View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Economy in Perspective

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

Worst-case scenarios…Most people pondering worst-case
scenarios for the U.S. economy this year are likely to be
concerned that the slowdown we have been experiencing
will be unusually steep and protracted. We cannot know
the future with certainty, and some U.S. contractions
have indeed been marked by large declines in output and
employment. A related concern is the possibility that
economic growth could remain sluggish for a period, entailing not an absolute loss of output, but a loss relative
to the economy’s imagined growth potential.
Many hypothetical business cycle contours are plausible because the economy has generated a number of patterns during its history. The magnitude, duration, and
composition of business cycle fluctuations have proven
extremely difficult to forecast reliably. In fact, there is
compelling evidence that even economic policymakers,
who arguably have access to the best data and forecasting tools available, may not always recognize an economic contraction until after its onset. By then, of
course, it is too late for any actions that might have prevented a downturn.
Whether policymakers can prevent economic contractions is debatable. Economists remain divided over how
many of our past business cycles can be attributed to
monetary and fiscal policy mistakes rather than exogenous
disruptive events. They also debate how aggressively policymakers should respond to business cycles, by trying either to speed up or slow down the economy. Some prominent economists have concluded that once business cycle
dynamics are set in motion by outside forces, a meaningful
part of the subsequent volatility results from people responding rationally to changes in their environment.
Macroeconomists have also learned that when policymakers presume to know too much, they may unintentionally exacerbate business cycle fluctuations. During the
1970s, policymakers thought the economy was capable of
expanding faster, and they repeatedly tried using monetary
and fiscal policies to spur growth. Higher inflation was initially regarded as an acceptable price to pay, but as it kept
accelerating, the government resorted to wage and price

controls for a solution. So many poor economic decisions
were made in those years by households and businesses
trying to shield themselves from runaway inflation that it
took nearly a decade for the economy to regain its health.
It is not surprising, therefore, that policymakers took
a cautious view of the economy’s growth potential in the
1990s. By then, they finally had learned that if there is
any relationship at all between inflation and economic
growth, it is that price stability promotes a strong economy. So it is probably fair to characterize the 1990s’ stabilization policy as one that primarily tried to do no
harm, and only attempted to “fine-tune” as a secondary
matter. In practice, that meant containing inflation expectations and relying on the economy to expand, rather
than assuming that policy actions were required to boost
the economy to a preconceived pace.
With a suddenly emerging softness in the demand for
durable consumer and investment goods, short-term interest rates have naturally declined. The Federal Open
Market Committee responded by quickly reducing the
federal funds rate target by 100 basis points. What comes
next? It is not clear how soon and with what intensity
economic growth will resume. Some analysts, claiming
the economy’s underlying growth potential has been exaggerated for several years, declare that unemployment
has a long way to rise before reaching its new equilibrium
rate. From this perspective, significant further easing in
monetary policy seems appropriate.
But a truly worst-case scenario is one in which core
inflation indicators continue to accelerate—as they did
last year—while the economy works its way through the
adjustments ahead. In a worst-case scenario, people become so convinced of what they “know” and so preoccupied with overriding ordinary business cycle dynamics
that economic policy stimulus eventually proves to be
excessive. Periods of below-par economic growth bring
difficult conditions, but these usually pale in
comparison to the ultimate damage that cyclical fine-tuning can inflict. Though such damage may seem remote
today, now is the time to be alert to the prospect.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
December Price Statistics
Percent change, last:
1 mo.a

3 mo.a 12 mo.

5 yr.a

1999
avg.

Consumer prices
All items

2.1

2.1

3.4

2.5

2.7

0.7

2.0

2.6

2.4

1.9

3.6

3.7

3.3

2.9

2.3

0.0

2.0

3.6

1.6

2.9

3.3

0.8

1.2

1.0

0.8

Less food
and energy
Medianb
Producer prices
Finished goods
Less food
and energy

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. The CPI 16% trimmed mean estimator eliminates the most extreme components in the price change distribution and computes a mean based on the
remaining 84% of the distribution.
d. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; and University of Michigan.

