View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

The Economy in Perspective

Monetary policy in a box…The Federal Open Market Committee has reduced its policy-controlled
interest rates—the federal funds rate target and the
discount rate—three times already this year, and if
the majority of Fedwatchers are right, more rate
cuts are in the offing. Why are commentators so
convinced? There are at least two reasons.
Judging from the way they discuss monetary
policy, many journalists, talking heads, and ordinary citizens believe that the Federal Reserve
should keep cutting the federal funds rate until
continued economic expansion is demonstrably
assured. News of weak economic conditions, like
the March labor report of further layoffs in manufacturing industries, convinces this audience that
additional monetary stimulus makes sense. Many
economists adopt a different framework but still
reach the same conclusion.
Experienced economists recognize that during a
period when excess inventory needs to be worked
down, manufacturing output and employment will
be curtailed temporarily. Since monetary policy
begins to affect economic conditions only after a lag,
experts know that at some point an aggressive reaction to current economic conditions may turn out to
be an over-reaction in the broader scheme of things.
With 150 basis points of policy-induced declines in
short-term interest rates only recently initiated, one
could argue that a wait-and-see approach is just as
valid as another cut in the funds rate. Why, then, are
some of the pros still impatient?
Those advocating hurried additional action cite
signals that, in their opinion, suggest continuing
weakness. Many business firms have been reporting
lower-than-expected earnings. Corporate profits in
high-tech sectors have been particularly disappointing, and these industries were so important during
the economy’s long expansion phase that it is sensible to question how vigorous the future can be
unless they get back on their feet. Investors have not
yet shown confidence in these industries, fearing
that it may take a while for demand to firm up and
stabilize at higher levels.
Finally, the stock market itself continues to be an
important factor. The “wealth effect” on consumption
is not always reliable, but the size of the market’s decline obliges us to take it into account. Many
people lost a significant share of their wealth in the
past year, so households might cut back on purchases
they otherwise would have made. Firms, for their
part, no longer have such liberal access to funds, so
capital investment is more costly and difficult to
support. Arithmetic tells the story: Economic growth

will remain feeble as long as consumption and investment spending are below par.
The focus on immediate prospects for growth is
what preoccupies many Fedwatchers, leading them
to advocate further quick policy actions. They evaluate the case for funds rate movements in terms of the
“Taylor rule,” a deceptively simple relationship between the funds rate, inflation, and real growth.
A central bank that followed the Taylor rule would
pay attention to two gaps: the gap between inflation
and the bank’s inflation target, and the gap between
actual output and the economy’s growth capacity.
Conventional wisdom places the inflation target for
the PCE price index at 2%, fairly close to inflation’s
actual performance for the past year.
Estimates of the economy’s growth potential are
more problematic and contentious, but most economists consider its current growth rate to be far
below reasonable estimates. For example, if potential growth falls in the 3%–4% range, the
current shortfall is somewhere between two and
three percentage points. Since the Taylor rule
suggests that the funds rate should decline in
response to significant output gaps, many analysts
call for further reductions.
Rules offer several advantages over pure discretion. In particular, the Taylor approach to monetary
policy is attractive because it limits the number of
variables to be considered, it offers a simple
method for balancing inflation concerns with
concerns about economic growth, and it yields a
numerical setting for the funds rate. Some analysts
seem to regard such rules of thumb as “monetary
policy in a box” and use them as a do-it-yourself
kit. But the old warning still applies: “Don’t try this
at home!”
Output gaps may be illusory because potential
output cannot be estimated with confidence.
Instead of gauging gaps in output, they may merely
betray gaps in our knowledge. If the economy is
currently growing more slowly than someone’s idea
of potential, it might well be because certain sectors
are undergoing adjustments that simply need more
time to work through. In some previous business
cycles, policymakers exacerbated inflation by
mistakenly responding to output gaps that
subsequently proved insubstantial.
As for inflation, although several core measures
have been escalating steadily during the last six
months, few analysts seem worried. After all,
when output grows slowly, inflation is not
supposed to be a threat. That combination of
outcomes just doesn’t fit into a handy box.

2
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND PCE CHAIN-TYPE PRICE INDEX

February Price Statistics
Annualized percent
change, last:
2000
a
a
a
1 mo. 3 mo. 12 mo. 5 yr. avg.

3.75
3.50
3.25
CPI

Consumer prices

3.00

All items

3.5

4.4

3.5

2.6

3.4

Less food
and energy

4.0

3.1

2.8

2.4

2.5

Medianb

4.2

3.8

3.3

2.9

3.2

2.75
2.50
2.25
2.00

Producer prices

FOMC central
tendency
projections as of
February 2001 c

1.75

Finished goods 1.7

6.1

4.0

1.8

3.6

Less food
and energy

1.9

1.3

1.1

1.2

1.50
PCE Chain-Type Price Index

–3.9

1.25
1.00
0.75
1995

Percent of distribution
40 DISTRIBUTION OF CPI COMPONENT PRICE CHANGES,
JANUARY 2001

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

DISTRIBUTION OF CPI COMPONENT PRICE CHANGES,
FEBRUARY 2001

30
Natural gas and electricity
Other
20

10

0
Less –4 to –3 to –2 to –1 to 0 to 1 to 2 to 3 to 4 to 5 to 6 to 7 to Greater
8 than 8
3
than –4 –3 –2 –1
0
5
6
1 2
4
7
Annualized monthly percent change

Less –4 to –3 to –2 to –1 to 0 to 1 to 2 to 3 to 4 to 5 to 6 to 7 to Greater
8 than 8
3
than –4 –3 –2 –1
0
5
6
1 2
4
7
Annualized monthly percent change

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Upper and lower bounds for inflation path as implied by the central tendency growth ranges issued by the FOMC and nonvoting Reserve Bank presidents.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

The recent acceleration in energy
price increases reversed course in
February, after a January in which the
Consumer Price Index (CPI) posted
its largest monthly increase in more
than a decade. The sharp January rise
was largely the result of an outsized
increase in the CPI’s energy
subindex; according to the Labor
Department, this measure rose an annualized 57.6%, accounting for over
half of the overall increase in the CPI.
The energy subindex itself was
propelled by a record increase in the

index for utility natural gas, which
rose 17.4% in the month.
In February, by contrast, retail price
increases settled down to a more
familiar pace. After an annualized increase of 7.8% in January, the CPI rose
an annualized 3.5% in February. Not
surprisingly, this more moderate
increase was also the result, in large
measure, of the CPI’s energy components. In particular, natural gas prices
rose a much more modest 2.4% in
February, while the energy subindex
as a whole fell an annualized 2.7%.

