View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

August 2011 (July 15, 2011-August 11, 2011)

In This Issue:
Monetary Policy
 The Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth
 A Subtle Shift in FOMC Policy
Inflation and Price Statistics
 A Few Bad Apples Spoil June’s Price Statistics
Regional Economics
 The Fourth District: The Next Big Energy
Producer?
 Recent Population Trends in the Midwest

Banking and Financial Markets
 Global Banking System Exposure to the Greek
Sovereign Debt Crisis
 Has the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market
Revived Yet?
International Markets
 The Net International Investment Position
Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages
 Labor Market not So Anomalous After All

Monetary Policy

Yield Curve and Predicted GDP Growth, August 2011
Covering July 1, 2011–August 3, 2011
by Joseph G. Haubrich and Margaret Jacobson
Overview of the Latest Yield Curve Figures
Over the past month, the yield curve barely moved,
experiencing a small parallel upward shift as both
short and long rates inched along. The three-month
Treasury bill rate rose to 0.03 percent (for the
week ending July 22), up from June’s 0.02 percent
though below May’s 0.05 percent. The ten-year
rate rose to 2.97, incrementally up from June’s to
2.96 percent, but also below May’s 3.15. The slope
stayed constant at 294 basis points, remaining at its
lowest level since last November.

Highlights
July

June

May

3-month Treasury bill rate
(percent)

0.03

0.02

0.05

10-year Treasury bond rate
(percent)

2.97

2.96

3.15

Yield curve slope
(basis points)

294

294

310

Prediction for GDP growth
(percent)

0.82

1.1

1.1

Probabilty of recession in 1
year (percent)

1.7

1.7

1.3

Yield Curve Predicted GDP Growth
Percent
GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4

Predicted
GDP growth

2
0
-2

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-4
-6
2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

Projecting forward using past values of the spread
and GDP growth suggests that real GDP will grow
at about a 0.8 percent rate over the next year, down
slightly from June’s 1.1 percent, most likely a reflection weak GDP numbers for the first two quarters
of this year. The strong influence of the recent recession is leading toward relatively low growth rates.
Although the time horizons do not match exactly,
the forecast comes in on the more pessimistic side
of other predictions, though like them, it does show
moderate growth for the year.
Using the yield curve to predict whether or not
the economy will be in recession in the future, we
estimate that the expected chance of the economy
being in a recession next July is 1.7 percent, even
with June’s prediction and up just a bit from May’s
1.3 percent. So although our approach is somewhat
pessimistic as regards the level of growth over the
next year, it is quite optimistic about the recovery
continuing.
The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic
Growth
The slope of the yield curve—the difference between the yields on short- and long-term maturity
bonds—has achieved some notoriety as a simple
forecaster of economic growth. The rule of thumb
is that an inverted yield curve (short rates above
long rates) indicates a recession in about a year, and

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

2

Recession Probability from Yield Curve
Percent probability, as predicted by a probit model
100
90
80

Probability of recession

70
60

Forecast

50
40
30
20

yield curve inversions have preceded each of the last
seven recessions (as defined by the NBER). One of
the recessions predicted by the yield curve was the
most recent one. The yield curve inverted in August
2006, a bit more than a year before the current
recession started in December 2007. There have
been two notable false positives: an inversion in late
1966 and a very flat curve in late 1998.
More generally, a flat curve indicates weak growth,
and conversely, a steep curve indicates strong
growth. One measure of slope, the spread between
ten-year Treasury bonds and three-month Treasury
bills, bears out this relation, particularly when real
GDP growth is lagged a year to line up growth with
the spread that predicts it.
Predicting GDP Growth

10
0
1960 1966 1972 1978 1984 1990 1996 2002 2008
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board, authors’
calculations.

We use past values of the yield spread and GDP
growth to project what real GDP will be in the future. We typically calculate and post the prediction
for real GDP growth one year forward.
Predicting the Probability of Recession

Yield Curve Spread and Real GDP
Growth
Percent
10
8
6

GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

4
2
0
-2
-4

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

While we can use the yield curve to predict whether
future GDP growth will be above or below average, it does not do so well in predicting an actual
number, especially in the case of recessions. Alternatively, we can employ features of the yield curve
to predict whether or not the economy will be in a
recession at a given point in the future. Typically,
we calculate and post the probability of recession
one year forward.
Of course, it might not be advisable to take these
number quite so literally, for two reasons. First,
this probability is itself subject to error, as is the
case with all statistical estimates. Second, other
researchers have postulated that the underlying
determinants of the yield spread today are materially different from the determinants that generated
yield spreads during prior decades. Differences
could arise from changes in international capital
flows and inflation expectations, for example. The
bottom line is that yield curves contain important
information for business cycle analysis, but, like
other indicators, should be interpreted with caution. For more detail on these and other issues re
3

Yield Spread and Lagged Real GDP Growth
Percent
10
8

One-year lag of GDP growth
(year-over-year change)

6

lated to using the yield curve to predict recessions,
see the Commentary “Does the Yield Curve Signal
Recession?” The Federal Reserve Bank of New York
also maintains a website with much useful information on the topic, including its own estimate of
recession probabilities.

4
2
0
-2
-4

Ten-year minus three-month
yield spread

-6
1953 1959 1965 1971 1977 1983 1989 1995 2001 2007
Note: Shaded bars indicate recessions.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

4

Monetary Policy

A Subtle Shift in FOMC Policy
07.21.11
by John B. Carlson and John Lindner
At his second press conference, Chairman Bernanke
was asked whether the Fed would ever institute
an explicit numerical inflation-targeting policy. In
responding, he confessed he has always been a fan
of that type of monetary policy. Recent adjustments
in some of the Fed’s communications suggest that
the Chairman may be gaining a few more Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) participants on
his side. Adopting an inflation target is a topic that
has gotten a lot of attention lately, and a review of
the Committee’s most recent minutes and the public discourse should help shed some light on why.
The minutes of recent FOMC meetings show that
at least some FOMC members have been considering the costs and benefits of an explicit inflation
target as an official policy goal. As expressed in the
minutes, “a few participants noted that the adoption by the Committee of an explicit numerical
inflation objective could help keep longer-term
inflation expectations well anchored.” This statement is not a new development, however, as it has
appeared in each of the last three sets of minutes
published. Perhaps more important was a change in
the Chairman’s interpretation of the Committee’s
inflation projections.