Consumer price inflation in December
had a familiar look, matching the 2.1%
annualized pace registered for the entire
October–December period. This rate of
price-level growth is well below the
3.4% advance for the year as a whole
and is, in fact, somewhat lower than the
trend for the past five years.
The inflation outlook indicated by
the CPI less food and energy components—a typical measure of so-called

core inflation—drew an even more benign picture, registering a scant 0.7% annualized increase in December. This
contrasts sharply with core measures
based on trimmed estimators, like the
median CPI, which continue to move
northward.
The mixed signals generated by the
different inflation figures bear some explanation. Unlike trimmed estimators,
which remove both high and low extremes in the growth of individual goods

prices, the CPI less food and energy removes only food and energy components, regardless of where they lie in the
price-change distribution. As it happens,
food and energy categories have
recently taken the honors for largest percentage price rises, so lopping them off
has naturally led to a more muted reading
of inflation than have core indicators
that also remove goods registering price
declines.
(continuedonnextpage)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)

Average Winter Natural Gas Usage and Costs
for Midwest Households
1997–98 1998–99 1999–2000 2000–01a

Usage
(thousands of
cubic feet)
82.4

84.5

81.7

96.8

Dollars per
thousand
cubic feet

6.56

6.27

6.61

9.58

Cost
(dollars)

541

530

540

927

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Energy Information Administration forecast.
b. Forecast bounds represent 95% confidence interval.
c. Henry Hub.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration; Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland; and Henry Hub.

Only time will tell which core
inflation statistic is currently giving us
the more accurate sense of longer-term
trends. On the bright side, inflation expectations over the course of 2000 held
fairly steady on average (although survey
responses spiked upward in December).
Whatever the long run may bring,
prospective energy-price developments
do not bode well for the
immediate future. The upward trek of
oil prices did reverse at the end
of last year, and government projections

suggest that crude oil prices will stabilize
near $25 a barrel through mid-2001, and
then decline into next year. Natural gas
prices, however, accelerated sharply as
2000 closed, and the outlook is fairly dismal going forward. Relative to recent
levels, inventories of natural gas shrank
throughout most of last year. Worse yet,
lower-than-normal inventories are expected to persist through 2002, with especially acute shortfalls anticipated in the
first half of this year.
The laws of supply and demand suggest

a predictable outcome for retail natural gas
prices. Average winter consumer prices for
natural gas in the Midwest have fluctuated
around $6.50 per thousand cubic feet for
the past three years. Government sources
project that the rate for the 2000–01 heating season will rise to $9.58 per thousand
cubic
feet
and
that
total
residential costs will jump 70% relative to
last winter. It will be no surprise, then, if
consumers find the modest advance in the
CPI
less
food
and
energy
statistic to be cold comfort indeed.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Subsequent target rate decreases (increases) are considered part of a single episode if they occur within four months of each other.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

At its January 31 meeting, the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) lowered the target federal funds rate 50 basis
points (bp) to 5.5%. In a related action, the
Board of Governors approved recommendations by most Reserve Banks’
boards of directors to lower their discount
rates a total of 50 bp to 5%. Reasons cited
for the rate cuts included erosion in consumer and business confidence as well as
weakness in retail sales and business capital
equipment spending. This was the second
decrease in the target federal funds rate in a

month, the first being a 50 bp rate cut on
January 3.
Implied yields on federal funds futures
often are used to gauge market participants’ expectations of the future course
of monetary policy. Participants placed a
high probability on a 50 bp cut in the federal funds rate at the January 31 meeting;
they have also revised upward the probability of future cuts. On February 1, the
July contract traded at 4.73%, a
decrease of nearly 75 bp since the end of
last year. As predictors of movements in
the target federal funds rate, federal funds
futures perform well. The average error

for the period 1996–present is 11 bp on
the 3-month future and only 5 bp
on the 1-month future.
Before the current easing period, the
last round of reductions in the
federal funds rate occurred from
September 1998 to November 1998,
when the intended rate was cut by a total
of 75 bp. The cumulative 100 bp decrease in the target has come
relatively quickly in this round. Since
1985, the FOMC typically has taken between three and four moves to achieve a
cumulative decline of 100 bp.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2001 growth rates for currency, M2, and M3 are calculated
on an estimated January over 2000:IVQ basis. Data are seasonally adjusted.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts.
NOTE: Last plots for currency, the monetary base, M2, and M3 are estimated for January 2001. Last plot for the sweep-adjusted base is December 2000.
Dotted lines for M2 and M3 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Now that 2000 is history, we can put its
monetary and financial developments into
perspective and, at the same time, use
them to illuminate the current state of the
economy.
Let’s start with the growth rate of
money, the key long-run determinant of
inflation. We cannot discuss the monetary
aggregates’ behavior during 2000 without
recalling the grave concerns that surrounded the century date change. These
concerns led to the substantial run-up in

