View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective
I am extraordinarily patient provided I get my
own way in the end.
—Margaret Thatcher

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

At the conclusion of its January 28 meeting, the
Federal Open Market Committee issued a press
release stating that it “could be patient in removing
its accommodative policy stance.” Stock and bond
markets, which had placed heavy odds against such
a message, immediately sold off.
Not surprisingly, certain talking heads initially pronounced some harsh words about the Fed on the
evening news, but quickly enough, other voices
pointed out that the FOMC had not, in fact, increased
interest rates. The real news lay in the change of tone
regarding how much time the FOMC expects to
elapse before it acts. Instead of repeating its earlier
language that it would be “accommodative for a
considerable period of time,” the FOMC said that
“with inflation quite low and resource use slack, the
Committee believes it can be patient in removing its
policy accommodation.”
That the FOMC eventually must hike the federal
funds rate seems obvious. At 1 percent, the rate is
likely to be several hundred basis points below its
natural rate—the rate consistent with price stability
in an expanding economy whose productive
resources are fully employed. By holding the funds
rate very low for a long period of time, the FOMC
has been accommodating liquidity requirements,
stimulative fiscal policies, and natural market forces
working to repair imbalances and propel the economy forward. As these forces increasingly take hold,
the need for monetary and fiscal policy “scaffolding” should lessen. Indeed, in the case of monetary
policy, maintaining an easy stance too long could
ultimately accelerate inflation.
Although market participants and policymakers
recognize that extremely accommodative monetary
policy cannot be maintained indefinitely, judging
when and how to throttle back involves elements of
the unknowable. Central bank actions affect inflation
most importantly several years into the future. In the
shorter run, the inflation process is governed by millions of decentralized wage and price decisions that
themselves depend heavily on inflation expectations.

With actual and expected inflation very low, businesses facing slack labor markets and idle industrial
capacity might find that price increases will not
stick—in fact, expectations of such failures might
keep businesses from even trying.
Inflation expectations are poised on a balance
point today. Some analysts, looking ahead, anticipate
that the rapidly expanding economy will quickly lose
whatever slack remains. They surmise that inflation
could easily accelerate somewhat next year and
beyond, unless the Fed prepares to act against it.
Other analysts, judging the amount of slack to be considerable and the FOMC’s surveillance to be vigilant,
are less animated. Consequently, even though it
seems unlikely that inflation in the United States will
decline further from this point, it could be quite some
time before the expansion’s dynamics translate into
significant overall inflationary pressures.
The FOMC’s statement about being patient before
removing its policy accommodation seems intended
to respond to the concerns of one camp without
alarming the other. Market participants expect the
FOMC to sift through the incoming economic data,
revise its thinking about policy, and remain prepared
to respond flexibly to developing circumstances. In
the short term, markets can be highly sensitive to
incoming information of all kinds, including the
FOMC’s assessment of further disinflation and the
degree to which it might be regarded as unwelcome.
How the economy will evolve remains, as always,
to be seen. It is often tempting and usually a mistake
to think either that the economy is charting entirely
new territory or that it follows a predictable cyclical
course. Two of the earliest students of U.S. business
cycles, Wesley Mitchell and Arthur Burns, observed
that although business cycles displayed some common patterns, each cycle also had its idiosyncratic
components. We tacitly acknowledge this insight
when we give a particular episode a name, such as
“the jobless recovery.” The irony, of course, is that the
original “jobless recovery” (1990–92) has already
been replaced by another, more pronounced one.
We are still too close to this episode to know by what
name it will ultimately be remembered.
To learn that, we must be patient—at least for a
period of time.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

December Price Statistics

3.75
CPI

Percent change, last:
2002
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr. avg.

3.50
3.25

Consumer prices

3.00

All items

2.6

0.0

1.9

2.4

1.9

Less food
and energy

1.2

1.0

1.1

2.1

1.1

2.50

Medianb

1.6

2.2

1.9

2.8

1.9

2.25

2.75

Producer prices
Finished goods
Less food
and energy

2.00

3.4

3.1

4.0

2.0

4.5

–1.6

1.3

0.9

0.7

1.0

1.75
1.50

CPI excluding
food and energy

1.25
1.00
1995

12-month percent change
4.25 CPI AND TRIMMED-MEAN MEASURES

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Annualized quarterly percent change
5.0 ACTUAL CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST c

4.00
3.75
3.50

4.0

Median CPI b

CPI

3.25

Highest 10%

3.0

3.00
Consensus

2.75
2.0
2.50

Lowest 10%

2.25
1.0

2.00
1.75

0

1.50
CPI, 16% trimmed mean b

1.25

–1.0

1.00
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 2004.

The general disinflation trend observed in the year-over-year comparisons continues. The Consumer Price
Index (CPI) posted an annualized 2.6%
increase in December after a 2.6%
annualized decrease in November,
resulting in an index level consistent
with the September and October CPI.
Meanwhile, the core CPI, a closely
watched measure of inflation that
eliminates the CPI’s volatile food and
energy components, increased at a
1.2% annualized rate—an uptick from
last month’s uncharacteristic 0.6%
decline in the core index. The median

CPI and the 16% trimmed-mean CPI,
inflation measures designed to
exclude the most extreme price
changes, increased at annualized
rates of 1.6% and 2.5%, respectively.
The 2003 growth rates for both the
core CPI and the median CPI were
roughly 1 percentage point less than
in 2002—the core CPI rose 1.1% in
2003 compared with a 1.9% rise in
2002, while the median CPI rose 1.9%
in 2003 versus a 3.0% rise in 2002.
The latest CPI consensus forecast
by the Blue Chip panel of economists
now predicts an average 1.7% inflation

rate in 2004, compared with 1.9% last
month. Although the range of individual panelists’ inflation forecasts has
widened, both the optimists and the
pessimists have generally lowered
their quarterly forecasts for 2004, with
the optimists predicting a CPI inflation
rate of about 1.2% by the end of the
year and the pessimists expecting
2.7%. The CPI inflation forecasts for
2005 show consensus expectations of
2.3% by the end of 2005.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics attributes the diminished 2003 core
CPI growth rate to a deceleration
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
12-month percent change
9 HOUSING PRICES