These marked fluctuations in the
prices of energy goods and services—
and their impact on the unadjusted
measures of inflation—are almost certainly distorting our sense of inflation’s current state. A look at the socalled core measures of inflation may,
therefore, be more instructive. Both
the CPI excluding food and energy
and the median CPI have shown similar rates of change thus far in 2001.
The CPI excluding food and energy
rose an annualized 4.0% in February,
just as it did in January, while the median CPI rose an annualized 4.2% in
(continued on next page)

3
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inflation and Prices (cont.)
12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND CPI EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY

12-month percent change
4.00 CPI AND MEDIAN CPI

3.75

3.75

3.50

3.50

3.25

3.25

Median CPI a

CPI
3.00

3.00

2.75

2.75

2.50

2.50

2.25

2.25
CPI

CPI excluding food and energy
2.00

2.00

1.75

1.75

1.50

1.50

1.25

1.25
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

12-month percent change
5.0 YEAR-AHEAD HOUSEHOLD INFLATION EXPECTATIONS b

Annualized quarterly percent change
5 CPI AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST c

4.5

4

1999

2000

2001

Highest 10%

CPI

3

4.0

Consensus

3.5

2

3.0

1

Lowest 10%

0

2.5
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
b. Mean expected change in consumer prices as measured by the University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers.
c. Blue Chip panel of economists.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; University of Michigan; and Blue Chip Economic
Indicators, March 10, 2001.

February after rising an annualized
3.6% in January. Taken together,
these measures suggest that the
underlying inflation rate is currently
about 4%.
Despite the decidedly upward
trend in both core and non-core
measures of inflation over the last
several quarters, households’ expectations of future inflation have
actually fallen in recent months. After
peaking at just above 4% in late 2000,
expectations fell to 3.2% in February.
For March, they rebounded somewhat to just below 3.5%. This recent

decline is important, because achieving price stability is less a matter of
limiting actual inflation than of keeping inflationary expectations in
check. This is because inflation’s corrosive influence on the economy
results from inefficient reallocation of
the nation’s resources as businesses
and households attempt to protect
themselves from an unknown future
price level. In other words, economic
prosperity is jeopardized by the
anticipation of rising prices, not by
realized price increases, so the
observed decline in the public’s

expectation of inflation may be more
significant than the recent upturn in
retail prices.
Like households, professional forecasters also see inflation falling in the
near future. After a slight increase in
early 2001, the consensus forecast
has the CPI settling at about 2.5% by
late 2001 and staying there through
2002. Even the most pessimistic forecasters do not anticipate that inflation
by year’s end will be much above
current levels; their expectation for
the CPI in late 2001 and through 2002
is about 3%.

4
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Monetary Policy
Percent
6.25 IMPLIED YIELDS ON FEDERAL FUNDS FUTURES

Percent
7.25 RESERVE MARKET RATES

6.00
6.75
5.75

Intended federal funds rate

January 4, 2001
5.50

6.25
Effective federal funds rate a

5.25

5.75
5.00
March 21, 2001

February 1, 2001

4.75

5.25

March 19, 2001
4.50

Discount rate
4.75

4.25
April 3, 2001
4.00

4.25
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

Basis points, daily
300 SPREAD: EFFECTIVE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE MINUS
TARGET FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
250

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

Nov.

Percent
18 FEDERAL DEBT HELD BY FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM/
TOTAL MARKETABLE FEDERAL DEBT
17

200
16
150
15

100
50

14

0

13

–50
12
–100
11

–150
–200
1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

10
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Weekly average.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of the Treasury; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; and Chicago Board of Trade.

At its March 20 meeting, the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC)
lowered the target federal funds rate
50 basis points (bp) to 5.0%, the
third 50-bp cut in 2001. Its press
release cited “substantial risks that
demand and production could
remain soft.” Separately, the Board of
Governors approved a 50 bp reduction in the discount rate to 4.5%.
Implied yields on federal funds
futures, often used to predict
monetary policy’s future path, declined moderately after the meeting.
Market participants place a significant probability on a further rate cut

by the end of May. As of April 3, the
October contract traded at 4.19%,
81 bp below the current federal
funds rate target.
By altering the supply of bank
reserves through open market operations, the Federal Reserve attempts to
maintain the federal funds rate near its
intended level. Typically, the effective
funds rate is close to the target rate;
since 1996, the average daily absolute
deviation from target has been less
than 12 bp. However, the effective
rate deviates significantly from target
at times, missing it by 100 bp or more
on several days.

The New York Fed’s trading desk
conducts most of its open market
operations in the form of U.S. Treasury securities. Since 1992, the Federal
Reserve’s share of these securities has
trended upward, partially due to
Treasury debt reduction. As of February 2001, this share exceeded 17%.
There is some concern that if the Fed
holds too large a proportion of Treasury securities, it may disrupt Treasury
markets and impede open market
operations. Currently, the Federal
Reserve is studying the impact on its
operations of further expected declines in the quantity of Treasury debt.