liquidity that characterized late 1999 and
early 2000, as well as its subsequent fall-off
when no significant problems occurred.
In retrospect, we see that Y2K dominated
the
behavior
of
the
narrow monetary aggregates. Growth
rates for currency and the sweepadjusted base were 4.5% and 2.1% for the
year. But it is important to
recognize that these low rates are
calculated relative to the elevated pre-Y2K
levels that resulted in sizable growth rates
during 1999. When the last two years are

combined, currency and the sweep-adjusted base have grown at annual rates of
7.9% and 7.5%, similar to the growth experienced in preceding years.
Y2K considerations had relatively little
impact on the broad monetary aggregates,
which grew robustly throughout 2000.
M2 and M3 ended the year up 6.8% and
10%, respectively, and neither shows signs
of slowing thus far in 2001. Year-to-date
annualized growth rates for January are
(continuedonnextpage)

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Constant maturity.
b. Last day of week.
c. Weekly average.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

estimated at 7.3% for M2 and 10.4% for
M3. While these rates are in line with the
experience of recent years, they arguably
provide reason for concern. If the economy slows in 2001, as most analysts predict, the substantial money growth rates in
2000 may contribute to a significant rise in
inflation rates later this year and into 2002.
Regarding interest rates, we see that
yields on the shortest-term government
securities rose during most of 2000, in tandem with an increase of 100 basis points
(bp) in the intended federal funds rate.

However, this trend reversed itself sharply
at the end of the year as the economy
weakened. The rate on the 3-month Treasury bill dropped substantially more when
a 50 bp decline in the intended federal
funds rate was announced on January 3.
The 3-month rate has fallen roughly 100 bp
since mid-November.
Medium- and long-term interest rates,
on the other hand, fell steadily during most
of 2000, even in the first half of the year
when the news media were reporting that
the Federal Reserve was “increasing inter-

est rates.” Rates on all Treasury securities
with maturities of two years or longer fell
more than 100 bp during the year, while
rates on conventional 30-year mortgages
fell 93 bp. All of these, except 30-year
mortgages, have increased somewhat since
the Federal Open Market Committee’s
rate action, possibly reflecting market concerns about rising inflation. A recent increase in the difference between the 10year Treasury rate and the 10-year TIIS
rate (a spread that may indicate long-run
(continuedonnextpage)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Closing price, last day of month
b. Index members as of January 26, 2001.
SOURCES: Bloomberg Financial Information Services; W allStreet Journal; and Financial Times.

inflation expectations) is consistent with
that view. Finally, the 10-year, 3-month
Treasury spread, which has been negative
since mid-July and dipped as low as –77 bp,
has narrowed to nearly zero. A negative
spread sometimes signals an impending
recession.
Finally, 2000 witnessed unprecedented fluctuations in equity markets.
Most notably, the NASDAQ rose 15%
between December 1999 and February
2000, fell 28% between February and
May, gained 24% through August, then
plummeted 41% between August and
year’s end (based on end-of-month clos-

ing prices). Movements in the S&P 500
were much less dramatic, with the index
down 10% for the year. These declines
followed five annual increases of at least
19% each for both indexes.
Although these broad market indexes
are so frequently reported, the wide disparity among their component stocks is
not fully appreciated. It is true that the
NASDAQ’s decline reflected widespread
decreases in the stocks included in the
index. But consider the S&P 500, which
rose 19.5% in 1999 before falling 10.1%
last year. While this change seems fairly
dramatic, note the overlap in the distribution of component stock price move-

ments over the two years. For example, in
1999 the stock prices of roughly 48% of
S&P companies dropped, and 38% fell
more than 10%, even as the index average
was rising. And in 2000, when the index
fell 10%, the stock price of 56% of its
companies increased, and fully 49% rose
more than 10%.
Many other countries’ markets also
had a rough 2000, although few matched
the wild gyrations of the NASDAQ. Equity indexes in the U.K., Japan, and Hong
Kong were down 10.2%, 7.5%, and 27%,
respectively, while the index for France
ended the year up 5.6%.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The U.S.Trade Balance
Billions of dollars
200 TRADE BALANCE IN GOODS AND SERVICES

