View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The authors are Michael W. Keran, Senior Vice President and Director of Research, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, and Ahmed Abdullah Al Malik, Director of Foreign
Procurement, Ministry of Defense and Aviation of Saudi Arabia.
The authors would like to thank the officials of the Saudi Arabia Ministry of Finance and the
Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency (in particular, Dr. Omar Chapra) for their guidance in
understanding the issues. Any errors are solely the responsibility of the authors. The views
expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily the views of the Federal Reserve
System or the Saudi Arabia Ministry of Defense and Aviation.

2

Monetary Sources of Inflation
in Saudi Arabia
Table of Contents
Page
5

Introduction
I. Theoretical Link Between Money and Prices
II. Which Money to Target?-A Stable Demand Function

6

7

III. Estimating the Relation Between Money and Prices

10

IV. Controlling the Money Supply

13

Control of Reserve Money ... Automatic Controls ... The Saudi BUdget: Unique
Features ... Monetary Tools of SAMA ... From Reserve Money to Currency

19

V. Techniques of Control
Foreign Assets ... Government Deposits ... Pass-Through Certificates

VI. Summary and Conclusions

22

Appendix

24

3

4

Saudi Arabia's great oil wealth has provided
the country with a unique opportunity to helpits
citizens achieve a better life. However, along
with this opportunity, oil wealth has created
some problems. Specifically, it has contributed
t~a substantial rate of domestic inflation. Some
Saudi Arabians believe that, at the current price
of oil,. the country's reasonable investment and
consumption needs could be met with the revenue from no more than 4million barrels perday
of oil production. As this level of output isJess
than half the current level of output,it couldlead
toa substantial increase in the price of oil. This
presents the country with a dilemma. A more
prudent and efficient level of spending which
would match its absorptive capacity would require considerably less oil revenue than is currently being earned. On the other hand, a lower
level of oil production would be disruptive to the
world economy in which Saudi Arabia has an
important stake.
Conceptuaily, revenues in excess of spending
should not be a problem. The excess revenue can
be invested in foreign assets whose risk is low and
on which interest is paid. The decision as to how
much oil to produce and how much excess
revenue to acquire should depend on whether the
interest rate on holding foreign assets. gives a
better or worse rate of return than holding oil in
the ground, i.e., the decision should depend on
whether the future priceoL oil will change by
more. than the current level of interest.1
At the practical level, however, the excess of
reyenueqver spending cft)atesmaj()r.probleills.
All oil reyenul.:)S accrue directly
ment, and the ollly way that individual citizens
can. ben.efitis thtoughthe government's budgetspenqingqecisions.2\Vhen the budgetisin sub·
stantial surplus there is, as in most cOJ.l:ntries,a
strong incentivet() increasl.:) spending. As aresult,
the number of proje(;t.~ proposed in tht). budget
can easily exceed the number which can be
carefully planned, • and projects may.tenqto be

more elaborate and costly than would otherwise
be the case. At the same time, the resulting
increase in aggregate demand leads to a higher
inflation rate. This article will analyze the causes
of inflation in the unique Saudi Arabian context
where
1. Real income.is dependent (at this point in
time) upon the ability to import goods and services, rather than the ability to produce goods and
services (other than oil);
2. Governmentspending, even with a budget
surplus, can still imply stimulative fiscal policy
because most government revenue comes from
abroad; and
3. Stimulative fiscal policy leads directly toan
increase in the money supply becaUse of the
underdeveloped state of the financial markets.
Section I briefly reviews the monetary theory
of inflation, which argues that the dominant
cause of inflation. is the growth in the nominal
money supply in excess of the. real money demand. Section II considers the proper definition
of money in the institutional setting of Saudi
Arabia. It concludes that currency has the most
stable demand function and, therefore, is the best
measure of money for central-bank control.
Section 1Il looks at the empirical relationship
betwee.n money and·· prices, and shows that
currency provides the best empiricalexplanation
of inflation.•• Section IV analyzes •the balance
sheet oLtne Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency
(SAMA), and sb.owstheunique relation which
exists between government. spending (not. the
budget surplus or deficit) anqthe growth in
currency because of (1). the Joreign source· of
mostgpvernment revenue and (2) the absence of
aWeIl-deyeloped financial. market. Section Y
contil1ues .• the . analysis of the .• SAMAbalal1cl.:)
sheet, and suggests several ways in which the
growth in rnoneycan becontroIled.Section..YI
provides a detailed summaryandconclusiotl.
The non-specialistmay • wish to·. go directly .to
Section VI.

I. Theoretieall..inkBetvlleen Money and Prices
In the last few years, the central banks ?f~
number of industrial countries have been setting
targets for the growth rate of the money supply.
In general, the targets are set over a period of a
year or more. The rationale for targeting the
money supply is based on the following arguments: 1) central banks have considerable control over the money supply, in the longrun,
through the use of a standard set of central-bank
monetary tools; 2) the use of interest rates asa
policy guide is unsatisfactory in the current
period of high inflation because a change in
interest rates may be more related to changes in
inflation expectations than to current actions of
the central bank.
In its simplest form the link between money
and prices can be stated in the following equation:
P = MS md*
Where the rate of inflation (P) is equal to the
difference between the growth in nominal money supply (M·S) and the real demand for money
(md*). When the growth in nominal money
supply equals that in real money demand, prices
are stable.
In most theoretical models, the money supply
is assumed to be determined by the central bank.
The real demand for money, on the other hand,
depends on the behavior of the public. When the
central bank permits the nominal money supply
to grow faster than the public's real demand for
money, an excess supply of money is created.
This is eliminated by an increase in nominal
demand for money through a rise in the general
price level, i.e., inflation.
Conceptually, the real demand/forrn.ofiey is
made up of two elements: 1)· a transactions
demand associated with real income, and 2) a.
financial demand associated with developments
in financial markets, interest ratesandpethaps
changes in
If it is assumed that the
for money is equal to
change in real income leads
change in real
structural changes in the real demand for money
will be associated with thei financialn10tive
rather than the transactionsmotive.3Aperiodof
rapid financial innovation or financiaFgt6wth