PCE Prices and Long-Run Projections
Percent
5
4
PCE price index,
4-quarter change

3

Long-run central
tendency projections

2
1
0
-1
12/07

6/08

12/08

6/09

12/09

6/10

12/10

6/11

In the past, the Fed has argued that in order to
maintain price stability—one half of its dual
mandate—it must achieve a rate of inflation that
is consistent with the mandate over the medium
term. Until recently, this rate was not specified but
was implicitly understood by market participants to
be 2 percent, or just a little bit less. Because inflation is approaching that level and economic growth
is still below its long-run trend, some contention
has emerged as to whether the Fed will stick to that
implicit, mandate-consistent target or let inflation
rise to spur growth.
Speaking at his April press conference, Chairman
Bernanke pointed out that the longer-run projection for inflation submitted by FOMC participants

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Board.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

5

PCE Prices and Long-Run Projections
Percent
5
Canadian CPI
4

United Kingdom and
Canadian inflation target

3
2
1
PCE price index

United Kingdom CPI
0
-1
3/93

3/96

3/99

3/02

3/05

3/08

3/11

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Office of National Statistics; Bank of Canada.

University of Michigan Inflation Expectations

for the April meeting was 1.7 percent to 2.0 percent. He went on to say that because the outlook
for inflation is determined almost entirely by monetary policy, the projections could be interpreted as
“the inflation rate that Committee members judge
to be most consistent with the Federal Reserve’s
mandate.” Those projections were dependent on
the assumption of appropriate monetary policy,
but in linking the FOMC’s projections to its role
in determining inflation, Chairman Bernanke gave
an explicit definition of what was considered a
mandate-consistent level of inflation at that time.
Naturally, these longer-run projections are likely to
change over time as economic conditions evolve.
Still, here is a specific definition of where policy is
trying to guide inflation rates in the medium term.
Giving this type of policy guidance offers several
advantages, one of which would be to anchor inflation expectations, which have been very volatile in
the past few years.

Percent
7
6

One-year ahead

5
4
3

5-year ahead

2
Potential target

1
0
4/00

9/01

3/03

9/04

3/06

3/07

3/09

Source: University of Michigan.

9/10

With this recent development, it seems as if the Fed
has very nearly adopted an unofficial inflation-targeting policy. Even though making it official would
be a new policy for the Fed, it has been implemented in several other countries, largely with positive
results. The 2010 Annual Report of the Cleveland
Fed noted the advantages of instituting an explicit
numerical target, and it also outlined some of the
success stories in other countries. Although the Fed
is currently doing about as well as other nations in
stabilizing its price level (see chart below), other
advantages might include more leeway in policy
decisions with anchored inflation expectations and
enhanced transparency and accountability.
One concern that has been raised about an explicit
inflation target is that it seems to favor the price
stability part of the Fed’s mandate over the full
employment part. This issue has been addressed in
a number of different ways (see, for example, the
Cleveland Fed’s 2010 Annual Report and Chairman Bernanke’s June press conference transcript ).
Ultimately, a more stable inflation trend will reduce
uncertainty for businesses and consumers, and
make the economy more conducive for employment growth.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

6

Inflation and Prices

A Few Bad Apples Spoil June’s Price Statistics
07.20.11
by Brent Meyer

June Price Statistics
Percent change, last
1mo.a

3mo.a

6mo.a

12mo.

5yr.a

2010
average

Consumer Price Index
All items

-2.6

1.5

3.8

3.6

2.2

1.4

Less food and energy

3.1

2.9

2.5

1.6

1.8

0.6

Medianb

1.7

2.2

2.1

1.6

2.1

0.7

1.2

2.4

2.8

2.0

2.1

0.8

1.0

1.5

1.8

1.4

2.0

0.9

-11.4

1.0

8.7

8.6

2.5

3.5

16% trimmed

meanb

Sticky pricec
Flexible pricec

a. Annualized.
b. Calculated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
c. Author’s calculations.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Until recently, the debate between the “inflation
is too high” crowd and the “subdued” inflation
adherents had centered on the use of headline and
core measures of inflation. Core measures exclude
food and energy prices, and energy prices had been
rising sharply through the first four months of the
year, pushing up the headline growth rate relative
to the core. In June, however, energy prices reversed
course, food prices posted modest gains, and the
core CPI jumped up markedly, perhaps causing
angst to some debaters. Fortunately at inflection
points like these, we have a few alternative price
change indicators that may shed some light on the
underlying inflation trend.
The headline CPI fell at an annualized rate of 2.6
percent in June, due largely to a sizeable decline
in gasoline prices, though declines in household
energy prices helped as well. Food prices rose 2.4
percent in June, the smallest monthly increase in
the series so far this year. But the unexpected (and
perhaps somewhat worrisome) aspect of the recently released figures was that the core CPI (the CPI
excluding food and energy prices) jumped up 3.1
percent, and has now risen at an annualized rate of
2.9 percent over the past three months. This is an
entirely different signal (and more than 1.0 percentage point higher) than that of the median CPI
(which increased just 1.7 percent in June, a slight
deceleration from its 3- and 6-month growth rates).
This raises the question: What gives?
Well, it appears that the core CPI was affected by a
few usually large price increases in June. These “bad
apples” were lodging away from home, auto prices,
and apparel prices. The index for lodging away
from home followed up a 40 percent spike up in
May (its largest price increase since October 2005)
by increasing 42.6 percent in June. Car and truck
rental, a particularly noisy series, rose 51 percent
in June, more than rebounding from a 42 percent
decrease in May. New vehicle prices, which jumped
up 14 percent in May, rose 7.5 percent in

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

7

June and have risen 8.3 percent over the past six
months. That compares to a growth rate of -0.5
percent over the prior six months. Also, used car
prices jumped up 22 percent during the month, the
largest monthly increase in the series since December 2009. Finally, apparel prices jumped up 18.3
percent in June (their largest monthly increase since
mid-1990), in part because the seasonally adjusted
index for men’s apparel posted its largest onemonth jump up in the history of the series (which
dates back to 1947), rising 35.4 percent.