5
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets
Billions of dollars
700 THE MONETARY BASE

Trillions of dollars
5.3 THE M2 AGGREGATE

Sweep-adjusted base growth, 1996–2001 a
15

5%

10

640

5%

M2 growth, 1996–2001 a
12
8

2%

5

4.8

4

Sweep-adjusted base b
0

1%

0

580

1%

5%

5%

12%

1%
4.3

7%

5%

520

1%

460

3.8
10/97

10/98

10/99

10/00

10/01

10/97

12-month percent change
3.9

Billions of dollars
120 EXCESS MONEY AND INFLATION

10/98

10/99

10/00

10/01

Percent
1.8 INTENDED FEDERAL FUNDS RATE MINUS
2-YEAR TREASURY BOND YIELD

CPI, all items
80

3.4

1.2

40

2.9

0.6

0

2.4

0

1.9

–0.6

1.4
2002

–1.2

Actual M2 minus predicted
demand, two quarters previous
–40

–80
1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Growth rates are percentage rates calculated on a fourth-quarter over fourth-quarter basis. The 2001 growth rates for the monetary base, sweep-adjusted
base, and M2 are calculated on a February, January, and estimated March over 2000:IVQ basis, respectively. Data are seasonally adjusted.
b. The sweep-adjusted base contains an estimate of required reserves saved when balances are shifted from reservable to nonreservable accounts.
NOTE: Last plots for the monetary base and the sweep-adjusted base are February and January, respectively. Last plot for M2 is estimated for March 2001.
Prior to November 2000, dotted lines for M2 and M3 are FOMC-determined provisional ranges. Subsequent dotted lines represent growth rates and are for
reference only.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The March 20 reduction of the
federal funds rate target (from 5.50%
to 5.00%) has not quelled discussion
on the appropriateness of monetary
policy. Debate about interest rates,
however, tends to ignore a crucial
aspect of the question—the money
supply. Monetary aggregates have
continued to grow at substantial
rates and might lead to the suggestion that monetary policy has, if
anything, become too loose.
The broad money aggregate, M2,
has grown at a year-to-date annualized

rate of 11.7%, faster than in 2000 and
well above the average rates for
1996–2000. Only part of this increase
can be attributed to the monetary
base, whose year-to-date growth rate
is just 7.9%. Monetary aggregates must
be treated with caution at this time of
year because of tax payments and
rebates, but the year-to-date numbers
are not encouraging.
Money growth by itself is only half
the picture: Money supply will not
be excessive if real money demand
is also growing briskly—and that

demand depends on the influence of
overall real economic growth and interest rates. A plot of the difference
between actual M2 and an econometric estimate of M2 demand
shows that M2 has been growing
faster than the economy can absorb
it, given real GDP growth and current interest rates. In the past, this
condition has often predicted an
increase in inflation correctly and it
appears to be doing so now.
One key interest rate measure,
however, does not reflect such
(continued on next page)

6
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent, weekly average
9.5 CAPITAL MARKET RATES

Percent, weekly average
7.0 YIELD CURVES a

Conventional mortgage

6.5

8.5

March 16, 2000 b

Moody’s AAA corporate bond

6.0
7.5

5.5

30-year Treasury a

February 26, 2001 b
6.5

March 16, 2001 b

5.0

5.5

4.5
Municipal bond
4.5

4.0
0

5

10

15
20
Years to maturity

25

30

1997

35

1998

1999

2000

2001

Percent
10 GDP GROWTH AND 10-YEAR, 3-MONTH TREASURY SPREAD
8
Year-to-year GDP growth c
6

4

2

0
10-year, 3-month Treasury yield spread
–2

–4
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. All yields are from constant-maturity series.
b. Average for the week ending on this date.
c. Real GDP growth leads four quarters.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial
Information Services.

excess money growth. The spread
between the target federal funds rate
and the yield on 2-year Treasury
bonds has increased dramatically
over the past year because interest
rates have generally been decreasing.
Of course, the 150 basis point reduction in the federal funds target rate
since January 3 seems to have
reduced the spread somewhat.
The yield curve has shifted downward since last month. While the
curve remains inverted at the short
end, the low point of the curve is

moving toward earlier maturities (the
current minimum is the 1-year yield),
suggesting an incipient unbending.
The 3-year, 3-month spread stands at
–15 basis points (bp) and the
10-year, 3-month spread stands at 28
bp. Longer-term rates generally have
also come down, as have long-term
Treasuries, but the recent picture is a
bit more mixed. Municipal bond
yields have actually increased so far
in 2001. In an unusual move, conventional mortgage rates have dropped
below AAA corporate bond yields.

One reason the yield curve receives
so much attention is its history as a predictor of future economic performance.
A steep yield curve usually indicates
high future growth, and an inverted
yield curve indicates a recession. While
this pattern is apparent in the plots for
the 10-year, 3-month spread, as well as
in GDP growth for the following year,
both the 1960s and the 1990s show long
periods in which low spreads were
associated with high growth. Does this
mean the recession suggested by the
recent yield-curve inversion should also
be discounted? Time will tell.
(continued on next page)

7
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Money and Financial Markets (cont.)
Percent
1.6 YIELD SPREAD: 10-YEAR INTEREST SWAP a

Percent
1.75 YIELD SPREAD: 90-DAY A1P1 COMMERCIAL PAPER

MINUS 10-YEAR TREASURY BOND b

MINUS 3-MONTH TREASURY BILL b

1.4

1.50

1.2
1.25
1.0
1.00
0.8
0.75
0.6
0.50
0.4
0.25

0.2
0

0
01/97

01/98

01/99

01/00

01/01

01/97

01/98

01/99

01/00

01/01

Percent
7 PENNACCHI MODEL c

Percent
5 TREASURY INFLATION-INDEXED SECURITIES

6
30-day Treasury bill

4
10-year TIIS yield

5

3

4

3

2

2

Estimated real interest rate

Estimated expected inflation rate

1
1
Yield spread: 10-year Treasury bond minus 10-year TIIS
0

0
01/31/97

02/06/98

02/12/99

02/18/00

02/16/01

01/97

01/98

01/99

01/00

01/01

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Quote for semiannually fixed rate versus the U.S. dollar’s 3-month London interbank offered rate (LIBOR).
b. Bloomberg generic series.
c. The estimated expected inflation rate and the estimated real rate are calculated using the Pennacchi model of inflation estimation and the median forecast
for the GDP implicit price deflator from the Survey of Professional Forecasters. Monthly data.
SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,” Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, Survey of Professional Forecasters; and Bloomberg Financial Information Services.