can lead to a major change in financial demand
for money. Also, changes in the government's
reguli;ltory environment can have unexpected
effects on the demand for money.4 This suggests
that the best measure of money is one which is
dominated by the transactions motive rather
than the financial motive, because without such a
stable and predictable demand, the conse'"
quences of the money supply on inflation become uncertain. (This will be discussed further in
Section II.)
The other issue to be considered is the degree
to which the central bank can actually control
the nominal money supply. Ceteris paribus, this
is directly proportional to the central· bank's
ability to control its balance sheet. When it
purchases an asset it pays for it by issuing
liabilities, which are in effect costless to the
monetary authorities. This is because of the
central bank's government-mandated right to
print money, which is costless except for a very
modest printing charge. The process operates
directly when the central bank pays for assets
with currency. The process is indirect when the
central bank pays for assets by writing a check
against itself, thereby creating a deposit which
can only be withdrawn in the form of currency.
The degree of central-bank control of money
depends upon the degree to which the central
bank can determine the amount of its purchases
and sales of assets. To the extent that other
institutions determine the size of changes in
central-bank assets and liabilities, monetary
control is transferred to those institutions. (This
will be discussed further in Section IV.)
To summarize, the role of the money supply ill
determining inflation is now well accepted in the
economics profession: the link operate~throu~h
the differences between nominal money supply
and real money demand. MOlley demand depends upon the behaviotofthe>public;imoney
supply depends uponthe behavior of the central
bank. In choosing a monetary tatget, the central
bank attempts to determine a)\Vhichtl1e~sure>()f
money has the most stabledemand function,and
b) which measure it can most easilyconttoJ.5
We will deal with the stability of money demand in the next Section,andwithcontrollirig
the money supply in Section IV.
6

u.

WhiCIlMoney to Target?-A Stable Demand Function

International Monetary FtInd statistics present three alternative measures of the money
stock in Saudi Arabia: currency in the hands of
the rion-bank public (M o), currency plus demand
deposits of the public at commercial banks (M I),
and currency plus all deposits of the public at
commercial banks (M 2).6
U.S. readers may find the distinction between
Mo and M, artificial. However, in the Saudi
context the distinction between currency and
demand deposits is significant. Salaries are paid
in currency; virtually all household spending is
transacted in currency; small businesses pay for
their supplies in currency. Interest payments on
deposits are legally prohibited. 7 Many citizens
will hold demand deposits for their convenience
and security, but will not hold time and savings
deposits because such deposits imply an association with interest payments. As a result, demand
and savings deposits are held for similar reasons,
which are quite different from the transactions
motive associated with holding currency.
In principle, the central bank should target the
monetary aggregate with the most stable or
predictable demand function. There are two
elements which make up the real demand for
money:

mand for money because they have ptifuarily
benefited deposit-accepting financial instittitions.
The standard way to test for stability in the
real demand for alternative measures of money is
to .estimate
money-demand equation.. This
would be done by constructing a data set with.an
empirical proxy for each of the theoretical
sources of demand described above, and then
estimating the appropriate equations. The allalysis of the statistical properties of the estimated
equations would provide a basis for judging
which definition of money is most stable.

1) Transactions demand for money, determined by growth in real income; and
2) Asset demand for money, determined by a)
financial developments, and b) interest rates,
which measure the opportunity costs of holding
non-interest-earning money balances relative to
holding· interest-earning financial assets or
incofue-earning real assets.

In the present case, data limitations make the
standard approach unfeasible. Therefore, money demand will be analyzed qualitatively rather
than quantitatively.8 Transactions demand provides the centerpiece in the demand for money in
a rapidly growing economy such as Saudi Arabia. As a first approximation, transactions demand is assumed to be directly proportional to
the volume of private transactions as measured
by real non-oil GOP. For every I-percent increase in real GOP, the real transactions demand
for money will increase by I percent (see footnote 3). In Saudi Arabia, where oil income
accrues directly to the government and. is a
significant portion of GOP, the private transactions demand for money is more appropriately
measured by the level of non-oil income. This is
the income which accrues to the private sector
directly through payments of wages and other
income sources. Thisincome obviously is strongly influenced by the government oil income via
the increase in government spending.

A rise in real income would clearly increase,
while a rise inthe interest rate would clearly
decrease, the real demand for money. Fin'lncial
innovations. could. have an uncertain effect. on
demand for money. Innovations which increase
the demand for currency or deposits would lead
to an increase in moneydemand,whileinnov'l~
tions which lead to an increase in the demand for
other types of financial instruments could work
in the opposite direction. Inthe.U.S.,Jinancial
developrnentshave tended toreduce the demand
for money.. In Saudi Arabia,however, finanqi'll
developments have tended to increase thede-

Actual money balances may not always equal
desired money balances because of the lag in the
adjustments between mqney and income. This
lag can be especiallyi Portant wll~n bothmoney and income values are accelerating at a rapid
rate. Saudi Arabia .provides a good example of
this relationship (Table I). Between Hijra years
1390 and 1397-approximately equal to the
Gregorian years 1970 and 1977-the currency/
income ratio increased 63 percent. However, the
ratio increased only 8 percent when measured
with a one-year lag between the increase in
currency and the adjustment in income.

rn

7

Considerable empirical
developed and developing countries, sugg~st~
that changes in desired money balances genera;Uy
adjust to changes in actual money balances \\lith
a one-year lag. Table I and Chart 1 indicate that,
with this one-year lag, the demand forcurrenc.yis
very close to unity and thus is almost entirely
associated with transactions motives, whi1et~e
demand for M I and M 2 is much great~rt~.an
unity and thus is strongly influenced by finan~ial
developments. As the data show, the currencyincome ratio increased very little over the past
seven years, while the other two money~il1come
ratios both increased more than 50 percent.
While the stability of the currencyjincome
ratio suggests a pure transactions motive, its high
level suggests the presence also ofsomel1ontransactions motive. Holding more than 25 percent of annual income in the form of currency
seems excessive, especially in view of the factthat
the currency / income ratio is stable at around 10
percent in most other countries~bothdeveloped
and developing. Whatever thenon·transactions
motive for holding currency, however, itappears
to be proportional to the transactions motive
and unrelated to changes in financial institutions. Thus as a practical matter, we can treat
currency as if it were dominated by a pure
transactions motive.
Dr. Omar Chapra, Economic Advisor to the
Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency (SAMA), also
argues that the demand for currency has been
strongly influenced by non-transactions factors.
In his view, currency is held for its own sake as a
store of value in a period when the Saudi Arabian economy is growing rapidly. The currency
supply rises in response to increased government
spending, partially because salaries which. rise