CPI Component Price Change Distribution
Annualized percentage change, June 2011
Car and truck rental
Lodging away from home
Men's and boys' apparel
Used cars and trucks
Women's and girls' apparel
Jewelry and watches
Motor vehicle parts and equipment
Leased cars and trucks
Infants' and toddlers' apparel
New vehicles
Cereals and bakery products
Other food at home
Dairy and related products
Personal care products
Water, sewer, & trash collection
Footwear
Tobacco and smoking products
Nonalcoholic beverages and bev. Materials
Tenants' and household insurance
Medical care services
Education
Food away from home
OER, West Urban Region
Miscellaneous personal services
Motor vehicle insurance
OER, Northeast Urban Region
Processed fruits and vegetables
OER, South Urban Region
Rent of primary residence
Alcoholic beverages
Motor vehicle maintenance and repair
Personal care services
OER, Midwest Urban Region
Motor vehicle fees
Household furnishings and operations
Recreation
Communication
Meats, poultry, fish, and eggs
Fresh fruits and vegetables
Miscellaneous personal goods
Gas (piped) and electricity
Fuel oil and other fuels
Public transportation
Motor fuel

-30 -20 -10

Median price change = 1.7%

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

A few relative price changes of such a large magnitude most likely indicate idiosyncratic shocks,
mismeasurement, or issues with the seasonal factors. Importantly, these relatively large price changes tend to impart noise into the underlying inflation measure and are not useful indicators of future
inflation. Indeed, one might suspect that the recent
increases in new auto prices are due to temporary
supply chain disruptions. Used auto prices could
have been buoyed by a dearth in supply stemming
from a prolonged period of dampened production during the recession and the government’s
CARS program. The increase in apparel prices may
reflect pass-through from earlier cotton price and
other commodity price increases. If these rationales
happen to be the root causes of these relative price
increases, we could simply exclude these categories
in June in an attempt to uncover underlying inflation. However, we don’t know this for certain, and
excluding the components on an ad hoc basis could
easily yield a poor signal of future inflation.
Fortunately, trimmed-mean measures—such as
the median CPI and the 16 percent trimmedmean CPI—remove sources of noise in a way that
does not rely on judgment and story-telling on a
monthly basis. These measures trim the largest absolute relative price changes from the price statistic,
lessening the amount of noise in the index. The
only judgment involved, apart from how much to
trim, is the decision to assume that large monthly
price swings in either direction do not reflect the
underlying inflation trend. (These measures say
nothing about which component will impart the
noise, unlike the core, which always excludes food
and energy categories).

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; author’s calculations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

8

Perhaps adding credibility to the price signal stemming from the median and trimmed-mean measures, the sticky price CPI—which is a composite
measure of prices in the consumers’ market basket
that change infrequently—rose just 1.0 percent
during the month, marking a slight deceleration
from its three-month growth rate (1.5 percent).
Meanwhile, the three-month growth rate in the
core CPI has continued to climb in recent months.

Core CPI Versus Sticky CPI
3-month annualized percent change
7
6
5

Core CPI

Sticky CPI

4
3
2
1
0
-1
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Sources: U.S. Department of Labor; Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.

Sticky CPI Versus Core Flexible CPI

Interestingly, the upward impulse in the core CPI
over the past few months appears to be flexible in
nature and, according to Bryan and Meyer (2010),
that suggests it has very little useful information on
future inflation. The core flexible CPI—composed
of items in the core CPI that change price frequently—has jumped up 11.6 percent over the past three
months (the swiftest growth rate in the series since
the early 1980s).

3-month annualized percent change
20
15
Core Flexible CPI

10
5

Sticky CPI

0
-5
-10
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010
Sources: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Incidentally, June’s “bad apples” (lodging away
from home, autos, and apparel) all happen to be
flexible-price goods, which as a set, do not appear
to be a useful predictor of future inflation. Also,
these “bad apples” almost exclusively comprised the
upper tail of the price-change distribution, and, as
outliers, were trimmed out of the median CPI and
the 16 percent trimmed-mean CPI for the most
part. Together, these observations suggest that the
snapback in core CPI over the past three months
has likely been driven in part by noisy relative price
movements, which are biasing up its signal on the
underlying inflation trend.

9

Regional Economics

The Fourth District: The Next Big Energy Producer?
08.04.11
by Robert J. Sadowski and Margaret Jacobson
When asked about domestic oil and natural gas
production and where most of it occurs, people
will likely reply: the region surrounding the Gulf
of Mexico. This response is correct. In fact, over
the past decade, two-thirds of active drilling rigs in
the United States were found in the states of Texas,
Louisiana, and Oklahoma, Texas being the frontrunner by a wide margin.

Active Drilling Rigs in the United States
Number of rigs
2000
1800

Total U.S.

1600
1400
1200
1000
800

Total TX, OK, LA

600
400
200

Total OH, PA, WV
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Source: Baker Hughes North America Rotary Rig Count.

Active Drilling Rigs in the Fourth District
Number of rigs
120
100
80
Pennsylvania
60
40
West Virginia
20
0

Ohio

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011
Source: Baker Hughes North America Rotary Rig Count.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Historically, states in the Fourth District have also
played an important role in oil and natural gas
production. Crawford County, in the northwest
corner of Pennsylvania, was the birthplace of the
modern oil industry in 1859, and the surrounding
region remained a major producer for the next 80
years. As the twentieth century dawned, Ohio was
considered the “Middle East” of the oil- and gasproducing world. At its peak in 1896, Ohio produced 24 million barrels of oil, or 39 percent of the
U.S. output during that year. To put these numbers
into some perspective, the United States currently
(2010) consumes 19.1 million barrels per day of
refined petroleum product, according to the U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA).
The Fourth District is now positioned to make a
comeback as a major domestic energy producer due
to exploration and production in the Marcellus and
Utica shales. The Marcellus shale is a rock formation that underlies much of Pennsylvania and West
Virginia and portions of New York and Ohio at a
depth of 3,000 to 7,000 feet. Pennsylvania State
University geoscientist Dr. Terry Engelder estimates
that there are between 360 trillion and 450 trillion
cubic feet of recoverable gas in the Marcellus shale,
enough to supply all of the U.S.’s natural gas needs
for almost 20 years at the current rate of usage.
Likewise, the energy consulting firm, INTEK, Inc.,
came up with a similar figure when it was hired
by the EIA to provide estimates of undeveloped
technically recoverable shale gas (natural gas that
is trapped within shale formations) in the lower 48
states. The firm estimated the potential output of
10

the Marcellus shale to be 410.7 trillion cubic feet,
making it the largest shale gas play in the United
States. The next largest are Haynesville at 74.7 trillion cubic feet and the Barnett at 43.4 trillion cubic
feet. Haynesville is located in northwest Louisiana
and east Texas, while the Barnett is found around
Fort Worth, Texas. Not only is the Marcellus big,
but shale gas is expected to constitute 45 percent of
the total U.S. natural gas supply by 2035, up from
14 percent in 2009, according to EIA estimates
(Annual Energy Outlook, 2011).