RELATIVE IMPORTANCE OF CPI COMPONENTS,
DECEMBER 2003

8
House Price Index a

Rent
6.5%

All other
16.0%

7
6

Owners’ equivalent rent of
primary residence
22.2%

Medical care
6.0%

5
4

Transportation
17.3%

Shelter (other expenses)
12.2%
Food and apparel
19.8%

3
2
CPI, owners' equivalent rent of primary residence

1
0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

12-month percent change
40 SINGLE-FAMILY HOME SALES

Percent
11.0 RENTER-OCCUPIED HOME VACANCY RATE b
10.5

New homes
30

10.0
9.5

20

9.0
10

8.5
8.0

0
7.5
Existing homes

7.0

–10

6.5
–20

6.0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Calculated by the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight.
b. Vacant housing units available for rent year-round divided by the sum of owner-occupied housing units and vacant housing units available for rent year-round.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census; Office of Federal Housing Enterprise
Oversight; and National Association of Realtors.

in shelter costs, which increased 2.2%
in 2003 compared with the 2002 rise
of 3.1%. Shelter costs are the largest
CPI component, accounting for over
30% of the index’s basket of goods.
The owners’ equivalent rent of primary residence (OER)—the cost that
homeowners would assume if they
rented their house instead of owning
it—is responsible for 70% of shelter
costs and 22.2% of the overall CPI.
The OER also decelerated in 2003,
rising 2.0% versus 3.3% in 2002.
However, the OER may understate

inflationary pressures from the housing market because it is computed
using rental prices, which are likely
to have been negatively affected by
the relative attractiveness of homeownership.
The House Price Index, compiled
by the Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight using data
provided by the Federal National
Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation, also reveals disinflating home
prices. However, the House Price

Index still maintains a 5.6% growth
rate, 3.5 percentage points higher
than OER growth. The discrepancy
between the growth rate of house
prices and the OER results from a
combination of strong home sales
and a related increase in rental
vacancies. In September 2003, rental
vacancies reached 10% (the highest
since at least 1965, when the rate was
first computed), and existing onefamily home sales reached near-peak
growth rates, increasing 20.6% on a
year-over-year basis.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Trillions of dollars
2.0 THE M1 AGGREGATE

Billions of dollars
800 THE MONETARY BASE
Sweep-adjusted base b

6%

750

15
12
700

9

6

6

4

8%

3
0

650

1.8

7%

1.6

7%
8%

2
0

Sweep-adjusted M1 b

2%
2%

12%

600

7%

Sweep-adjusted M1 growth, 1998–2003 a
10
8

Sweep-adjusted base growth, 1998–2003 a

5%
1.4
Monetary base
6%

8%

550

M1

1.2
500

1.0

450
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Trillions of dollars
6.8 THE M2 AGGREGATE

5.6

10%

4%

5%
12%

8%
8%
10%

2000

2001

2002

7%

8%
5.0

1999

2003

2004

Growth Rates of Monetary Components
(percent)

M2 growth, 1998–2004 a
12
9
6
3
0
–3
–6

6.2

1998

5%

5%

4.4
5%

Annual
2000 2001

Average,
1998–
2002 2003 2002

1998

1999

8.1

12.6

2.2

8.7

7.8

6.2

7.9

M1d
6.5
M2
8.5
Currency
8.4
Total
reserves
–3.1
Checkable
depositse –2.1
Money market
funds
23.0
Small time
deposits –1.3
Savings
deposits 14.0

5.0
6.3
11.1

1.7
6.1
4.3

7.9
10.2
9.1

6.7
6.8
8.2

6.8
5.2
6.0

5.8
7.2
8.2

–7.2

–6.2

8.8

–6.7

9.5

–2.9

–4./8

–6.8

4.9

–1.6

7.5

–2.1

13.7

11.4

8.2

–6.0 –11.5

10.1

–0.7

9.5

–4.9

–9.0

–9.7

–1.3

10.1

6.6

21.7

21.1

15.1

14.7

Monetary
basec

3.8
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. The far-right bars refer to the most recent data available. Growth rates are calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis except for the far-right bar
for M2, which refers to the annualized year-to-date growth rate from 2003:IVQ to January 2004. All data are seasonally adjusted.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts. Sweepadjusted M1 contains an estimate of balances temporarily moved from M1 to non-M1 accounts.
c. Refers to the sweep-adjusted base.
d. Refers to the sweep-adjusted M1.
e. Refers to demand deposits and other checkable deposits.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Money Stock Measures,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.6.

Growth in the sweep-adjusted monetary base (total currency in circulation
plus total reserves including
depository institutions’ vault cash) has
been fairly constant over the past couple of years. In 2003, however, it
recorded an annual growth rate of
6.2%, slower than the 7.9% average for
1998–2002. The decline in base
growth results primarily from a decrease of 2.2 percentage points (pp) in
currency growth, which more than offset total reserves’ increase of 12.4 pp.
Total reserves fell 2.9% from 1998 to
2002 before rising 9.5% in 2003.

M1 (currency in the hands of the
public plus demand and other checkable deposits) is a slightly broader
monetary aggregate. Like monetary
base, sweep-adjusted M1 growth has
been fairly stable over the past couple
of years, but it is roughly 1.3 pp above
its 1998–2002 average. Much of the acceleration resulted from a sharp increase in the sum of demand deposits
and other checkable deposits, which
comprise nearly half of M1. After falling
2.1% in 1998–2002, its growth rate
rose 7.5% in 2003, primarily because
the opportunity cost of M1 (market

interest rate minus interest rate on M1
accounts) fell over the same period.
An even broader monetary aggregate, M2, grew 5.2% in 2003, 2.3 pp
less than its 1998–2002 average.
Although M2 grew overall in 2003, it
has fallen almost 1.9% (3.8% annualized) since August. This resulted from
sharp declines in retail money market
mutual funds (21.6 pp) and small time
deposits (8.4 pp) from their averages.
These declines were more than offset
by higher M1 growth and a slight
uptick in savings deposits.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Percent
8 RESERVE MARKET RATES

Percent, weekly average
8 SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES c

7

7

Effective federal funds rate a

Six-month Treasury bill
6

6
Intended federal funds rate b
5

5

4

4
Three-month Treasury bill
3

3
Primary credit rate b

One-year Treasury bill
2

2
Discount rate b
1

1
0
1998

0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Percent, weekly average
9 LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES

Percent
1.500 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

8

1.375

2004

December 10, 2003 d

Conventional mortgage
7

1.250

6

1.125

January 29, 2004 d

October 29, 2003 d

August 13, 2003 d
January 23, 2004
5

1.000

20-year Treasury bond c

September 17, 2003 d
4

0.875
10-year Treasury note c

3

0.750
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Aug.