Ratio Of Money To Non·Oil Income
.75

.50

.25

almost every. year-are paid in currency. According to this argument, the public responds by
passively increasing the share of assets held in the
form of currency-as is seen from the 120percent increase, from 15.5 riyals to 34.0 riyals,
in the average denomination of currency in
circulation in the decade ending in Hijrayear
1395 (approximately 1975).
While acknowledging that there is anontransactions element to currency demand, we
believe it is not passive. Rather, it isproportioual
to the transactions demand. For support, we may
point to two pieces of evidence which tend to
disprove the existence of an independent nontransactions component to currency. First, the
ratio of currency to non-oil income has remailled
remarkably stable in the face of a very rapid rise
in currency. Second, the average currencydenomination has increased only 120 percent,in
comparison to a 190-percent increase in the. price
level, over the past decade. The fact th~t the
currency denomination went lipless rapidlytl1an
the rate of inflation suggests that households are
not hoarding currency at any greaterrate-'--'relativeto income~than in the past. Thus any
currency hoarding is apt to be only tempora.rY,as
reflected in the one-year lag between currency
and income shown inTable I. As soon as households find more profitable alternative uses of
funds, they shift their demand to such alternative
uses.
Most studies of currency hoardihg doneelse~
where suggest that the primarynon-transactiof1s
demand for currency relates to avoidance of
taxes and other Government· restrictions on
private exchange. But the Saudi economyhasho

Table 1
Ratio of Money to Non-Oil Income
Ratio

Hijra
1390 (1970)
1397(1977)

Mj/Y
.42

1.02

Percent change
Ratio (lagged 1390 (1970)
1397 (1977)
one year)
Percent change
( 1390-97)

54%

8

significanttaxesand is extremely open andfree
with respect to private transactions. So this
incentive to hold a significant portion ofwealth
in the form of currency does not exist.
The same type of evidence, however, would
suggest that there is a strong non-transactions
motive in the demand for M I and M 2. As We have
seen, the growth rate for both monetaryaggregates was more than 50 percent greater than the
growth rate of nominal income over the past
seven years. The growth of those aggregates
apparently was related to increased demand for
financial assets in excess of the growth of real
income, i.e., financial deepening. Otherwise, the
inflation-stimulated growth of nominal income
would have been larger than actually observed,
so that the ratio of money to income would have
remained relatively stable as in the case of currency. The sharp rise in M I and M 2 balances relative toincome, or to put it another way, the fall in
velocity, suggests that the demand for deposits
rose substantially faster than transaction needs
would suggest in the last seven years.
Additional evidence can be found in the movements of the currency ratio, which reflects the
relative demand by households and .firms for
currency and deposits (Chart 2). In 1964 the
average private Saudi held approximately 1.3
riyals of currency for every riyal of deposit, but
this ratio declined by half by 1976. This suggests
a strong shift in the preferences of Saudis towards holding financial assets relative to currency. This is a natural consequence of financial
deepening, as households increase their proportionof savings in the form of financial deposits
rather than as currency.
Nonetheless, the relative importanceoHinancial and transactions demands for money does
not help us select an appropriate measure of
money. That choice does not depend on the array
ofmotives which influence the demand for money, but·· rather on our ability to. forecast·· its
movement over time.
The. financial demand for money has been
growing much more rapidly than the.transactions demand because of a major change the
perceptions of the average Saudi regarding financial institutions. Along with. the recentrapid
growth in wealth, there has been a remarkable
change in the desired composition of. wealth

Chart 2
Currency Ratio'
Ratio

1.40
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00

1.00

.90

.90

.80

.80

.70

.70

.60

.60
1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

'Ratio of currency to deposits.

holdings. The traditional forms of wealth-gold,
silver and jewelry-are being supplemented with
financial wealth in the form of domestic deposits
and foreign securities. 9
The average rate of growth in real financial
assets (i.e., deposits) has been very rapid, and has
also varied considerably over time. For example,
from 1974 to 1977 the money-income ratio
increased between 0 and 36 percent per year for
M I , and between I and 24 percent per year for
M 2, In absolute terms, bank deposits have grown
between 35 and 105 percent per year. This wide
variance in the rate at which the private sector
acquires financial assets is not surprising for a
small country which possesses a rudimentary
financial system and which is undergoing a
period of major expansion and transformation.
Shifts in government regulation can also affect
the rate of growth in the demand for financial
assets. For example,a rise in reserve requirements in.creases the cost to commercial banks of
acquiring deposits, so that they tend to offer a
lower rate of return (either in services or convenience) to depositors and, thus, discourage the
public from investing its savingsin this financial
form. At the same time, the banksarefotced to
charge relatively high fees
making .loans,
which discourages potential investorsfrom using
bank services in meeting their. needs,· Saudi
Arabia's dramatic increase in reserVe requirements in I973 (discussed below)slowedfinancial
9

development for several years. By the same
token, the reduction of current high reserve
requirements could acceleratefinancial development in the future. 1O
In summary, this section shows that the real
demand for currency (not surprisingly) is dominated by transactions considerations, while the
real demand for M I and M 2 is dominated by

financial considerations. If, as· seems likely,
Saudi Arabia's financial markets continue to
develop rapidly, but at an irregular and l.lnpred·
ictable rate, then the real demand forcurtellcy
will be more stable and thus more predictable
than the real demand for M lor M 2. This suggests
that currency is the most appropriate central
bank target for controlling the rate of inflation.

III. Estimating the Relation Between Money and Prices
In Section I we showed that the relation
between money and prices takes the following
form:

•
12
•
(CPI) = -3.3 + I 0.83 (M o)
(2.4)

. . .
P MS - md*

R' .83
DW = .64
SE = 5.25 DF 37

(13.4)

(I)

(CPI) is the rate of change of prices, and (M o) is
the rate of change of currency. The estimated
coefficient linking currency and prices is equalto
0.83 (see box). Thus, for every I-percent increase
in the growth of currency (M o) over the past 12
quarters (3 years), there is approximately an .83percent increase in the consumer price index
(CPI).'2 However, the low DW statistic (0.64)
suggests that one or more important variables
have been omitted in the explanation of inflation. Economic theory suggests two other possible influences: I) the real transactions demand
for money associated with the growth of real
income, and 2) the effects of world inflation on
domestic inflation.
Real demand for money. As discussed above,
a rise in the money supply associated with an
equal proportional rise in real demandformoney will have no impact on the domestic inflation
rate. The equation as estimated aboveimpIicitly
allows only for a constant growth in the teal
demand for money. Given Saudi Arabia's substantial increase in real income since 1973, this is
a significant omission. The problem atisesbecause there are no reliable data, other than post1970 annual data, to measure changesiinnon.oil
real income. Attempts to translate annual data
into quarterly approximations have not led to
statistically significant results.· Thus,thereaIdemand variables cannot be explicitly Introduced into the empirical model at this poinLAn