Number of Shale Gas Wells: West Virginia
1400
1200
1000
800
600
400
200
0
2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Source: West Virginia Office of Oil and Gas.

Shale Gas Production: Pennsylvania
Billions of cubic feet
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Source: Pennsylvania Department of Environmental Protection.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

At this time, a substantial share of the Marcellus drilling and production is concentrated in the
state of Pennsylvania, mainly the southwest corner
and the north central region. Additional activity is
found along the central to western regions of West
Virginia. Activity in Ohio is limited due to the
thinning out of the Marcellus as it enters the state.
As of June 2011, there were only 30 Marcellus
producing wells in Ohio. Shale gas production has
increased exponentially in Pennsylvania during the
past few years, with output in 2010 estimated at
327 billion cubic feet. While that may seem like a
sizeable amount, it is a tiny share of the total natural gas consumed in the United States on an annual
basis. In fact, 327 billion cubic feet accounts for
only 6.5 percent of residential usage during 2010.
Nonetheless, the rate of growth in the extraction of
gas from the Marcellus closely tracks early production results from the Barnett shale, which started in
the late 1990s and by 2010 approached 2 trillion
cubic feet.
Geologists have known about the existence of shale
gas for decades. However, the technology to extract
natural gas on a large scale from shale rock located
a mile or more below the surface, and at an economically viable cost, has only been in existence for
the past dozen years. The base technology, hydraulic fracturing or “fracking,” has been in use since
the 1940s. It involves the injection of a mixture of
water, sand, and chemicals under high pressure into
a well. The refinement of this technology augmented by the use of extended reach (horizontal) drilling gave impetus to the shale gas industry boom.
Horizontal drilling is attractive because the production factor is 15 to 20 times that of a conventional
vertical well, although the initial cost may be three
11

times greater. During 2010, horizontal drilling was
used in just over half of the Marcellus production
wells in Pennsylvania. Yet those wells accounted
for almost 90 percent of the gas produced. Oil
is also extracted from Marcellus shale. However,
the amount on a yearly basis is minimal, typically
no more than a half-million barrels from all the
producing wells in Pennsylvania and West Virginia
combined.

Shale Gas Production: West Virginia
Billions of cubic feet
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

Source: West Virginia Office of Oil and Gas.

Utica shale is a rock formation generally located a
few thousand feet below the Marcellus. It is concentrated in New York, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and
West Virginia, although Utica extends into four
adjacent states. It also lies beneath parts of Lake
Erie, Lake Ontario, and Ontario. Geologists believe
that Utica shale has the potential to become an
enormous natural gas and oil resource. However,
because of differences in mineralogy between the
Marcellus and Utica shales, hydraulic fracturing
methods used in the Marcellus might not produce
as much fracturing in the Utica, and more research
is needed to significantly improve the fracturing
rate.
Eastern Ohio is currently the center of Utica activity in the Fourth District, primarily because the
shale is less than a mile below the surface. Also, the
productive portion of the Marcellus extends for
only a relatively short distance into the state, making Utica a more attractive play. Data provided by
the Ohio Department of Natural Resources indicate that 43 permits for Utica drilling have been
issued, almost all within the past 12 months. As of
June 2011, 16 wells have been drilled and four have
been fractured. No production data are available.
Investment in exploration and production of the
Marcellus shale continues to grow. A study conducted by Pennsylvania State University researchers
shows that investment spending by the private sector in Marcellus exploration and production in the
state of Pennsylvania grew from an estimated $3.2
billion in 2008 to over $11 billion during 2011.
Data made available by the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides insight into the direct employment
impact. Between 2001 and 2010, employment in
the oil and gas industry across Ohio, Pennsylvania, and West Virginia rose by almost 68 percent.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

12

Fourth District Oil and Gas Employment
Number of employees
30000
25000

Total WV
Total OH
Total PA

20000
15000
10000
5000
0
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Growth in Pennsylvania was the highest, with
payrolls rising by about 10,000, or 166 percent.
Half of this growth was realized between 2009 and
2010, with an estimated employment rise in the oil
and gas industry of just over 5,000 workers. During
that same 12-month period, the net growth in total
employment across Pennsylvania was 2,300 workers.
A possible impediment to continuing investment
in the shale gas industry is the concern about
contamination of drinking water from chemicals
used in the fracking process. The state assembly in
New York passed a bill in June 2011 that creates a
one-year moratorium on hydraulic fracturing, both
vertical and horizontal, across the state because of
environmental concerns. This is the second consecutive year that a moratorium has been in place.
Pennsylvania and Wyoming already require drilling
companies to publicly disclose the chemicals they
use and how they dispose of them. Texas recently
passed a similar law. As investment in shale gas continues to grow, so does a regulatory environment
that balances the concerns of residents living near
drilling sites with the need for energy production.

13

Regional Economics

Recent Population Trends in the Midwest
08.09.11
by Daniel Hartley and Kyle Fee

Chicago Population Density
1950

People per square mile
1–1,000

2010

The release of the latest Census data reveals that
Cleveland’s population has fallen since the last
census and dipped below the 400,000 mark. From
2000 to 2010, the city’s population fell from
around 478,000 to about 397,000 (a 17.1 percent
drop). Cleveland’s recent loss of population is not
uncommon for cities in the Great Lakes region.
Even the largest city in the region, Chicago, has
shrunk over the past 10 years. Chicago’s population
fell to about 2.7 million in the latest census, a 6.9
percent drop from 2000. Interestingly, both cities
experienced their peak population in 1950. Since
then, Cleveland has lost over half of its population,
while Chicago has lost slightly more than a quarter.
Things look a bit different when we expand beyond
the city boundaries to the Metropolitan Statistical
Area (MSA) or the Combined Metropolitan Statistical Area (CSA). While the five counties that make
up Cleveland’s MSA decreased in population by 3.3
percent, the eight counties that make up Chicago’s
MSA grew by 4.0 percent. Similarly, the eight
counties in Cleveland’s CSA shrank by 2.2 percent
while the 14 counties in Chicago’s CSA grew by 4.0
percent.

