View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Gold: End of an Era?
. . . Editorial Summary

The Changing Role of Gold in
the International Monetary System
. . . Hang-Sheng Cheng and Nicholas P. Sargen

Gold Policy: The Thirties and The Seventies
. . . Kurt Dew

Gold as a Private Hedge Against Inflation
. . . Michael W. Keran and Michael Penzer

The Business Review is edited by William Burke, with the assistance of
Karen Rusk (editorial) and Janis Wilson (graphics).
Subscribers to the Business Review may also be interested in receiving
this Bank’s Publications List or weekly Business and Financial Letter.
For copies of these and other Federal Reserve publications, contact
the Research Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120. Phone
(415) 397-1137.

2

"Gold is a wonderful clearer of the understanding," wrote Thomas Addison in a 1711 issue of the
Spectator, yet many misconceptions have grown up
around the lustrous metal during the intervening
centuries. In an attempt to clarify the situation as it
stands in the mid-1970's, this special issue of the
Review presents three analytical articles written
against the background of recent far-reaching
changes in U.S. gold policy. Within a brief halfdecade, we have witnessed the creation of the twotier gold market, two devaluations of the dollar, and
now in 1975, the lifting of the longstanding ban on
the private ownership of gold, followed by the auctioning of a small portion of the nation's gold stock.

World War II, because of an asymmetry in its
exchange-rate adjustment mechanism. Any other
country could change a "fundamental disequilibrium" in its balance of payments by altering the
exchange rate of its currency against the U.S.
dollar-but the United States, with its currency
pegged to gold, was poorly situated to change its
exchange rate. This asymmetrical situation was
compounded by a devaluation bias in exchange-rate
adjustments, which permitted surplus countries to
postpone or avoid revaluation, while deficit countries were forced to devalue by their weakening reserve positions. Consequently, when the U.S. allowed its domestic inflation rate to get out of hand in
the late 1960's, the dollar became increasingly
overvalued, and this resulted in massive accumulations of dollars in foreign official holdings, as well
as a decline in the competitive position of American
manufacturers in foreign and domestic markets.

In the first article, Hang-Sheng Cheng and
Nicholas P. Sargen place these recent events in historical perspective, before analyzing the reasons
for the U.S. Government's decision to end the
monetary role of gold. They consider several traditional arguments advanced by advocates of
gold-for example, the need for the "discipline" of
the gold standard to set prescribed automatic limits
to the power of the nation's monetary authorities.
But they note that the world economy in the heyday
of the gold standard did not benefit from such discipline, but instead was characterized by wide fluctuations in both output and prices. Again, gold supposedly has provided a safer asset than national
currencies-but in their view, this argument puts
the cart before the horse. It was the official support
of the price of gold that sustained its value, and not
the reverse.

In the meantime, Special Drawing Rights
(SDRs) developed as a major new reserve asset,
providing a superior alternative to gold. Unlike
gold, they earn interest, cost nothing to produce and
store, and provide means for an internationally controlled growth of world liquidity.
Looking toward the future, Cheng and Sargen
note the existence of 1.2 billion ounces of gold in
official holdings-and perhaps 2.5 billion ounces in
private holdings-and they ask what may happen to
these stocks in the wake of the U. S. decision to
demonetize gold. Their conclusion is that the prospects for a resurrection of gold are rather dim. Unless a new" gold-center country" emerges to buy
and sell gold at some official price, gold may join
silver as just another historical relic. They even

In accounting for the recent shift in U.S. policy,
Cheng and Sargen point to an element of instability
in the Bretton Woods gold-dollar standard after

3

suggest the possibility of governments selling off
their stocks. In that event, an international agreement might be necessary to maintain the value of
official gold holdings, in order to preserve the value
of national savings already embodied in such assets.

tor would have profited considerably if he had
bought in 1968 and sold in 1975, but he would have
lost half of his purchasing power if he had instead
bought in 1934 and sold in 1968. Next they examine
the possible return on alternative investments, such
as other commodities, foreign currencies and
interest-bearing financial assets. These investments
at times have provided better returns than
gold-and without the accompanying problems,
such as the illiquidity of gold investment and the
large variance of gold prices.

In the second article, Kurt Dew contrasts the
1968-75 shift in U.S. gold policy with the policy of
the 1930's, when the Administration prohibited
private gold holdings and tried to push up gold
prices as a means of supporting farm prices. He asks
several questions about these quite dissimilar
episodes: Did the policies achieve their intended
results? Did external actions offset the intended beneficial effects? Did gold help in either case to advance the nation's economic welfare?

Keran and Penzer then evaluate gold's future in
terms of the supply and demand factors that have led
to the sharp price upsurge of the 1970' s. On the
supply side, they note the 20-percent decline in flow
that occurred in the past four years, largely because
of the production problems of the dominant producer, South Africa-but they contend that recent
peak prices should lead to production increases in
the longer run. Also, they argue that downward
price pressures could arise from the massive stocks
over-hanging the market; central-bank holdings
alone are more than 25 times larger than current
production.

Dew argues that the policy of the 1930's achieved
its intended effect, but that it was a Pyrrhic victory,
in view of the severe problems caused in the European gold-bloc countries by the vast outflow of gold
to the United States. A fundamental policy flaw in
that period was the tendency of both this country
and the gold-bloc nations to follow gold policies
rather than expansionary monetary policies.
Turning to the current situation, Dew says that
U.S. policy has achieved its intended effect by relegating gold to the same status as that of any other
commodity. He considers several factors that could
offset the benefits of this policy, but argues that
each of these possibilities is rather remote. For example, small individual investors and large institutional investors could both create problems for the
economy by switching their assets into gold, but
they are not likely to have much incentive to do so.
Also, foreign and domestic financial authorities
will probably not repeat the perverse policy errors
of the 1930's, but will instead continue on their
present path of monetary cooperation.

On the demand side, Keran and Penzer note the
existence of a flow demand for industrial, commercial and artistic purposes, as well as a stock demand
for inventory building by central banks and private
investors and speculators. Flow demand could decline because of the recession and because of the
very high price of gold. Stock demand could
weaken on the part of central banks, reflecting the
continued efforts to demonetize gold, and it could
also weaken for investors and speculators, to the
extent that inflationary expectations are somehow
kept in check. Thus, they conclude: caveat emptor.
Despite gold's excellent record as an investment in
the last several years, the remainder of the decade
will inevitably bring changes in the supply and demand factors governing the price of gold-changes
which could easily shift the price trend downward.

In the third article, Michael W. Keran and
Michael Penzer examine the role of gold as a private hedge against inflation. They note that the timing of gold purchases is crucial; naturally, the inves-

4

By Hang-Sheng Cheng and Nicholas P. Sargen

Without any fanfare, the United States has now
closed a long chapter in its monetary history. On
December 31, 1974, the Government revoked a
41-year ban on U.S. citizens' ownership of gold,
and a week later, on January 6, 1975, it started
auctioning a portion of its gold stock on the open
market. These actions not only signaled the U. S.
Government's decision to end the monetary role of
gold, but also called into question the metal's future role in the world economy. Symbolically, the
auction was conducted not by the U.S. Treasury, a
monetary authority, but rather by the General Services Administration, a housekeeping arm of the
U.S. Government. Thus, in a quiet way the U.S.
Government suggested to the world that henceforth it will handle its gold in the same way it han dies its used office furniture.

gold holdings, from the former official price of
$42.22 per ounce to $170.40 per ounce, in order to
bring the valuation closer to the market price of
gold. It also declared that another revaluation
would be made six months later. The operational
meaning of the French decision was unclear, since
nothing was said about the intended relationship, if
any, between the "valuation price" and future official gold transactions. Since France holds the
world's third largest official gold reserves l and has
long advocated a stronger international role for
gold, its policy will undoubtedly have a very large
influence on the metal's future.
In this atmosphere of controversy and uncertainty, it is essential that the public obtain a clear
understanding of the changing role of gold in the
international monetary system. In the gold market,
perhaps more than in any other market, demand
and supply conditions depend crucially on what
governments do with their huge stock of the
commodity.2 Although predictions are difficult to
make, it is well to remember that there is a long
evolutionary process behind recent government actions, as well as a certain logic that limits and
compels policy decisions.

This historical decision presaging an end to the
monetary role of gold has important implications
for the world at large. As far back as mankind's
memory extends, gold has been associated with
money as a store of value, as a means of payment,
and as a backing for national currencies. Because of
the deep-rooted association of gold with money,
many people will continue to regard gold as a prime
financial asset for a long time into the future. Advocates of gold will question not only the
Government's wisdom in attempting to demonetize
the metal, but even its ability to end unilaterally the
monetary role of gold, either in the international
monetary system or in the minds of the public.

The next section provides an historical perspective on the role of gold in international finance.
The third and fourth sections then consider the
rationale of recent Government actions towards
demonetizing gold, especially in view of the criticism that much of the recent financial disorder, national and international, can be traced to the gradual
abandonment of the gold standard. The final section

Subsequent to the U.S. actions, France announced on January 9 a revaluation of its official

5

explores the future prospects of gold in the international monetary system.

world gold market. In that case, an international
agreement might become necessary to maintain the
value of official gold holdings for preserving national savings already embodied in such assets.
The International Monetary Fund possibly could
function as an ultimate depository of unwanted official gold in exchange for Special Drawing Rights
(SDRs) at some agreed official price. In any event,
some contingency planning might be needed in
order to forestall large-scale dumping of official
gold, which could result in disorderly conditions in
the market to the detriment of the interests of gold
producers, users, and holders alike.