100
Services
0

–100
Goods
–200

–300

–400
1980

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

1998

Trade in Services, 1989–99
(Billions of dollars)
Exports

Total
services

1989

1999

Imports
Percent
changea

1989

1999

Percent
changea

127.1

271.9

11.4

102.5

191.3

8.7

Travel

36.2

74.9

10.7

33.4

59.4

7.8

Passenger
fares

10.7

19.8

8.6

8.3

21.4

15.9

20.5

27.0

3.2

22.2

34.1

5.4

Royalties and
licensing

13.8

36.5

16.4

2.5

13.3

42.5

Other private
services

36.7

96.5

16.3

18.9

46.7

14.6

9.2

17.2

8.8

17.2

16.5

–0.4

Other
transportation
services

U.S. government

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Average annual percent change.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

While many Americans are aware of
the enormous overall U.S. trade deficit,
few realize that our trade in services
shows a surplus. The overall trade
deficit results solely from our trade in
goods. The trade balance in services
has been in surplus for more than 15
years and has helped to offset the large
and growing trade deficit in goods. In
1999, the U.S. had a surplus of $80.6
billion on cross-bordertransactions in

private services, compared with a
$345.6 billion deficit on trade in goods.
The U.S. is one of the world’s leading
exporters of services, with most going to
developed countries. Western Europe and
Japan purchase 48% of U.S. services exports but only 32% of our goods exports.
For Canada and Latin America, the pattern is reversed: These regions account
for only 26% of U.S. services exports, but
45% of U.S. goods exports.

Royalties and licensing as well
as other private services (such as
financial services and business, professional, and technical services) make up
49% of total services exports. They have
grown rapidly in the past decade and accounted for most of the services surplus in
1999. Other, more traditional services, such
as tourism and transportation, constitute
45% ofservice exports.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Argentina’s Currency Board

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

SOURCES: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; Standard and Poors Corporation; and DRI/McGraw–Hill.

Countries fare best with either a perfectly
fixed or a completely floating exchange
rate rather than a hybrid. Choosing the
best arrangement for a particular country,
however, is a difficult task. To gain insight
into the decision, economists have been
watching Argentina’s currency board,
which began in 1991.
The board pledges to exchange
Argentine pesos freely, one-for-one, against
U.S. dollars; it supports this promise by
backing the monetary base with dollar reserves. So its monetary base cannot expand
unless there is a net inflow of dollars, and
that will happen only if the inflow of pri-

vate capital exceeds the country’s current
account deficit. Consequently, when former
president Alfonsin suggested that Argentina might suspend repaying $124 billion in foreign debts, he inadvertently
threatened the currency board’s viability.
That crisis now seems to have passed. On
January 12, 2001, the International Monetary Fund approved a package to help Argentina continue financing its external
debts.
The currency board has proven enormously successful at eliminating inflation
and inflationary expectations, but it also restricts ability to adjust quickly to economic

shocks. The dollar’s overall appreciation in
recent years and the devaluation of Brazil’s
real in January 1999 adversely affected Argentina’s competitive position, particularly
in Latin American markets. To regain its
edge without depreciating the peso, it has
had to lower domestic goods prices. Since
early 1999, consumer prices have been
falling,
but
Argentina’s economy, particularly its labor
markets, is not very flexible. Prices adjust
slowly and as they do, output and employment typically fall. Limiting exchange-rate
flexibility seems to require increasing domestic price flexibility.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

EconomicActivity
a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IVQ
(Advance estimate)
Change,
billions
of 1992 $

Real GDP
Personal consumption
Durables
Nondurables
Services
Business fixed
investment
Equipment
Structures
Residential investment
Government spending
National defense
Net exports
Exports
Imports
Change in business
inventories

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

32.0
44.8
–7.7
3.7
46.0

1.4
2.9
–3.4
0.8
5.3

3.5
4.5
5.1
3.8
4.7

–5.2
–13.8
6.5
–2.3
11.4
8.5
–14.5
–12.6
2.0

–1.4
–4.7
9.4
–2.5
2.9
10.2
—
–4.3
0.5

10.1
9.4
12.5
–2.3
1.3
–1.7
—
7.3
11.8

—

—

–5.4

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census; and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, January 10, 2001.