The inflation rate (P) is equal to the difference
between the growth in the nominal money supply
(MS) and real money demand (md*).ll If the real
money demand is unstable, then the relation
between MS and P would be less predictable.
In Section II we showed that the available
evidence (although fragmentary and incomplete)
suggested that the demand for currency was the
most stable of the alternative measures of money. In this section, we will attempt to measure the
relation between the growth of currency (M o)
and the inflation rate. In the Appendix, we
present similar measures of the link between M I
and M 2 and inflation.
The data problems which made it difficult to
perform standard statistical analysis of the demand for money are not as serious in this case.
Money stock and price data for Saudi Arabia are
available, on a quarterly basis, for the period
1964 to date, which provides a long enough run
of data· for statistical regression analysis.· The
simplest initial test is to compare changes inthe
nominal stock of currency with changes in the
consumer price index. Becauseit takes some time
for the price of goods to adjust to a change inthe
stockofcl.lrrency, the equation is estimated with
a lagc-oe-specifically, a 12-quartcr distributed lag,
on the basis of the price experience of the U.S.
and other countries. (All equations are estimated
with· a second-degree. polynominal distributed
lag to conserve degrees of freedom.)
10

export prices of the major industrial countries
from monthly IMF statistics)4 This index is in
dollars, which in the Saudi Arabian context is a
reasonable first approximation of world inflation. A second equation was estimated with both
the world inflation rate (Pw) and Saudi Arabian
currency growth (M o) as explanatory variables
for the domestic inflation rate (CPI). The results
are summarized below.

indirect method of dealing with this problem will
be discussed below.
World inflation. Saudi Arabia is a very open
economy with imports (including government
imports) representing a significant share of total
spending. For that reason, some would suggest
that the domestic inflation rate is primarily
determined outside the Kingdom. This proposition would seem to be overstated, especially
with respect to the consumer price index. Even if
an goods were imported, domestic prices would
not be completely determined by world prices
because imports are a "joint product," ot llm"ort_
ed goods and domestic services. When an imported good is sold to a Saudi national, he is
purchasing not simply that good but also the
domestic value added in the form of port deliveries, internal transportation, and wholesale and
retail marketing. Thus, the goods component of
the CPI represents a weighted average of foreign
and domestic value added. This said, it must
nevertheless be recognized that the Saudi Arabian economy is strongly influenced by the inflation rate in the rest of the world, especially given
the relatively fixed nature of the Saudi Arabian
exchange rate with respect to the U.S. dollaLl3
As one of the authors has shown, the world
inflation rate can be measured on the basis of

o
4
12
CPl = -5.2 + ~ 0.51(Pw) + ~ 0.70 (M o)
(5.6)
(8.0)
(16.0)
0

R2 .94
SE = 3.24

DW = 1.62
DF 35

0

(2)

In this equation, every I.O-percent increase in
world inflation over the previous four quarters
had approximately a 0.5 I-percent effect on the
Saudi Arabian price leveL
The addition of the world inflation variable
(Pw) substantially improved the statistical properties of the equation. The oR 2 which measured
the explained variance in (CPI) increased from
83 percent to 94 percent. The standard error fen
from 5.25 percent to 3.24 percent. Most important, the DW statistic increased from 0.64 to 1.62.
This substantial fall in systematic error strongly
supports the inclusion of (Pw) as an important
factor in explaining inflation in Saudi Arabia.

11

It is interesting. to note that while the coefficient value on domestic currericydeclinedsom.e~
what (from 0.83 to 0.70), the statistical signifi~
cance of that coefficient increased. (The/'t"
statistics went from 13A to -16.0)..As shown in
Chart 3, the estimated values of(CPl) matched
the actual inflation rather closely. The actual
inflation rate averaged below 5 percentperyear
through 1972, but increased sharply in 1973 and
1974 largely because of the rise in (Pw). However, it continued high in 1975-76, in spite of a
substantial fall in (Pw), because. of a rapid
acceleration in domestic currency (Chart 6).
These results might be compared with the U.S.
1964-·75 experience, where an equation of the
same nature was estimated to explain U.S.
(CPl).15 (See footnote 14.)

4

CPI

-3.6-~.3DUM+I

(3.9) (5.8)
R2:= .87
SE:= 1.11

DW:= 1.66
DF:=.4I

•

12

Chart 3
Inflation Rate ~
Actual and Estimated
Percent

40
35
30

25
20
15
10

1967

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

Without an explicit income variable, this
equation represents only an approximation of
the true relationship between world -inflation,
domestic money and domestic inflation. As such,
while it can provide confidence in the importance
of the variables being considered, it cannot
provide exact guidance on setting monetary
targets. For example, consider a case where the
world inflation rate was zero, and the underlying
growth in currency was 50 percent, that -is,
somewhat below the actual rate of currency
growth in 1976. The result would be calculated as
follows:

•

0.16Pw+I 1.49(M r)
(5.3)
(7.4)
(3)

In this equation, every LO-percent incre~sein
world inflation over the previous four quarters
had approximately a .16-percent effect on the
U.S. domestic price leveL
As Saudi Arabia is probably one of the most
open economies in the world, and the U.S. one of
the most closed in terms of ability to nr,,,,;,jp
goods and services from domestic S011rces--rlOt
in terms of pn)telctICJll!Sml-the
cient values, between O. 16 for
for Saudi Arabia, may
range of world-inflation mfluenc()s
generally. •The
cannot ignore world rneJl1etaty irlflulences
domestic
level,

Currency

Constant
term

5
5

12

Inflation
Implied
rate
Real Growth
30

20

9

II

artifact. The results reflect the fact that currency,
prices and real income have all accelerated together since J967, the periodc.overed by this
equation. This tends to bias the constant term
(thereal-income proxy) to a negative value, and
the CPl inflation/ currency coefficient belowLO.
Thus equation 2 cannot be applied "mechanically" to determine the non-inflationary growth in
currency.
The discussion to this point would suggest the

following . conclusions: First, the appropriate
monetary aggregate is currency.• Second; the
non-inflationary growth rate should be es.tablished as equal to the growth rate of the real
absorptive capacity of Saudi Arabia. That topic
is beyond the scope of this>paper. However,
casual evidence suggests that the absorption
capacity of the country hasincreasedsubstantially in recent years, and is probably in the range
of 20-to-30 percent per year in real terms.