The spread between long- and
short-term yields, often called the
term spread, has a counterpart in
the spread between risky and safe
bonds, often called the risk spread.
This can sometimes be interpreted as
a predictor of future growth—under
the assumption that risk increases in
a recession—but it can also be seen
as a more contemporaneous indicator of uncertainty. If so, then bond
markets are having a rather tranquil
time. At longer maturities, the spread
between 10-year interest rate swaps

and 10-year Treasuries has decreased 42 bp since May 2000,
although it remains above the levels
seen in 1997 and 1998. On the short
end, the spread between 90-day
commercial paper and 3-month
Treasury bills has eliminated the
spike seen around the turn of
the year and resumed a value on the
low side of its range for 1997–2001.
Yet another sort of spread may
provide information about future
inflation. The spread between
nominal Treasury bond yields and

yields on Treasury inflation-indexed
securities (TIIS) measures the difference between real and nominal
interest rates, of which inflation is an
important component. Another
approach is to estimate inflation and
real rates from nominal rates
and survey measures of inflation.
Although both of these measures
indicate that real rates have fallen in
2001, they differ as to the prospects
for inflation.

8
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Inventories and Imports
Ratio
5.0 REAL PRIVATE NONFARM INVENTORIES/SALES a

Real GDP and Components

4.8

(Billions of chained 1996 dollars)
2000:IVQ

9,393.7

24.2

Personal
consumption

6,329.8

6,373.3

43.5

4.2

Business fixed
investment

1,438.8

1,438.3

–0.5

4.0

362.3

359.0

–3.3

3.8

Residential
investment
Change in
business
inventories

Change

4.6

2000:IIIQ

9,369.5

Real GDP

4.4

3.6

72.5

55.7

–16.8

Government
spending

1,578.2

1,589.6

11.4

3.2

Net exports

–427.7

–441.7

–14.0

3.0

3.4

3/55

Ratio
35 INTERNATIONAL TRADE/GDP b

3/60

3/65

3/70

3/75

3/80

3/85

3/90

3/95

3/00

Percentage Change in Imports Resulting from
a 1% Increase in Inventoriesc

30

Confidence range
25

20

Point
estimate

95%

90%

1956–79

1.3

0.3 to 2.3

0.5 to 2.1

1980–89

1.8

0.5 to 3.1

0.7 to 2.8

1990–2000

1.2

0.3 to 2.2

0.4 to 2.0

15

10

5

0
6/55

6/60

6/65

6/70

6/75

6/80

6/85

6/90

6/95

6/00

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
b. Real imports plus exports, divided by GDP.
c. Calculations are based on quarterly data for imports of goods and nonfarm inventories.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Many economists believe that the
current cooling in economic activity
largely reflects an inventory correction that will pass fairly quickly and
painlessly. Two observations support
this prognosis. First, businesses have
managed their inventories closely,
fostering a general decline in the
ratio of inventories to sales since
the early 1980s. Because manufacturers reacted quickly when the ratio
began to rise last year, the necessary
correction might be less extensive
than it often has been in the past.

The second reason for optimism is
the increasingly global nature of production. International trade (exports
plus imports) equaled 29% of GDP in
2000, up from 7% in 1960. As businesses rely more heavily on imports
to manage their inventories—so the
story goes—corrections have less
impact on their domestic production
and employment than they had 20 or
30 years ago.
The relationship between inventories and imports is not wholly
inconsistent with this account. Over

the past 10 years, a 1% increase in private nonfarm inventories has been
associated with a 1.2% increase in
goods imports. Nevertheless, the story
falls short. After allowing for the inherent randomness of any such estimate,
it appears that the relationship
between inventories and imports has
not changed in 45 years. Imports are
no more an inventory escape valve
today than they were in the past.

9
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Fourth District Export Growth
NET RELATIVE CHANGE IN MANUFACTURING EXPORTS

Positive
Negative

Percent
7.5 U.S. MANUFACTURING EXPORTS AS A SHARE OF GDP

Shift-Share Results
(Percent)

7.0
Net
relative
change

6.5

Ohio

Industrymix Competitive
effect
effect

Destination
effect

1.7

0.1

2.2

–0.6

Kentucky

44.1

–4.4

51.1

–2.7

Pennsylvania

–0.8

3.5

–4.6

0.4

West Virginia –33.2

–12.7

–17.8

–2.8

6.0

5.5

5.0

4.5

4.0

Illinois

19.6

0.8

21.3

–2.6

Indiana

22.7

–0.4

23.7

–0.6

New York

–31.2

3.2

–31.1

–3.3

Michigan

–35.0

1.9

–46.3

9.4

3.5
1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Cletus C. Coughlin and Patricia S. Pollard, “Comparing Manufacturing Export
Growth across States: What Accounts for the Difference?” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, vol. 83, no. 1 (January/February 2001), pp. 25–40.

Since the mid-1980s, overall U.S.
manufacturing exports have increased sharply as a share of gross
domestic product, but their state-bystate performance has been uneven.
In the Fourth Federal Reserve
District, Ohio’s and Kentucky’s
manufacturing exports grew faster
than the national average, while
Pennsylvania’s and West Virginia’s
lagged behind it.
Cletus Coughlin and Patricia
Pollard, economists at the St. Louis
Federal Reserve Bank, recently
examined relative export growth by

splitting the change in each state’s net
manufacturing exports into three constituent effects. The industry-mix
effect indicates that a state contains a
higher concentration of industries
whose exports expanded faster than
the U.S. average. The competitive
effect indicates that exports from a
state’s industries are leading or lagging
export growth among similar industries nationwide. The destination effect
attributes a state’s differential export
performance to whether its manufacturers predominantly serve faster- or
slower-growing foreign markets.

