with a
five-year lag.

European Union: No minutes.
United Kingdom: Minutes of meetings released on
the second Wednesday after the policy decision.
Japan: Minutes approved at the first or second
meeting, held about one month after the meeting
concerned and released after approval.

European Union: Press conference immediately after
the meeting. Press conference transcripts published
on the EU website a few hours later. No press release.
Meeting transcripts not yet published.
United Kingdom: Press release announcing the
policy decision immediately after the meeting. No
press conference or meeting transcripts.
Japan: Same-day press release of policy decision.
Press conference for a policy change. Meeting transcripts published with a 10-year lag.

FRB Cleveland • February 2005

a. Federal Reserve: overnight interbank rate. Bank of Japan: a quantity of current account balances (since December 19, 2001, a range of quantity of current
account balances). Bank of England and European Central Bank: repo rate.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bank of England; Bank of Japan; and European Central Bank.

On February 2, the Federal Reserve’s
Federal Open Market Committee
again raised its target for the
overnight interbank (federal funds)
rate by 25 basis points, bringing the
target to 2.50%. The Bank of England and the European Central Bank
have not changed their target repurchase agreement rates recently, and
the Bank of Japan continues to
maintain its ¥30–¥35 trillion target
for the supply of its current account
balance liabilities.

The current theory of monetary
policy entails transparency of operations. Markets can operate more efficiently if the public understands the
policy objective, knows how the central bank calibrates its policy instrument to achieve that objective, and
believes that the central bank is
credible—that is, that it will do what it
says it will. Policy actions usually can be
detected quickly by expert money
market analysts, but immediate announcement of an action ensures that
even those who are not active market

participants have up-to-date information. Public understanding of the policy process is enhanced by timely
release of detailed information about
policy deliberations. The Federal
Open Market Committee recently
accelerated the release of its minutes
from just after the next meeting to
before the next meeting. While the
European Central Bank does not
publish minutes, its governor holds a
press conference immediately after
each meeting to characterize the deliberations and respond to questions.