After examining the various options available to
governments, we conclude that the prospects for a
resurrection of gold are rather dim. Unless a new
"gold-center country" emerges to buy and sell
gold at fixed "official" prices-which appears
unlikely-gold will soon join silver as just another
relic of the past. If, as seems likely, the mystique
of gold does begin to fade away, there might be a
scramble of governments to sell off gold but few
buyers for the metal. The market price conceivably
could tumble very sharply in view of the huge official gold stocks relative to the potential size of the

Historical Perspective
The international gold standard, although extinct in practice, continues to survive in the minds
of men today. Intelligent laymen frequently ask,
"If the dollar is not backed by gold, what holds up
its value?" Such misgivings are deeply rooted in
tradition. Historically, the value of money in most
major countries was anchored on gold. For centuries gold coins circulated within those countries
as well as across national boundaries as a generally
accepted means of payment. Throughout the
nineteenth century, especially during the last quarter of the century, monetary authorities were above
all concerned with maintaining the public's confidence in the national currency by insuring its convertibility into gold.

The popular misgivings seem to stem from two
fundamental misconceptions about the relationship
between gold and money. The first suggests, mistakenly, that it was the gold backing of national
currencies that supported their values under the
gold standard. The second misconception ignores
significant changes that have occurred in the international monetary system since the high watermark of the gold standard nearly a century ago.
On the first point, recent studies have indicated
that it was the national currencies that supported
the value of gold, not the other way around. 3
Throughout the nineteenth century, the convertibility of major national currencies into gold provided the necessary support of the value of gold in
terms of those currencies. Whenever the price of
gold threatened to fall below its official support
price, as happened in the case of major gold discoveries or technological breakthroughs in metal
refining, the monetary authorities would buy up all
the gold offered to them. Moreover, at the officially
fixed prices, newly mined gold poured into official
reserves in both the gold-avalanche periods of
1849-72 and 1893-1913 and the leaner years of
1873-92. 4 This suggests that the marketequilibrium price of gold in the absence of official
support would have been consistently below official support prices between 1849 and 1913. A
similar phenomenon occured in the 1930's when
the United States raised its official support price

This mode of official thinking lasted well into
the twentieth century, long after most nations
abandoned the gold standard in the 1930's. Although private citizens could no longer convert
dollars into gold, U.S. monetary authorities continued in the 1960's to speak of the need to "defend the dollar" at its then par value of $35 per
ounce of gold. When that value became indefensible, the dollar was twice devalued, and the action
was officially described each time as a devaluation
in terms of gold: first to $38 per ounce in December 1971 and then to $42.22 per ounce in February 1973. It is thus small wonder that the general
public should continue to view the dollar's value in
terms of gold.

6

from $20.67 to $35 per ounce, thereby setting off a
gigantic flood of gold into its monetary reserves.

after another, went off gold. Rising economic
nationalism and the huge dislocations of the Great
Depression completely destroyed any chance of
success for the interwar restoration of the gold
standard. On the other hand, the restoration of that
standard at inappropriate par values of national
currencies contributed significantly to the
economic instability of the 1920' s, and the failure
of the "gold-bloc" nations to go off gold until
1936 retarded economic recovery in the 1930's. 8

The national monetary authorities supported the
value of gold throughout this period because gold
then played a key role in the international monetary system. Over the last one hundred years, however, that role has gradually diminished. Instead of
saying that the U.S. dollar is no longer backed by
gold, we should say that gold is no longer supported by the U.S. dollar.

The post-World War II international monetary
system, as set forth in the Articles of Agreement of
the International Monetary Fund, was nominally a
gold-exchange standard but functioned primarily
as a dollar standard. The United States took upon
itself the responsibility of maintaining the convertibility of its currency into gold for foreign official
holders at a fixed par value, while other member
nations pegged their currencies to the U.S. dollar.
The coexistence of both gold and the dollar as
international reserve assets proved to be a major
source of instability for the IMF system. After
1965 strong speculative pressures developed
against the dollar, when it became increasingly apparent that that currency was overvalued.

The decline and fall of the gold standard has
been so exhaustively analyzed in standard textbooks and popular writings 5 that it would not be
worthwhile repeating here. Suffice it to say that
gold's relative importance started to decline even
during the nineteenth centry, as its share in the
aggregate money supply of Britain, France, and
the United States declined from about one-third in
1815 to only one-tenth in 1913, while the share of
bank deposits expanded from a mere six percent to
sixty-eight percent. 6 Robert Triffin has characterized this period as a century of "gradual
euthanasia" of gold money and its replacement by
credit money. 7

The rest is familiar history. When in August
1971 the United States closed its gold window
even to foreign official dollar holders, it severed in
one stroke the last functional link between the dollar and monetary gold. Nevertheless, another three
years passed before the world's monetary authorities decided, in January 1975, to abolish the
official price which has maintained gold nominally
as the standard of the international monetary system. The U.S. Government is now treating its stock
of gold as an ordinary commodity to be auctioned
off piecemeal if it so wishes. For this country at
least, there is little prospect that gold will ever again
playa prominent role in the reformed international
monetary system.

After World War I, national monetary authorities made numerous efforts to restore the prewar gold standard, but their efforts ended in complete collapse in the 1930' s, when all nations, one

7

The Case Against Demonetization

"impersonal," because it is mechanically governed
by set rules, requiring no forecasting and no administrative or legislative decisions; hence it is not
subject to the hazards of erroneous forecasting and
bad decisions. The mechanism is also "automatically stabilizing," because-under certain
conditions l O-it tends to augment national income
when it is relatively low and to subtract from income when it is relatively high.

The objective of the U.S. Government to demonetize gold has hardly gone unquestioned. Indeed, the advocates of gold believe that its role
should be strengthened rather than weakened.
They advance three arguments: (1) the constraints
of a gold standard would check excessive monetary expansion and world inflation; (2) stable exchange rates based on the gold par value of national currencies would facilitate international
trade and investment; and (3) gold remains
superior to either SDRs or foreign exchange as a
reserve asset.

In fact, however, neither the gold standard nor
the silver standard worked out very well. Discoveries of new mines and breakthroughs in refining technology were major sources of instability in
the nineteenth-century international monetary system. Indeed, far from the idealized version, the
world economy during the heyday of the gold
standard was characterized by wide fluctuations of
both output and prices. As Robert Mundell has
pointed out, instead of controlling liquidity in
order to avoid inflation and deflation, "under the
gold standard, inflation and deflation were the
means by which liquidity was controlled."ll

(1) The "discipline" of the gold
standard and domestic price stability

One of the gold advocates' strongest arguments
is the need for the so-called "discipline" of the
gold standard to set prescribed automatic limits to
the powers of national monetary authorities. When
a country's money supply is not tied to gold or to
some other commodity standard, it is asserted,
political expediency or misguided judgment would
too often lead the monetary authorities to expand
the money supply at an excessive rate for a prolonged period of time, resulting in inflations followed by recessions. But economic instability
could be avoided or at least lessened if money were
rigidly tied to a commodity standard, under which
the monetary authorities would be obligated to
convert the national fiat money into gold or
another commodity (e.g., silver) or into a standard
basket of commodities at some fixed rate. Convertibility could be either universal or limited; in the
first case, it would be available to all holders of fiat
money (domestic or foreign) and, in the second
case, limited to foreign official holders. 9 The standard of reference in most of these discussions is the
1870-1914 version of the international gold standard and the monetary doctrines underlying it.

Twentieth-century reality has also conflicted
with the idealized version of the gold-standard adjustment mechanism, which presumes a great deal
of price flexibility in both upward and downward
directions. Wage and price rigidity has increased
significantly, especially since the end of World
War II, as a result of growing unionization and
oligopolistic market structures throughout the
world. Given the present structure of the economy,
sustained monetary deflation would result in widespread unemployment and business recessions to a
much greater extent than in the preceding century .
Moreover, given modem full-employment
policies, a strict adherence to the gold-standard
rules of monetary management probably would be
politically unacceptable .12

There is indeed considerable truth in these arguments. The chief virtues of a commodity standard
are impersonality and automaticity. A gold standard or, for that matter, any commodity standard is

This is not to imply that the world monetary
system in the twentieth century has fared any better
than in the nineteenth century.13 Rather, the central point is that a gold standard is neither neces8

sary nor sufficient for insuring monetary stability.

(3) Gold as a superior
international reserve asset

If national monetary authorities can accept rigid

monetary restraints, then tying currencies to gold
is clearly not necessary. On the other hand, the
experiences of the nineteenth century and of the
1920'sand 1930's show that adherence to a gold
standard was not sufficient to insure a situation of
monetary stability.

As far back as man can remember, gold has
been used as a safe store of value. National currencies may come and go, but gold remains precious
in people's minds. Especially during times of war
and inflation, when national currencies rapidly
lose their value, the public seeks refuge in that
precious metal. Why has gold been universally regarded as a safe asset in preference to national
currencies?

(2) EXChange-rate stability
and international trade

Gold advocates have frequently argued that,
when national currencies are tied to gold at fixed
prices, the resultant fixed-exchange rates would
effectively tie the various national economies together in a common-currency area and thus greatly
facilitate international trade and investment. Conversely, flexible exchange rates would break up
these ties and hamper international trade and investment.
The argument has lost much of its former attractiveness in the past decade. Throughout the 1960's
and early 1970' s, the mounting barriers to international trade and investment in the name of "defending" the par-value system made an irony of
the argument, and in the last few years, our actual
experience with flexible exchange rates has further
demonstrated its hollowness. Even the most dedicated opponents of flexible exchange rates must
admit that the system has worked much better than
they had expected, and that restrictions on capital
flows are much less now than previously.