Oct.
2003

Dec.

Feb.

Apr.

June
2004

Aug.

Oct.

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Weekly average of daily figures.
b. Daily observations.
c. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
d. One day after the FOMC meeting.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

At its January 27–28 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
left the federal funds rate target unchanged at 1% and the primary credit
rate at 2%. Short-term interest rates
and the federal funds rate have moved
roughly in tandem, dropping significantly since late 2000. At the June 25
FOMC meeting, the funds rate was
lowered to its current target level of
1%, and the yields on three-month, sixmonth, and one-year Treasury bills
roughly followed suit. Just before that
meeting, however, longer-term interest rates increased markedly. Although

they have decreased slightly since
then, they remain significantly above
their June 2003 lows.
The best way to tell how interest
rates, especially short-term rates, will
move in the foreseeable future is to
look at the federal funds futures market. Federal funds futures reflect
where the market expects the fed
funds rate to head. To gauge this, the
market often attends to the exact
wording of FOMC press releases, and
changes in the phrasing can create
nearly as much action as a movement
in the rate itself.

Since its August 12, 2003 meeting,
the FOMC has maintained that “policy
accommodation can be maintained
for a considerable period.” After its
January 27–28 meeting, it changed the
wording slightly to state that “it can be
patient in removing its policy accommodation.” Fed funds futures moved
up significantly after this statement
was released.
One measure of policy accommodation considers the relation between
long-term real interest rates and the
funds rate. Policy should be more accommodating when inflation is lower
(continued on next page)

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent
6.0 YIELD CURVE a

Percent, annualized
4.0 HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS e

5.5
October 31, 2003 b

5.0

December 12, 2003 b

3.5
Five to 10 years ahead
3.0

4.5
4.0

2.5

3.5

January 28, 2004 d

2.0

3.0
1.5

2.5
January 23, 2004 c

One year ahead

2.0

1.0

1.5
0.5

1.0
0.5

0
0

5

10
Years to maturity

15

20

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percent
3.5 TREASURY-BASED INFLATION INDICATORS

Percent
5.0
REAL RISK-FREE INTEREST RATES f
4.5

3.0
10 to 30 years h

4.0
10 to 30 years g
2.5
3.5

30 years j

30-year TIIS
2.0

3.0

2.5
1.5
10 years i

2.0
10-year TIIS
1.0
1.5
0.5

1.0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
b. The first weekly average available after the FOMC meeting.
c. The last weekly average available before the January 27–28 FOMC meeting.
d. Daily data, January 28 at close of business.
e. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
f. Treasury inflation-indexed securities (TIIS).
g. Implied forward rate derived from 10-year and 30-year TIIS. Quarterly data.
h. The implied inflation expectation 10–30 years out is the implied forward rate from nominal Treasury bonds minus the implied forward rate from TIIS. Quarterly data.
i. Yield spread: 10-year Treasury minus 10-year TIIS.
j. Yield spread: 30-year Treasury minus 30-year TIIS.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; University of Michigan;
and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

than its long-run target. The FOMC,
however, has no such inflation target.
Policy thus depends on two things that
are difficult to measure: inflation expectations and real (that is, inflationadjusted) rates.
There are few good measures of
near-term inflation expectations. Nominal Treasury bills also depend on the
real interest rate and expected inflation. If real interest rates stay the same,
the yield curve provides one measure

of inflation expectations. Real rate
volatility, however, limits this measure’s usefulness. The University of
Michigan’s Survey of Consumers suggests that households expect inflation
of 2.5%–3% over the next year, but the
series is volatile and many question its
reliability. Assuming a constant longrun real rate can also be troublesome. Treasury inflation-indexed
securities (TIIS), however, provide a
market-based measure of future real

rates. Implied forward rates based
on TIIS suggest that real rates are not
constant, even over long horizons.
Subtracting real interest rates from
nominal Treasuries gives marketbased measures of expected inflation
suggesting that inflation will drift up
from its current levels and average 3%
in 2014–34. This provides an indirect
measure of the FOMC’s inflation
target, which has increased nearly
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent
4.0 OUTPUT AND INFLATION GAP a

Percent
6 REAL INTEREST RATES

3.5
5

3.0

Real effective federal funds rate e

2.5
4

Output gap
2.0
1.5

3

1.0

Mean

Inflation gap assuming
a changing inflation target b,c

0.5

2

10–30 years in the future a,d

0
1

–0.5
–1.0

0

Inflation gap assuming 2% inflation target b
–1.5
–2.0
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percent, quarterly
8 ACTUAL AND PREDICTED FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
7

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2003

2004

Percent, daily
12 YIELD SPREADS: CORPORATE BONDS
MINUS THE 10-YEAR TREASURY NOTE i

Rule using actual long-term real interest rate and 2% inflation target h

6

–1
1998

10

Rule using actual long-term real interest
rate and moving inflation target c,f

8
High yield

5
6
4
4

Rule assuming a 2% long-term real
interest rate and inflation target g

3

BBB
2

2
AA

Actual federal funds rate
0

1
0

–2
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

a. Quarterly data.
b. Core PCE chain price index.
c. The inflation target is the implied inflation expectations 10 to 30 years out. Inflation expectations are the implied forward rate from nominal Treasury bonds
minus the implied forward rate from Treasury inflation-indexed securities (TIIS).
d. Derived from Treasury inflation-indexed securities. It is adjusted to have the same mean as the real effective federal funds rate.
e. Effective federal funds rate deflated by the core PCE chain price index.
f. The Taylor Rule is modified by using actual long-term real interest rates and moving inflation targets.
g. The formula for the implied funds rate assumes a 2% long-term interest rate and inflation target. The formulation is from John B. Taylor, “Discretion versus
Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (1993), pp. 195–214.
h. The Taylor Rule is modified by using actual long-term real interest rates.
i. Merrill Lynch AA, BBB, and High Yield Master II indexes, each minus the yield on the 10-year Treasury note.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; Congressional Budget Office; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
“Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