Gross domestic product (GDP) grew at a
paltry 1.4% annual rate in 2000:IVQ. Despite this weak showing, the year still finished with a healthy fourth-quarter to
fourthquarter growth rate of 3.5%. Major contributors to the deceleration were business
fixed investment and personal consumption, which fell to –1.4% and 2.9% from
their respective third-quarter growth rates
of 7.7% and 4.5%. The trade balance also
contributed to slower growth, as exports
contracted 4.3%. These declines were
partly offset by an upturn in government

spending, which grew 2.9% after having
fallen 1.4% in the third quarter. Blue Chip
forecasters expect the downturn to be
short lived; GDP growth should nearly
equal its 30-year average by 2001:IIIQ.
While growth in most sectors of the
economy slowed last year, none was hit
harder than manufacturing. Year-over-year
manufacturing sales growth dropped
from 8.4% in January 2000 to 2.4% during
November. Retail sales were close behind,
dropping from 10% to 5% over the same
period. Of the December series
available, retail sales have weakened fur-

ther to 3.4% as year-over-year growth of
auto sales decelerated from 14% in January 2000 to less than 1% in December.
The Conference Board’s Index of
Leading Economic Indicators has
dropped during five of the last six
months, yielding a 0.76% decline over the
past year. Historically, when the index’s
year-over-year growth has dipped below
zero, a recession has followed in every
case except 1995.
The drop in the Leading Economic Indicator series prior to recessions is typi(continuedonnextpage)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Components of Leading Economic Indicators
Index
weight
(percent)

Interest rate spreada 32.7
Money stock, M2
30.3
Average weekly hours,
manufacturing
19.0
New orders,
consumer goods
4.9
Index of stock price
3.0
Vendor deliveries
2.7
Consumer
expectations
1.8
Other
5.5
Total composite index

Percent
change,
December

Percentagepoint
contribution,
December

–0.4
0.7

–0.12
0.22

–1.9

–0.37

0.2`
–3.2
5.7

0.01
–0.10
0.15

–10.7
–17.5

–0.20
–0.23
–0.64

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Percent change in December imputed using percentage-point contribution and index weight.
b. Correlation coefficient computed using quarterly growth rates over a moving 10-year period.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and the Conference Board.

cally quite large—averaging 4.4% prior to
every recession before 1990. The most recent 0.76% decline is in line with the 1995
experience and small compared to past recessions. Recently, however, the index has
fallen more sharply, declining 0.64% in
December
alone.
The
leading
contributors to the drop were average
weekly hours of manufacturing firms,
consumer expectations, and interest rate
spreads. Changes in real M2 helped to offset some of these declines.
Even if this drop continues, it is diffi-

cult to gauge whether a recession is imminent. There is some indication that the
correlation between changes in the Leading Economic Indicators and future
GDP growth has not remained stable
over the last three decades. During the
1970s and 1980s, the moving
40-quarter correlation between quarterly
growth rates of the index and GDP
growth averaged 0.76. After 1990, however, the correlation dropped precipitously and has averaged only 0.33 since
1994.

The correlation between GDP growth
and the largest contributors to the index (in
terms of weight) has also fallen significantly
during this period. One hypothesis is that the
1990s’ relatively stable GDP growth makes it
appear that the Leading Economic Indicator
series is now a poor predictor of oncoming
recessions. However, when the large changes
in GDP prior to 1990 are eliminated from
the samples to mimic volatility since 1990,
the correlation is still 0.6—significantly
higher than the recent correlation of 0.33.
The index’s reliability appears to have
declined substantially in the 1990s.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)
1997

1998

1999

2000

Jan.
2001

Payroll employment 280
Goods-producing
48
Mining
1
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
27
Nondurable goods –2
Service-producing
232
TPUa
16
Retail trade
24
FIREb
21
Services
141
Government
17

251
22
–3
37
–12
–2
–11
229
20
30
22
120
28

229
4
–3
25
–18
–6
–12
225
16
36
10
124
28

152
0
1
14
–15
–5
–10
152
15
27
4
91
9

268
85
5
145
–65
–71
6
183
–3
27
29
81
54

Average for period (percent)

Civilian unemployment 4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

4.2

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Transportation and public utilities
b. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
c. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
d. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Unusual winter weather made for large
seasonally adjusted employment gains in
construction, contributing strongly to January’s 268,000-job surge in nonfarm payrolls. Severe November and December
weather initiated earlier-than-normal seasonal layoffs in construction, while mild
weather last month brought lower-thannormal layoffs; the net result was a large
employment gain. Similarly, unusually light
holiday hiring at the post office meant
fewer January layoffs, causing large seasonally adjusted net gains in government employment as well.