The answer has already been suggested, but it is
worth reiterating here. Historically, gold and silver
were regarded as safe stores of value, not because
of any intrinsic value, but rather because of their
adoption at one time or another as the bases of
national and international monetary standards. The
official endorsement of these metals as standards
of value-and the official assurance of their convertibility into national currencies at fixed
prices-supported their values and thus their general acceptance as stores of value. During times of
war and inflation, these metals were preferred to
depreciating national currencies because of the fact
(or belief) that gold or silver could be converted
into other foreign currencies that were not falling
so rapidly in value in terms of commoditypurchasing power. Ever since the rise of fiat
money, it was the ultimate official support of the
price of gold in terms of a national currency that
made this metal valuable, not the other way
around.

In this contradictory world, characterized by national policy decisions in a tightly-integrated and
mutually-interdependent world economy, national
governments have tried but failed to maintain a
fixed-exchange-rate system. They now realize that
a flexible-exchange-rate system may well be the
only workable system under the circumstances.
Furthermore, even if countries wished to reestablish fixed rates at some time in the future, they
could readily achieve this goal without resorting to
gold as an intermediate measure of value.

The popular idea of gold being a safe store of
value puts the cart in front of the horse. Also, it
stems from a set of institutional arrangements that
have long since passed into history. Witness the
fate of silver. After the monetary authorities
stopped supporting the price of silver in terms of
their national currencies, silver became no more
than an ordinary metal. Now that the United States
has stopped supporting gold and no other nation
has shown any readiness to take her place, gold
cannot be considered a safe asset any longer.

9

The Case For Demonetization

But why should the U.S. Government decide to
demonetize gold? The answers are twofold: (1) the
gold-dollar standard was unstable, and (2) SDRs
have emerged as an international reserve asset
superior to gold and foreign exchange.

productivity growth, relative to its major trading
partners, and an acceleration in U.S. inflation after
the mid-1960's. Thus, over time the U.S. dollar
became increasingly overvalued.
The progressive overvaluation of the dollar had
two major consequences. First, U.S. payments
deficits resulted in an accumulation of dollar
liabilities in foreign official holdings increasingly
larger than what foreign monetary authorities desired to hold. By mid-1971, such liabilities
amounted to about $50 billion, nearly three times
their size five years earlier, and almost five times
the then-official value of U .S. gold reserves. The
reality of gold convertibility of the dollar was already dead when the United States officially
closed its gold window in August 1971.

(1) Instability of the
gold-dollar standard
For a quarter-century following World War II,
the international monetary system was fonnally on
a gold-dollar standard, with the value of the dollar
tied to gold at a fixed price of $35 per ounce and
linked to other national currencies through a system of fixed exchange rates. With respect to
exchange-rate adjustments, the United States was
in a fundamentally different position from other
countries, in that each of the latter could repeg the
exchange rate of its currency against the U.S. dollar, subject to approval of the International Monetary Fund, for correcting a "fundamental disequilibrium" in its balance of payments. The
United States, on the other hand, with its currency
pegged to gold, was not well situated to alter the
exchange rates between the dollar and other currencies for correcting its own balance-of-payments
problems-as was demonstrated by the difficult
dollar depreciation of August - December 1971.

The second major consequence was a mounting
stress in the U. S. domestic economy, as industries
here found it increasingly difficult to compete with
foreign products in either the export or the domestic markets, and as investment incentives turned
more and more in favor of production abroad than
in the United States. Demands for protectionist
legislation against imports and overseas investments mounted in the Congress and among the
general public.
The gold-dollar standard under the IMF system, in principie, was not necessarily unstable. it
could have endured, for instance, if (a) the surplus
and deficit countries had been equally ready to
adjust their exchange rates against the dollar, (b)
the growth rate of the U.S. money supply had been
more in tune with what was required for the stability of the international monetary system, and (c)
there had been an adequate growth of world reserve assets other than liabilities of individual
countries.

Compounded with this asymmetry was a devaluation bias in the exchange-rate adjustments
that took place in the quarter-century between the
establishment of the IMF system in 1946 and its
collapse in 1971. Except for the reserve-currency
country, the stock of any deficit country's international reserves ultimately placed a limit on the extent to which devaluation could be delayed. However, there was no corresponding constraint forcing a surplus country to revalue its currency
against the dollar. In fact, with the exceptions of
the German mark, the Dutch guilder, and the
Canadian dollar, all the exchange-rate adjustments
during that quarter-century were devaluations
against the dollar. This development took place
against the background of a significant lag in U.S.

However, since none of these conditions was
met, the system was in fact unstable. The United
States found itself increasingly in an untenable
position, with mounting liabilities to foreigners
and mounting problems among domestic produc-

10

ers. In one stroke, it severed the link between the
dollar and gold in August 1971. Since then, it has
resisted all pressures to retie the dollar to gold.

United States, as the principal issuer of international money under the gold-dollar standard, was
widely accused of abusing the seigniorage privilege
by excessive monetary expansion, especially after
the mid-1960's. The benefits of seigniorage under a
pure gold standard accrued to gold-producing nations, to the extent that the official price of gold was
set above its production cost. In contrast, the
seigniorage gains of SDR creation are distributed to IMF members in accordance with inter nationally agreed rules.

(2) SDRs as a primary
international reserve asset
Since their initial creation in January 1970, the
IMF Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) have grown
to a total of $10.6 billion at the end of 1974. Although they account for only about five percent of
total world reserves,14 SDRs possess a number of
highly attractive features as an international reserve asset.
First, unlike gold, SDRs are costless to produce; this is an important feature in a world of
expanding trade and investment, where there is a
need for steady growth of reserve assets. Second,
they provide a means for internationally controlled
growth of world liquidity. This is in contrast to
gold, the supply of which can fluctuate considerably because of technological or speculative factors,
or to the dollar, the supply of which is controlled
by the monetary authority of a single country. The
creation of SDRs reflects the collective will of the
international community and hence might avoid
both inflationary and deflationary extremes,15 and
it is thus more rational than the creation of liquidity
under the gold-dollar standard.

Fourth, unlike gold, SDRs pay interest. The annual interest rate was 1Vl percent until mid-1974,
but it was then raised to 5 percent, adjustable
periodically in line with money rates in several
major markets. Also, SDRs have a more stable
foreign-currency value than any single national currency, since their value is now set daily by the IMF
on the basis of a weighted composite of 16 major
currencies. Moreover, with gold's future in doubt,
SDRs should be a less risky international reserve
asset than gold. Indeed, in view of all the desirable
properties enumerated here, SDRs can be expected
ultimately to replace gold as a primary international
reserve asset. The U.S. phase-out of gold as a
monetary instrument contributes to that objective.

Third, SDRs represent a more equitable way of
distributing reserve assets than does either gold or
the dollar. Money embodies command over resources. The issuer of money possesses the power
to command resources-" seigniorage"-wherever
the money is accepted as a means of payment. The

11

Prospects of Gold in the International Monetary System
What will be the future role of gold in the aftermath of U.S. demonetization? The subject was
discussed in a meeting of the IMF Interim Committee (successor to the Committee of 20) on
January 15-16 in Washington. Agreement was
then reached to abolish the official gold price and
to allow all central banks to value their gold and
use it in any way they want. 16 Subject to ratification by the IMF Governors at their annual meetings in September, the agreement would in effect
demonetize gold for the international monetary
system as a whole, but leave it to individual countries to decide on their national gold policies. It is
useful to explore what options there are for individual countries, and what problems are likely to
arise when and if those options are exercised.

establishment of a new, higher official gold
price. I8 The proposal would have prolonged the
use of gold as a means of settlement between national central banks, and thus might have avoided
too abrupt a termination of gold's age-old role as a
major international reserve asset. Raising the official price of gold, however, would run the risk of
conferring official sanction on an arbitrary price
which has little prospect of adjustment. It is hard to
conceive how gold could be phased out once an
official price was restored. More importantly, on
the basis of the preceding analysis of the U.S.
experience with the former gold-dollar standard, it
is extremely doubtful that the U.S. Government
would be willing again to tie the dollar to gold.
Official Gold Holdings
(End of June 1974)

The basic facts are fairly straightforward. As
shown in the table below, the world's official gold
reserves-holdings of the monetary authorities of
non-Communist nations as well as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the Bank for International Settlement (BIS)-amount to about 1.2
billion ounces. There is no way to measure the size
of the world's private gold holdings, although they
probably amount to about 2.5 billion ouncesY

Million oz.

United States
West Germany
France
Switzerland
Italy
Netherlands
Belgium
Portugal
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Austria
South Africa
Other Developed
Countries
Latin America
Middle East
Other Asia
Other Africa
IMF
BIS

This country is by far the largest official holder
of gold, followed by Germany, France, Switzerland, and Italy. The U.S. holdings amount to
about one-fourth of total official gold holdings. In
addition, the IMF also holds a sizable
amount-more than any individual country except
the United States.
Because of the size of this country's holdings,
U.S. policy should be the most important, if not
the deciding, factor governing the future course of
gold. The United States has begun to demonetize
gold, but others might still question the finality of
that decision. After all, the modest amount-less
than one million ounces-that was sold in the recent auction represents only a small fraction of the
U.S. gold stock.

Total

276.0
117.6
100.9
83.2
82.5
54.3
42.2
27.9
22.0
21.1

21.0
20.9
18.5
36.5
28.3
28.8
18.0
11.5
153.4

6.1
1,180.3

Source: Based on data in International Monetary Fund,
International Financial Statistics, December 1974. Original
data are values in U.S. dollars, converted to ounces at $42.22 per
ounce.

