View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

April 2013 (March 15, 2013-April 12, 2013)

In This Issue:
Banking and Financial Markets
 What Shape Is Commercial Bank Capital In?
Growth and Production
 Government Spending and Employment in
Recoveries
Households and Consumers
 Household Financial Position
Inflation and Price Statistics
 Long-term Inflation Expectations
Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 GDP Growth in U.S. Metropolitan Areas during
the Recovery

Monetary Policy
 Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth,
March 2013
 Recent Changes in FOMC Communication and
the Committee’s Updated Projections
Regional Economics
 The Impact of Sequestration on Federal Outlays
in Fourth District Metropolitan Areas

Banking and Financial Markets

What Shape Is Commercial Bank Capital In?
03.22.13
by Kristle Romero Cortés and Sara Millington
Regulators require banks to maintain a certain level
of capital. Those requirements are put into place
to ensure that banks will have enough of a cushion
to maintain their daily activities in the event of an
unforeseen shock. Due to the nature of bank debt,
regulators focus on bank capital—the difference
between a bank’s assets and its liabilities—when
they are overseeing the safety and soundness of
individual banks and the banking system overall.

Average Total Liabilities
and Assets Breakdown
Thousands
12,000

Average total assets
Difference (average total assets minus
Average total liabilities average total liabilities)

10,000
8,000
6,000
4,000
2,000
0
2009

2010

2011

2012

Note: Data comprise commercial banks with total assets of more than $500 million.
Source: Federal Reserve Board Call Reports.

Average Cash and U.S. Treasury Securities
Thousands of dollars

Thousands of dollars
40

1400
Average cash
1200

35
30

1000

25
800
20
600
400

15
Average U.S. Treasury securities
10

200

5

0

0

Bank debt differs from corporate debt because the
U.S. government provides certain guarantees for
people who hold bank debt. Programs such at the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
reduce the incentives of debt holders to require
higher interest rates from firms that partake in
riskier behavior. So bank capital requirements are
in place to provide adequate incentives to bank
managers to manage the bank’s risk well.
Since 2009 the total liabilities of commercial banks
have remained relatively steady, as total assets have
slowly crept up over time. With the exception of
the first quarter of 2012, the difference between
total assets and liabilities has had an upward trend.
Bank capital is often defined in tiers or categories.
Different tiers include shareholders’ equity, retained
earnings, reserves, hybrid capital instruments, and
subordinated term debt. The minimum capital
required is specified as a percentage of the riskweighted assets of the bank. Tier 1 capital is the
book value of a bank’s stock plus its retained earnings. Tier 2 capital is loan-loss reserves, some preferred stock, and subordinated debt. Total capital
is the sum of Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital. Assets such
as cash and equivalents and government securities
are assigned a risk weight of zero. Yet interbank
loans have a 0.2 risk weight, and mortgage loans
have a risk weight of 0.5. Ordinary loans have a risk
weight of 1.

3/2009 9/2009 3/2010 9/2010 3/2011 9/2011 3/2012 9/2012
Note: Data comprise commercial banks with total assets of more than $500 million.
Source: Federal Reserve Board Call Reports.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
created in 1974 by the central banks of the G-10
2

Average Allowance for Loan and Lease Losses
U.S. dollars
47,000
Allowance for loan and lease losses

42,000
37,000

Linear trend

32,000
27,000
22,000
17,000
12,000
7,000
2,000
3/2009

9/2009

3/2010 9/2010

3/2011

9/2011

3/2012

9/2012

Note: Data comprise commercial banks with total assets of more than $500 million.
Source: Federal Reserve Board Call Reports.

Bank Capital Ratios
Percent
0.25

0.20

Average total risk-based capital ratio

0.15
Average tier 1 risk-based capital ratio
0.10

0.05

0
3/2009 9/2009 3/2010 9/2010 3/2011 9/2011 3/2012 9/2012
Note: Data comprise commercial banks with total assets of more than $500 million.
Source: Federal Reserve Board Call Reports.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

countries, sets capital ratio requirements to help
standardize the banking sector worldwide. In 1989
the U.S. adopted these capital requirements (the
so-called Basel I rules), established by the Bank for
International Settlements. The Federal Reserve announced in December 2011 that it would implement substantially all of the more recent Basel III
rules.
Basel III will require banks to hold 4.5 percent of
common equity (up from 2 percent in Basel II)
and 6 percent of Tier I capital (up from 4 percent
in Basel II) of risk-weighted assets. It also introduces additional capital buffers, leverage ratios, and
liquidity coverage ratios.
A bank’s capital can be thought of as the margin to
which creditors are covered if a bank liquidates its
assets. Loan-loss reserves, or loan-loss provisions,
are amounts set aside by banks to allow for any loss
in the value of the loans they have on their books.
Loan-loss reserves have been trending downward
since the crisis. There is currently a debate about
whether loan-loss reserves ought to be built up
during boom years, the result of which could be
an increase in future reserve requirements. Some
policymakers are arguing that reserves typically fall
during busts so that they are often too low during
downturns. They see higher reserve requirements
during recoveries as a way to give banks full coffers
from which they could draw down during recessions.
Bank capital will be one of the most useful tools
that regulators can use to avoid deep financial
crises. The ongoing debate between the ability of
banks to build capital while still extending credit
will help shape the role of capital ratio requirements in the future.

3

Growth and Production

Government Spending and Employment in Recoveries
04.08.13
by Daniel Carroll and Samuel Chapman

Government Spending and GDP
Annualized level in
billions of 2005 dollars

Annualized level in
billions of 2005 dollars
14,000
GDP
13,500

2,700

13,000

2,200

Federal spending and government employment
have an intricate relationship to GDP growth. During a recession, government spending faces competing forces, as lower levels of economic activity result
in lower revenues and, simultaneously, automatic
stabilizers such as unemployment benefits begin to
increase as the labor situation deteriorates. Government stimulus and bailouts may further accelerate spending, as the government tries to stimulate
economic activity. A trend analysis of government
spending and employment during past recessions
shows how the most recent recession differs from
others as well as how the government sector may
evolve as the recovery continues.