1,001–4,000
4,001–7,000
7,001–15,000
Greater than 15,000

Note: 1950 data was only available for the segments of the MSA.
Source: Census Bureau, National Historical Geographic Information System.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

A different way to analyze the recent population
data would be to convert it into density figures.
Looking at population density allows one to examine the concentration of people in a given area. In
general, denser areas have the potential to support
a greater amount of economic activity than more
diffuse ones. Mapping population density allows
one to compare the spatial distribution of population over time, and sheds some light on population
movement within a region.
From 1950 to 2010 the city of Cleveland’s population density fell from about 11,800 people per
square mile to 5,100 people per square mile. Over
the same period, the city of Chicago’s population
density fell from 15,900 people per square mile to
11,900 people per square mile.
14

Cleveland Population Density
1950

Chicago’s population has pushed outward since
1950, and much more of the surrounding area is
now covered by low-density suburban development. At the same time, the north side of Chicago
has remained densely populated, while parts of the
south and west sides are a bit less densely populated
now than they were in 1950. The other noteworthy
change is that some parts of the downtown area,
which had very light population density in 1950,
are now densely populated.
Cleveland was similar to Chicago in 1950, in that
population density exceeded 15,000 people per
square mile across much of the city. But by 2010
almost nowhere in Cleveland or its MSA was the
population that dense. Like Chicago, Cleveland has
seen its population disburse into the surrounding
suburbs over the last 60 years. However, Cleveland
was unable to retain high levels of density in the
central city.

2010

People per square mile
1–1,000

The Cleveland pattern looks similar to Detroit’s and
Toledo’s. All three have lost the population density in the core that they used to have in 1950. In
contrast, some cities such as San Francisco are still
about as dense as they were in 1950. Philadelphia
and Chicago also have mostly kept the density that
they had in 1950 and added other dense area in the
suburbs. Other cities like Columbus and Pittsburgh
are middle cases: They still have some core density,
but not as much as they had in 1950.

1,001–4,000
4,001–7,000
7,001–15,000
Greater than 15,000
Note: 1950 data was only available for the segments of the MSA.
Source: Census Bureau, National Historical Geographic Information System.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Moving forward, the big question for Cleveland is
to what degree population loss at its core is a cause
or consequence of its overall population loss. Is an
empty middle just a manifestation of population
loss or is it a contributing factor?

15

Banking and Financial Markets

Global Banking System Exposure to the Greek Sovereign Debt Crisis
08.04.11
by Ben Craig and Matthew Koepke

Country Banking System Exposure to Greece
by Sector
Dollars in billions
160
Public sector
Banking sector
Non-bank private sector

140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
European
banks

France

Germany

U.K.

U.S.

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

In the past year, the Greek sovereign debt crisis has
been the focus of much financial press. According to the Bank for International Settlements, 24
countries reported that their banking systems had
foreign claims on Greek debt as of December 2010,
representing a total debt exposure of $145.8 billion
and additional exposures of $60.7 billion related to
derivative contracts, guarantees, and credit commitments. Moreover, the total risk exposure is highly
concentrated in the European banking system,
representing nearly 94.0 percent of the total foreign
claims on Greek debt. Given the European banking
system’s level of exposure to Greek debt, it is little
wonder that European leaders have moved quickly
to mitigate the risk of a potential Greek default.
In order to reduce the systemic risk related to a potential Greek default, the European Union agreed
to support a new program that would provide €109
billion to Greece to fully cover its financing gap.
The program will provide the financing through
loans that will be issued by the European Financial
Stability Fund. The loans will have longer maturities (increased from 7.5 years to a minimum of 15
years) and lower interest rates at levels equivalent to
the balance of payments facility (currently around
3.5 percent).
Additionally, the program will include voluntary
private sector involvement, where private creditors
can exchange their current Greek debt for new debt
securities that are fully collateralized or partly collateralized and are priced to produce a 21.0 percent
net present loss to the value of the current debt
(assuming a 9.0 percent discount rate). Assuming a
90.0 percent participation rate from private investors, the Institute of International Finance (IIF)
expects that private investors will contribute €135.0
billion in financing to Greece from mid-2011 till
the end of 2020. Additionally, the IIF expects voluntary private sector involvement to significantly
improve the maturity profile of Greek debt, increasing it from 6 years to 11. The implications of the

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

16

Greek Real GDP Growth and Public Sector
Debt as a Percentage of GDP
Percentage

Multiple

5

3

2.00
Greek public sector
debt as a multiple
of GDP

Greek real GDP growth

1.75
1.50

0

1.25
1.00

-3
0.75
-5

0.50
2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

Source: International Monetary Fund.

German and Greek Debt Default Expectations
Basis points per year
3,000
2,500

Greek 5-year credit
default swaps

new financing program are that private creditors are
now certain to sustain losses, and credit agencies
are likely to view the exchange of debt at a loss as a
default. Upon review of the new program, Moody’s
investor service downgraded Greek sovereign debt
from Caa1 to Ca to reflect the potential default
event.
Given its high debt-to-real GDP ratio and slow
GDP growth, Greece was unlikely to be able to
achieve healthy levels of debt without defaulting. A
recent report by the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) projected that Greece’s public debt would
peak from its current level of 143 percent of GDP
to 172 percent of GDP in 2012 and remain above
130 percent through 2020. In its assumptions, the
IMF assumed that Greece would be successful in
fully implementing its fiscal adjustment plan and
the transfer of government assets to the private sector. Consequently, any deviation would have significant implications in the reduction of Greece’s debt
going forward. The IMF estimated that if Greece is
unsuccessful in implementing its fiscal program or
if it fails to fully realize its planned privatizations,
debt could remain at unsustainable levels at around
150 percent of GDP through 2020. Additionally,
the IMF lowered its projections for Greek real GDP
growth going forward, forecasting a decline of 3.8
percent in 2011, an improvement to 0.6 percent in
2012, and eventually a leveling off to 3.0 percent
in 2017. The high levels of existing debt and slow
real GDP growth suggest that some form of default
is likely the only option for Greece, and additional
future defaults are very possible.

2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0
2006

German 5-year credit
default swaps
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Source: Bloomberg.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

A close examination of Greek credit default swaps
shows that while investors have lowered their
expectations of a Greek default, they still believe
that the probability of a default remains very high.
Since the announcement of the new financing plan,
credit default swaps on Greek sovereign debt have
fallen nearly 400 basis points. Credit default swaps
are credit derivatives that function as an insurance
policy that a creditor can purchase to hedge the risk
associated with a borrower defaulting. The seller
of the credit default swap would pay the difference
between the original face value of the bond and the
recovery value in the instance that the borrower
fails to make a scheduled payment; however, the
17

U.S. Bank Exposure by Region
Dollars in billions
3,500

Public sector
Banking sector
Non-bank private sector

3,000
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0
All Countries

Europe1

Asia Pacific2

Americas3

1.

Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherland, Norway,
Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom.
2.
China, Chinese Taipei, Hong Kong, India, Japan, New Zealand, Singapore.
3.
Brazil, Canada, Cayman Islands, Mexico.
Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

seller would not have to pay if a creditor voluntarily
trades his current bonds in for new bonds valued at
a discount, as is the case in the new Greek financing plan.
Currently, five-year Greek sovereign debt is trading
at 1,635 basis points per year (the spread represents
the premium the purchaser pays for the insurance
policy). Comparatively, it only costs 62.2 basis
points per year to insure $10 million in five-year
German sovereign debt. Thus, despite the new
financing plan proposed, investors still believe that
there is a very high probability that Greece may
default on its debt.
The direct effects of a Greek default would initially
be concentrated within the European banking
system. As of December 2010, the U.S. banking
system’s total risk exposure to Greece is only $7.3
billion, with other potential exposures related to
derivative contracts, guarantees, and credit commitments summing to $34.1 billion (compared to
the total risk exposure to Greece of $136.3 billion
for European banks). However, given that Europe
represents nearly 50.0 percent of the U.S. banking
system’s total risk exposure, any credit event that
significantly affects the European economy will
likely adversely affect the U.S. banking system as
well.

18

Banking and Financial Markets

Has the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market Revived Yet?
08.11.11
by Jian Cai
Derivatives are financial instruments whose values
depend on the values of other assets such as stocks,
bonds, and commodities. Firms, banks, and investors can use derivatives to hedge various kinds of
risks. However, derivatives can also be used for
speculation, and consequently they can magnify
the degree of risk-taking that market participants
engage in. Trading in derivatives reached tremendous levels before the recent financial crisis, and
that burst of activity received a great deal of criticism later, reflecting perceptions that risk-taking by
financial institutions was excessive and that derivatives helped to elevate considerably the severity of
the crisis.

Global Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
800
700
600
500

Foreign exchange
Interest rate
Equity
Commodities
CDs
Other

400
300
200
100
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03 6/04 6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10
12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

There are two major types of derivatives markets:
exchange-traded and over-the-counter (OTC). In
contrast to the heavily regulated exchange-traded
market, the OTC market is bound by little regulation and offers customized derivative products.
Those features enable it to provide greater flexibility
in terms of meeting individual investors’ hedging
and speculation needs. As a result, the OTC market
is much larger than the exchange-traded market.
For example, as of December 2010, the notional
amount outstanding (the gross nominal value of all
deals) in the entire OTC market, excluding commodity contracts, was $598 trillion, nearly nine
times the amount outstanding in the exchangetraded market ($68 trillion).
A look at recent trends in the global OTC derivatives market reveals that the market has stayed
generally flat since trading volume fell significantly
at the peak of the financial crisis. Although foreign
currency derivative contracts have started to increase, and interest rate contracts have recovered to
pre-crisis levels, trading in equity and commodity
derivatives and credit default swaps continues to
stay low and, in some cases, it has further declined.
Prior to the financial crisis, the global OTC derivatives market grew strongly and persistently. Over

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

19

Global Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market:
Gross Market Value
Trillions of U.S. dollars
40
Foreign exchange
Interest rate
Equity
Commodities
CDs
Other

35
30
25
20
15

the ten-year period from June 1998 to June 2008,
the market’s compounded annual growth rate was
25 percent. The total notional amount outstanding
reached its peak of $673 trillion in June 2008, but
just six months later it had fallen to below $600
trillion in the wake of the financial crisis. Since
then, the market has stayed about 10 percent-13
percent smaller than it was at its peak. In December
2010, the total notional amount outstanding was
$601 trillion.

10
5
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03 6/04 6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10
12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Foreign Exchange Contracts:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
70
60
50

Forwards and foreign exchange swaps
Currency swaps
Options

40
30
20
10
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03

6/04 6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10

12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Interest Rate Contracts:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
500
450
400

FRAs
Swaps
Options

350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03

6/04 6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10

12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

While the notional amount outstanding measures
the size of the derivatives market, the gross market
value provides an estimation of market risk, that
is, the potential for gains or losses from derivative
transactions. Gross market value had an upward
trend over time until 2008: It stayed around $2
trillion-$3 trillion during 1998-2001, increased
to $6 trillion-$7 trillion during 2002-2003, grew
to around $10 trillion during 2004-2006, reached
$16 trillion in 2007, and finally rose to $35 trillion at the end of 2008. As the derivatives market
experienced its first and biggest drop in size in December 2008, the risk level ironically increased to
its historical high, which indicated how vulnerable
and dangerous the market was then. By December
2010, the gross market value came down to $21
trillion, 40 percent lower compared to two years
before. Yet, as a risk measure, it still seems quite
volatile, ranging from $21 trillion to $25 trillion
during the past two years.
There are six main categories of derivatives: foreign
exchange, interest rate, equity, commodity, credit
default swap, and other.
Foreign exchange contracts have the second-highest
notional deal value among all types of derivative
products. As of June 2008, they accounted for
9.4 percent of the entire derivatives market, with
a notional amount outstanding of $63 trillion.
Derivative trading in this category was down by 21
percent in December 2008. It stayed at that level
in 2009 but started to recover in 2010. Its notional
amount outstanding got back to $58 trillion in
December 2010, which accounted for 9.6 percent
of the derivatives market at that time. The recovery
was mainly driven by an 18 percent increase in

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

20

currency swaps, whereas the decline was the greatest
in currency options (31 percent).

Equity-Linked Contracts:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
12
Forwards and swaps
Options

10
8
6
4
2
0

6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03 6/04

6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10

12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Commodity Contracts:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
14
12