One proposal reportedly advanced in earlier
meetings on international monetary reform was the
12

More modest proposals for a transitional monetary role for gold have been to allow official transfers of gold at variable market-related prices or to
use gold as collateral for official loans. While no
government or central bank (as far as is known)
has yet shown any interest in buying gold at the
market price,19 one large gold-collateral loan has
been made. In 1974, Italy borrowed approximately
$2 billion from Germany on this basis. This transaction illustrates the type of transitional arrangement which can assist countries traditionally dependent upon gold reserve assets through a period
when outright gold transactions are no longer feasible measures.

cial holdings of about 450 million ounces, account
for about 35 percent of total world gold reserves,
and they might conceivably attempt to preserve
gold's former role by agreeing to an official price
of gold in terms of one of their currencies. In such
an event, that chosen currency would in effect become the reserve currency for the gold bloc and for
all other countries that might wish to tie their currencies to gold-bloc currencies. The centercurrency country would then be called on to "defend" the gold parity of its currency, thus finding
itself in much the same position as the United
States did prior to August 1971. However, it appears rather unlikely that any of them would be
willing to be maneuvered into such an unenviable
position.
The question of how to handle the transitional
role of gold is particularly significant in view of
the serious balance-of-payments problems resulting from the recent quadrupling of world oil
prices. The official gold reserves of the major industrial nations originally had been accumulated
through past balance-of-payments surpluses. Now,
their balance of payments have turned adverse. It
stands to reason that these nations should at least
have the option of using their gold reserves for
financing oil-related payments deficits, rather than
suffering a large depreciation of their currencies.

With the U.S. Government committed to a
course of demonetizing gold, the question arises of
what it should do with its remaining 275 million
ounces. Since the gold stock serves no useful function and only costs money to store, the taxpayers'
interest might dictate selling it off as quickly as the
market can absorb, at prices that would maximize
the return to the Treasury without unnecessarily
antagonizing foreign central banks. In 1973, we
imported (net of exports) more than 2 million
ounces of gold-down sharply from the nearly 6
million ounces in 1971, but still a very substantial
volume. Now that gold ownership is permitted to
U.S. citizens, U.S. demand for gold ought to be
met out of idle government stocks, rather than out of
imports.

But, who might be the potential gold buyers?
Offhand, they would appear to be the buyers in the
world's private gold markets. In fact, however,
those markets are notoriously thin. If a number of
governments started to unload their gold stocks
there, the gold price could decline substantially
before reaching equilibrium. Potential gold purchasers would probably react quickly and add to
the downward pressure by speculating on further
declines in the gold price. The already thin market
would become even thinner on the buyers' side.

The U.S. Government's decision certainly will
affect what foreign governments do with their
gold. Traditionally, many of them have strongly
supported the status quo and thus have resisted the
U.S. attempt at demonetization of gold in the international monetary system. The recent French
action in raising the value of its official gold reserves to $170.40 per ounce might suggest the possibility of a new "gold bloc" arising around the
French franc as it did in the 1930's. The European
Economic Community (EEC) nations, with offi-

Even if the private demand for gold remained
strong because of the public's deep-rooted attachment to gold, official gold sales would only shift
the balance-of-payments problem from goldselling nations to gold-buying nations. Such a
move might cushion the balance-of-payments adjustments between surplus and deficit countries,
but it would not help the financing of the oil deficits of consuming nations unless oil- producing

13

could well arise, say, several years down the road.
This suggests the need for some sort of contingency
stabilization plan, if only for the preservation of the
value of the gold assets in official reserves, which
after all represent substantial amounts of national
savings.

nations were willing to absorb gold. 20
But would the oil producers be willing either to
take gold for oil payments or to purchase gold from
the open market? The former probably would be
hard to negotiate because of the difficulty of agreeing on a price for gold. The latter would be quite
unlikely, especially if the gold price started to tumble. In any case, the Middle East nations, contrary
to their popular image, traditionally have not been
large gold holders. 21

As one possibility, the International Monetary
Fund could be asked to purchase from national
monetary authorities any gold they wish to sell in
exchange for SDRs at an agreed price, say, at the
current official price of SDR 35 per ounce. National monetary authorities should also be free to
sell gold on open markets at higher prices when
possible. The IMF gold price would support the
value of official gold assets only to the extent of
indirectly supporting the open market, by forestalling potentially large liquidations of official gold
stocks at prices below SDR 35 per ounce. Alternative approaches could also be devised, but since
negotiations on international monetary issues take
time, it is not too early to start thinking now about
various types of contingency plans.

What governments could do with their existing
gold holdings, aside from financing oil deficits,
remains an unanswered question. The foregoing
analysis suggests the possibility of a disorderly
market, with governments attempting to sell off
their gold stocks and few buyers on the other side
of the market. The analysis might be overdrawn,
in view of individuals' traditional preference for
gold over national currencies, especially during
periods of world inflation. Yet such an eventuality

"For earlier proposals of commodity standards other than gold
and silver, see Benjamin Graham, Storage and Stability (New
York: McGraw-Hill, 1937) and World Commodities and World
Currency (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1944); also Frank D.
Graham, Social Goals and Economic Institutions (Princeton,
New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1942), pp. 94-119.
For an analysis of the conceptual basis of commodity standards
in general and the commodity-reserve standard in particular,
see Milton Friedman, "Commodity-Reserve Currency,"
Journal of Political Economy, June 1951, pp. 203-232.

FOOTNOTES
1 After the United States and Gennany. For data on official gold
reserves, see table on page 12.

2For a detailed analysis of demand and supply conditions in the
gold market, see the accompanying article by Michael W.
Keran and Michael Penzer, "Gold as a Private Hedge Against
Inflation."
3Robert Triffin, Our International Monetary System: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow (New York: Random House,
1966), especially pages 3-60; and Robert A. Mundell, The
International Monetary System: Conflict and Reform (Quebec,
Canada: The Canadian Trade Committee, 1965), especially
page 21.

10 Among the necessary conditions for the smooth working of a
commodity standard are (a) a close relationship between GNP
and changes in money's share of total national assets and (b) the
existence of a large stock of the commodity currency that can
readily shift into or out of official money holdings in response
to small changes in commodity prices. On the other hand, if
monetary changes exert only a weak impact on GNP, the
smooth functioning of a commodity standard requires (a) a
highly elastic supply of the currency commodity, such that the
output of the commodity can be rapidly expanded or contracted
in response to small changes in the general price level, and (b)
that the industry producing the commodity (say, gold) account
for a sizable fraction of GNP. Friedman notes that gold satisfies only one of these conditions-the existence of a large private stock capable of shifting back and forth between monetary
and private holdings. He cites Charles O. Hardy's view that
common building bricks (except for their lack of glamor) would
be a much better currency commodity than gold. Friedman, op.
cit., pp. 204-210, esp. p. 208.

4Triffin, op. cit., page 25.
5For instance, "The Rise of Gold as a Domestic Standard" in
this Review. May '1961, pages 84-96.
6Robert Triffin, op cit., Table 1.2, page 26. The balance of the
aggregate money supply in 1913 was accounted for by silver (3
percent) and currency (19 percent), both of which had declined
sharply since 1815.

7Ibid., page ix.
8See the accompanying article by Kurt Dew, "Gold Policy:
The Thirties and the Seventies."

"Mundell, op. cit., p. 22.

14

'"New York Times, January 17, 1975, p. 39.

l2In Robert Mundell's words, "Trade unions made the gold
standard inefficient, while universal suffrage made it unpalatable." Ibid., p. 23. It can also be argued, of course, that expansionary monetary policies since the 1930's have indirectly supported unions and oligopolistic producers by "validating"
cost-push price increases. The latter interpretation, however, is
not inconsistent with the view that growing unionism and market concentration have made monetary contraction politically
and economically less feasible than previously.

17Merrill, Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc., Gold, Special
Report, November 1974, p. 14. The Soviet Union's gold reserve is a tightly held national secret, but is perhaps on the order
of 64 million ounces. New York Times, November 6, 1974,
p. 67.

13In fact, one could well argue that price and output fluctuations
in the nineteenth century were mild in comparison with those in
the last fifty years. Moreover, since the 1930's thete has been a
pronounced inflationary bias in the system, which was not true
under the gold standard.

19Indeed, IMF members are legally prohibited by the present
Articles of Agreement from buying gold at prices in excess of
the current official price.

'"See, for instance, The Wall Street Journal, July 23, 1973,
p. 1.

2°The same stricture applies to the so-called "Ossola Plan,"
proposed by the Deputy Governor of the Bank of Italy, Rinaldo
Ossola. Under this plan, the IMF would sell gold-denominated
bonds to help provide temporary relief for the countries hardest
hit by oil-price increases. New York Times, December 3,1974,
p.57.

14Foreign exchange holdings (mostly dollars) comprised about
70 percent; gold, about 20 percent; and IMF reserve positions,
5 percent of total world reserves.
15The system per se, however, does not preclude over- or
under-creations of SDRs. Creations of SDRs require the approval by an 85-percent weighted vote of IMF participants. A
handful of surplus countries conceivably could block SDR creations if they together hold more than 15 percent of the vote. On
the other hand, excessive creations could arise if members holding more than 85 percent of the vote were so inclined.

21Middle East nations hold small amounts both in absolute
terms and in relation to the size of their total reserve holdings.
At mid-1974, they held only $1.2 billion of their $21.1 billion
total reserves in gold. International Monetary Fund,
International Financial Statistics, December 1974.

15

By Kurt Dew

cember 31, 1974. The rationale for these actions
was the termination of the role of gold in U.S.
monetary dealings. As in the Thirties, this policy is
being conducted during a period of economic
weakness-but a period marked this time by a rapid
fall in the value of the dollar, that is, inflation.

The gold policy of the United States during the
twentieth century has been marked by two distinct
shifts. The first shift in the 1930's was characterized
by expropriation-with citizens turning their private holdings over to the U.S. Treasury-and by a
rise in the price of gold in terms of the U.S. dollar.
This policy was conducted during a period of unprecedented economic weakness, evidenced by a
rise in the value of the dollar in terms of domestic
goods and services, that is, deflation.