1/

2 percentage point over the past six
months.
Is current monetary policy overly
accommodative by historical standards? At first glance, policy seems particularly easy. The current funds rate is
significantly (1.14 percentage points)
lower than the Taylor rule, a benchmark widely used to describe past
FOMC actions. This rule posits that
past policy accommodation was balanced between weakness (the output

gap) and inflation’s deviation from
its target.
The Taylor rule usually assumes that
long-term real interest rates are constant at 2%. If we replace this with the
real rate that markets expect in the
distant future, current policy is only
19 basis points below this historical
benchmark. The 2% inflation target
assumed by the Taylor rule, however,
is also questionable. Replacing it
with what markets expect inflation to

average in 2014–34 shows that policy
is slightly tighter than this modified
Taylor rule predicts.
The output gap also enters into this
popular policy benchmark. The gap is
especially difficult to measure, but
sharp declines in yield spreads—
hence the cost of business borrowing—suggest that the output gap may
close, causing upward pressure on the
funds rate.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Brazil’s Public-Sector Debt
Percent
28 BRAZIL'S ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

Percent change
5

Brazil’s Public-Sector Debt, September 2003

Real treasury bill rate a
Real GDP growth b
24

Billions of Percent of Billions of
Brazilian real
GDP
U.S. dollars

4

Gross publicsector debt
20

3

1,230.4

79.7

420.2

363.6

23.6

124.2

891.1

57.7

304.3

General
government

866.9

56.2

296.1

Central bank

2.0

0.1

0.7

Gov’t-owned
enterprises

22.2

1.4

7.6

Assets
Net publicsector debt

16

2

12

1

8

0
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Percentage-Point Change in Brazil’s Debt-toGDP Ratio, 2003–13, under Alternative
Economic Assumptionsc
Interest rate
(percent)
8.0

GDP growth (percent)

Percentage-Point Change in Brazil’s Primary
Surplus Needed to Stabilize the Debt-to-GDP
Ratioc
Interest rate
(percent)
8.0

GDP growth (percent)
2.0
–0.9

3.0
–1.4

3.5
–1.7

4.0
–2.0

4.5
–2.3

9.0

–0.3

–0.9

–1.2

–1.5

–1.8

10.0

0.3

–0.3

–0.6

–0.9

–1.2

–8.8

11.0

0.8

0.2

–0.1

–0.4

–0.7

2.7

–1.5

12.0

1.4

0.8

0.5

0.2

–0.1

11.1

6.5

13.0

2.0

1.4

1.0

0.7

0.4

2.0
–11.2

3.0
3.5
–18.1 –21.2

4.0
4.5
–24.2 –27.0

9.0

–4.0

–11.6 –15.1

–18.4 –21.5

10.0

–4.0

–4.5

–8.4

–12.0 –15.4

11.0

12.7

3.3

–1.0

–5.0

12.0

22.2

11.9

7.2

13.0

32.6

21.2

16.0

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Nominal treasury bill rate minus inflation. Real interest rates are averaged over the first eight months of 2003.
b. GDP figures for 2003 and 2004 are International Monetary Fund projections.
c. The ratio of initial debt to GDP is 57.7%, and the initial primary budget surplus is 4.25%.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; International Monetary Fund; and Banco Central do Brasil.

The Achilles heel of sustained economic prosperity in Brazil—Latin
America’s biggest economy and the
twelfth largest in the world—is the
nation’s public-debt burden. High
and still-growing levels of debt increase Brazil’s chances of defaulting
on its obligations, either by repudiating its contractual commitments or
through inflation and currency depreciation. These prospects cause investors to demand a risk premium,

which raises real interest rates in
Brazil and reduces its investment,
employment, and growth.
With relatively small improvements in economic conditions and
continued fiscal improvements, however, Brazil could stabilize its ratio of
public debt to GDP. For a given level
of Brazil’s primary budget surplus
(receipts minus non-interest expenditures), this will happen only if the
country’s rate of economic growth
exceeds its real interest rates.

Given Brazil’s experience, the combinations of growth and real interest
rates that could achieve a decline in
the nation’s consolidated debt ratio
over the next decade seem feasible,
but they lie on the more optimistic
end of the assumptions. If, however,
Brazil maintains a primary budget surplus of roughly 5%, which it recently
attained, the country could lower its
debt burden, even if its economic
growth and real interest rates were no
better than their past averages.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Current Account and the Dollar
Foreign currency per U.S. dollar, monthy average, February 2002 = 100
120 NOMINAL EXCHANGE RATES a

Index
175 NOMINAL EXCHANGE RATES a
13.2% drop from peak

150

110

Other important trading partners, 3.4% rise from peak b

Major Currency Index,
March 1973 = 100

125

100
Canadian dollar, 19.2% drop from peak
100
90
75

Yen, 20.4% drop from peak
80

50

Euro, 31.3% drop from peak
Broad Dollar Index, January 1997 = 100

70

25
24.8% drop from peak
0
1973

Pound, 22.1% drop from peak
60

1977

1981

1985

1989

1993

1997

2001

Feb.

2005

June
2002

Oct.

June
2003

Feb.

Oct.

Feb.
2004

Balance of Payments (billions of dollars)

2002:IQ
2002:IIQ
2002:IIIQ
2002:IVQ
2003:IQ
2003:IIQ
2003:IIIQ
Change
2002:IQ–
2003:IIQ
2003:IIQ–
2003:IIIQ

Current account
Total net
balance
financial flows
–426.9
446.3
–491.3
370.7
–490.9
684.8
–514.3
610.2
–554.8
562.7
–557.6
600.0
–540.2
493.2

Official
financial flows
26.5
183.0
30.2
124.9
164.0
229.0
175.3

Private
financial flows
419.8
187.7
654.6
485.3
398.7
371.0
318.0

Other
items
–1.1
–1.1
–1.5
–1.4
–1.6
–6.2
–3.2

Statistical
discrepancy
–18.3
121.8
–192.4
–94.4
–6.3
–36.2
50.1

–130.7

153.7

202.5

–48.9

–5.1

–17.9

17.4

–106.8

–53.8

–53.0

3.0

86.3

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Data through January 27.
b. Weighted average of a subset of Broad Dollar Index currencies that do not circulate widely outside the country of use.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Foreign Exchange Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.10.