Gold
Other commodities

10
8
6
4
2
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03 6/04

6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10

12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Interest rate contracts have the highest deal value,
accounting for 68.1 percent of the derivatives
market in June 2008, with a notional amount outstanding of $458 trillion. Trading in this category
did not suffer as much as other categories, as it was
down by only 4 percent-6 percent during the crisis.
It reached $465 trillion in December 2010, even
1.5 percent higher compared to June 2008, and
accounted for 77.4 percent of the entire derivatives
market. An increase of 31 percent in forward rate
agreements—contracts which lock in borrowing
rates at a future time—is the main reason that this
part of derivatives market has stayed strong. However, interest rate options experienced a 21 percent
decline at the same time.
Although equity-linked contracts are one of the
most commonly known types of derivatives, they
account for only a tiny portion of the total derivatives market in terms of notional deal value. For
example, in June 2008 the notional deal value was
$10 trillion, which represented just 1.5 percent of
the total market. After a 45 percent drop in the
notional amount outstanding, the share of equity
contracts further decreased to 0.9 percent ($5.6
trillion) in December 2010. All types of contracts
on equity declined significantly: Options declined
49 percent and forward and futures declined 31
percent during this period.
Commodity derivatives are probably the category
that experienced the most dramatic changes both
prior to and after the crisis. The compounded annual growth rate of this type of derivative was 40
percent during the 10-year period from June 1998
to June 2008, or 65 percent during the three-year
period from June 2005 to June 2008. Its notional
amount outstanding was highest in June 2008
at $13 trillion, but it dropped by two-thirds six
months later to $4.4 trillion. Since then, trading
volume in commodities has continued to decline.
In December 2010, the notional amount outstanding of commodity contracts was $2.9 trillion,
accounting for only 0.5 percent of the total derivatives market. The notional value of gold contracts
declined by nearly 40 percent during this period,
21

Credit Default Swaps:
Notional Amounts Outstanding
Trillions of U.S. dollars
70
60

Single name
Multi-name

50
40
30
20
10
0
6/98 6/99 6/00 6/01 6/02 6/03 6/04

6/05 6/06 6/07 6/08 6/09 6/10

12/98 12/99 12/00 12/01 12/02 12/03 12/04 12/05 12/06 12/07 12/08 12/09 12/10

Source: Bank for International Settlements.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

whereas the drop in nongold commodity contracts
was a more drastic 80 percent.
Intended to help financial institutions better manage counterparty risk, the credit default swap is a
relatively recent innovation in the derivatives market. After its trading statistics started to be released
in December 2004, its notional amount outstanding increased eight times and reached $58 trillion
within three years. However, it dropped to $42 trillion in December 2008 and continued to decline
during the next two years. In December 2010, the
notional value of credit default swaps was slightly
below $30 trillion, accounting for 5 percent of the
total derivatives market. Both single-name and
multi-name instruments in this category decreased
by about half.

22

International Markets

The Net International Investment Position
08.04.11
by Owen F. Humpage and Margaret Jacobson

U.S. and Foreign Claims
Trillions of U.S. dollars
25

20
Foreign claims on U.S.

15

10

5
U.S. claims on foreigners

0
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Net International Investment Position
Percent of GDP

Trillions of U.S. dollars
1.0

15

0.5

10

0.0

5

-0.5

0

-1.0
-5
-1.5
-10

-2.0
-2.5

-15

-3.0

-20

-3.5

-25
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

The Importance of Valuation Effects
Trillions of U.S. dollars
0
-1
-2
-3
-4
-5
-6
-7
-8

Net international investment position
Cumulative current account

-9
2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

The United States has run a current-account deficit
almost every year since 1982, primarily because
U.S. residents have imported more goods and
services than they have exported. We finance this
deficit by issuing financial claims—such things as
stocks, bonds, and bank accounts—to the rest of
the world. Since 1986, foreigners have held more
claims on the United States than U.S. residents
have held on the rest of the world, leaving the
United States with—in econspeak—a negative net
international investment position. These financial
instruments give foreigners claims on future U.S.
output, so economists often gauge them as a share
of GDP. Last year, our negative net international
investment position equaled 17 percent of GDP,
the same as in 2009 but down from an all-time
peak of nearly 23 percent of GDP in 2008.
The U.S. current-account deficit, which equaled 3
percent of GDP last year, has been narrowing from
its peak of 6 percent of GDP in 2006. This has
helped limit the growth in our negative net international investment position, but the current account
is not the only factor in the mix. Besides the net
issuances of new financial claims, year-to-year adjustments in the international investment position
reflect changes in the valuation of previously issued,
outstanding financial claims.
Valuation changes can result from movements in
the market price of the underlying assets, but in recent years a substantial proportion of the valuation
changes has also resulted from the dollar’s depreciation. The dollar has depreciated since its recent
peak early 2002 by approximately 30 percent on
a trade-weighted basis against a broad array of our
key trading partners. When the dollar depreciates,
a given amount of foreign currency translates into
a greater number of dollars. Because many U.S.
claims on foreigners are denominated in foreign
currencies, dollar depreciations increase the dollar
value of U.S. claims on foreigners. On the other
hand, dollar depreciations do little to affect the
23

dollar value of foreign claims on the United States
because these are typically denominated in dollars.
Absent favorable valuation adjustments, our negative net international investment position would
reflect only our cumulative current-account deficit
and would be substantially larger than it is today.

Net International Income Receipts
Billions of U.S. dollars
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010
Note: Income receipts on U.S. assets abroad less income payments on foreign assets
in the United States.
Source: Haver Analytics.

Foreign Claims on the United States
2010

2000
Official
reserves
14%

Bank
15%

Bank
19%

Nonbank
10%

Direct
investment
19%

Official
reserves
25%

Nonbank
4%

Direct
investment
14%

Treasuries
5%
Other
corporates
30%

Currency
3%

Other
corporates
34%

Currency 2%

Treasuries
6%

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Despite 18 years of near-persistent current-account
deficits and an associated negative net international
investment position, the United States has—surprisingly—continued to receive more income on
assets held abroad than we have paid out on foreign
assets held in the United States. U.S. claims on
foreigners have a higher average return than foreign
claims on the United States.
The dollar value of each type of foreign claim on
the United States has increased over the past decade
along with the total, but the composition of the
overall foreign portfolio has changed as well. Most
notably, the share of foreign official claims on the
United States has increased 12 percentage points,
notably squeezing down the share of direct foreign
investment. Likewise the dollar value of each type
of U.S. claim on foreigners has increased. The
compositional changes are not as dramatic, but the
United States has reduced the share of bank claims
on foreigners and nonbank claims on unaffiliated
foreigners that it holds in its overall portfolio.