12,500
1,700

12,000
11,500

1,200
State and local
700

11,000

Federal, non-defense

10,500

Federal, defense
200
2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

10,000

Notes: Government spending and GDP have been seasonally adjusted. Shaded bars
indicate recession. Government spending includes government (”federal “and “state
and local”) consumption expenditures, and gross investment.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Government Employment
Thousands of workers
23,000

Over this same period, government employment at
the local, state, and federal levels followed a pattern
similar to government spending. Government employment had been steadily increasing since 2000,
reaching nearly 23 million in the second quarter of
2010. Since then, it has been decreasing and is now
below 22 million.

22,500
22,000
21,500
21,000
20,500
20,000
2000

Spending at all levels of government was steadily
increasing between 2000 and 2010. Spending
includes what is officially called “government consumption expenditures”—everything from salaries
to bridges to social programs like Medicaid—and
“gross investment”— which could be a new office
building to house a government agency. Government spending reached its peak of about $2.8 trillion half way through 2010, and then it started falling. By the fourth quarter of 2012, it had decreased
to $2.6 trillion (measured in deflated 2005 dollars).
Real GDP was also rising over much of this period
until the recession hit in the first quarter of 2008.
Since the third quarter of 2009 it has been slowly
growing and recouping the losses of the recession.

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

Note: The number of workers is seasonally adjusted.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

2012

Looking at government spending and employment as a share of the country’s total spending and
employment provides additional insight into the
government’s role over the years as the economy has
4

Government Share of GDP and
Employment
Percent
24
Government spending as a percentage of GDP
22
Average = 20.4

grown. Government spending as a percentage of
total GDP is currently below its historical average
of 20.4 percent. As of the fourth quarter of 2012,
it was 19.3 percent. Government employment as a
percentage of total nonfarm payrolls is also currently below its historical average of 16.9 percent. As of
the fourth quarter of 2012, it was 16.3 percent.

20
18

Average =
16.9

16

Government employment
as a percentage of total nonfarm payrolls

14
12
1956

1965

1974

1983

1992

2001

2010

Notes: Shaded bars indicate recession. Government spending includes government
(“federal” and “state and local”) consumption expenditures and gross investment.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Government Share of GDP around
Recession Troughs
Percent
24
Recessions before 1980
23

Average for 1956–2012

22
21
20
19

2008 recession

18
17

Recessions in
or after 1980

The chart below restricts our window of analysis
to around the trough of each recession in order to
more clearly compare government spending as a
percentage of GDP. On average, a slight hump can
be seen around the troughs, as the ratio increases
up to the trough and then begins to decrease afterward. This is intuitive, as the denominator of the
ratio—GDP—is naturally falling up to the trough
of a recession. Furthermore, as the recession progresses, federal spending typically increases as the
automatic stabilizers (unemployment insurance,
progressive taxes) begin to kick in.
The clear trend in the government’s share of GDP is
a decrease over time. Compare, for example, shares
during the 1957 and 2001 recessions (top line from
the left in the figure above and the bottom-most
line, respectively). The most recent recession (2008)
began to deviate from this trend eight quarters before the trough of the recession, when the government spending ratio jumped above the trend and
even above the average. This sharp increase may
imply a higher level of government spending—such
as stimulus bailouts—as opposed to just lower
GDP, compared to previous recessions.

Trough of recession

16
-8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quarters
Note: Government spending includes government (“federal” and “state and local”)
consumption expenditures and gross investment.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

We are now almost four years into the recovery, but
government spending and employment have not
returned to levels typical of past recoveries. The current shares for both are still very low. One reason
for their low levels may be that the shares typically
take months to respond to increases in GDP. We
found about a six to eight quarter lag for government spending and employment when we investigated the issue with a statistical analysis.
The analysis consists of finding the trend in a variable, computing the deviation of the variable from
its trend over time, and then analyzing the deviation in various ways. Comparing a variable’s deviations to deviations in GDP allows us to see the variable’s typical cyclical behavior and its responsiveness

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

5

to GDP. If a variable is very responsive to changes
in GDP, then the deviations from its trend would
show a strong correlation to the deviations of GDP
from its trend. A large positive correlation indicates
that, on average, when spending or employment is
above its trend at that lag or lead date, GDP at the
reference point was also above its trend.

GDP and Employment:
Percent Deviation from Their Trends
Percent
4

GDP

3

Employment

2
1

Private employment has the strongest correlation
with GDP, coming just shy of 0.9 at the onequarter lag. This is intuitive as the private market is
more flexible in its ability to immediately adjust to
changing conditions. Government employment, on
the other hand, responds less nimbly to changes in
GDP. We would expect such sluggishness because
government employment includes services that
must operate regardless of market conditions, such
as police or airport security. In fact, government
employment lags the recovery in GDP by about six
quarters. Total government spending and state and
local spending have fairly similar lags of about six
to eight quarters out from a recovery in GDP. Federal spending has a lag of about 10 quarters out.

0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
1956

1966

1976

1986

1996

2006

Notes: Trends were calculated using an HP filter. Shaded bars indicate recession.
Government spending includes government (“Federal” and “State and Local”)
consumption expenditures and gross investment.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; authors’ calculations.

GDP and Government Spending:
Correlation to Deviations from Trend

GDP and Employment:
Correlation to Deviations from Trend

Correlation

Correlation

0.8

0.9

State and local spending

0.7

0.6

Government payrolls

0.5

0.4
Total government spending
0.2
0

0.1
0.0
-0.1

-0.2

-0.3

Federal spending

-0.4
-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

Total private payrolls

0.3

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Quarters
Notes: Trends were calculated using an HP filter. Total government spending includes
“federal” and “state and local” combined. Federal as well as state and local spending
implies consumption expenditures and gross investment combined.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; authors’ calculations.