The current account deficit narrowed
in 2003:IIIQ, the first significant drop
since the dollar began its recent
decline. This pattern—smaller deficit,
depreciating dollar—suggests that
investors’ diversification out of dollardenominated assets has become a key
underlying market development.
When investors diversify out of dollar
assets, the supply of dollars in foreign
exchange markets outpaces the
demand, and the dollar depreciates.
This depreciation makes U.S. goods
more competitive in world markets

and narrows the current account
deficit. All else equal, diversification
could put upward pressure on real
interest rates and make investment in
the U.S. harder to finance. Although it
will tend to raise the prices of traded
goods, a dollar depreciation fueled by
investor diversification need not signal an accelerating inflation rate.
Prior to last year’s third quarter—
between 2002:IQ and 2003:IIQ—
the dollar depreciated, and the U.S.
current account deficit widened
as business activity in this country
outpaced economic growth abroad.

All else equal, when the U.S. grows
faster than the rest of the world, our
imports increase relative to our exports, and the current account deficit
expands. As we buy more abroad
than we sell there, the supply of dollars in the foreign exchange market
outpaces the demand for them, and
the dollar depreciates. Should it
reappear and persist, this pattern of
events would have few negative
implications for real interest rates
and investment but could be a harbinger of future inflation pressures.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Real GDP and Components, 2003:IVQ

Percentage points
3.0 CONTRIBUTION TO PERCENT CHANGE IN REAL GDP b

(Advance estimate)

2.5

a

Annualized
Change, percent change, last:
billions
Four
of 2000 $
Quarter
quarters

Real GDP
104.0
Personal consumption 47.6
Durables
2.3
Nondurables
23.3
Services
21.8
Business fixed
investment
32.9
Equipment
21.9
Structures
–1.8
Residential investment 13.1
Government spending
3.9
National defense
2.2
Net exports
4.5
Exports
46.2
Imports
41.7
Change in business
inventories
15.2

4.0
2.6
0.9
4.4
2.1

4.3
3.8
11.2
4.6
2.0

6.9
10.0
–3.0
10.6
0.8
1.8
__
19.1
11.3

6.4
8.9
–1.3
8.9
2.4
7.7
__
6.1
3.4

__

__

Personal
consumption

Last four quarters
2003:IVQ

2.0

Exports

1.5
1.0

Residential
investment

Government
spending

0.5
0
–0.5

Business fixed
investment

Change in inventories

–1.0
–1.5
Imports
–2.0

Percent change from previous quarter
9 REAL GDP AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST b
8

Percent change from peak
125 GDP GROWTH AFTER BUSINESS CYCLE PEAKS
Final percent change

120

Advance estimate

7

Blue Chip forecast c

Average of previous four recoveries

6

115

5
110

30-year average

4
3

GDP since 200I:IQ

105

2
100
1
0
IIIQ

IVQ
2002

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2003

IVQ

IQ

IIQ
2004

IIIQ

95
1

4

8
12
16
20
Number of quarters after NBER-defined peak

24

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 2000 dollars. Components of real GDP need not add to the total because the total and all components are deflated using
independent chain-weighted price indexes.
b. Data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
c. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 2004.

The advance estimate from the national income and product accounts
revealed that real gross domestic
product (GDP) rose at a 4.0% annual
rate during the fourth quarter of
2003, a little less than most forecasters had expected. Major contributors
to the increase in real GDP included
personal consumption expenditures,
exports, equipment and software,
inventory investment, and residential
fixed investment. Personal consumption expenditures rose 2.6%, less

than the third quarter’s 6.9% increase
and less than 2003 as a whole. Exports
posted substantial growth of 19.1%
(annualized) and contributed 1.69
percentage points to total output
growth. In an encouraging sign for
business activity, equipment and software rose 17.6% in the third quarter
and 10% in the fourth.
Government spending added 0.16
percentage point to output growth in
2003:IVQ, down from the previous
quarter and below the 2003 average.

About half of the government contribution came from growth in national
defense, which ticked up 1.8%, contributing 0.08% to output growth.
Residential fixed investment rose
10.6% and business fixed investment
posted a 6.9% gain in 2003:IVQ,
pushing fixed investment to an 8.1%
increase.
Blue Chip forecasters expect that
output growth in the next four quarters will be slightly higher than in
2003:IVQ.

(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Trillions of 2000 dollars, (index, 2001:IQ = 100)
115 REAL GDP COMPONENTS

Percentage points, 1997 = 100
Index points, 1997 = 100
120 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION AND CAPACITY UTILIZATION
120

Personal consumption expenditures

110

115

115

110

110
Total index

105
GDP
100

95

105

105

100

100

95

95

90

90

Government
85

90
Gross private domestic investment

85
Capacity utilization

80

80

85
75
80
1/98

75

70
1/01

1/04

70
1/98

1/01

1/04

Index points, 1997 = 100
160
INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION: EQUIPMENT

Index points, 1997 = 100
145 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION: CONSUMER GOODS
140

150

135
140
130
130

125
Durables

Business equipment
120

120
115

110

Total index

Total index

110

Consumer goods

Equipment

100

105

Industrial equipment
90

100

Nondurables
80

95
1/98

1/01

1/04

1/98

1/01

1/04

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Gross investment increased
markedly in 2003, but the investmentintensive aggregates of the industrial
production index do not reflect this
improvement. During the 2001
downturn, GDP consumption and
government spending remained
steady, whereas gross investment
suffered large losses. As total GDP
output improved in 2003, so did
investment. Over the course of 2003,
business fixed investment posted
gains of 2.8%, reversing the negative
changes of the previous two years.