IV. Controlling the Money· Supply
In this section, we consider what tools the
central bank has available to control the monetary aggregates. Money-supply control can be
thought of as a tWCJ~stage process which is sum- marized by the following identity:16
M
(RM)
(4)
The money supply (M) is equal to the money
l11ultiplier (m), times the level of reserve money (R M). Reservemoney is the liabilities of the
central bank to the private sector in the form
of currency (C) and bank reserves (Rb).
RM = C + Rb
(5)
The money multiplier (m) is simply theratio of
total money (M) to reserve money (RM).

m=~

RM
~
The broader measure of the money stock is
equal to currency (C) plus deposits (D). For
M I it includes only demand deposits; for M 2 it
includes all deposits at comil1ercial banks.
M=C+D
Byrearranging terms in equations 5 through 7
and multiplying both the numerator and denominator .• by (D) we get the following extended
definition of the money multiplier:

rn

m

M

wealth in deposit form rather than in currency
form. This is a symptom of financial deepening.
The reserve ratio (r) describes the behavior of the
banks with respect to their desire to hold reserves
relative to deposits (Rb/ D).
The total money supply is simultaneously
determined by the behavior of the central bank,
the commercial banks and the public. The centr~l bank's behavior is summarized. bythe movements in reserve money (RM); the behavior of
the banks and public is summarized by movements in the money multiplier (m). In Saudi
Arabia the dominant element behind the growth
in the monetary aggregates is central-bank reserve money.17 In Section II we concluded that
currency was the appropriate measure of money
for central-bank control. Thus a direct analysis
of the money multiplier is not necessary. However, itis necessary to consider control of reserve
money as a precondition for control of currency.
Control of Reserve Money
The specific tools of monetary control differ
among central banks for reasons which are
related to the institutional circumstances of each
country. For example,. in the United States, with
its large and. widely~held national. debt, the
Federal Reserve's dominant tool is buying and
selling government securities in the open market
(open-market operations). The purchase of government securities adds to Federal Reserve assets
and, therefore, increases reserve money. InJapan, with its relatively small national debt, the
dominant toolis the discountwindow.The Bank
of Japan adds to its assets byextending loans to

= C+ D
C +Rb
(8)

The currency-deposit ratio (k) describes the
behavior of the non-banking public with respect
to its desire to hold currency relative to deposits
(Cj D). (Chart 2) The currency ratio has declined
steadily over time. This reflects the incentive of
the public to hold an increasing share of
13

in Saudi Arabia.
This should not be interpreted to mean that
there are no controls on reserve money. In fact,
one automatic mechanism~the ·link between
foreign assets and government .deposits'--provides a substantial amount of control over
the growth of reserve money. In •. addition,
SAMA makes effective use of one major policy
tool, reserve requirements.

commercial banks, thereby influencing the level
of reserve money. Germany, which has neithera
large national debt nor heavy commercial~bank
indebtedness to the central bank,uses reserve
requirements as its dominant tool.
While central banks differ among themselves
with respect to the dominant monetary tool,they
agree on a common element in defining the
degree of central-bank control~that is, their
ability to determine the level of reserve money. 18
To the extent that control of reserve money is in
the hands of others, effective control of monetary policy lies outside of the
A central bank's control can be limited by
decisions made outside its jurisdiction, in numerous ways. For example, during the 1970---73
period, fixed exchange rates imposed such. a
limitation on the central banks of Western Europe and Japan. A fixed exchange-rate regime
requires that the central bank purchase all foreign assets presented to it at a fixed price in
domestic currency. During the period in question, these central banks were forced to purchase
large numbers of dollars. This increase in foreign
assets led to a parallel increase in reserve money.
Because the volume of dollars involved was
large, it was impossible to offset the impact and,
as a result, the domestic money supply in each of
the major industria! countries increased at an
unprecedented rate. This was a major contribution to the world-wide inflation of 1973~74.19
The ability of the Saudi Arabian Monetary
Agency (SAMA) to control reserve money is
directly proportional to its ability to control the
size of its balance sheet. The two dominant
elements in SAMA's balance sheet are foreign
assets and government deposits. <Considered
separately, foreign assets add to reserve morley
while government deposits reducereservemoney. When they increase together,astheytypically
do in the first instance, there will be no changein
reserve ,money. Given that foreign assets are
determined exogenously (by the price andquan~
tity of oil), and that government deposits are
determined exogenously by thebudgetactiol1sof
the fiscal authorities, there may belittle roorn for
discretionary monetary policy.20 This is a clear
case where fiscal policy and monetary policy are
not separate tools but rather a singletool.Fiscal
decisions determine the rate ofgrowth of morley

Automatic Controls
There is a very close link between the growth
of foreign assets (FA) and the growth of government deposits (GO), which acts as an automatic
stabilizer on the growth of reserve mOrley.. In
effect, the difference between (FA) and (GO)
determines reserve money. As Chart 4 shows,
three general observations can be made regarding the movement in reserve money over the
1965-76 period: I) Changes in foreign assets
induce parallel changes in government deposits,
the series moving closely together on ayear-overyear basis; 2) Foreign assets almost always increase at a somewhat faster rate than government
deposits, accounting for the modest growth in
reserve money in the 1965-7 I period; and 3) a
substantial acceleration in foreign assets (as in
1972-73 and 1975-76) is associated with a slowdown in government-deposit growth in the second year of the expansion, so that reserve money
tends to accelerate about one year after a sharp
acceleration in foreign assets.
This automatic process can be described as an
initial iQjection of reserve money and its offset in
a series of leakages. Assume, for simplicity, an
initial condition of a balanced government budget, to which is added I million riyals of oil
revenue. This will initially flow to SAM A as an
increase in both foreign assets and government
deposits. At this· stage, there is no changeirl
reserve money because the transactions are all
within the government. However, SAMA.'s larger government deposits mean that the budget is
now in surplus by I million riyals. Given the
official policy of balancingexpendituresiand
receipts, an increase ingovetnmentdepositsmay
induce an increase in spending, which transfers
government deposits to the private sector in
payment for goods and services. The decline in
government deposits will lead to an increaseirl

14

economy but, rather, the degree to which private
Saudi Arabian citizens are willing to hold their
assets abroad in foreign-currency form and to
accept foreign-exchange risk. This is an especial­
ly important constraint in the current environ­
ment of uncertainty regarding the international
value of major foreign currencies, especially the
dollar.
3.
Private purchases o f domestic financial
assets. To the extent that government spending
induces increased private savings in the form of
domestic financial assets, the decline in govern­
ment deposits at SAMA will be matched by an
increase in bank reserves to support the new
private deposits, which is the most likely form in
which domestic assets will be held.21 This would
be a leakage only if SAMA acts to control
currency—not if it acts to control M, or M2.