Overall nonfarm employment growth
was strong last month, especially compared to the weak average monthly gain
of 46,000 workers in 2000:IVQ, but
manufacturing sector employment continued to decline precipitously, shedding
65,000 jobs in January for a total net loss
of 254,000 since last June. Manufacturing employment declines were widespread, but the largest was in motor vehicles, which had a net loss of 38,000 jobs
last month. On the other hand, the service-producing industry grew by a

healthy 183,000 jobs, led by net gains in
services (81,000 jobs) such as health services (30,000 jobs).
Other January labor market
measures were mixed. A large monthly
increase in the number of jobless people (303,000) caused the unemployment
rate to rise 0.2% to 4.2%, but the employment-to-population ratio remained
unchanged at 64.5%, near its all-time
high. Another measure, initial claims for
unemployment insurance, showed the
labor market to be weaker than last year
but not at recession levels.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

W orkers
’ Health Insurance Costs
Characteristics of Uninsured
W orkers by Incomea
Percent of
poverty line

Full-time workers
Less than 100%

W orkers
(millions)

Uninsured
(millions)

Uninsured
(percent of
workers)

93.4

14.0

15.0

2.8

1.3

48.4

100–199%

10.3

3.8

37.2

200–299%

15.4

3.2

20.5

300% or more

64.9

5.7

8.7

Part-time workers

11.5

2.6

22.4

Less than 100%

1.2

0.5

41.7

100–199%

2.0

0.8

40.4

200–299%

1.9

0.5

23.9

300% or more

6.4

0.8

12.7

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Workers aged 18–64.
b. Transportation and public utilities.
c. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Current Population Survey, March 2000; Kaiser Survey of Employer-Sponsored Health
Benefits, 1999; Health Insurance Coverage, 1999; and the Urban Institute.

The incidence of health insurance coverage varies considerably by income. As the
table above shows, full-time workers at or
below the poverty line are over five times
more likely to be uninsured than are
workers whose income is at least 300% of
the poverty line.
This has become an even greater problem because welfare reform and a strong
economy have drawn many of the poor
back into the labor force. The low-wage
jobs they receive often lack employersponsored health insurance, yet frequently
make them ineligible for Medicaid.

Even when employers do offer health
insurance benefits, many low-income employees cannot afford to pay their portion
of the premium. Moreover, for workers
with families, the employee-paid portion
varies widely, and not as one might expect.
In fact, the employee’s portion of the premium is 54% higher in firms with the
largest shares of low-wage workers (where
more than 35% of workers earn 200% of
the poverty line or less) than in firms with
the smallest share of low-wage workers
(less than 10% of employees).
The incidence of coverage, like the cost

to employees, differs widely by industry. At
one extreme, nearly 40% of the agriculture
workforce is uninsured; at the other, only
7% of government workers lack health
insurance. Coverage rates also vary by firm
size. Perhaps because they can pool their
risk, almost all firms of 200 or more employees offer health insurance benefits (although not all employees in such firms receive them or are even eligible), while only
60% of smaller firms, which employ 20%
of the workforce, offer such benefits.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Health Care Coverage in the U.S.

Percent
35 UNINSURED NONELDERLY ADULTS BY GENDER, 1998 b
30
Male
Female
25

20

15

10

5

0
19–64

19–34

35–54

55–64

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Includes only non-Hispanic members of the race.
b. Nonelderly adults are those aged 19–64.
c. Low-income is defined as less than 200% of the poverty line. In 1998, a person who made less than $16,632 was classified as low-income. A family of four
was low-income if its household income did not exceed $33,320.
d. Poor refers to those living at or below the poverty line. In 1998, the poverty line for an individual was $8,316. For a family of four, the poverty line
was $16,660.
e. Near-poor refers to those living in a household whose income is above the poverty line, but less than 200% of the poverty line.
f. Working less than 35 hours per week.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Health Insurance Coverage, 1999; and the Urban Institute.