Three questions may be asked about these seemingly quite different policies. First, could we
reasonably expect them to produce the results for
which they were intended? Secondly, could external actions cause these policies to result in detrimental side effects capable of overpowering the intended beneficial effects? Finally, was gold itself in
either case a useful vehicle for the attainment of
national economic welfare?

A second change in U.S. gold policy began in
1968 with the establishment of a two-market goldtrading system-one for the public, one for central
banks. This shift was continued with the closing of
the gold window in 1971, and it culminated in the
legalization of private holdings of gold on De-

The Thirties
In the earlier case, the evidence suggests that the
first two questions can be answered in the affirmative, and the last, in the negative. In the Thirties, the
basic intent of President Roosevelt's gold policy
was originally ill-defined, but it evolved gradually
into an attempt to influence food prices. The gold
decisions of that era had their genesis in Roosevelt's
inaugural speech, where he affirmed his intention to
subordinate international interests to those of the
United States. The exact means of accomplishing
this were unclear at first, possibly even unclear to
himself. However, the form of his commitment
became clearer at the International Monetary Conference of 1933.

This conference had been called to explore the
possibility of a return to the gold standard and a
reduction in the tariff and quota restrictions which
were hampering international-trade flows. Advocates of these goals hoped that the United States
would take a leading role in a successful outcome;
in fact, Cordell Hull, a firm internationalist, headed
the U.S. delegation. But Roosevelt sounded the
death knell of the conference with his statement:
"Let me be frank in saying that the United States
seeks the kind of dollar which a generation hence
will have the same purchasing and debt-paying
power as the dollar value we hope to attain in the
near future. That objective means more to the good
16

of other nations than a fixed ratio for a month or two
in terms of the pound or franc." In other words,
while we were still tied in 1933 to fixed-exchange
rates between the dollar and other currencies, there
was no firm commitment to a continuation of that
policy.

Billions of Dollars

GOLD HOLDINGS

10

After the conference, the dollar prices of
goods--especially agricultural goods-eontinued
to fall, further exacerbating an already serious farm
situation. Professor George Warren of Cornell suggested a solution -a dollar devaluation vis-a-vis
gold- on the basis of the close relationshi'p he had
observed between weekly agricultural prices and
gold prices in terms of the pound sterling. The
President bought the idea as a way to help the
farmers, and raised the gold price from $20.67 per
ounce on September 8, 1933, to its final level of $35
an ounce on February 1, 1934. The prices of a large
range of commodities (including agricultural ones)
rose on international markets, and Roosevelt's goal
was largely achieved. The answer to the question,
"Did he achieve his purpose?" is yes.

6

4

2

0L-..J.._ _.L...-...L.---l._.L...-...L.---l._.l.-..J..--L_.l.-...J

1928

1930

1932

1934

1936

1938

1940

Note: Does not adjust for change in price of official gold

Yet the increase in farm prices was in many ways
a Pyrrhic victory, primarily because of the lack of
coordination between the Administration's gold
policy and the policies of two other governmental
entities, one foreign, one domestic. Consider first
the behavior of the foreign entity, the gold bloc.

In principle, the growth in the money stock
should have helped to raise both U.S. income and
U.S. export demand, potentially in sufficient
amounts to reverse the inflow into this country and
to return the gold-bloc economies to their predevaluation level of prosperity. However, reality
failed to coincide with principle. France and several
other European countries had remained on the gold
standard in 1934 with insufficient gold reserves,
and holders of these gold-bloc currencies hence
suspected that devaluation was inevitable, This
suspicion further increased private incentives to
trade for dollars, and the ensuing run on gold-bloc
currencies reduced their domestic money stocks and
brought about a deeper depression. The adverse
primary effects of gold-bloc decisions upon their
own economies had adverse secondary effects upon
the U.S. economy as well, by sharply reducing the
demand for internationally traded goods produced
in this country. Had the gold-bloc countries devalued at the same time as the United States, they
would not have suffered severe gold outflows. If
they had raised the price of gold in terms of their
own currencies, they could have avoided the problem of insufficient gold reserves.

The first effect of the higher dollar price of gold
was an inflow of gold to the U.S. Treasury. This
inflow was naturally associated with an outflow of
gold elsewhere, most importantly from the gold
bloc, the group of European nations determined to
maintain a fixed price of their currencies in terms of
gold. When the United States raised the dollar price
of gold, private holders of these foreign currencies
(and of gold) had an incentive to exchange their
holdings for dollars. This phenomenon was damaging to the gold bloc in the short run, but it need not
have had the long-lasting detrimental effect upon
them that it eventually had. Initially the devaluation
of the dollar followed the classic pattern of a currency devaluation in a gold-standard world. The
dollar remained a gold-backed currency throughout
this period - at least in the minds of most citizens,
economists, and government officials - and thus
the total U.S. money stock increased as gold flowed
into the country.

17

On the home front, the expansionary effects of
the Administration's gold policy were partly offset
in the late Thirties by a tightening of Federal Reserve policy. Money expanded in line with the
post-1933 gold inflows, thereby helping to stimulate the economy. But the monetary authorities became concerned about the large quantities of excess
reserves building up in the banking system. They
responded in late 1936 by doubling bank reserve
requirements within a six-month period. This action sterilized a large share of bank reserves, which
induced a reduction in loans and in the gold-backed
supply of money, and thus helped create the recession in 1937.

dollar-price of gold - in failing to realize that the
economic source of this relationship was the monetary expansion which had been induced by the high er dollar-price of gold.
The Administration need not have purchased
gold at all to achieve its aims, but instead, could
have purchased labor, bridges, dams, and other
useful resources rather than gold for storage in Fort
Knox. Sale of the resulting debt to the Federal
Reserve would have provided the same base for
monetary expansion as did gold, without any damage to the gold-bloc countries. For their part, these
countries viewed devaluation as almost immoral, a
move to be made only under compulsion. Their
policy, ironically, became the source of their desperate situation. Had they not been so intent on
linking their currencies to gold, the outflow of gold
they suffered would not have affected their money
supplies. This experience suggests that gold was
not a beneficial vehicle for the provision of
economic welfare in the 1930's.

Yet the fundamental flaw - the thing that turned
a potentially beneficial policy into a disaster - was
the tendency of both the United States and the
gold-bloc countries to follow gold policies rather
than monetary policies. President Roosevelt's mistake was in assuming the increase in the price of
agricultural goods to be mystically related to the

The Seventies
The same questions may be asked about the gold
policy of the Seventies as were asked about the
Thirties. First, will the current Administration's
goals be fulfilled? Secondly, will these actions have
repercussions, at home or abroad, that would make
these intended aims more difficult to achieve? Finally, is gold beneficial for the conduct of economic
policy in the 1970' s?

boundaries. This is largely because we are now
operating in a world of flexible exchange rates,
where the link between money and gold has been
effectively broken, despite gold's continued role as
a major reserve asset.
The second and more interesting question concerns the factors which could offset the effects of
the current gold policy. To limit the discussion, we
should make two basic assumption. These are (1)
that the American public has been well-informed
enough about gold that it will not operate irrationally with its new found freedom, and (2) that all
current gold agreements among nations will be
honored. These two assumptions, if correct, put
firm limits on the possible detrimental side effects
of the new gold policy.

The first question may be answered in the affirmative. The Administration's intention is to relegate gold to the same status as that of any other
commodity, rather than to continue gold's historical role as a constraint upon the de~isions of the
monetary authorities. It is clear that this objective
is being realized. With private gold purchases and
sales legalized in this country, gold has become
more like all the other items traded in the commodity markets. Also, since the closing of the gold
window, the monetary authorities have not been
substantially affected in their decisions by the price
of gold or the shifting of gold across international

The public at large and, indeed, some
economists believe that the whole issue is rather
simple - namely, that legalization of private gold
ownership is part of the U.S. Government's covenant with its citizens to provide a maximum of

18

individual freedom consistent with general welfare. Yet, while legalization demonstrably increases freedom of choice, some analysts question
its benefits for the general welfare. They raise the
question - if a substantial number of investors
choose to buy gold, what assets will they sell in
order to do so? As the price of gold and/or the
quantity held by private citizens increase, the price
of the assets sold and/or the quantity of these assets
held by private citizens will go down. The
economy could be adversely affected if investors
sold substantial amounts of two types of assets:
first, time deposits of banks and thrift institutions;
and, second, corporate equity and debt liabilities.

vidual investors or large institutional investors, the
potential demand for gold should be relatively
small.
Is it possible that other government actions
might offset the benefits of the recent Treasury decision, repeating the experience of the Thirties?
Again, this seems unlikely. First, in view of the
U.S .-French agreement regarding the official valuation of gold at free-market value, the Administration may have achieved the international cooperation that its predecessor so signally failed to
achieve a generation ago. If the major national
holders of gold have agreed not to be net purchasers, any increase in the gold price will be the result
of private decisions. This is the type of accord that
could have helped forestall the serious difficulties
of the 1930's.

In the first situation, such sales would represent
a decision by large groups of relatively small investors that the yield on gold would be higher than
the yield on savings deposits. This would be
reasonable if the price of gold were to increase so
rapidly as to make its yield greater than the
7.75-percent maximum yield available from
savings-and-loan deposits. But this possibility appears rather remote, since the price of gold would
have to rise 30 percent just to make it possible for
the small investor to break even after paying commissions plus storage and assay costs. The investor
might also choose gold if he believed that thrift
institutions were going to collapse and the government default on its insurance, but this of course
would happen only in a period of complete
economic and social chaos.