reserve money in the hands of the public, except
to the extent of offsetting leakages. There are
three potential leakages associated with 1) pur­
chases of foreign goods and services by the
government or private sectors, 2) purchases of
foreign assets by the private sector, and 3) pur­
chases of domestic financial assets other than
currency by the private sector.
1. Purchases o f foreign goods and services. To
the extent that government spending involves
direct purchases of foreign goods or indirect
inducement to the private sector to make such
purchases, the effect on reserve money is neutral­
ized because of a parallel reduction in foreign
assets. The major constraint here is the technical
capacity of the domestic economy to absorb
imports without creating bottlenecks. An exam­
ple is the well-publicized port congestion of 1976,
which was successfully eliminated by early 1977.
2. Private purchases o f foreign assets. To the
extent that government spending leads to an
increase in private savings, and thence to pur­
chases of real or financial foreign assets, it will
neutralize the effect on reserve money in much
the same way as imports. The constraint here is
not the technical absorptive capacity of the

The Saudi Budget: Unique Features

This discussion brings out an important and
unique feature of the Saudi Arabian Govern­
ment budget and its relation to monetary policy.
Most developing countries with rudimentary
financial systems would observe close links be­
tween the government budget and the money

Chart 4
Trillions of riyals
75

15

supply. A budget deficit would be financed by
borrowing from the central bank, leading to\an
increase in the money stock. A budget surplus
would have the reverse effect. The reasonforthis
close association is that, without a welldeveloped financial market, the only Source offin<tnc..
ing a deficit or disposing of a surplusis yiathe
central bank's money creating and cancellation
process.
Saudi Arabia is similar to other developing
countries in terms of its relatively underdeveloped financial markets. And yet in. spite ofa
substantial budget surplus, Saudi Arabi<t. has
experienced a large increase in the reserve money and currency issue of its central bank.. Thisis
contrary to what would be expected to. occur
with the large and persistent government buciget
surpluses which Saudi Arabia. enjoys.
The reason is that Saudi Arabia has been
running budget surpluses only in a narrowaccounting sense-not in a real economic sense. An
"eco/nomic" balanced budget can be defined· as a
condition in which the government demandfor
resources (spending) is equal to the governmentinduced reduction in demand for resources by
the private sector (receipts). In most countries
the accounting and economic balanced budget
can be treated as identical. This is because
government revenues are almost all acquired by
levying taxes on domestic individuals andfirm.s.
These, in turn, reduce the private demand for
resources. If spending is just equal to tax receipts, the central bank will be free from monetizing the budget deficit, and there will be no
change in reserve money from this source.
In Saudi Arabia, the accounting and economic
balanced budget are different because so large a
proportion of government revenue is paid by
non-resident foreigners as oil royalties rather
than by domestic Saudis in income or sales taxes.
In this special case, economic balance is the
equality of government spending with imports of
foreign goods, services and financial assets.
Government spending in excess of these imports
would represent a net fiscal stimulation of the
private economy, and therefore, would be exactly analogous to a budget deficit in most other
countries. This economic deficit
financed
under Saudi conditions by central
etization, which leads to the rise in

ey and currency which contributes to the rate.of
inflation.
In terms of the SAMA balance sheet,government spending appears initially as a dedinein
government deposits. There would, however,be
no increase in reserve money if it were matched
by an equal decline in foreign assets of SAMA,
i.e., imports of goods, services and foreign assets.
Thus, an economic balanced budget in the case
of Saudi Arabia would lead to a zero increasein
reserve money issued by SAMA. This is precisely
the effect of an ordinary balanced budget inmost
other countries.
Another feature which sets Saudi Arabia apart
from other high-income nations, but is common
to many developing countries, is the rudimentary
nature of its financial system. This has important
implications for monetary policy. It means that
when Saudi Arabia runs an economic deficit
there are relatively few ways in which that deficit
can be financed other than via the Central Bank.
The ability of government to finance its "deficits" via sales of its own securities directly or
indirectly to the private sector is a key element in
distinguishing monetary policy from fiscal policy. To the extent that mobilizing private domestic savings is an alternative to monetizing the
government's economic deficit, one can distinguish fiscal policy (the size of the deficit) from
monetary policy (growth of money supply).
To summarize, we may make the following
observations for the Saudi Arabian case:
I) Because of the absence of a well developed
financial system, the government budget is the
most important factor in determining the growth
in reserve money and the other measures of
money.
2) Because government revenue comes almost
exclusively from abroad rather than from domestic taxes, the appropriate definition of a
balanced budget is not that spending equals
receipts, but rather that spending equals imports
of goods, services and foreign assets. Economic
consequences exactly analogous to a budget deficit occur in Saudi Arabia when spending is in
excess of imports of goods, services and foreign
assets.
3) This economic-deficit analogy applies to
SAMA. When government spending (declinein
government deposits) is· greater than imports
16

(decline in foreign assets) there is an increase in
reserve money (see Chart 4). The central bank
mustmonetize government spending in eXcess of
imports.
4) The automatic neutralization of reserve
money from government spending via imports is
an important source of monetary stability. However, in recent years, the economic deficit has
increased as government spending has increased
faster than imports. This has led to a significant
acceleration in reserve money, currency, and
inflation. Thus, it is important for SAMA to
have· sufficient monetary tools to control the
growth in reserve money.

Chart 5
Reserve Ratio"
Ratio

Ratio
.55

.55

.50

.50

.45

.45

.40

.40

.35
.30

.30

.25

.25

.20

.20

.15

.15
1964

Monetary Tools of SAMA
Monetary control in Saudi Arabia consists of
controlling the spread between the growth of
foreign assets and governrnent deposits. Therefore, SAMA's monetary tools can be judged on
the basis of how they affect this spread.
Actually, SAMA has available only one of the
three traditional central-bank tools-reserve
requirements. Open-market operations are excluded as a potential tool of policy, partly because the large cumulative governrnent-budget
surplus has made it unnecessary to issue governmentdebt, and partly because the legal prohibition of interest payments has prevented the
development of a domestic securities market.
The discount rate is not a viable tool either,
because SAMA's charter does not allow it to
lend to commercial banks or to receive interest.
That leaves reserve requirements as the primary
monetary tool. 22
SAMA has the statutory authority to vary
reserve requirements within a range of 10 to 1712
percent of deposits. It can exceed those limits 1)
when it receives permission from the Ministry of
Finance and National Economy, or 2) when
coromercial-bank deposits exceed IS times th.e
banks' net worth. In the twenty years since
SAMA's creation, it has changed the statutory
reserve requirement only three times. 23 SAMA's
reluctance to pursue an active policy of monetary
control via reserve requirements reflects the fact
that most domestic money creation results from
government spending and loan programs, rather
than from lending and investment activities by
commercial banks,24lfmost domestic liq1;1idity is

1966

1968

1974

1976

"Ratio of bank reserves to deposits.