-0.5
-12

-10

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Quarters
Note: Trends were calculated using an HP filter.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; authors’ calculations.

These findings suggest that once GDP is above its
trend, government employment and government
spending will begin to see an increase around a year
and a half and two years later, respectively. GDP
went above its trend around the third quarter of
2011, which would imply that government emFederal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

6

ployment will rise above its trend about half way
through 2013. This also implies that government
spending may not rise above its trend until toward
the end of 2013.
This analysis estimates that GDP went above its
trend around the third quarter of 2011. Historical
norms then suggest that government employment
will rise above its trend about half way through
2013, and government spending will above its
trend near the end of 2013. However, this may
be optimistic, given that other measures of trends
put current GDP and government spending and
employment further below trend and continued
downward pressures (such as federal sequestration)
on government spending and employment are possible.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

7

Households and Consumers

Household Financial Position
Households are paying down their debt, spending cautiously, and expecting the economy to get worse
03.26.13
by O. Emre Ergungor and Patricia Waiwood
In the years preceding the stock market and housing
bubbles, household wealth grew faster than incomes,
leading Americans to believe that they were getting
richer. As the bubbles burst, the nation’s wealth-to-income ratio took a dive and returned to its long-term
trend.

Household Wealth and Consumption
Ratio
7

Four-quarter percent change
20

15

6

Wealth-to-income ratio

5
10

4
3

5

2

Personal consumption
expenditures

0

1

-5
1980 1983 1987 1991 1994 1998 2002 2005 2009
Notes: Wealth is defined as household net worth. Income is defined as personal
disposable income. Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

Percent of income
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
2001

2003

2004

2006

While people often associate the word “savings” with
money in the bank, an increase in the savings rate
also means that people are paying down their debts.
Before the downturn in April 2005, the personal savings rate had reached a record low of just 0.8 percent.
The rate peaked at 8.3 percent during the recession,
and since then, it has remained between 6 percent
and 3 percent.
However, the savings rate behaved somewhat enigmatically during the last month of 2012 and the
first of 2013: the savings rate rocketed to 6 percent
from 3 percent, and then dropped to 2.4 percent.
Personal savings, not personal income, is clearly the
component more responsible for these movements.
The reason for savings-rate volatility is skyrocketing
dividend income before higher marginal taxes kicked
in. The reason for this savings-rate volatility is that
dividend income skyrocketed before higher marginal
taxes kicked in.

Personal Savings Rate

0
2000

0

The adjustment took place as households constrained
their spending and reduced their debt. Spending
(consumption expenditures) peaked in 2008, and
then hit their trough in 2009. Yet since then, the
wealth ratio has oscillated along an upward-sloping
path. Although consumption expenditures have
rebounded since hitting the trough, growth has not
been consistent.

2007

2009

2010

2012

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

Revolving consumer credit, which includes credit
card balances primarily, plummeted in 2008 and
has been flat in real terms for more than a year.
Nonrevolving consumer credit, which consists of
the secured and unsecured credit for student loans,
8

auto financing, durable goods, and other purposes,
is actually 8.2 percent above year-ago levels. In the
first month of 2013, total consumer credit increased
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 7.0 percent
to $2,795 billion, adding a sixth month to a string
of positive monthly increases. (The latest numbers
are preliminary numbers from the Federal Reserve
Board.)

Outstanding Debt
12-month percent change
30
25
20

Revolving
consumer credit

15
10
5
0
-5

Certain delinquency rates have dropped to their precrisis levels. As of the fourth quarter of 2012, this is
true for commercial and industrial loan delinquency
rates, as well as credit card loan delinquency rates.
However, delinquency rates for residential real estate
and commercial real estate loans remain elevated,
extremely so in the case of residential real estate loan
delinquencies. They stand a dizzying 7.3 percentage
points above where they were at the start of the recession. Commercial real estate loan delinquency rates
meanwhile stand 2.33 percentage points above where
they were in late 2007.

Nonrevolving
consumer credit

-10
-15
-20
1990 1992 1995 1997 2000 2002 2005 2008 2010
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Delinquency Rates
Percent of average loan balances
14
12

Commercial real
estate loans

Residential real
estate loans

10
8
6

Commercial and
industrial loans

Credit cards

4
2
0
1991

1995

1999

2003

2007

2011

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Consumer Attitudes
Index, 1966=100
120

Index, 1985=100

Consumer sentiment:
University of Michigan

180.00
160.00

100

140.00
80

120.00
100.00

60

80.00
40
20

60.00

Consumer confidence:
Conference Board

40.00
20.00

0
2000

0.00
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: University of Michigan, The Conference Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

Indexes of consumer sentiment and confidence have
gained some traction since early 2009. Be that as it
may, the indexes still have a ways to go before returning to pre-recession levels. The going looks tough, if
we use as a gauge the University of Michigan’s index
(which leads the Conference Board’s index by one
month). Preliminary numbers show that the University of Michigan’s index of consumer confidence
dropped to 71.8 in early March from a slightly upwardly revised 77.6 in February. In March, according
to the data release, the fewest consumers in decades
anticipated that their finances would improve during
the year ahead, as evidenced by an 11-point drop in
the index’s expected personal finances component.
Also, unlike the more favorable employment prospects that consumer held over 2012, they now expect
net increases in the national unemployment rate. This
is reflected in the drop in the economic outlook component from 87 to 70. In addition, just 20 percent of
surveyed consumers expected their financial situation
to improve during the year ahead. This was the lowest
figure ever recorded, matching the lows first recorded
in 1979 and 1980. When asked about the outlook for
their finances over the next five years, just 33 percent
of all consumers expected to be better off, the lowest
level ever recorded.
9