But on the domestic scene, what if the monetary
authorities should feel compelled to adopt a course
of excessive monetary expansion, say, to forestall
a deepening recession? Most projections of the effects of monetary expansion are based upon experience prior to the legalization of gold trading.
These projections, utilizing the quantity equation
MV = PT, assume that an increase in money balances (M) held by the public will initially result in
an increase in real economic growth (T), because
velocity (V) is relatively constant over long
periods of time, and because the price level (P)
does not change as rapidly as real economic
growth in view of the high cost to the market place
of changing P. But there are two factors that can
act to reduce the cost of changing P - first, inflation, and second, the existence of close substitutes
for currency.

A second posibility is that holders of corporate
stocks and bonds transfer their holdings into gold.
These investors are primarily large institutions
with portfolios controlled by quite sophisticated financial managers. To assume that they would now
shift into gold, we must first suppose that they
have not been able to do so in the past - a dubious
assumption in their case, especially since it has
been quite legal to own equities of corporations
that produce gold. Second, we must suppose that
these financial managers believe an asset whose
chief virtue lies in its fixed supply is preferable to
an asset whose value depends upon the productivity of American capital - again an unlikely assumption in the absence of an actual decline in the
effective stock of capital, as would happen only in
the case of confiscatory taxation or physical destruction of assets. Thus, for either small indi-

Now, consider the case of an overly rapid
monetary expansion in today's situation, with the
legalization of the closest of money substitutes gold. Sophisticated investors with large portfolios,
realizing the implications of excessive money
growth for the rate of future inflation, and uncertain of the future course of monetary policy, might
switch to gold, or more importantly, debt and credit instruments payable in terms of gold. But inflation would have to be rapid enough to make such
an expensive institutional change profitable. In particular, pervasive substitution of gold for money
by small traders would be entirely unlikely without

19

a hyperinflation, simply because money is legal
tender, while gold is not.

ina! money balances would have the same impact on
real growth that it had in the past, for such an
hypothesis ignores the presence of major changes in
the economic environment. It would be better to
recognize that rapid inflation in the presence of
close currency substitutes, such as gold, is tantamount to a self-imposed reduction in influence of
monetary actions upon the behavior of real
economic variables.

In the inflationary case, where the transition
from cash to gold is profitable for trading purposes, the excess supply created by monetary expansion would be rapidly soaked up by a corresponding excess demand for gold. In response, the
relative prices of gold and other "real" commodities (those not denominated in dollars) would
rise more rapidly than they usually do in response
to a given monetary expansion. The pass-through
of easy money into inflation would be more rapid
than before, leaving the economy with less real
growth and higher unemployment than expected.

Finally, as in the Thirties, there are fiscal implications to the current policy. Treasury sales of
gold could make possible the attainment of such
objectives as tax reductions, increased publicservice jobs, or reduced deficits. The monetary
expansion of the Thirties could have been accomplished - but was not - by the purchase of things
other than gold. The current Administration has
learned that lesson well, as it showed with its recent gold auction.

Judging from the experience of other industrial
nations, it is somewhat unlikely that there could be
an extensive substitution of gold for currency. But
a dilemma could be created for monetary policy if
such substitution should occur. It would be
dangerous to assume that a greater increase in nom-

20

By Michael W. Keran and Michael Penzer

On December 31, 1974, American citizens
were, for the first time in 41 years, legally permitted to buy, sell and hold gold bullion. The extent
to which they exercise this privilege will depend
largely on their private views concerning the future
rate of increase in the price of gold and the variance in this rate of change. In other words, will
the price of gold increase faster than the general
price level, and will variations in its price be suffi-

ciently narrow so as not to expose holders to undue
risks? The purpose of this article is to examine the
role of gold as a private hedge against inflation.
This will be done by analyzing the factors which
have determined the price of gold during both the
distant and more recent past, in order to come to
some conclusion regarding gold's possible role as
an inflation hedge during 1975 and beyond.

Gold Prices
Whether or not gold proves to be a good inflation hedge for the private U.S. citizen obviously
depends upon the amount of appreciation in the
dollar value of his gold holdings between the time
that he buys the gold and the time that he sells it
(Chart 1). In this regard, our primary criterion for
evaluating gold's performance as an inflation
hedge is the degree to which the price of gold
moves with the general price level (either up or
down). The question of whether gold is a good investment depends upon factors other than its role
as an inflation hedge, mainly the return available
on alternate investments. We will consider both issues here.

the same interval the value of other U.S. goods
declined by about 30 percent as measured by the
wholesale price index. Hence, a gold purchase in
1929 would have been an unusually good investment because while most prices were falling, the
gold price rose in succeeding years (Chart 2a).
Chart 1
U.S. Dollars Per Ounce

160

r-----------------,
GOLD PRICE

120

Timing one's purchase obviously is very important. For example, someone purchasing gold in
1929 and legally entitled to hold it beyond 1933 1
would have seen each ounce of his gold investment
increase by 69.5 percent, from $20.65 in 1929 to
$35.00 on January 31, 1934, when the Roosevelt
Administration officially revalued gold. During

80

40

0'-'-'..J..WW-J-J...U..l..U...l..L.'W-J-J...U..l..UW-J-l.U.J...U...l..l..l..l-\...u..J..J..U..J-J
1930

21

1940

1950

1960

1970 1974

Chart 2 (a)

Chart 2 (b)

Chart 2 (c)
1968=100

1934=100

1929=100
250

400

400

300

300

200

200

200

Gold Price

150

Commodities

100

100

50
1930

1940

1950

1960

1967

1935 1940

On the other hand, if our hypothetical gold
buyer had purchased gold in February 1934, after
gold's official price had been raised, and if he held
his gold until 1968, he would have gained only a
12-percent rise in price, compared with a
165-percent rise in wholesale prices (Chart 2b).
Hence, during this 34-year period, gold would
have been no hedge against inflation; indeed, our
buyer would have lost more than one-half of the
purchasing power of his gold.

1960

1950

19701973

100
1968

1970

1972

1974

In the most recent period, when gold prices have
shown their most dramatic increases, prices of
other internationally-traded goods have also risen
very sharply. As Chart 4 demonstrates, world
export-price indices for all commodities - and
primary commodities in particular - increased
substantially between the first quarter of 1971 and
the first quarter of 1974 (latest data available).
During this three-year period, gold prices rose by
nearly 290 percent, while export prices of all
commodities rose by more than 50 percent, and
those for primary commodities increased by more
than 160 percent. Hence, the gold price has been
moving in the same direction as the prices of all
other internationally-traded goods.

Finally, if our buyer had purchased bullion in
1968, his gold investment would have been a good
inflation hedge by the end of 1969, no hedge at all
by year-end 1970 and 1971, and an excellent
hedge by year-end 1972, 1973, and 1974 (Chart
2c). Nevertheless, there is no assurance that gold
purchased now would continue to be a good inflation hedge. Gold purchased on December 30,
1974 at the London afternoon gold-fixing price of
$195.25 per ounce, a record until that time, fell by
$25.75 per ounce over the next week. Ex post, we
see the necessity of timing one's gold purchases
well if one desires to hold gold as a worthwhile
inflation hedge.

Chart 3
Dollars

,-----------------,

20

MONTHLY CHANGES IN GOLD PRICES

10

fI

0

As Chart 3 demonstrates, the variance in gold
prices has increased as the price of gold has
increased.2 Hence, the risk of buying high and sell·
ing low has increased through time; this risk, of
course, is one of the costs of holding gold, of
which more shortly.

A

V

VlJ

~

,A

oAf\

f

W

-10

I

-20
1966

22

I
1968

I

I
1970

1972

1974

Costs and Benefits of Holding Gold

Before proceeding further in an analysis of gold
as a commodity investment, we need to be aware
of the essential difference between this and other
commodities, and the many costs (as well as benefits) incurred in buying, selling and holding
gold. Because of its historical monetary role, gold
cannot (yet) be treated like any other commodity,
whether it be soybeans, pork bellies or steel scrap.
Even now, despite official U.S. efforts to demonetize gold, it is still regarded by many nations,
including the United States, as an integral part of
their international reserves.

did in May 1970, the dollar also buys less foreign
currency - in particular, 48.5 percent fewer Swiss
francs and 41.9 percent fewer German marks. One
must thus conclude that gold has been a better inflation hedge than foreign currency in that particular time span, May 1970 to December 1974. This
is because the current inflation is worldwide in nature, so that even a "strong" currency (such as the
German deutschemark) has experienced record inflation rates by recent historical standards. In such
an environment, a commodity will always be
superior to currency. However, when the current
bout of worldwide inflation ends, that particular
advantage of gold should also end.

Besides being a possibly good hedge against inflation, gold ownership may bestow other benefits.
These include the psychological satisfaction from
holding a metal which historically has provided
security in times of trouble and uncertainty, as well
as the enjoyment of gold's intrinsic physical properties. However, these benefits must be matched
against the possible costs of gold ownership. There
is an opportunity cost in terms of the benefits that
could be obtained from holding other goods instead of gold - from holding, for example, other
commodities, foreign currencies, and interestbearing financial assets. The prices of all commodities, industrial commodities, and metals and
metal products each increased faster than the gold
price between 1934 and 1973 (Table 1), so that a
basket of various commodities held during that
period would have been a better inflation hedge
than the single commodity gold. By November
1974, only the prices of metal and metal products
continued to remain above those for gold. Thus,
depending on the period chosen for comparison,
investments in other commodities may be better inflation hedges than gold. 3

Interest-bearing financial assets are another alternative to gold. While interest rates rose to record levels in 1973 and 1974, they still did not
compensate investors for inflation because the
nominal rate of interest - which included an inflation premium over and above the real interest rate
- was less than the actual inflation rate. As a result, investors were attracted to commodities, such
as gold, during this period. Nevertheless, financial
assets in certain recent periods have been a better

Chart 4
Price 1966=100

500

400

300

Foreign currencies may at times be a better
hedge than gold against increases in the U.S. general price level. Since various currencies were allowed to float against the U.S. dollar in June 1970,
the dollar has depreciated against some currencies
(Table 2), and appreciated against others. While
each dollar now buys 80.8 percent less gold than it

200

100

0
1966

23

1968

1970

1972

1974

fluctuating more than the prices of other commodities.

store of value than gold. For example, if a conservative U.S. investor had placed the equivalent of
$1 million in West Germany in 1949 at an average
yearly rate of 6.75 percent, he could have repatriated $8.8 million by June 1974. In comparison,
$1 million invested in gold at $35 per ounce in 1949
would represent today a value of $4.5 million, less
storage charges over a period of 25 years. 4 In this
example, the investor in deutschemarks benefited
not only from the compound interest on his investment, but also from the appreciation of the West
German mark.