While all seniors in the U.S. are covered by
Medicare, not all younger Americans have
health insurance. After rising steadily
throughout the 1990s, the share of the
population not covered by health insurance declined in 1999. It now stands at
roughly 15%.
Rates of uninsured nonelderly adults,
broken
down
by
race
and
ethnicity, show that whites have the smallest fraction of uninsured. One of every
four blacks and more than one of every
three Hispanics has no health insurance

coverage. Uninsured rates are higher
among low-income individuals, with whites
showing the most drastic income-related
changes in incidence. Among low-income
individuals, the rate of uninsured whites
doubles, nearing the uninsured rate of lowincome blacks. For low-income Hispanics,
the uninsured rate rises to 45.7%.
Although females tend to have higher
poverty rates, males are less likely to be insured. A breakdown of categories by age
shows that young adult males (19–34) have
the highest percent of uninsured individuals. Surprisingly, near-elderly females

(55–64) have a higher percent of uninsured
than males of the same age.
Past welfare efforts have been criticized
for not allowing the working poor or nearpoor to retain supplemental benefits (such
as health care benefits) when they enter the
workforce or improve their financial
situation slightly. A breakdown of uninsured
nonelderly adults by family work status supports this contention: The poor and nearpoor have higher uninsured rates when at
least one person in the house is working
than if no one in the family has a job. Unin(continuedonnextpage)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Health Care Coverage in the U.S.(cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Children are defined as those younger than 19.
b. Multigenerational/other families include at least three generations in a household and/or families where adults are caring for children other than their own.
c. In 1998, the poverty line for an individual was $8,316. For a family of four, the poverty line was $16,660.
d. Includes only non-Hispanic members of the race.
e. Poor refers to those living at or below the poverty line.
f. Near-poor refers to those living in a household whose income is above the poverty line, but less than 200% of the poverty line. In 1998, an income of $16,632
was 200% above the poverty line for a single person. A family of four was 200% above the poverty line if its household income was $33,320 or more.
g. Low-income is defined as less than 200% of the poverty line.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Health Insurance Coverage, 1999; and the Urban Institute.

sured rates among the poor appear to rise
with the number of workers in the family.
Children’s coverage rates show a similar
pattern. In the aggregate and for two-parent families, the percent of uninsured children falls as family income rises. However,
in one-parent households and multigenerational/ other households, poor children
have a higher rate of coverage than do the
near-poor.
Distinguishing between poor and nearpoor does not yield a difference for black or

Hispanic children in terms of coverage
rates. Among white children, however,
those from poor families have lower coverage rates than those whose families are classified as near-poor. Among poor families,
the percent of uninsured children is higher
for whites than for blacks. Like the larger
nonelderly population of Hispanics, more
than one of every three Hispanic children
living in poverty or near-poverty lacks
health insurance.
In the Fourth District states of
Kentucky, Ohio, and Pennsylvania, as in the

nation as a whole, the share of low-income
individuals without health insurance is considerably higher than the share of all individuals without insurance. These Fourth
District states show better rates of coverage
for the nonelderly, and more specifically for
children, than does the U.S. While the percents of uninsured adults and children in
Kentucky are fairly close to those for the
nation, Ohio and Pennsylvania enjoy considerably lower rates.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Credit Unions
Thousands
14 NUMBER AND ASSETS

Billions of dollars
450

Millions
80 MEMBERSHIP

75

400

13

70

Number of credit unions
350

12

65

300

11
Assets

60

250

10

200

9
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999 2000 a

55

50
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999 2000 a

Percent change
15

Billions of dollars
400 SHARES

350

12
Shares

300

9

250

6
Share growth b
3

200

150

0
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999 2000 a

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Through June 2000.
b. Annualized.
NOTE: Data are for federally insured credit unions.
SOURCES: National Credit Union Administration, Year-End Statistics for Federally Insured Credit Unions and Mid-Year Statistics for Federally Insured
Credit Unions.

Credit unions are mutually organized depository institutions that provide financial
services to their members. Like banks and
savings associations, credit unions seem
to be consolidating. Their numbers fell
from 12,596 in 1992 to 10,479 at mid2000. However, their total assets rose
nearly 65% over the same period, from
$258.4 billion to $426.8 billion. The number of credit union members also increased steadily from 61.4 million in 1992
to 76.7 million at the end
of 2000:IIQ.