Inflation and Prices

Long-term Inflation Expectations
03.28.13
by Mehmet Pasaogullari and Patricia Waiwood
In February, the CPI stood at 2.0 percent yearover-year, and the core CPI, which is simply the
headline CPI measure excluding food and energy
prices, was also 2.0 percent over the same period.
How can we predict what inflation will be in the
more distant future, especially in light of the Fed’s
accommodative policies?
We look at several measures of inflation expectations to gauge where economic agents think inflation will go in the future. We report three measures,
the first two being inputs in the third: marketbased estimates, survey results, and estimates of the
Cleveland Fed’s model of inflation expectations.
Further, we focus on longer-term measures (that is,
measures of inflation five years in the future and beyond), because, being more immune than shorterterm measures to short-lived shocks, their paths are
truer to more persistent drivers of inflation.
Market-based measures reflect the inflation expectations of investors. These measures rose in the days
after September 13, 2012, when the Federal Reserve announced a third round of large-scale asset
purchases and decided to keep the target range for
the federal funds rate at an exceptionally low level
at least through mid-2015. This round of asset
purchases, unlike its predecessors, was open-ended,
meaning it would continue until the outlook for
the labor market improved substantially.

Market-Based Inflation Expectations
Percent
4.0

FOMC statement

3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
10-year inflation swaps
10-year breakeven inflation
5-year inflation swaps
5-year breakeven inflation

-1.0
-2.0
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Source: Bloomberg.

2013

Between then and now, longer-term inflation
expectations rose moderately and then tapered off
slightly. As of March 2013, investors expected inflation to average about 2.4 percent over the next five
years and 2.6 percent over the next 10 years. These
numbers suggests that investors are not expecting
the new Fed policy to boost inflation too far beyond the Fed’s target over longer time horizons.
Two well-known surveys of inflation expectations
reflect the views of consumers and professional
forecasters. The University of Michigan’s Survey of
Consumer Attitudes and Behavior (UM Survey)

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

10

Survey Measures of Inflation Expectations
Percent

reports its findings monthly, and the Philadelphia
Fed’s Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) is
quarterly.

3.5
FOMC statement
3.0

2.5

2.0
UM survey (5- to 10-years)
SPF survey (5-years)
SPF survey (10-years)

1.5

1.0
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, University of Michigan.

Estimates from the Cleveland Fed’s model of inflation expectations paint a similar picture. Throughout 2012 and so far in 2013, longer-term measures
from the model have remained quite stable, hovering comfortably between 1 percent and 2 percent.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland’s
Model-Based Inflation Expectations
Percent

Of course, we cannot associate all the swings in the
measures with the Fed’s policy announcements.
Like any other macroeconomic variable, expectations are affected by other variables and beliefs
about future economic conditions. It is very hard
to disentangle the effects of such assessments from
announcements of policy changes. However, looking at the data, it seems that agents do not see an
inflationary threat on the horizon.

3.0
FOMC statement
2.6

2.2

1.8

1.4

1.0
2007

10-year
5-year
5-year, 5-year forward
2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Both UM Survey (5- to 10-year) and SPF (5-year
and 10-year) expectations were rather stable over
2012. The former hovered between 2.7 percent
and 3 percent, ended the year at 2.9 percent, and
have stood at 3 percent for the past two months.
The 5-year SPF expectation fluctuated between 2.2
percent and 2.3 percent and ended the year at 2.28
percent. Ten-year SPF expectations stayed between
2.3 percent and 2.48 percent. Interestingly, SPF
measures for both horizons currently stand at about
2.3 percent.

2013

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

11

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

GDP Growth in U.S. Metropolitan Areas during the Recovery
04.01.13
by Timothy Dunne and Kyle D. Fee
The Bureau of Economic Analysis recently released
preliminary 2011 GDP data for all 366 metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) in the nation. In
general, these metropolitan areas account for 90
percent of the nation’s GDP. Metro-area real GDP
increased 4.7 percent between 2009 and 2011—the
first two years of the recovery. However, the growth
of GDP during the recovery varies widely across
metropolitan areas.

MSA GDP Growth, 2009–2011
Percent
25
20

Fourth District MSAs

15
10
5

-5

Lakeland-Winter Haven
Stockton
Virginia Beach-Norfolk-Newport News
Las Vegas-Paradise
North Port-Bradenton-Sarasota
Tucson
Fresno
Cape Coral-Fort Myers
Modesto
Little Rock-North Little Rock-Conway
Tulsa
Sacramento--Arden-Arcade--Roseville
Columbia
Orlando-Kissimmee-Sanford
Harrisburg-Carlisle
Palm Bay-Melbourne-Titusville
Los Angeles-Long Beach-Santa Ana
Albany-Schenectady-Troy
Birmingham-Hoover
St. Louis
Wichita
Miami-Fort Lauderdale-Pompano Beach
Springfield
Akron
Providence-New Bedford-Fall River
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater
New Haven-Milford
San Diego-Carlsbad-San Marcos
Jackson
Memphis
Omaha-Council Bluffs
Jacksonville
Riverside-San Bernardino-Ontario
Honolulu
Syracuse
Cincinnati-Middletown
Albuquerque
Philadelphia-Camden-Wilmington
Columbus
Rochester
Bakersfield-Delano
Kansas City
Richmond
Dayton
Buffalo-Niagara Falls
Indianapolis-Carmel
Phoenix-Mesa-Glendale
Milwaukee-Waukesha-West Allis
Allentown-Bethlehem-Easton
Cleveland-Elyria-Mentor
San Francisco-Oakland-Fremont
Oklahoma City
Seattle-Tacoma-Bellevue
Hartford-West Hartford-East Hartford
Washington-Arlington-Alexandria
Greensboro-High Point
New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island
Augusta-Richmond County
Lancaster
Chicago-Joliet-Naperville
Scranton--Wilkes-Barre
Charlotte-Gastonia-Rock Hill
Baltimore-Towson
Denver-Aurora-Broomfield
Louisville/Jefferson County
Poughkeepsie-Newburgh-Middletown
Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Marietta
Madison
Minneapolis-St. Paul-Bloomington
Charleston-North Charleston-Summerville
Chattanooga
Salt Lake City
Toledo
Youngstown-Warren-Boardman
Colorado Springs
Oxnard-Thousand Oaks-Ventura
Knoxville
Pittsburgh
Greenville-Mauldin-Easley
Provo-Orem
Raleigh-Cary
McAllen-Edinburg-Mission
Boston-Cambridge-Quincy
Worcester
Dallas-Fort Worth-Arlington
Boise City-Nampa
Des Moines-West Des Moines
Grand Rapids-Wyoming
El Paso
Nashville-Davidson--Murfreesboro--Franklin
Houston-Sugar Land-Baytown
Ogden-Clearfield
Detroit-Warren-Livonia
Bridgeport-Stamford-Norwalk
New Orleans-Metairie-Kenner
San Antonio-New Braunfels
Baton Rouge
Austin-Round Rock-San Marcos
Portland-Vancouver-Hillsboro
San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara

0

Note: Sample includes the top 100 metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs).
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

MSA Productivity, Employment,
and GDP Growth, 2009–2011:
Highest- and Lowest-Growth
Metro Areas
Productivity

+ Employment

= GDP

Top 100 MSA average

1.9

2.5

4.4

San Jose, CA

16.1

4.6

20.7

Portland, OR

12.1

3.7

15.8

Austin, TX

4.5

6.4

10.9

Baton Rouge, LA

8.2

1.5

9.7

San Antonio, TX

5.4

3.6

9.0

New Orleans, LA

6.5

2.4

8.9

Tucson, AZ

−1.0

0.7

−0.3

Sarasota, FL

−2.1

1.7

−0.4

Las Vegas, NV

−1.0

0.3

−0.7

Norfolk, VA

−1.3

0.5

−0.8

Stockton, CA

−1.3

−0.6

−1.9

Lakeland, FL

−1.2

−0.9

−2.1

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

On one end of the distribution are MSAs that continued to struggle with the effects of the housing
boom and the subsequent bust. Metropolitan areas
in the “sand states” of Florida, Nevada, California,
and Arizona populate this lower end of the growth
distribution. The upper end of the GDP growth
distribution tends toward MSAs associated with
natural resource extraction or high-tech industries.
In addition, several metros associated with automobile assembly also showed significant growth, as
production of vehicles picked up markedly over this
period.
One can disaggregate GDP growth at the metropolitan level into two components: the contribution due to changes in output-per-employee (labor
productivity) and the contribution due to expansion in the number of employees. Both factors
contribute to the changes that we observe in overall
GDP growth. For the top 100 metros (by population), GDP grew on average by 4.4 percent from
2009 to 2011. About 43 percent of that growth
was due to increases in GDP per employee and 57
percent was due to growth in employment. For
the fastest-growing metros, output-per-employee
accounts for the majority of GDP growth, with
the exception of Austin, Texas, where employment
growth exceeded output-per-employee growth. For
slow-growing MSAs, there is actually a decline in
output-per-employee over the 2009 to 2011 period.
Combined with very slow (and sometimes negative)

12

employment growth, this yields a set of metro areas
where real GDP contracted over the early phases of
the recovery.

MSA Productivity, Employment,
and GDP Growth, 2009–2011:
Fourth District Metro Areas
Productivity

+ Employment

= GDP

Pittsburgh, PA

3.7

3.1

6.8

Toledo, OH

3.6

2.9

6.5

Youngstown, OH

4.4

2.1

6.5

Cleveland, OH

1.9

2.0

3.9

Lexington, KY

0.6

3.3

3.9

Dayton, OH

1.3

2.3

3.6

Columbus, OH

−1.5

4.8

3.3

Cincinnati, OH

1.5

1.6

3.1

Akron, OH

0.0

2.3

2.3

Fourth District metro areas also experienced considerable variation in real GDP growth between
2009 and 2011. Pittsburgh had the highest growth
rate over period, experiencing both solid growth
in employment and labor productivity. Pittsburgh
was followed closely by Toledo and Youngstown in
terms of growth during the recovery. However, it
is important to note that Toledo and Youngstown
suffered severe contractions during the Great Recession, while Pittsburgh had a much milder recession. The net result is that Pittsburgh’s real GDP in
2011 had risen above its pre-recession (2007) level,
whereas Youngstown and Toledo’s economic activity
remained well below their 2007 levels.

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Employment Growth versus
Productivity Growth

Over the 2009–2011 period, there was little correlation between employment growth and growth
in output-per-employee at the metropolitan level.
The correlation is weakly positive. Fourth District
metros are generally in the middle of the scatterplot, showing that the District’s metros had pretty
typical employment and labor productivity growth.
The exception is Columbus, which experienced
relatively high employment growth but negative
productivity growth.