created outside the commercial banks, any
SAMA action to restrain their activity would
contribute to the relative decline ofthose institutions while only temporarily affecting the total
amount of liquidity. In addition, if bank loans
were an important source of private investment,
then squeezing the banks would also reduce the
production capacity of the economy.
On one occasion, however, SAMA apparently
used reserve requirements to absorb an excess
growth in reserve money. In 1972 and 1973, the
worldwide business-cycle boom greatly increased oil revenues, and thus SAMA's foreign
assets rose to what were then unprecedented
heights (Chart 4). Government deposits at
SAM A also rose proportionately in the first year
of the expansion (1972), thereby keeping the
growth in reserve money only moderately above
its average growth rate of the preceding eightyear period. But in 1973, government spending
increased ·il1·· response· to the .higher ·level of
revenue, and government-deposit growth· declined relative to
as a consequence, increased by 62 percent
1973, versus 25 percent in 1972 and the No-13
percent growth range of the preceding eight-year
period (Chart 6).
Commercial··. banks participated·. in this domestic boom with a substantial increase in deposits. While SAMA normally sets reservere~
quirements within a legal range of 10 to 1712
17

repeat.25 The theoretical maximum reserve
requirement—100 percent—would destroy the
banking system, and it would also greatly impede
the financial development which is such an
important ingredient of the economic-develop­
ment process. Thus, this powerful monetary tool
probably has already been used to the fullest
extent practical.
The reluctance of the monetary authorities to
repeat the 1973 action in the face of another rise
in reserve money is demonstrated by what oc­
curred in 1975-76. This was almost a repeat of
the 1972-73 story, except that all the numbers
were scaled up by a factor of ten due to a
dramatic rise in the price of oil. The large in­
crease in oil revenues which commenced in early
1974 led to an unprecedented rise in SAMA’s
foreign assets, and this led in 1974 and early 1975
to a proportional unprecedented rise in govern­
ment deposits (Chart 4). But after mid-1975,
government-deposit growth fell behind the
growth of foreign assets, and reserve money
accelerated once again.This time,while there was
a small rise in dejure reserve requirements,there
was no change in de facto reserve requirements
and no exceptional increase in the demand for
reserves by commercial banks. As a result, cur­
rency, M, and M2 all increased in line with the
accelerated growth in reserve money (Charts 6
and 7).

Chart 6
Components of Reserve Money
— Liabilities to the Public

percent, it can raise the requirement to 50 percent
for any bank whose deposits exceed 15 times that
bank’s net worth. Previously, when deposit
growth approached the 15-times-net-worth lim­
it, SAMA under its statutory authority permit­
ted banks to increase their capitalization, so that
they could avoid the higher marginal-reserve
requirements. It apparently did not follow this
path in the 1972-73 period, however, and the
ratio of reserves to deposits (r) thus went from an
average of .16 in 1971 to .22 in 1972 and to more
than 0.50 in the third quarter of 1973 (Chart 5).
SAMA later permitted some banks to increase
their capitalization, and the reserve ratio then
declined to about 0.40.
The de facto increase in reserve requirements
increased the demand for reserves by 90 percent
in 1972 and by more than 200 percent in 1973
(Chart 6). This absorbed much of the excess
growth in reserve money generated by the in­
crease in government spending, so that the cur­
rency increase was held to 15 percent in 1972 and
25 percent in 1973. The growth in M , and M2was
also held below what would be implied by the
expansion in reserve money (Chart 7).
This de facto rise in reserve requirements was
clearly successful in restraining the potentially
inflationary expansion in reserve money from
being transmitted to the monetary aggregates.
However, this action, once taken, is hard to

Chart 7
Reserve Money And M2

18

From· Reserve Money to Currency
While the discussion above has focused on the
control of reserve money, our primary interest is
the control of currency. Reserve money equals
currency plus bank reserves, so that targeting the
growth of currency means that SAMA should
accommodate increases in the demand for bank
reserves, but not increases in the demand for
currency.26
Once control of reserve money has been
achieved, there are few additional technical
problems involved in controlling currency. All
that is needed is information on the break-down
of reserve money between currency and bank

v.

reserves. As reserves playa more important role
in supporting financial deepening, they could be
allowed to grow unhindered. A currency target
could be achieved in the same way as a reservemoney target, i.e., by controlling the spread
between foreign assets and government deposits.
The growth in bank reserves, treated as a potentialleakage, would probably permit a somewhat
faster growth in reserve money than in currency.
Data on bank reserves are available from
commercial-bank reports made to SAMA, with
a relatively short time lag. Thus currency data
could be determined as the difference between
reserve money and bank reserves.

Techniques of Control

In the preceding section, we showed that
control of reserve money and currency required
control of foreign assets, or of government
deposits in the SAMA balance sheet. A number
of possible control techniques are considered
below.
Foreign Assets
Given the importance of oil revenues, the only
way that foreign assets can be controlled is by
inducing the private sector of the economy to
exchange domestic assets for foreign assets or
goods. Purchase of foreign goods is constrained
not by government controls but by the capacity
of the economy to absorb additional goods and
services. This is the most important limit in the
growth of real income, and thus is the main
factor in targeting currency growth. The private
Saudi purchase of foreign assets is independent
of the absorptive capacity of the Saudi economy,
but is constrained by the degree of foreignexchange risk people are willing to take. SAMA
could provide various incentives to encourage
private Saudis to increase their foreign-asset
holdings, and thus reduce proportionately SAMA's own holdings offoreign assets. SpecificalIy, this could be done by denominating government foreign contracts in foreign currency, or by
encouraging the development of financial institutions to invest private Saudi funds abroad.
Denominating foreign contracts in both foreign and local currencies. Present practice in
Saudi Arabia differs from one ministry to another and from one contractor to another. Since the

budget is defined in local currency, it is easier for
the government to control its spending ifforeign
contracts also are defined in local currency.
Without this provision, a change in the exchange
rate could cause the government's budgeted
spending to be in error. Problems could arise
from local-currency denomination because payment in riyals would add to private liquidity as
government deposits with SAM A are transferred to private ownership. At first blush the
problem would seem to be minimal, occurring
only if foreign contractors kept their receipts in
riyals for an extended period of time. To the
extent that most foreign contractors would convert into foreign assets of SAMA, parallel with a
decline in government deposits, this would neutralize the effect on reserve money.27
But where an appreciation of the riyal is
expected, the payment of foreign contractors in
riyals could lead to a substantial increase in
domestic liquidity as they maintained riyal balances and borrowed foreign exchange to cover
their expenses. These considerations suggest the
advantages of denominating foreign contracts in
foreign currency, especially dUring periods of
intense speculation about riyal appreciation,
because this course would provide better control
of the domestic money supply and hence of
inflation. However, by denominating foreign
contracts in foreign currency, any change in the
exchange rate would create errors in the government's budget and spending plans.!t is difficult to
determine whether the advantage of improved
19