Although GDP has surpassed the
peak levels set in March 2001, total
industrial production has not broken
the highs established in June of 2000.
Last December, the industrial production index rose only 0.1%. Moreover,
the rate of capacity utilization was
unchanged at 75.8% in December and
is running well below the 30-year average of 81.3%.
The industrial production series
related to the consumer portions
of GDP have grown steadily, but
equipment and other investment-

related aggregates have not performed as well. Consumer durable
goods, which account for about 8%
of the industrial production index,
have grown at a higher rate than the
index as a whole: Consumer durables
are up 6.8% from March 2001, but the
total index rose only 1.7%. Industrial
equipment, which represents about
5% of the index, fell about 15% over
the same period.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
300 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT CHANGE
250

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

Preliminary
Revised

200

2000
159

2001
–149

2002
–47

2003
–4

Jan.
2004
112

Goods producing
Construction
Manufacturing
Durable goods
Nondurable goods

–1
7
–9
2
–11

–124
–1
–123
–88
–35

–76
–8
–67
–48
–19

–42
7
–49
–31
–18

7
24
–11
3
–14

Service providing
Information
Financial activitiesa
PBSb
Education and health
Leisure and hospitalityc
Government

159
15
6
40
32
22
22

–25
–15
8
–63
50
–1
46

29
–19
6
–17
40
11
21

37
–10
6
23
28
8
–5

105
–10
2
–22
22
21
–13

Payroll employment

150
100
50
0
–1
–50
–100

Average for period (percent)
Civilian unemployment
rate

–150

4.0

4.8

5.8

6.0

5.6

–200
1999 2000 2001 2002

IQ

IIQ
IIIQ IVQ
2003

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKET INDICATORS

Nov. Dec. Jan.
2003
2004
Percent
6.5

Millions
130.5 REVISIONS IN TOTAL NONFARM EMPLOYMENT

Employment-to-population ratio
64.5

6.0

130.3
Previously reported
Revised

64.0

5.5

130.1

63.5

5.0

129.9

63.0

4.5

129.7

4.0

129.5

3.5

129.3

62.5
Civilian unemployment rate
62.0
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Jan.

Mar.

May

July
2003

Sept.

Nov.

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted
a. Financial activities include the finance, insurance, and real estate sector and the rental and leasing sector.
b. Professional and business services include professional, scientific, and technical services, management of companies and enterprises, administrative and
support, and waste management and remediation services.
c. Leisure and hospitality include arts, entertainment, and recreation, as well as accommodations and food service.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Nonfarm payroll employment posted
a net gain of 112,000 jobs in January
2004, its fifth consecutive monthly
gain. The employment increase for
December 2003 was revised to 16,000.
Total payroll has increased by 366,000
jobs since last September.
Construction remained strong,
making a net gain of 24,000 jobs in
January, which brought the sector’s
increase to 147,000 jobs since March
2003. Employment in health and education services continued to grow,
rising by 22,000 jobs in January and
bringing its gain to an impressive 1.5
million jobs over the last three years.

Manufacturing employment continued to fall, but much more slowly than
before; it was down 11,000 jobs in January, compared to its average monthly
loss of 49,000 in 2003. Information services posted a net loss of 10,000 jobs in
January 2004; the sector’s employment decreased by 117,000 in 2003.
Professional and business services
declined by 22,000 jobs in January
2004, after an increase of 45,000 jobs
the month before.
The household unemployment rate
in January 2004 decreased 0.1 percentage point to 5.6%—a significant drop
from its peak of 6.3% in June 2003.

The employment-to-population ratio
rose to 62.4%, continuing the upward
trend that began in October 2003.
Effective February 2004, the Bureau
of Labor Statistics implemented revisions in the establishment-based employment series to reflect the annual
benchmark adjustments; it also updated the seasonal adjustment factors.
The revisions lowered the employment numbers for the reference
month, March 2003, by about 122,000.
Incorporating the new seasonal adjustment factors has smoothed the 2003
employment growth pattern.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Unemployment Insurance Claims
Thousands
800 UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE CLAIMS

Millions
8

700

7
Initial claims

600

Percent
14 MEASURES OF UNEMPLOYMENT
12

6
10
Total unemployment rate
5

500

8
400

4

300

3

200

2

6

4

Insured unemployment rate

Continued claims
100
0
1973

1977

1981

1985

1989

1993

1997

1

2

0

0

2001

1973

1977

1981

1985

1989

1993

1997

2001

Index, January 1989 = 1.00
3.0 INITIAL CLAIMS FOR UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE
(JANUARY 1989–AUGUST 1992)

Index, April 2000 = 1.00
3.0 INITIAL CLAIMS FOR UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE
(APRIL 2000–NOVEMBER 2003)

2.5

2.5

Kentucky

U.S.
2.0

2.0
Kentucky

Ohio

Ohio

1.5

1.5
U.S.
West Virginia

1.0

1.0

West Virginia

Pennsylvania

Pennsylvania
0.5

0.5

0
1/89

0
7/89

1/90

7/90

1/91

7/91

1/92

7/92

4/00

10/00

4/01

10/01

4/02

10/02

4/03

10/03

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

NOTES: All data are seasonally adjusted. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, and Employment and Training Administration.

Unemployment insurance claims, a
closely followed economic indicator,
have trended sharply downward over
the last two months. In the week ending January 22, the four-week moving
average reached 344,500 claims, the
lowest level since the most recent
recession ended. Typically, initial
claims increase sharply when a recession begins and fall immediately after
it ends. This was not the case for the
last two recessions, 1990–91 and 2001.
During the recovery periods that followed them, sometimes called “jobless recoveries,” the number of initial
claims stayed high for several months
before starting to fall. Of the two, the

post-2001 recovery went on longer
before initial claims dropped below
400,000, the level typically associated
with employment growth.
During the last two months, the
number of continuing claims (those
made by individuals receiving regular
26-week state benefits) also fell to a
postrecession low. Continued claims
are slower to fall because several
weeks may pass before workers are
employed again. Combined decreases
in initial and continuing claims have
lowered the insured unemployment
rate to 2.6%.
The bottom two charts show the
trends across states in the Fourth

Federal Reserve District as well as the
U.S. average for January 1989–August
1992 and April 2000–November 2003
(each period starting from the prerecession low of the initial claim level
and ending 43 months after it). For
most of January 1989–August 1992
(indexed to 1.0 for January 1989), increases of initial claims in Ohio and
Kentucky outpaced the U.S. average.
The pattern was similar for April
2000–November 2003 (indexed to
1.0 for April 2000), but the rates of
increase in initial claims for these
two states were higher than in the
previous period.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Domestic Steel Industry
Thousands of employees
250 EMPLOYMENT IN METAL INDUSTRIES a