The illiquidity of gold investment and the large
variance in gold prices represent real costs of ownership. If circumstances require the quick sale of a
gold asset, such a sale is more likely to occur in a
down market than is the case with alternative investments. Moreover, buying and holding gold include costs of fabrication, packaging, shipping,
handling, storage, insurance and state sales taxes.
Such costs may boost the cost of the typical purchase to more than 20 to 30 percent above the freemarket price for gold bullion. In addition, transaction costs of between 6 and 15 percent may be
charged for trading by dealers; usually, these costs
are higher for small than for large transactions. As
a result, the free-market price would have to rise
more than 20 percent before the purchaser could
recover his total buying and selling costs. Because
of the risks associated with counterfeiting, he
would also have to pay assay costs whenever he
decided to sell his holdings. Thus, holding gold as
an asset in one's portfolio requires much expertise.
Those who are tempted to view gold as a good
inflation hedge ignore the fact that it may not be
better than other hedges and that there are many
costs involved.

There are many other risks and costs involved in
holding gold besides the opportunity costs involved in not holding other commodities, foreign
currencies, or paper assets. For example, gold
prices fluctuate widely, especially in the short-run,
as speculative activity develops in a thin market
because of the relatively small demand for use in
the arts and industry in relation to current supply
(Chart 3). Moreover, the extent of speculative
buying is a function of the current price and the
expectation that the gold price will rise by at least
the cost of owning and holding gold. If this expectation is not realized, the price must fall enough to
create a new expectation of a rise. These changes
in speculators' expectations result in gold prices

Gold During the Greenback Period
Besides the recent (1968-74) experience, one
other period in American history had no
officially-fixed price of gold in terms of the U.S.
dollar; namely, the Greenback Period from 1862
to 1879. 5 The average monthly price of gold varied widely during this period, but by 1879, the United States was back on the gold standard at the
pre-Civil War parity. The price level rose
throughout the Civil War, then dropped 50 percent
between 1865 and 1879, with the price of gold in
greenbacks moving in parallel. A unit of gold in
greenbacks that was worth a dollar before the war
was worth $2.50 in 1865, before beginning to decline. Given this historical perspective, anyone
wishing to make a good investment would have

been well-advised to trade his greenbacks for gold
at the beginning of the Civil War and then to trade
back in 1864 when the gold price was at its height.
Different supply and demand factors operated
during the 1862-79 period than during the more
recent (1968-74) period. A century ago, the price
of gold was essentially the dollar-pound exchange
rate. With the United Kingdom on the gold standard, the Bank of England stood ready to settle
transactions at the rate of one pound sterling per
unit of gold. Hence, the gold price in terms of
greenbacks was determined by the demand and
supply for greenbacks vis-a-vis the pound sterling.
Although gold was traded on the New York Stock
24

freely in its own market. Nevertheless, one implication may be drawn from the experience of a century ago: if the price of gold is not fixed by government action to a given currency, then gold is a
good investment only during inflation and is a very
bad buy during deflation.

Exchange, its price in terms of greenbacks reflected changes in the day-to-day value of greenbacks vis-a-vis British pounds in the foreignexchange market. Today, no country operates on a
gold standard; instead, all major currencies float
against each other, and the gold price also floats

Gold Price Determinants - Supply
In contrast, the U.S.S.R., the world's second
largest producer, increased its annual gold production from 304 metric tons in 1968 to 371 metric
tons in 1973, an increase of almost 22 percent
(Table 3). Nevertheless, only a portion of the Russian output is sold in the West each year - an
estimated 220 metric tons in 1974. Altogether, the
total supply in Western gold markets declined from
1,634 tons in 1970 to 1,473 tons in 1973.

In order to evaluate gold's future value as an inflation hedge, we need to consider those supply
and demand factors which resulted in generallyrising gold prices during the past seven years and,
in particular, during the past four years. While part
of the recent price increase may be traced to a
stock-adjustment process which occurred when the
gold price was set free, most of the increase reflects changing supply-and-demand forces which
have implications for the future price of gold.

World supply is also dependent on the gold
strategies and foreign-exchange needs of South
Africa and the U.S.S.R. Russian sales depend
largely on the market price and on the size of
liabilities incurred by the U.S.S.R. in its transactions with the West. These sales were particularly
large in the 1972-74 period, but there is no guarantee that they will continue to be so. In the South
African case, the Reserve Bank performs the role of
a price leader by withholding gold from the market
in the face of sluggish demand or an unusual increase in supply, such as the recent Treasury sales
from the U.S. gold stock.

Stock and flow determinants affect both the
supply and demand sides of the gold market. On
the supply flow side, free-world output decreased
from 1,288 metric tons in 1970 to an estimated
1,034 metric tons in 1974, a drop of almost 20
percent in four years (Table 3). South Africa, the
dominant producer, accounted for more than 90
percent of the production decline. Labor problems,
a shortage of skilled technicians, and occasional
operational difficulties contributed to the lower
South African output. This decline also reflected
the perverse short-run elasticity of supply in response to higher gold prices; gold producers have
been either encouraged or required to transfer men
and equipment to mining poorer-quality veins, in
an attempt to conserve higher-quality ore, and
hence to extend the life of the mines. A
downward-sloping flow supply curve is implied by
South Africa's emphasis on long-run rather than
short-run production considerations, which depend
on that producer's expectations regarding long-run
prices and mining costs. This policy assumes that
incentives to increased exploration will not lead to
increased gold discoveries. If the assumption is incorrect, then South Africa's limitation on current
production will be self-defeating.

Conflicting factors thus have affected production during the recent period of rising gold prices.
Hence, from the supply flow point of view, the
private inflation-hedger cannot feel confident that
gold prices will continue to rise faster than the
general price level. World production apparently
declined in 1974 for the fourth straight year, helping ceteris paribus to raise the gold price. For the
longer-run, however, higher gold prices are likely
to result in more gold production.
The supply-stock side of the market is dominated by the amount of monetary gold held by central banks and by the amount in private gold hold25

ings, which together are many times larger than
annual world production. Total stocks today may
approximate 3.7 billion ounces. Central-bank
holdings alone are more than 25 times as large as
annual production. Incidentally, the United States
still holds more than any other nation, accounting
for more than 23 percent of central-bank holdings
at the end of November 1974 (Table 4).

foreign governments are always a possibility. In
fact, Senator William Proxmire, new Chairman of
the Senate Banking Committee, recently said that
he will introduce a bill requiring the Treasury to
sell 25 million ounces of gold (9 percent of its
stock) in 1975 at prevailing market prices. Such
sales should certainly tend to lessen gold's role as a
good hedge against inflation.

Consequently, if central banks sold off only 4
percent of their gold stocks, they could have a disastrous effect on prices, because that would equal
the total world production for an entire year. The
U.S. Treasury conducted such a sale on January 6,
1975, when 753.6 thousand ounces - from a total
of 2 million ounces offered at auction - were sold
at prices varying between $153.00 and $185.00
per ounce. Future sales either by the U.S. or

A decision by foreign central banks to sell their
stocks in the free market will depend largely on
their views concerning gold's future role as international money. If gold is gradually demonetized,
then central bankers may gradually sell off their
gold holdings. The trend towards the use of gold as
collateral for loans (as recently done by Italy) is a
practical step in this direction.

Gold Price Determinants - Demand
demand has been constant for several years. Increased official gold holdings overseas (71.8 million ounces) were almost matched by declining
official U. S. gold holdings (62.8 million ounces)
between the end of 1969 and late 1974 (Table 4).

The demand for gold depends on stock and flow
considerations, as does the supply. There is a flow
demand for gold for industrial, commercial and artistic purposes. There is also a stock demand for
purposes of inventory building, whether it be by
central banks or by private hoarders, investors and
speculators. As gold prices have risen, flow demand generally has declined (Table 5). The largest
decline has occurred in jewelry fabrication, which
in 1973 was less than half of the 1970 level as a
consequence of the 170-percent rise in gold prices
over that period. At currently high prices, flow
demand may continue to decrease in 1975 and
beyond, reflecting the high price elasticity of demand for gold jewelry, and also for coins, medals
and medallions. Another factor likely to reduce
flow demand is the current world recession, which
is causing a decline in demand for most raw materials, including gold.

The speculative and investment demands for
gold became very large in 1973, and undoubtedly
continued high in 1974, with investors and
speculators buying relatively large amounts of official gold coins. Hoarding demand meanwhile
expanded in 1973 after an earlier decline. It should
be noted that different factors underlie each of
these three types of demand. Hoarding demand is
strongest in those parts of the world with a long
record of political and economic turmoil, such as
France and South and East Asia, particularly
India. Gold is regarded in those areas as the ultimate store of value, as well as a means of exchange in times of emergency or flight. Hoarding
demand appears to be price elastic as indicated by
Table 5, which shows smaller or negative additions to hoards during the recent period of rising
gold prices.