A consistent pattern does not
emerge in the Fourth District.
Kentucky, which showed solid relative export growth, benefited from a
strong competitive effect. Ohio’s
relative export growth stemmed from
modest competitive and industrial-mix
effects. Pennsylvania’s exports benefited from a favorable industrial mix
and fast-growing foreign customers,
but its competitive effect held
Pennsylvania back. West Virginia lost
ground on all counts.

10
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity
Contribution to percent change in GDP
0.3 PERCENTAGE POINT CHANGE FROM

a,b

Real GDP and Components, 2000:IVQ

ADVANCE TO FINAL ESTIMATE, 2000:IVQ

(Final percent change)
Change,
billions
of 1996 $

Real GDP
Personal consumption
Durables
Nondurables
Services
Business fixed
investment
Equipment
Structures
Residential investment
Government spending
National defense
Net exports
Exports
Imports
Change in business
inventories

Percent change, last:
Four
Quarter
quarters

24.2
43.5
–7.2
4.8
43.2

1.0
2.8
–3.2
1.0
4.9

3.4
4.5
5.2
3.8
4.6

–0.5
–9.7
7.2
–3.3
11.4
7.5
–14.0
–19.0
–4.9

–0.1
–3.3
10.4
–3.6
2.9
9.0
—
–6.4
–1.2

10.5
9.8
12.7
–2.6
1.3
–2.0
—
6.7
11.3

–16.8

—

—

0.2

0.1
Residential
investment

Personal
consumption

0

Business
fixed
investment

–0.1

Imports

Government
spending

–0.2
Exports
–0.3

–0.4
Change in
inventories

–0.5

Ratio
1.65 INVENTORY/SALES a

Annualized percent change from previous quarter
6 GDP ESTIMATES AND BLUE CHIP FORECAST

1.60

Final percent change

5

Manufacturing

Advance estimate

1.55

Preliminary estimate

1.50

Blue Chip forecast c

4

1.45
3
1.40

30-year average
Trade

1.35

2

1.30
1
1.25
1.20

0
1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
2000

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

2001

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Chain-weighted data in billions of 1996 dollars.
b. Components of real GDP need not add to totals because current dollar values are deflated at the most detailed level for which all required data are available.
c. Blue chip forecasts are based on Blue Chip Economic Indicators, March 10, 2001.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, and Blue Chip Economic Indicators, March 10, 2001.

Gross domestic product (GDP) grew
at a 1.0% annual rate in 2000:IVQ.
Consumer spending was revised
downward but remained healthy,
with nearly 3% growth. Business
fixed investment fell only slightly
this quarter, the drop in equipment
and software purchases being offset
by strong growth in business structures. Residential investment and exports were also off modestly, while
greater government spending added
to fourth-quarter growth.

The final estimate for 2000:IVQ,
released late in March, is 0.1 percentage point below the preliminary
estimate of a month earlier and
0.4 percentage point below the
advance estimate. The most recent
revision resulted primarily from
business inventory accumulations
that were slower than originally
estimated. Adjustments to inventory
accumulation can account for the
entire –0.4 percentage point revision
in quarterly GDP growth, with

revisions in the other components
offsetting one another.
Despite much slower inventory
accumulation, inventory-to-sales ratios
remain above their recent lows. Ratios
for both trade and manufacturing
broke trend and began to rise in
2000:IQ. While the trade ratio has
begun to fall again, manufacturers’
inventories continue to accumulate
faster than sales.
Quarterly real GDP growth is
slower than at any time since
1995:IIQ, and Blue Chip forecasters
(continued on next page)

11
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Economic Activity (cont.)
Contribution to Change in Real GDP Growth

Percentage point contribution to GDP growth
2.5 PERSONAL CONSUMPTION OF SERVICES

Last Four Recessions, Peak to Trough

Change in GDP
growth a

1973–75

1979–80 1981–82 1990–91

–15.6

–10.8

–14.5

–8.3

Percent contribution to change in GDP growth b,c
Personal
consumption
16.7
73.4
–2.5
54.3
Durables
10.6
42.0
–0.3
28.7
Nondurables
4.2
21.2
5.7
15.5
Services
2.0
10.1
–7.8
10.1
Investment
104.6
47.9
98.2
57.8
Structures
8.5
12.3
5.1
11.2
Equipment
and software 21.7
27.9
8.5
6.5
Change in
inventory
63.1
–24.7
81.2
23.4
Government
spending
–4.6
–1.2
7.9
5.3
Net exports

–16.5

–20.4

–4.0

–17.3

1991 recession
Average of four recessions since 1973

2.0

Current period

1.5

1.0

0.5

0
Three quarters prior Two quarters prior One quarter prior

Percentage point contribution to GDP growth
2.0 PERSONAL CONSUMPTION OF GOODS

Percentage point contribution to GDP growth
2.0 CHANGE IN INVENTORY

1.5

1.5

First quarter of
negative GDP growth

1991 recession
Average of four recessions since 1973

1.0

Current period

1.0

0.5

0.5

First quarter ot
negative GDP growth

First quarter of
negative GDP growth
0

–0.5

0

Two quarters prior

Two quarters prior

–0.5

Three quarters prior

One quarter prior
–1.0

–1.0
One quarter prior

1991 recession
Average of four recessions since 1973

–1.5

–1.5

Three quarters prior

Current period

–2.0

–2.0

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Annualized quarterly growth rates.
b. Components of personal consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports sum to 100.
c. Negative numbers indicate an offset to GDP contraction.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted and annualized.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, the Census Bureau, and National Bureau of Economic Research.