U.S. Claims on Foreigners
2000
Official
2%

2010

Other U.S.
government
1%

Bank
20%

Official
3%
Direct
investment
25%

Other U.S.
government
1%

Bank
27%
Direct
investment
27%

Nonbank
13%
Nonbank
5%
Securities
37%
Securities
39%

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

24

Labor Markets, Unemployment, and Wages

Labor Market Remarkably Bad, but not So Unpredictable
08.09.11
by Murat Tasci and Mary Zenker
July’s employment report was welcome news, especially after the slowdowns in payroll growth that
had occurred over the previous two months. The
U.S. economy added 117,000 new jobs, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics report. That
is slightly better than the average monthly gain
of the second quarter (about 105,000), but definitely worse than that of the first quarter (about
165,000). Manufacturing, trade, professional and
Payroll Employment: Average Monthly Changes business services and education and health posted
significant gains in July, as in recent months. GovSeasonally adjusted, thousands
ernment payrolls, on the other hand, kept declin60
ing. July’s decline was 37,000, most of it due to
Education
Manufacturing
and health
40
state and local governments (their payrolls declined
−23,000 and −16,000, respectively). The temporary
20
Finance
help services sector, which is thought of as a leading
Government
0
indicator for future payroll growth, was basically
Trade,
Leisure and
Professional and
transportation, business services
hospitality
Construction
flat.
and utilities
-20
2010
2011:Q1
2011:Q2
July

-40
-60

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Cumulative Decline in Employment:
Beginning of Recession to 43 Months Out
Index
108
2007 recession
1990 recession
2001 recession
Recession average

106
104
102
100

July 2011

98
96
94
92
M0

M5

M10

M15

M20

M25

M30

M35

M40

Notes: X-axis represents months from start of the recession. Recession start level of
payroll employment is normalized to 100. Red line represents the average employment
index progression for post-war recessions, and dotted lines are +/-one standard deviation.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Separately, the household survey showed that the
unemployment rate ticked down 0.1 percentage
point to 9.1, partly due to a decline in the labor
force of 193,000. However, among those who are
unemployed, almost 45 percent have been unemployed more than six months, which is close to
the all-time high reached in the midst of the last
recession. So the news from the labor market is at
best mixed: We do not see an all-out slowdown, but
there are no robust improvements either.
Overall, the labor market has been adjusting very
slowly during this recovery. Six months after the
economy had started growing again, we were still
losing jobs. In other words, employment, as measured through payroll survey, had experienced its
largest decline (more than 6 percent) two years
after the recession started. More troubling still is
the slow pace at which employment is returning to
normal. Three and a half years after the beginning
of the recession, we are still 5 percent below the
prerecession level of employment, almost 6.8 million jobs! This pattern of slow progress in the labor
market was a key feature of the two recoveries that
25

preceded the last one, and they were sometimes
dubbed the “jobless recoveries” on account of it.
The only difference between those two recoveries
and the last one seems to be that this time around
we suffered a much larger decline in employment.

Cumulative Increase in Unemployment Rate:
Beginning of Recession to 43 Months Out
Percentage points
6.0
July 2011

5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0

Recession average

1.0
0.0
-1.0
M0

M5

M10

M15

M20

M25

M30

M35

M40

Notes: X-axis represents months from start of the recession. Red line represents
the average unemployment rate progression for post-war recessions, and dotted
lines are +/-one standard deviation.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Employment decline (percent)
First
revision

6

Original
GDP

Current

5
1957-58

1948-49

4

1953-54

3

1981-82
2001

2

1960-61

1973-75

1990-91
1980
1969-1970

1
0
0

1

2

3

4

5

However, there is a hint of good news. Some
perspective about the type of a recession we just experienced might help to see it. When one thinks of
the impact of the recession on the labor market on
its own, one gets a pretty bleak picture. However,
in light of the recent revisions of estimates to gross
domestic product (GDP), the recession’s effects on
the labor market don’t seem to be so far from what
we would expect.
The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) occasionally revises its estimate of GDP to reflect new data
as well as methodological improvements. One such
revision recently showed that U.S GDP, the broadest measure of aggregate economic activity, declined
more than 5 percent between the fourth quarter of
2007 and the second quarter of 2009, making it
the largest ever decline in postwar history. There is
nothing good about this news per se, but the fact
that the recession was actually much worse than
initially thought puts things in a different context.

Real GDP and Employment
7

The unemployment rate does not paint a better
picture. It increased more during the past recession than in any previous recession, and moreover,
since it peaked over the 23 months ago, it has come
down only 1 percentage point. There is always some
persistence in the unemployment rate; that is, the
unemployment rate does not necessarily return to
pre-recession levels even three or four years after the
start of the recession. But the degree of persistence
at these levels is a significant exception by historical
standards.

6

Real GDP decline
Notes: Real GDP percent decline is measured peak to trough (2009:Q2 for
thelast recession). Percent decline in employment is from start of recession
to employment trough measured at quarterly frequency. Employment trough
for the last recession is 2010:Q1.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

Economic theory suggests that bigger contractions in GDP will have bigger impacts on the labor
market; deeper recessions imply large losses in
employment and greater rises in the unemployment
rate. Consider this relationship between the decline
in payroll employment and the decline in measured GDP, from peak to trough. If we had done
this calculation for the last recession sometime in
mid-2009, we would have found that a 3.7 percent
decline in GDP was associated with more than a 5
26

percent decline in payrolls, and that response would
have been somewhat of an outlier. Similarly, a year
later, after one set of downward revisions to GDP,
the last recession might have still looked a bit puzzling—4.1 percent decline in GDP associated with
a 5.9 percent in payroll employment (the cumulative decline by that time). Since then, both the
BLS and BEA have revised their estimates (payroll
employment and GDP estimates). The bad news is
that the overall declines in payroll and GDP, from
their respective peaks to their respective troughs,
are larger. However, in some sense, this makes this
last episode much less puzzling.

Real GDP and Unemployment
Unemployment increase (percentage points)
6.0

First
Original
revision Current
GDP

5.0

1973-75
4.0

1953-54
1948-49

3.0
2.0

1969-70
2001

1957-58
1981-82

1990-91
1960-61

1980

1.0
0.0
0

1

2

3

4

5

6

Real GDP decline
Notes: Real GDP percent decline is measured peak to trough (2009:Q2 for the
last recession) around NBER recessions. Rise in unemployment is from start
of recession to unemployment peak measured at quarterly frequency.
Unemployment peak for the last recession is 2009:Q4.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

The unemployment rate’s behavior during this
recovery also looks less mysterious after the GDP
revisions. However, unlike the employment figures,
the unemployment rate was not revised during
this period. So every change we have seen over the
last two years in the relationship between GDP
and unemployment is due to changes in the GDP
estimates. The 5.1 percent increase in the unemployment rate between December 2007 and October 2009 was exceptionally high relative to the first
estimate of the GDP decline. However, as we got a
better handle over time on how bad this recession
really was, it became less of a puzzle.

27

Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted
provided that the source is credited.
If you’d like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Trends | August 2011

28