Employment growth, 2009–2011 (percent)
7 Grand Rapids, MI
6
5

Austin, TX

Fourth District MSAs

Bakersfield, CA

San Jose, CA

4 Fort Meyers, FL
3

Portland, OR

2

Baton Rouge, LA

1
0
-1

Stockton, CA

Wichita, KS

Lakeland, FL

Albuquerque, NM

-2
-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Productivity growth, 2009–2011 (percent)

18

Real GDP Growth and Real GDP

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Real GDP growth per capita, 2009–2011 (percent)
25

Fourth District MSAs

San Jose, CA

20
Portland, OR
15
10

Austin, TX
McAllen, TX

Bridgeport, CT

5

San Francisco, CA
Washington, DC

0

Las Vegas, NV
-5
10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

GDP per capita, 2007 (thousands of dollars)

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis; American Community Survey.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

13

Real GDP Growth and
College Attainment
Real GDP growth, 2009–2011 (percent)
25
San Jose, CA

Fourth District MSAs
20
15

Portland, OR

McAllen, TX

El Paso, TX Baton Rouge, LA

Austin, TX

10

Madison, WI

5
0
-5
0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

College attainment, 2000 (percent)
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, American Community Survey.

The growth in real GDP over 2009 to 2011 is related to a number of different attributes and measures of economic activity for metropolitan areas.
Metropolitan areas that saw higher growth in real
GDP over the period tended to be metropolitan
areas that had higher GDP per capita prior to the
recession (2007) and higher educational attainment. In the latter case, educational attainment is
constructed as the share of the adult population
with a four-year college degree (or college attainment). San Jose, California, and Portland, Oregon,
are clearly outliers in the scatter diagrams with high
growth, high per capita GDP, and high educational
attainment. Even if such data points were omitted from the analysis, there would still remain a
positive correlation between real GDP growth and
per capita GDP and real GDP growth and college
attainment.

Post-Recession versus
Recession GDP Growth
Real GDP growth, 2009–2011 (percent)
25
Fourth District MSAs
20
15

San Jose, CA

Grand Rapids , MI
Detroit, MI

Portland, OR

Bridgeport, CT

Austin, TX

10

McAllen, TX
5 Youngstown, OH
Bakersfield, CA

0
Fort Meyers, FL
-5
-20
-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

Real GDP growth per capita, 2007–2009 (percent)

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

14

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, March 2013
Covering February 23, 2012–March 19, 2013
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Patricia Waiwood

Highlights

Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures
March

February

January

Three-month Treasury bill rate (percent)

0.10

0.13

0.08

Ten-year Treasury bond rate (percent)

2.04

2.00

1.87

Yield curve slope (basis points)

194

187

179

Prediction for GDP growth (percent)

0.5

0.4

0.6

Probability of recession in one year (percent)

5.9

6.4

7.1

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; authors’ calculations.

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
Predicted
GDP growth

4
2
0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread
GDP growth
(year-over-year
change)

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

2014

Over the past month, the yield curve has gotten
somewhat steeper, as long rates rose and short rates
fell (both slightly). The three-month Treasury bill
fell to 0.10 percent (for the week ending March
15), down from February’s 0.13 percent but above
January’s 0.08. The ten-year rate moved up to 2.04,
up from February’s 2.00 and well above January’s
1.87 percent. The slope increased to 195 basis
points, surpassing both February’s 187 basis points
and January’s 179 basis points.
The steeper slope had a small impact on projected
future growth, however. Projecting forward using
past values of the spread and GDP growth suggests
that real GDP will grow at about a 0.5 percent rate
over the next year, up just a bit from February’s 0.4
percent rate over the next year, and just down a bit
from January and December. The strong influence
of the recent recession is still leading towards relatively low growth rates. Although the time horizons
do not match exactly, the forecast comes in on the
more pessimistic side of other predictions but like
them, it does show moderate growth for the year.
The change in slope had a bit more impact on the
probability of a recession. Using the yield curve to
predict this, we estimate that the expected chance
of the economy being in a recession next March at
5.9 percent, slightly less than the February prediction, which came in at 6.4 percent, and also less
than January’s 7.1 percent. So although our approach is somewhat pessimistic as regards the level
of growth over the next year, it is quite optimistic
about the recovery continuing.

15

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
80

Probability of recession

70
60

Forecast

50
40
30
20
10
0
1960 1966

1972 1978 1984

1990

1996

2002 2008

2014

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and
yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.
More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP
Growth
Percent

Predicting GDP Growth

10
8
GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6
4
2

We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.
Predicting the Probability of Recession

0
-2

10-year minus 3-month
yield spread

-4
-6
1953

1960

1967

1974

1981

1988

1995

2002

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

2009

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
numbers quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materi-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

16

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

8
6
4
2
0

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-2
-4
-6
1953

1960

1967

1974

1981

1988

1995

2002

2009

Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

2016

ally different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For more detail on these and other issues related to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” Our friends at the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York also maintain a website with
much useful information on the topic, including
their own estimate of recession probabilities.
For more on the yield curve, read the Economic Commentary “Does
the Yield Curve Signal Recession?” at http://www.clevelandfed.org/
Research/Commentary/2006/0415.pdf.
For more on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s estimate fo
recession, visit http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/capital_markets/ycfaq.html.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

17

Monetary Policy

Recent Changes in FOMC Communication and the Committee’s
Updated Projections
03.26.13
by Todd Clark and Bill Bednar
Over time, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) has sought to improve its public communications by providing more guidance on the likely
future path of monetary policy. That is, the FOMC
has tried to better explain to the public the direction the Committee expects its target for the federal
funds rate to take in the future. In one historic
example, in August 2003, the Committee extended
its usual post-meeting statement to provide unprecedented forward guidance about the future path
of the federal funds rate, which the FOMC had
lowered to 1 percent in June 2003: “…the Committee believes that policy accommodation can be
maintained for a considerable period.” In the last
few years, the FOMC has taken several additional
steps to extend the forward guidance on policy.