Credit unions’ asset growth was
fueled by positive loan growth throughout
the period. Loans rose from $139.5 billion
at the end of 1992 to $287.4 billion
through June 2000; loans as a share of assets grew from 54% to 67.3% over the
same period. Loan growth was remarkably
strong in the early 1990s but tapered off in
the middle of the decade; however, it has
accelerated since 1998, reaching 12.7% for
the 12 months ending June 30, 2000.
Credit union shares have also risen

steadily since 1992. Shares (the equivalent of deposits in banks and savings associations) are the primary source of
funds for credit unions, accounting for
roughly 87% of total funds. Share
growth increased every year from 1994
to 1998, when it peaked at 10.7%. It
then fell in 1999 and the first half of
2000. This may be the result of high
stock-market returns during 1998 and
1999.
(continuedonnextpage)

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Credit Unions (cont.)

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Through June 2000.
c. Allreturns and expenses are for the average quarterly level of assets during the year.
d. Return on equity is for average equity.
e. All ratios are for total assets.
NOTE: Data are for federally insured credit unions.
SOURCES: National Credit Union Administration, Year-End Statistics for Federally Insured Credit Unions and Mid-Year Statistics for Federally Insured
Credit Unions.

Credit unions continued to accumulate
capital from the end of 1992 through mid2000, more than doubling over the period.
However, the rate of capital growth fell
from 19.3% in 1992 to 8.1% at the end of
2000:IIQ. However, the 8.1% growth rate
in capital represented its first increase since
1995.
Because retained earnings are credit
unions’ only source of capital, the pace
of capital accumulation since 1995 has
mirrored the decline in return on assets
and return on equity. Return on assets

fell from a high of 1.4% in 1992 to 0.9%
in 1999 before rising to 1.0% in mid2000. Return on equity peaked at 16.4%
in 1993 and fell steadily to 8.2% in 1998
before increasing to 9.4% at the end of
2000:IIQ. The decline in credit unions’
profitability during most of the 1990s resulted partly from a steady increase in
operating expenses per dollar of assets
after 1993 and a sharp increase in the
cost of funds in 1995, a consequence of
monetary policy actions in 1994.
Overall, the credit union industry’s
health appears to be good. Capital as a

percent of assets stood at 11.1% at mid2000, equaling its 1997 peak. On the other
hand, delinquent loans as a percent of assets fell from 0.67% in 1997 to 0.44% at
mid-2000. In other words, at the end of
2000:IIQ, credit unions held more than
$25 of capital for every $1 of delinquent
loans.
Credit unions remain a viable alternative to commercial banks and
savings associations for basic services
such as consumer loans, checking
accounts, and savings accounts.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Foreign Central Banks

Percent
0.35 JAPANESE MONETARY POLICY RATES
0.30

0.25
Call money rate
0.20

0.15
Target rate
0.10

0.05

0
1/1/99

5/1/99

9/1/99

1/1/00

5/1/00

9/1/00

1/1/01

FRB Cleveland • February 2001

a. The weighted average of rates on trades made through New York City brokers.
b. The weighted average rate on all overnight unsecured lending transactions in the interbank market, initiated within the euro area by contributing
panel banks.
c. The weighted average rate of all brokered unsecured sterling overnight deals between money market institutions and their overseas branches, transacted
between midnight and 3:30 p.m. GMT.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Wholesale Markets Brokers Association.

Central banks for the major currencies use
somewhat different institutional and market devices to implement policy. Despite
these differences, in the very short run
they all operate in ways that lead daily
overnight market interest rates along a desired path—albeit with more or less
interday volatility.
In the U.S., the first of two January reductions (50 basis points each) in the intended federal funds rate was largely unexpected, but the market rateimmediately
dropped and has remained near 6%. The

European Central Bank, at its regular biweekly meeting the next day and again on
January 18, kept the rate on its main refinancing facility unchanged at 4.75%.
Consequently, the European overnight
index average has shown no clear change.
The sterling overnight interbank rate
seemed to move in the same direction as
the federal funds rate early in January, perhaps in anticipation of a similar policy
move by the Monetary Policy Committee.
The Committee, however, made no change
in the 6% Bank of England RP rate at its

regular monthly meeting on January 11.
The Japanese call money market seemed to
be anticipating a Bank of Japan rate cut at
the end of last year. But after the Bank’s
regular monetary policy meeting on January 19, Governor Hayami instructed its
staff to “examine the possible room for
further improvements in the way of liquidity provision to the market, with a view to
ensuring the smooth functioning and stability of the financial market” and to report
the results to the Policy Board by its next
meeting on February 9.