expect it to slow further before
rebounding later this year. Forecasters predict that real GDP growth
for 2001:IQ will be less than 1% but
expect it to reach its long-term
average by 2001:IVQ.
Over the last 30 years, the U.S. has
undergone four periods of economic
contraction. By comparing current
patterns of consumption and investment with historical trends, one may
gain insight about the likelihood of
a recession.
Some argue that the risk of a recession is minimal because services

growth has accelerated over the last
three quarters. If history is any
teacher, however, this does not
necessarily mean that a recession
can be avoided. Personal consumption of services has remained strong
going into each contraction, particularly the last one.
Personal consumption of goods
has proven a better predictor of
looming contractions. In each of the
last four, goods consumption fell in
the quarter immediately preceding a
drop in real GDP. Thus far, goods
consumption has remained flat,

suggesting that a recession is not
necessarily imminent.
Past inventory changes may also
provide some insight into the
current situation. Changes in inventory usually spike one quarter before a drop in GDP and then decline
the following quarter. Changes in inventory spiked during 2000:IIQ and
then fell slightly in 2000:IIIQ. That
spike probably portended the slow
growth that occurred in 2000:IVQ
rather than the beginning of an
actual recession.

12
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Labor Markets
Change, thousands of workers
350 AVERAGE MONTHLY NONFARM EMPLOYMENT GROWTH

Labor Market Conditions
Average monthly change
(thousands of employees)

300
1997

1998

1999

Mar.
2000 2001

Payroll employment
280
Goods-producing
48
Mining
1
Construction
21
Manufacturing
25
Durable goods
27
Nondurable goods –2
Service-producing
232
16
TPUa
Retail trade
24
b
21
FIRE
Services
141
Government
17

251
22
–3
37
–12
–2
–11
229
20
30
22
120
28

229
4
–3
25
–18
–6
–12
225
16
36
10
124
28

153
1
1
14
–14
–4
–10
153
15
26
4
91
11

250
200
150
100
50
0

–86
–67
2
12
–81
–59
–22
–19
5
–46
17
11
–4

Average for period

–50

Civilian unemployment
rate (%)

4.9

4.5

4.2

4.0

4.3

–100
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

IQ

Jan. Feb.
2001

Mar.

Percent
65.0 LABOR MARKETS INDICATORS c

Percent
8.2

64.5

7.6
Employee-to-popluation ratio

Percent of civilian labor force
5.0 MEASURES OF LABOR UNDERUTILIZATION
4.5
Job losers plus temporary job completers

4.0

64.0

7.0

63.5

6.4

63.0

5.8

3.5

62.5

5.2

3.0
2.5
2.0

Civilian unemployment rate

1.5
62.0

4.6

Persons unemployed 15 weeks or longer

1.0
61.5

4.0
3.4

61.0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

0.5
0
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Transportation and public utilities.
b. Finance, insurance, and real estate.
c. Vertical line indicates break in data series due to survey redesign.
NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

In March, manufacturing and helpsupply services (temporary help)
posted large employment losses,
which combined with below-average
gains in most service industries to
cause a net decrease of 86,000 in total
nonfarm payrolls.
Manufacturing continues to struggle mightily; it shed another 81,000
jobs in March, bringing its losses to
451,000 since June. Similarly, helpsupply services decreased by 86,000
jobs in March, for total losses of
273,000 jobs in the last six months.
Labor conditions in both industries

are considered leading indicators and
may portend more widespread employment declines. The large job
losses in help-supply services, as well
as in retail trade, more than offset
gains in other industries, such as
health services (23,000) and computer
services (11,000); as a result, serviceproducing industries posted a rare
overall monthly employment decline.
Other labor market indicators also
deteriorated slightly in March. The
unemployment rate edged up 0.1% to
4.3%; since last October, when it
reached a 30-year low of 3.9%, it has

risen 0.4%. The employment-topopulation ratio fell 0.1% to 64.3%.
The percent of the civilian labor force
unemployed for 15 weeks or longer
recently increased, albeit slightly.
Similarly, the percent of the civilian
labor force that recently has lost a job
or completed a temporary job rose
slightly. While variations in these
series are common, even during
periods of robust economic growth,
their recent simultaneous movements
seem atypically strong and suggest
that first-quarter economic activity
slowed considerably.

13
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Federal Budget
Percent of GDP
31 REVENUES AND OUTLAYS

Percent of GDP
12 NET BUDGET SURPLUS

28

9

25

6

Outlays, current projection

Net surplus
22

3
Off budget
0

19

–3

16

Revenues, July 2000
projection
Revenues, current projection
Outlays, July 2000 projection

On budget
13

–6
–9

10
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

1980

1985

Percent of GDP
21 REVENUES

Percent of GDP
18 OUTLAYS

18

15

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

Other
Entitlements and other mandatory spending
15

12
Social insurance taxes

12

9
Corporate income taxes

Discretionary spending

9

6

6

3

Net interest

Individual income taxes
3

0

0

–3

Offsetting receipts a
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. Offsetting receipts result from market-oriented public transactions that are not authorized to be credited to expenditure account.
NOTE: Dotted lines indicate projections.
SOURCE: U.S. Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2002–2011 (baseline budget projections).

Recent projections by the Congressional Budget Office place the
cumulative 10-year (FY2002–11)
surplus at $5.6 trillion. This figure is
more than $1 trillion higher than the
estimate given last July for FY2001–10,
primarily because the projection
window was shifted forward a year.
Of the 10-year total, $3.1 trillion
accrues on budget and $2.5 trillion off
budget—which includes the Social
Security and Postal Service accounts.
The improved budgetary projections
depend on several economic assumptions—that the recent economic
weakness will be short-lived; real

GDP growth will average 3% annually
in FY2002–11; and interest rates will
be slightly lower relative to the
Congressional Budget Office’s July
assumptions, implying lower debtservice costs.
Almost all ($808 billion) of the
increase in the projected 10-year
surplus comes from higher revenue
projections, which assume an
improved economic outlook. Individual income taxes are expected to
contribute the most revenue growth as
a percent of GDP, especially in the
later years of the projection horizon, as
the recent increase continues and

accelerates. This upsurge in revenue
has resulted from rapid growth in
several categories: taxable personal
income, capital gains realizations,
taxable withdrawals from 401(k) plans
and individual retirement accounts,
and a higher effective tax rate because
a greater proportion of Americans are
in higher marginal income-taxrate brackets.
On the outlay side, discretionary
spending as a percent of GDP
continues its downward trend,
primarily because of slower growth
in defense expenditures.