FOMC Projections: Timing of Policy Firming
Number of participants
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
2013

2014

2015

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

2016

In the more recent set of enhancements, the
FOMC gave its first new bit of forward guidance
about the path of the federal funds rate in the beginning of 2009, when it stated that exceptionally
low interest rate levels were expected to be warranted for “an extended period of time.” In August
2011, the Committee replaced this initial qualitative guidance with a more explicit, date-based
guidance approach, reporting in its post-meeting
statement that exceptionally low levels of the
federal funds rate were expected “at least through
mid-2013.” Arguably the biggest innovation, however, came in December 2012, when the Committee replaced the date-based guidance with specific
thresholds related to economic activity. Since the
Committee’s December 2012 meeting, FOMC
statements have indicated that exceptionally low
federal funds rates “will be appropriate at least as
long as the unemployment rate remains above 6.5
percent, inflation between one and two years ahead
is projected to be no more than a half percentage
point above the Committee’s 2 percent longer-run
goal, and longer-term inflation expectations continue to be well anchored.”
18

The current threshold-based forward guidance
allows the public to more easily relate the likely
future path of the federal funds rate to the Committee’s outlook for inflation and unemployment.
From the most recent release of the FOMC’s
projections, a majority of participants see very low
short-term interest rates extending into 2015. This
makes sense considering their projected paths for
GDP growth, the unemployment rate, and inflation.

FOMC Projections: GDP Growth
Percent
7

Projection
Central tendency

5
3
1

Range

-1
GDP growth
-3
-5
2009

2011

2013

2015

Longer-term

Source: Federal Reserve Board

FOMC Projections: Unemployment Rate
Percent
11
10

8

Central
tendency

Unemployment rate

7
6
6.5%

5

Range

4
3
2009

2011

2013

2015

The expectation of continued recovery is also
reflected in the FOMC’s most recent projections
of unemployment, which show unemployment
gradually declining over the next few years. While
there is some variation among participants in terms
of the expected length of time it will take to reach
more normal employment levels, the central tendency of the unemployment rate projections for
FOMC participants reaches the 6.5 percent threshold sometime during 2015. For the longer term,
most participants expect an unemployment rate of
between 5.0 percent and 6.0 percent.
Turning to inflation, most FOMC participants
project PCE inflation rates below the 2.5 percent
threshold mentioned in the statement. The top end
of the central-tendency-projection range for PCE
inflation is 1.7 percent in 2013 and 2.0 percent in
2014 and 2015.

Projection

9

In terms of overall economic activity, most participants see GDP growth in the range of 2.3 percent
to 2.8 percent over the next year, 2.9 percent to 3.4
percent in 2014, and 2.9 percent to 3.7 percent in
2015. These projections reflect an economy continuing to recover from the deep 2007-2009 recession, with GDP growing at a rate at or above the
long-term growth rate of GDP, which most FOMC
participants put at 2.3 percent to 2.5 percent.

Longer-term

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

Consistent with these projections for GDP growth,
unemployment, and inflation and with the sense
that longer-term inflation expectations currently
remain well anchored, the most recent Summary of
Economic Projections indicates that most FOMC
participants see the federal funds rate increasing
above the current 0 to 0.25 percent target sometime during 2015. While most participants project
19

that inflation will remain lower than the 2.5 percent threshold in 2015, most also expect the unemployment rate to hit or fall below the 6.5 percent
threshold.

FOMC Projections: PCE Inflation
Percent
5
4

Projection
2.5%

Central
tendency

3
2
1

Range

0
PCE inflation
-1
-2
2009

2011

2013

Longer-term

2015

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

FOMC Projections: Fed Funds Rate
Percent
5.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

Still, some caution about the importance of these
unemployment and inflation thresholds is needed,
as the FOMC has stated that they are not automatic triggers for action on the fed funds rate. For
example, the most recent FOMC statement indicates that, “in determining how long to maintain a
highly accommodative stance of monetary policy,
the Committee will also consider other information, including additional measures of labor market
conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and
inflation expectations, and readings on financial
developments.
It is also important to note that the thresholds are
intended for guidance on the path of the federal
funds rate and not for guidance on asset purchases,
the other main policy tool currently in use. However, what the thresholds do provide is a way of
viewing the projected path of the fed funds rate in
terms of the projected path of the overall economy,
and they provide some context for the timing in
which FOMC members expect that this target
interest rate may begin to adjust toward a more
normal long-term level.

1.0

0.0
2013

2014

2015

Longer-term

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

20

Regional Economics

The Impact of Sequestration on Federal Outlays in Fourth District
Metropolitan Areas
03.26.13
by Stephan Whitaker and Chris Vecchio
During the previous decade, federal expenditures
and transfers flowing into the metro areas of the
Fourth District rose by 48 percent. By 2010, nine
of the district’s ten largest metro areas were receiving inflows of federal funding larger than one-fifth
of their gross metropolitan product. Federal money
has helped smooth the district’s economy through
both the business cycle and structural changes.
However, reliance on federal spending means the
districts’ metro areas will feel the impact of the
sequestrations mandated by the Budget Control
Act of 2011.

Growth of Total Federal Expenditures
in Fourth District Metro Areas
Index, 2001=100
180
170
160
150

Cincinnati
Cleveland
Columbus
Pittsburgh

140
130
120
110
100
2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Sources: Consolidated Federal Funds Reports , U.S. Census Bureau; and authors’
calculations.