The private stock demand for gold increased in
the 1972-74 period, as world inflation accelerated
and as investors bought gold as an inflation hedge.
This demand could continue to increase during
1975, the first year of legal bullion purchases for
American citizens. In contrast, central-bank stock

The basic motive for investment demand is to
26

Chart 5

speculative commodity purchases rather than currency or paper-asset retention.

1959.1=100
300...------------------,

Central-bank demand has decreased in recent
years, reflecting the continued efforts to demonetize gold. When the two-tier market was established in March 1968, central banks agreed not
to purchase any newly mined gold, nor to buy or
sell gold on private markets. In 1973, this agreement was terminated, and central banks may now
sell gold in the free market at going prices. However, International Monetary Fund rules currently
prohibit government purchases in the free market
at more than the official price of $42.22 per ounce.
Hence, central-bank gold purchases have been
minimal in recent years. The trend to demonetization was confirmed this January, when France
abolished the official price of its gold reserves.

Total International Reserves

of Industrial

Between March 1968 (when the two-tier market
was established), and September 1974, gold reserves of non-Communist nations increased only
one percent (11.6 million ounces), reflecting restrictions on central-bank purchases during this
period. South Africa accounted for all of the increase since 1971. Because the South African Reserve Bank purchases all of that nation's output
and releases gold in the free market only when it
desires to do so, its recent tendency to add to its
stocks reflects its intention (as the world's dominant producer) to keep gold prices high.

buy and hold gold for an extended period, at least
until investment in other assets becomes more attractive. In contrast, the motive for speculative
demand is to profit from short-run variations in
gold prices, buying when the price is relatively low
and selling when it is relatively high. Both of these
types of demand have been encouraged by the
1973-74 inflation, and also by the expectations of
inflation which many market participants hold for
1975. Inflation and inflation expectations promote

Future Course of Gold Prices
Hence, caveat emptor: gold may not continue to
be a good private hedge against inflation.

Gold is unlikely to be a good short-term hedge
against inflation, because of the wide price fluctuations which can occur on a month-to-month basis.
Even during the inflationary 1972-74 period, the
price of gold sometimes fell for months at a time
(Chart 3).

Among the many price determinants analyzed
here, gold's role as a hedge against world inflation
is one of the most important. Just as domestic inflation is strongly influenced by growth in the
domestic money stock, so world inflation is also
influenced by growth in the world money stock. 6
World money is a common factor in the demand
functions of all internationally traded goods (including gold). Thus, the rate of increase in the
world money stock will, with a substantial lag,
lead to an increase in the prices of internationally
traded goods. When world money growth was rela-

Over the entire course of the 1972-74 inflation,
gold turned out to be an excellent investment.
Nevertheless, the remaining years of this decade
will inevitably bring changes in the many supply
and demand factors which determine its price.
This paper has shown the many costs and risks involved in gold-market participation, as well as the
complexity of factors which affect the gold price.

27

tively moderate, as in the period from 1963
through 1968, internationally traded goods prices
were stable (Chart 5). However, when world
money growth later accelerated sharply, prices of
internationally traded goods responded. Given the
substantial lag between world money and world
prices, the stability in world money growth which
was resumed in early 1973 should be reflected in

renewed stability in world prices in 1975.
A renewal of stable prices for internationally
traded goods should reduce demand for gold as an
inflation hedge. Given the relatively small demand
for gold for other purposes at its current price, this
could lead to a substantial fall in the price of gold.

FOOTNOTES

well as the price appreciation of that particular commodity as
compared with the increase in the general price level during the
period in question.

1 In 1933, U.S. citizens were forbidden by law to own gold
except by license from the U.S. Department of the Treasury for
certain specified artistic, commercial and industrial purposes.
At the end of 1973, U.S. restrictions were eased on the holding
of gold coins originally minted prior to 1960. On December 31,
1974, U.S. citizens were once again legally entitled to purchase, sell and hold gold bullion.

Charles R. Stahl, American Metal Markets' Gold Conference, October 1974. David O. Tyson, "Record Gold Price
Abroad Anticipates Dominance of Coming U.S. Market,
Dealers Feel", American Banker, November 12, 1974, p. I.

4

For a more detailed discussion of this period, see Milton
Friedman and Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History of the
United States 1867-1960 (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1963), pp. 15-88.

5

Technically, it would be more appropriate in Chart 3 to plot
percentage changes in the gold price rather than absolute
changes, but for practical purposes it makes little difference.
2

The choice of any commodity as an inflation hedge depends
crucially upon the particular time span in which it is held, as

World money stock may be measured by the total international reserves of industrial countries.

3

6

28

Table 1
Price Indices
(1934 = 100)
U.S. Wholesale Prices
Period

Gold Price
(Free-market average)

All
Commodities

Industrial
Commodities

Metals and
Metal Products

1934
1940
1950
1960

100
100
100
100

100
105.0
212.0
245.9

100
106.1
187.6
229.2

100
111.4
196.1
273.3

1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974 (Nov.)

112.2
117.5
102.7
116.6
166.3
277.8
519.1

265.6
276.0
286.0
295.2
308.7
349.0
445.4

246.5
254.9
264.5
274.1
283.5
302.7
398.7

303.5
320.9
345.2
352.0
365.3
392.7
552.2

Sources: Gold Price: Index constructed from London gold price data (U.S. dollars per ounce fine at daily fixing), Annual
Bullion Review, Samuel Montagu and Co. Ltd., London, various years; and Dow Jones News Service, Dow Jones and Co.
Inc., New York, New York, daily reports for November 1974. U.S. Wholesale Prices: Index constructed from the B.L.S.
wholesale-price index, Economic Report of the President (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1974), and Monthly
Labor Review, December 1974.

Table 2
Depreciation of the Dollar vis-a-vis
Gold and Foreign Currencies
May 1970 to December 20,1974
Depreciation
(percent)
-80.8

Gold
Swiss franc

-48.5

West German mark

-41.9

Dutch guilder

-36.4

Belgian franc

-30.1

Swedish krona

-22.5

French franc

-21.2

Japanese yen

-18.0

Australian dollar

-17 .1
29

Table 3
Estimated World Gold Production
(metric tons)

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

1973

969.5
85.3
46.0
22.6
16.4
24.3
15.5
7.0
7.5
5.5
5.3

973.0
79.2
53.9
22.0
17.8
21.7
14.9
7.7
6.8
5.6
5.5

1000.4
74.9
54.2
21.9
18.7
19.4
15.6
8.0
6.3
6.2
5.5

976.3
70.3
46.5
21.7
19.8
20.9
15.6
7.9
5.9
4.7
5.4

908.7
64.7
44.4
22.5
18.7
23.4
15.6
7.4
5.9
4.5
4.3

852.3
59.9
36.7
22.7
18.2
18.0
15.6
7.8
6.5
4.7
3.6

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

Other Non-Communist
Countries

43.3

52.9

56.8

55.1

52.8

48.0

n.a.

Total Non-Communist

1248.2

1261.0

1287.9

1250.1

1172.9

1094.0

1034.2

304.2

318.2

335.5

344.8

360.2

370.6

n.a.

8.4

8.4

8.4

8.4

8.4

8.4

n.a.

1560.8

1587.6

1633.8

1603.3

1541.5

1473.0

n.a.

60

220

280

South Africa
Canada
United States
Ghana
Philippines
Australia
Rhodesia
Japan
Colombia
Mexico
Zaire

U.S.S.R.
Other Communist
Countries
Estimated world
total
Sales by the
U.S.S.R. to the West

10

Sources: Bank for International Settlements, Annual Reports, June 1973, p. 116, and June 1974, p. 123.
Peter D. Fells, Gold 1974 (London: Consolidated Gold Fields, Ltd., 1974), pp. 24 and 47.
E. M. Bernstein, Ltd. U.S. Participation in the Free Gold Market, Report No. 75/1, p. 3.

30

1974

220

Table 4
Official Gold Reserves
(millions of ounces at end of period)
Nov.

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

1973

1974

United States

311.2

338.8

316.3

291.6

276.0

276.0

276.0

Rest of World*

857.5

833.1

863.0

884.4

905.3

904.7

904.9

Total World**

1168.7

1171.9

1179.3

1176.0

1181.3

1180.7

1180.9

* Rest of World includes International Monetary Fund
** Excludes U.S.S.R., other Eastern European countries, and Peoples Republic of China.
Source: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, Vol. 28, No. I, January 1975.

Table 5
Estimated Uses of Gold
(metric tons)

Flow Demand
Jewelry
Electronics
Dentistry
Other Industrial
and Decorative
Fake Coins, Medals
and Medallions

Stock Demand
Purchases by
Governments
Hoarding
Speculation
and Investment
Official Coins

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

1973

1974

1159.6

1180.3

1335.6

1339.2

1287.8

800.2

496.1

913.3
84.2
64.5

906.2
102.4
64.6

1062.6
93.6
63.9

1058.7
90.6
70.0

992.7
110.2
72.5

505.2
129.5
72.7

267.5*
93.3
65.3*

57.6

63.1

61.9

68.2

71.2

71.0

60.7

40.0

44.0

53.6

51.7

41.2

21.8

9.3

+58.8

+56.8

-61.7

-43.1

+115.4

+601.0

-619.0
+72.0
+537.0

+90.2
+60.0
-118.0

+236.4
+88.0
-432.0

-96.4
+80.0
-79.0

+ 152.4
-8.0
-91.0

-6.2
+46.0
+508.0

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

+67.8

+24.6

+45.9

+52.3

+62.0

+53.2

+293.9

* Does not include Middle East and Far East demand for these purposes.
** Includes errors in estimates of other uses.
Source: Peter D. Fells, Gold 1974 (London: Consolidated Gold Fields, Ltd., 1974), pp. 12 and 13.
E. M. Bernstein Ltd., U.S. Participation in the Free Gold Market, Report No. 75/1, p. 3.

31

+908.2**