METAL INDUSTRIES’ CONTRIBUTION
TO GROSS STATE PRODUCT, 2001

Thousands of employees
2,700

2,500

230
Ohio

2,300

210
U.S. total

2,100

190

1,900

170
Pennsylvania
More than $10 billion
$5 billion–$10 billion
$1 billion–$5 billion
Less than $1 billion

130
1990

Millions of net tons
120

Millions of net tons
18 ANNUAL RAW STEEL PRODUCTION b

1,700

150

115

16

1,500
1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Millions of dollars
750 NEW ORDERS PLACED WITH IRON AND STEEL MILLS c
700

Pittsburgh/Youngstown
110

14

650
105

12

600
100

10
U.S. total

550

8

95
Lake Erie

500

6

90

4

85

450

80

400
1992

2
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

NOTE: Metal industries are those classified under primary metal and fabricated metal product manufacturing.
a. Not seasonally adjusted.
b. The American Iron and Steel Institute’s raw steel production regions are Northeast Coast, Pittsburgh/Youngstown, Lake Erie, Detroit, Indiana/Chicago,
Midwest, Western, and Southern.
c. Seasonally adjusted.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
and American Iron and Steel Institute.

President Bush’s December decision
to eliminate the Section 201 steel tariffs on various carbon and alloy steel
products refocused national interest
on the domestic steel industry. Over
the past three years, more than 30
U.S. steel companies have filed for
bankruptcy and many more have
consolidated significantly. Steel production directly affects the economy
of our region, which is home to the
nation’s three largest integrated domestic steel producers: ISG (the former LTV Steel Corporation), U.S.
Steel, and AK Steel.

Within the U.S., nine states derived
more than $5 billion of gross state
product from the primary metal and
fabricated metal industries in 2001.
Two of the nine, Ohio and Pennsylvania, fall within the Fourth Federal
Reserve District, with significant
earnings from these industries concentrated in northeast Ohio and
western Pennsylvania.
Both of these states have experienced declines in employment
throughout the primary metal and
fabricated metal manufacturing industries, like the U.S. as a whole. The

accelerated employment decline in
the region’s metal industries over
the past three years results partly
from surging steel company bankruptcies since 2000 and ongoing
consolidation of steel production
and distribution channels.
Nationally, total raw steel production, about one-fifth of which originates in the Fourth District, remains
significantly below 2000 production
levels. Although raw steel production
in the Lake Erie region increased
slightly in 2003, the Fourth District as a
whole is still below its production
(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Domestic Steel Industry (cont.)
12-month percent change
120 STEEL IMPORTS AND EXPORTS

12-month percent change
40 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION

100

Motor vehicles and parts
30

Exports

80
Imports
60

20
Durable manufacturing

40

10
20

\

0

0

–20
–10
–40
–20
1995

–60
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

12-month percent change
20 BROAD DOLLAR INDEX

Index, 1982 = 100
125 PRODUCER PRICE INDEX: STEEL MILL PRODUCTS

15

120

10

115

5

110

0

105

–5

100

–10
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

95
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, G.17 and “Foreign Exchange Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.10; and American Iron and Steel Institute.

levels of the 1990s and early 2000.
However, activity in the domestic
steel industry has recently increased
somewhat. New orders placed with
iron and steel mills are at the highest
level since early 2000, probably
because of increased manufacturing
activity and decreased imports into
the domestic market.
The Institute for Supply Management’s Production Index has signaled
an expanding manufacturing economy
for the past eight months, and durable
goods manufacturing was up 4.9%
in December on a year-over-year
basis. Demand from the automotive

industry, which accounts for 16% of
domestic steel shipments, is strong
and expected to remain so.
Many industry observers note that
lifting Section 201 tariffs on steel imports will not affect the domestic steel
industry immediately. Although the tariffs were still effective in November—
when steel imports to the U.S. were
30% less than the year before—many
analysts assert that the current low
levels of steel imports to the U.S. have
resulted largely from increased demand in steel markets overseas and
the depreciation of the U.S. dollar.
The price of imported steel rises as

the dollar depreciates, making imported steel relatively less attractive to
domestic consumers. The Broad Dollar Index, a trade-weighted average of
the dollar’s foreign exchange value
against the currencies of our major
trading partners, has fallen since 2002.
Reduced import competition and
increased domestic demand are also
partly responsible for the recent upward trend in steel prices. Flat-rolled
steel products, largely used in industrial, automotive, and appliance
applications, have posted significant
price spot market increases, rising
approximately 20% since June 2003.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Institutions
Billions of dollars
4 NET INCOME a

Billions of dollars
5

Billions of dollars
26 SOURCES OF INCOME
Net operating income

3

24

4
Total noninterest income

2

1

22

3

20

2

Securities and other gains/losses
Total interest income
18

0

–1
1997

1

16
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

0
1998

2003

Percent
3.5

Percent
14 NET INTEREST MARGIN AND ASSET GROWTH b

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Percent
1.5 EARNINGS b

Percent
15

3.4

12
Net interest margin
10

3.3

8

3.2

6

3.1

4

3.0

2

2.9

13

1.3
Return on equity

11

1.1
Return on assets

0.9

9

0.7

7

Asset growth rate
0

2.8

–2

2.7
2.6

–4
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

5

0.5
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Net income equals net operating income plus securities and other gains and losses.
b. Data for 2003 are annualized based on the first three quarters.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