Growth of Total Federal Expenditures
in Fourth District Metro Areas
Index, 2001=100
160
Akron
Dayton
150
Erie
Toledo
140
Youngstown
130
120
110
100
2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Sources: Consolidated Federal Funds Reports , U.S. Census Bureau; and authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

Federal expenditures include Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, defense contracts, research grants,
and all salaries of military and federal employees.
Federal outlays in most Fourth District metros have
increased between 37 percent and 55 percent over
the decade. The Dayton area experienced the least
growth at 29 percent. From 2008 to 2009, federal
grants recorded for the Columbus metro area nearly
doubled from $3.75 billion to $7.42 billion. These
grants, which included stimulus spending, placed
Columbus’s federal outlay growth at 67 percent.
When federal inflows are considered relative to
Gross Metropolitan Product (GMP), some pronounced differences are revealed across the Fourth
District. In the Cleveland and Cincinnati areas,
federal spending is just below the national average
of 24.1 percent of gross domestic product. In Toledo, Pittsburgh, Columbus, and Akron, federal inflows are 0.75 to 1.5 percentage points higher than
the average. Columbus is distinguished by receiving
the most in grants—equivalent to 8.6 percent of its
GMP—while its direct payments receipts, including Social Security and Medicare, are very low at
7.6 percent of GMP. In the Erie and Youngstown
metro areas, direct payments equal 18.2 percent
and 24.6 percent of the metros’ GMPs, respectively.
Dayton, Erie, and Youngstown receive federal in21

flows equal to more than 29 percent of their GMPs.
In Dayton, a mid-sized metro (approximately
850,000 residents), the presence of a major military installation, Wright-Patterson Air Force Base,
can be seen in the salaries and in the procurement
category, which includes defense procurement.

Federal Funding by Type
Youngstown
Dayton
Erie
Toledo
Pittsburgh

Medicare and other
direct payments
Social Security, other
retirement and disability
Medicaid and other
grants
Federal salaries
and wages
Procurement and other

Columbus
Akron
Cleveland
Cincinnati
0

10

20

30

40

Percent of GMP (2010)
Sources: Consolidated Federal Funds Reports , U.S. Census Bureau; and authors’ calculations.

The sequestration’s cuts exempt Social Security,
Medicaid, and military pay. Cuts of 7 percent to 10
percent will be imposed on nonmandatory spending, including defense spending other than military
pay. Medicare was not entirely exempt, but the cut
to Medicare was limited to 2 percent. In this round
of cuts, Columbus and Dayton stand to lose the
most because their receipts of grant, salary, and
procurement income are the largest relative to their
GMPs. An 8 percent decrease in grants (excluding Medicaid), salaries, and other expenditures
would correspond to a loss of $1.1 billion or 1.2
percent of the GMP for Columbus. For Dayton, an
8 percent cut would correspond to $408 million,
which is also approximately 1.2 percent of its GMP.
This assumes a third of Dayton’s federal salaries are
drawn by military members, and thus would be
exempt.
More recent data would help us understand the immediate impact of the sequestration, but the source
of our data above, the Consolidated Federal Funds
Reports (CFFR), was discontinued after reporting on the 2010 Fiscal Year. An alternative source
of data is available from the Bureau of Economic
Analysis (product CA35), though it is an incomplete substitute. The CFFR grouped Social Security,
Medicare, and Medicaid payments into its “direct
payment” and “grants” categories. These three large
budget items are also reported in the “personal
transfers” category of the BEA’s product CA35.
From the BEA’s 2010 to 2011 figures, we can see
that “personal transfers” from the federal government rose only modestly or declined for most
metro areas after adjusting for inflation.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

22

Metro Aggregate Flows Including Social Security,
Medicare and Medicaid
CFFR 2010

BEA CA35

BEA CA35

BEA CA35

Direct payments
and grants, 2010

Personal transfer
receipts, 2010

Personal transfer
receipts, 2011

Percent change,
2010 to 2011

Akron

4.68

5.44

5.43

-0.2

Cincinnati

12.90

14.50

14.44

-0.4

Cleveland

16.50

16.80

16.87

0.4

Columbus

15.10

11.70

11.83

1.1

Dayton

6.21

6.53

6.53

0.1

Erie

6.21

6.53

6.53

0.1

Lexington

1.01

2.90

2.89

-0.4

Pittsburgh

20.10

21.50

21.04

-2.2

Toledo

4.65

5.31

5.32

0.2

Youngstown

4.95

5.26

5.23

-0.7

Notes: Figures are in billions of 2010 dollars. The CFFR, discontinued after reporting on the 2010 fiscal year,
grouped Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid payments into its “direct payment” and “grants” categories.
The BEA’s product CA35 groups these items in its “personal transfers” category.
Sources: Consolidated Federal Funds Reports , U.S. Census Bureau, Bureau of Economic Analysis (product
CA35).

Despite the recent pause, personal transfers should
be driven higher by two strong trends: the increase
of health care costs and the aging of the population.
Social Security and Medicare payments are positively related to the share of the population that is
over 65. Over the next decade, the cohort of people
currently aged 55 to 64 will become eligible to
receive these benefits. This cohort is nearly as large
as all cohorts over 65 combined.

Age Cohorts and Retirement Benefits
25
20
15

55 to 64 years
65 to 74 years
75 to 84 years
85 years and over
(Social Security + Medicare)/GMP

10
5
0
Columbus
Cincinnati
Akron
Lexington
Toledo

Erie

Dayton
Pittsburgh
Cleveland Youngstown

Sources: Consolidated Federal Funds Reports , U.S. Census Bureau; and authors’
calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

Policymakers in every region of the Fourth District
have pursued explicit policies of growing “Eds and
Meds” sectors. These growth industries depend
heavily on federal expenditures. If future entitlement reforms apply a sequestration-like cut (8
percent, for example) to Social Security and Medicare, this would reduce payment flows to Akron
and Pittsburgh by the equivalent of nine-tenths
of a percentage point of their GMP. The same cut
would reduce funding to Erie and Youngstown,
which rely heavily on Social Security and Medicare
dollars flowing to their elderly, by 1.1 percent and
1.5 percent of their GMPs, respectively. To the
extent that there is a multiplier effect of federal
spending in a region, the cumulative impact of
federal spending cuts could be worse than these direct impacts. Federal jobs, contracts, and pensions
23

used to be prized because they were stable through
the business cycle and even countercyclical. The
impending arrival of federal budget cuts reminds
us that being dependent on politically-determined
streams of revenue carries its own risks.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

24

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | April 2013

25