14
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Fourth District in Focus
Year-over-year percent change
1.5 POPULATION GROWTH

FOURTH DISTRICT COUNTIES

1.2
U.S.
0.9

0.6
Fourth District total
0.3
Fourth District MSAs
In MSA
Not in MSA

0

–0.3

–0.6
1981

1984

1987

1990

Dollars per year
28,000 PER CAPITA INCOME

Thousands
8,500 CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE

26,000

8,300

24,000

8,100

1993

1996

1999

Thousands
7,250

7,050

6,850
Fourth District total

U.S.

Fourth District MSAs

22,000

7,900

6,650

7,700

6,450

Fourth District total
20,000

18,000

7,500
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

6,250
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

SOURCES: Analysis by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and from U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census.

The Fourth District is an unwieldy entity, composed of 169 counties in four
states, but its composition is important
for understanding its evolving economy. New figures indicate that the
District’s population now stands at
16.6 million, 13.4 million of whom live
in counties that the Census Bureau
classifies as part of a metropolitan
statistical area (17 MSAs are located at
least partly in the District). Only 68 of
169 counties (40%) are located in
MSAs, yet they account for 81% of the
District’s population, 83% of its labor
force, and 85% of its income.

The District’s population grew at
a decreasing rate throughout the
1990s, lagging national growth
trends considerably. The story is
similar for District MSAs.
In 1996, the District’s per capita
income fell relative to the U.S. average
(that is, the gap between national and
District figures widened), and that gap
has remained relatively larger than it
was when the expansion began. In
1991, annual per capita income in the
Fourth District was $1,784 less than
the U.S. average; by 1998, the gap had
nearly doubled. In that year, per

capita income in the District was
$25,496, compared to the U.S. average
of $28,542 (a difference of $3,046).
Although the District’s population
growth was relatively low throughout
the 1990s, its labor force grew
because of rising labor force participation rates. (Bureau of Labor Statistics
data show that the District’s labor
force declined in 1998, perhaps
reflecting the Bureau’s switch from
using a direct counting method for the
10 largest states to using a standardized sampling method for all 50
states). Throughout the 1990s, labor
(continued on next page)

15
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

The Fourth District in Focus (cont.)
Percent
15 ANNUAL UNEMPLOYMENT RATES

Year-over-year percent change
2.0 CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE GROWTH
U.S.

13
1.5
Fourth District total
11
1.0
Fourth District total

9

0.5

U.S.
7
Fourth District MSAs

0

5
Fourth District MSAs
3

–0.5
1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

FOURTH DISTRICT ANNUAL UNEMPLOYMENT RATES

1980

1983

1986

1989

About U.S. average
( ± 0.2 percentage points)
Lower than U.S. average

1995

1998

Unemployment Rates

Dec.
2000

Higher than U.S. average

1992

Nov.
2000

Dec.
1999

Year/
year
change

Fourth District
total

3.9

3.9

3.8

0.1

Fourth District
MSAs

3.6

3.7

3.6

0

3.7
3.8
3.7

3.7
4.1
3.8

3.9
3.7
3.9

–0.2
0.1
–0.2

3.7

3.8

3.7

0

Ohio
Pennsylvania
Kentucky
U.S. average

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

SOURCES: Analysis by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, based on data from U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census.

force growth in District MSAs closely
followed changes in the District as a
whole. The year 2000 appears to be
an exception: Although the labor
force shrank in the District overall, it
grew in District MSAs. In fact, labor
force growth in District MSAs even
outpaced the U.S. average in 2000.
Unlike population growth rates,
the District’s unemployment rate generally followed the national trend
over the last decade. During the
1980s, the District—as well as its
MSAs—reported unemployment rates
considerably higher than the nation’s;

starting with the current expansion,
however, it has enjoyed lower unemployment rates than the U.S. as a
whole. Over the last two years,
the figures have fluctuated around the
U.S. average. These varying relationships to the national unemployment
trend can likely be explained by the
District’s heavier-than-average dependence on manufacturing as a source
of employment. When manufacturing
unemployment is high, the District’s
rate tends to be high.
The eastern part of the District
tends to have higher unemployment

rates than the nation as a whole,
while the western part reports figures below or at national rates. (The
western counties are more heavily
concentrated in agriculture, which
generally has lower unemployment.)
In December 2000, the District’s
non–seasonally adjusted unemployment rate was slightly higher than
the rate reported by District states
and the U.S., but year-over-year
changes for the District and its MSAs
were comparable to the nation’s.

16
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Commercial Banks
Percent
4.50 BANK EARNINGS

Percent
1.4

Percent of total assets
8.00 BANK CAPITAL

Percent
15.5

Net interest margin a
4.25

1.3

7.75

15.0
Core capital

4.00

1.2

7.50

1.1

7.25

14.5

Return on assets

3.75

14.0
Return on equity

3.50

1.0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Percent of total loans
1.00 BANK ASSET QUALITY

1999

7.00

2000

1993

Percent of total assets
2.0

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Percent of all banks
10 UNPROFITABLE AND PROBLEM BANKS

1999

13.5
2000

Percent of all banks
5

8

4

6

3

1.5

0.75
Net charge-offs

Unprofitable banks

1.0

0.50

4

Problem assets

2

0.5

0.25

Problem banks

2

0

0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

1

0

0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. The net interest margin equals interest income less interest expenses, both divided by average earning assets.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