FDIC-insured savings institutions
(S&Ls) reported net income of $4.56
billion for 2003:IIIQ. This was $590 million (14.9%) higher than a year earlier
but $152 million lower than the second quarter. As in previous quarters,
net income was buttressed by onetime gains on the sale of securities—
to the tune of $1.13 billion.
S&Ls’ noninterest (fee) income
stood at $4.06 billion, up 64.7% from
a year earlier. Their total interest income of $17.1 billion is far below the

recent high of $22.3 billion in the first
quarter of 2001 and 8.1% lower than a
year ago. However, the process of
repricing S&Ls’ loan portfolios seems
to have been completed around the
end of 2003:IQ. In the face of this portfolio adjustment, net interest income
has increased only 2.1% over the past
year, because reductions in interest
income from lending have been nearly
matched by declines in borrowing
between 2002:IIIQ and 2003:IIIQ.
Although the net interest margin
declined slightly to 3.29% from its

recent peak of 3.35% at the end of
2002, overall earning performance
continued to be strong. (The net
interest margin is calculated as interest and dividends earned on interestbearing assets minus interest paid to
depositors and creditors; it is
expressed as a percentage of average
earning assets.) S&Ls’ net income
grew at a 14.9% rate on a year-overyear basis, outstripping the relatively
robust asset growth of 9.86% for
the same period. As a result, S&Ls’

(continued on next page)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Institutions (cont.)
Percent of total assets
70 NET LOANS AND LEASES

Percent
0.5 ASSET QUALITY

Percent
1.2

68

0.4

1.0

66

0.3

0.8
Problem assets

0.2

64

0.6
Net charge-offs

0.1

62

0.4

0

60
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Percent
10 HEALTH

0.2
1997

2003

Percent
1.4

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Ratio
8.3 CAPITAL

Ratio
1.4

Problem S&Ls
9

1.2

8

1.0

7

0.8

6

0.6

1.3

8.2

1.1

7.9

1.0

0.2

4

0
1998

1999

0.9

Core capital (leverage) ratio

0.4

Unprofitable S&Ls

3
1997

1.2

8.0

7.8
5

Coverage ratio

8.1

2000

2001

2002

2003

7.7

0.8

7.6

0.7

7.5

0.6
1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

NOTE: Observations are through 2003:IIIQ. Data are annualized.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

return on assets continued its recent
upward trend, rising to 1.29% in
2003:IIIQ. A similar picture emerges
for return on equity, which reached
13.81% for the quarter.
In 2003:IIIQ, net loans and leases
as a share of total assets rose slightly
to 66.2% compared to the previous
quarter. This share was less than its
recent high of 67.9% in 2000:IIIQ,
however, indicating a continued decline in savings institutions’ direct
holdings of loans.

Asset quality showed mixed signs
in 2003:QIII. Net charge-offs (gross
charge-offs minus recoveries) rose to
0.31%. Problem assets (noncurrent
assets plus other real estate owned)
made up 0.63% of total assets for the
quarter, a slightly smaller share than
the 0.69% posted in 2002.
However, asset quality is not currently a significant problem for FDICinsured savings institutions. Problem
S&Ls (those with substandard exam
ratings) declined significantly to 0.77%
in 2003:QIII compared to 1.16% in

2002. The percent of unprofitable
institutions continued to fall, reaching
5.47%. The coverage ratio stood at
$1.06 in loan loss reserves for every
dollar of noncurrent loans. The slight
increase in the coverage ratio compared to 2002 resulted from a $351
million increase in loan loss reserves
and a $208 million decrease in noncurrent loans for the same period. In
2003:IIIQ, core capital, which protects
savings institutions against unexpected losses, decreased to 7.89%
from 8.06% in 2002.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks
Percent, daily
7 MONETARY POLICY TARGETS a

Trillions of yen
–35
–30

6

–25

5
Bank of England

4

European Central Bank

–10

2
Federal Reserve

1
0
–1

Current account balances (daily)
27
24

0

21

5

18

15

–3

30

–5

10

Bank of Japan

–2

33

–20
–15

3

Trillions of yen
39
BANK OF JAPAN b
36

15
12

20

Excess reserve balances
9

–4

25

–5

30

6

–6

35
40

3

–7
4/1

9/28

3/27

2001

0.6

Current account balances

9/23
2002

3/22

Current account less required reserves
0

9/18

4/1

2003

GDP WEIGHTS OF FRANCE, GERMANY,
AND THE OTHER 10 EURO ZONE NATIONS, 2003

10/1

4/1

2001

10/1

4/1

2002

10/1
2003

Index points, 1999 = 100
140 GROWTH OF GDP OF FRANCE, GERMANY,
AND THE OTHER 10 EURO ZONE NATIONS
130

0.5

France
120
0.4
Other 10 nations
110
Germany

0.3
100
0.2
90
0.1

80

0

70
France

Germany

Other 10 nations

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

FRB Cleveland • February 2004

a. Federal Reserve: overnight interbank rate. Bank of Japan: a quantity of current account balances (since December 19, 2001, a range of quantity of current
account balances). Bank of England and European Central Bank: two-week repo rate.
b. Current account balances at the Bank of Japan are required and excess reserve balances at depository institutions subject to reserve requirements plus the
balances of certain other financial institutions not subject to reserve requirements. Reserve requirements are satisfied on the basis of the average of a bank’s
daily balances at the Bank of Japan starting the sixteenth of one month and ending the fifteenth of the next.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bank of Japan; European Central Bank; and Bank of England.

The Bank of Japan, alone among the
four major central banks, adjusted its
monetary policy setting recently. The
actual monthly average supply of
current account balances has been
increasing gradually for most of the
past year, reaching a level of about
¥30 trillion. On January 20, the Bank
raised its current account balance target from “around 27 to 32 trillion
yen” to “around 30 to 35 trillion yen,”
in order to “reaffirm its policy stance
to overcome deflation and ensure a
continued recovery.”

In the euro area, implementation
of the Stability and Growth Pact continues to be an issue. The European
Commission has filed a legal action
with the European Court of Justice,
formally challenging the finance ministers’ decision to hold in abeyance
the Commission’s November 2003
recommendation that excessive
deficit procedures be imposed on
France and Germany. Moreover, in a
regularly scheduled review of several
European Union nations, the Commission warned that France’s debtto-GDP ratio was projected to run

above 60% throughout 2005 and that
risks surround the nation’s plan to
reduce its budget deficit below 3% of
GDP by the end of 2005. By comparison, the ratio of publicly held Treasury debt to GDP in the U.S. was
about 36% in 2004:IIIQ. Germany is
one of the nations scheduled for
review in February.
Trend growth through 2005 for
France and Germany, which together
account for about half of the euro
area’s GDP, is noticeably slower than
that of the other 10 euro area nations.