Commercial banks showed negligible
deterioration in 2000, with earnings of
$71.176 billion, off slightly from 1999.
Return on assets also declined somewhat (1.19% in 2000, compared to
1.31% in 1999). Downward pressure
on profits was apparent in the net
interest margin, which dropped from
4.07% at the end of 1999 to a 10-year
low of 3.95% at year-end 2000.
Return on equity for 2000 was
14.07%, compared to 15.31% the
previous year. This drop must have
been due primarily to a lower return
on assets, since core capital remained
a healthy 7.71% of total assets, only a

small decrease from 1999. Asset quality continued strong, with problem
assets still less than 1.00% of the total.
However, the increase in this share
(from 0.63% in 1999 to 0.74% in
2000) could indicate some weakness
in asset quality. This bears watching,
especially as the economy slows
down. In addition, net charge-offs
increased slightly (from 0.61% of
loans at year-end 1999 to 0.64% at
year-end 2000, but still below the
1998 peak of 0.67%).
While earnings have slowed somewhat, the share of unprofitable banks
fell from 7.47% of all banks at

year-end 1999 to 7.06% in 2000:IVQ.
On the other hand, the share of problem banks (those with substandard
examination ratings) rose slightly to
0.91% at year-end 2000.
Although these changes in performance indicators are consistent with
some weakening in the banking
sector, they do not suggest significant deterioration. However, the
current economic slowdown raises
the question of whether the deterioration observed in 2000 will remain
negligible in 2001.

17
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Savings Associations
Percent
3.75 SAVINGS ASSOCIATION EARNINGS

Percent
1.2

Return on assets

3.50

0.9

Percent of total assets
8.25 SAVINGS ASSOCIATION CAPITAL

Percent
12

8.00

11

Net interest margin a
Core capital
0.6

3.25

7.75

10

Return on equity
3.00

0.3

7.50

0

7.25

2.75
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

9

8
1993

Percent of all associations
Percent of all associations
7
14 UNPROFITABLE AND PROBLEM SAVINGS ASSOCIATIONS

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Percent of total loans
1.0 SAVINGS ASSOCIATION ASSET QUALITY

1999

2000

Percent of total assets
2.5

6

12
Unprofitable associations
10

5

8

4

6

3

4

2

0.8

2.0

0.6

1.5

0.4

1.0
Problem assets
Net charge-offs

0.2

Problem associations
2

0.5

1

0

0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

0

0
1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

a. The net interest margin equals interest income less interest expenses, both divided by average earning assets.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

In many ways, savings associations’
performance mirrored commercial
banks’ in 2000. Savings associations’
earnings were $10.7 billion, slightly
below the 1999 record of $10.826
billion. Return on assets was 0.92%,
down from 1.00% in 1999—its second
consecutive annual decrease. The
earnings slowdown is also reflected in
the net interest margin’s drop below
2.96% to its lowest level since 1991.
Return on equity’s fall (from 11.72%
at year-end 1999 to 11.14% at yearend 2000) was apparently driven by a
lower return on assets; core capital

remained a healthy 7.81% of total
assets, only a small decrease from
1999. Further signs of weakening
include a greater number of problem
institutions and more savings associations reporting losses. The share of
savings associations reporting losses
rose steadily from 4.1% in 1997 to
8.36% at year-end 2000. In addition,
1.13% of savings associations received
substandard examination ratings in
2000, the largest share since 1997.
Asset-quality indicators are mixed.
At year-end 2000, problem assets fell
to 0.56% of total assets, the smallest

share in over a decade. On the other
hand, net charge-offs rose slightly
to 0.20%.
Most changes in performance
indicators are consistent with some
weakening in housing finance, but
the latest data do not suggest
significant deterioration in savings
associations’ health. As with banks,
the question for savings associations
is whether the deterioration noted in
2000 will remain negligible this year.

18
•

•

•

•

•

•

•

Japan’s Monetary Policy
Percent
8 GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT AND CONSUMER PRICE INDEX

Year-over-year percent change
6 REAL INTEREST RATE
5

6
4
GDP
4

3
2

2
1
0

0
CPI
–1

–2
–2
–4

–3
1991:IQ

1993:IQ

1995:IQ

1997:IQ

1999:IQ

2001:IQ

2/1/91

2/1/93

2/1/95

2/1/97

2/1/99

2/1/01

Trillions of yen
12 BALANCES AT THE BANK OF JAPAN

Percent
9 MONETARY POLICY RATES
8

Current account balances
10

7
6

8

5
6
4
4

3
Call money rate

Required reserves

2
2

Discount rate
1

0

0
2/1/91

2/1/93

2/1/95

2/1/97

2/1/99

2/1/01

2/1/91

2/1/93

2/1/95

2/1/97

2/1/99

2/1/01

FRB Cleveland • April 2001

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; Bank of Japan; and International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics.

Deflation and relatively weak economic growth have bedeviled the
Japanese economy for more than two
years. Sharp declines in real growth
and inflation during the early 1990s
were followed by several years of
advancing growth rates and very low
measured inflation. This recovery was
cut short during the Asian crisis,
which brought plummeting growth
rates and a year of rising prices,
followed by the current deflation.
Over the past decade, the Bank of
Japan has reduced both the overnight
call loan rate and its own lending rate

through a steady succession of cuts.
The real call loan rate (the actual rate
minus the annual rate of inflation)
reached a low of –2% during the 1997
period of rising prices, but then averaged about zero in 1998 and 1999
before moving up slightly further to
average closer to 1% in 2000. This
occurred despite a monetary policy
that brought the nominal call loan rate
close to zero. The Bank, perhaps encouraged by the halting pickup in real
growth, modified the zero-rate policy
slightly in August 2000 to maintain a
target of 0.25%, which it reduced to
0.15% in early March of this year.

On March 19, the Bank of Japan
adopted a new policy strategy, abandoning interest rate targets to achieve
a drastic easing “unlikely to be taken
under ordinary circumstances.” The
new policy target is the quantity of
current account deposit balances at
the Bank. Initially, by ensuring a
surplus of balances over required
levels, this approach is expected to
keep the call loan rate close to zero.
In addition, the Bank of Japan
pledged to continue this way of
implementing policy until inflation
stabilizes at zero or above.