control over inflation would outweigh the disad~
vantages arising from denominating foreign
contracts in foreign currencies. 28
Encouraging foreign investment· by Saudi
nationals. Private capital outflows, as we have
seen in recent years, represent an important way
of reducing SAMA's foreign assets. However,
the incentive to invest abroad is weakened in any
period of exchange-rate uncertainty, such as the
present. The government could take several
actions to counter this uncertainty, such .as
absorbing part of the exchange risk involved or
developing new institutions to channel funds
abroad.
The government could absorb part of the
foreign-exchange risk involved in foreign investment by guaranteeing all or part of the domestic-currency value of foreign assets. Such a
guarantee could be potentially costly to the
government, but perhaps no more so than other
transfer payments that are designed to add to the
wealth of the public. For example, the government provides a housing subsidy in the form of
long-term, zero-interest-rate loans in which only
80 percent of the value need be repaid. A foreignexchange subsidy would have the added advantage of not straining-as a housing subsidy
does-the already heavy demand for real goods
and services within Saudi Arabia. However, with
a foreign-exchange subsidy, the goverment could
be criticized for apparently encouraging investment abroad rather than at home-even though
the major hindrance to domestic investment is
the lack of ability to import additional real
resources. In any event, the proposal for a
foreign-exchange subsidy is probably premature
at this stage.
Alternatively, the government could provide
increased information regarding foreign-investment opportunities, and even support financial
institutions which act as conduits for investing
private funds abroad. Such a step,withoutat
least partial coverage of foreign-exchange risks,
would probably not stimulate increased savings
in the form of foreign securities. But any success
in transferring private domestic assets into foreign assets would reduce SAMA's foreign-asset
holdings.
Increasing the incentive of the private sector to
invest abroad could not be considered a "fine-

tuning" technique of controlling reserve money,
because this approach requires the voluntary
cooperation of private persons in controlling the
level of foreign assets on a continuing basis.
Thus, while foreign-asset control is an important
tool, it is also blunt-analogous to the use of
reserve requirements to control the money supply in the U.S.
Government Deposits
The control of government deposits represents the only fine-tuning technique for controlling the currency issue of SAM A. The reason
is quite simple: the government can unilaterally
determine the level of these deposits. Thus, once
the Council of Ministers decrees a given currency
issue, the decision can be implemented directly
via control of government deposits at SAMA.
This policy tool is highly flexible, and can be
fine-tuned in a way analogous to open-market
operations in the U.S. The government can
operate in either of two ways: directly, via control of government spending, or indirectly, via
mobilization of domestic private assets.

Controlling government spending. One approach would be to develop a "monetary" budget
parallel to the normal spending and loan budget.
Budget makers would determine the target
growth in currency, and would then look at the
government spending budget to see if leakages
into imports, foreign assets and domestic assets
(other than currency) would lead to a growth in
currency which is consistent with the target. In
Section 1V, we showed that these three leakages
between government spending and the currency
growth act as an automatic control on the
growth of currency. Thus, given a currency
target and knowledge of the leakages, one can
target government spending to hit a currency
target with some small margin of error. If for
whatever reason the government-spending target
is not realized, the resulting excess growth in
currency could be calculated and the consequences for domestic inflation determined.
The necessary institutions for controlling currency growth are already in place. The Council of
Ministers currently must approve the size of any
SAMA currency issue. At present, if SAMA
issues more currency than expected within a
given time period, the Council will generally
20

authorize a further issue of currency as a matter
of routine. In other words, any error is treated as
a simple forecasting error, representing an overor under-estimate of the growth of the economy.
But if policy makers perceived that currency
growth was not simply a consequence of domestic growth, but rather a major cause of domestic
inflation, they could utilize this same procedural
mechanism to make the currency target a matter
of high policy.
Mobilizing private savings. A second approach would be to finance government spending by borrowing from the public so that there
would be no need to draw down government
deposits at SAMA. This isthe type of "leakage"
used by developed countries to finance government spending. Indeed, this is the very technique
used to separate monetary policy (control of
money) from fiscal policy (government budget).
In Saudi Arabia. however, ther~ would be
several problems with such an approach. First, it
might seem strange if a government with a large
budget surplus were to "borrow" money to meet
its expenditures. The action could bejustified on
the basis that because government revenue
comes from abroad, any government spending
which is not directed at foreign purchases will be
analogous to running a government deficit in the
United States. This "deficit" should be financed
by domestic savings if it is to avoid adding to
inflation.
A second and more substantial problem would
be the government's inability, for legal and
religious reasons, to pay interest on its securities.
The problem may not be insurmountable, for
reasons discussed below. Even if such securities
could be made acceptable to the public, they
could increase the pr\:1ssure on the governmentto
raise its spending even further, because the
statistical budget surplus would remain large.
And with increased government spending, we
woulctbe faced again with the original dilemma.
This particular proposal thus is not technically
viable, but it does point to an important potential avenue of monetary control, i.e., providing
the private sector with a secure and risk~free
asset. Such an asset would be in great demand in
this financially conservative country. It would
also tend to legitimize financial assets generally,
in a land where the public suspicion of banks is

still strong. All that is needed, as discussed
below, is a technically feasible way of mobilizing
private savings to achieve the desired monetarypolicy goal.
Pass-Through Certificates 29
A potentially useful method of controlling
curr9ncy, combining elements of both foreignasset control and government deposits, would
involve the use of "pass-through certificates".
These certificates would. operate as follows:
I. SAMA would establish a special passthrough account, to which it would transfer a
certain share of its foreign assets.
2. SAMA would stand ready to sell riyaldenominated pass-through certificates in an
amount equal to the local currency value of the
foreign assets in the special account. If these
certificates were purchased by the government,
they would be paid for by a reduction in government deposits at SA MA, with no initial effect on
reserve money or currency. If the certificates
were purchased by the public, they would be paid
for by both currency and checks, which (via a
reduction in bank reserves) would reduce the
amount of reserve money and currency in the
hands of the public.
3. These certificates would not pay interest
directly, but would simply "pass-through" the
income received by SAMA on the foreign assets
in its special account. In addition, because the
certificates are denominated in local currency,
there would be no foreign-exchange risk to the
purchaser. 30 These characteristics would make
the pass-through certificates desirable to hold by
the public.
4. Government purchases of these certificates
would not immediately affect the level of reserve
money, because the reduction in government
deposits at SAMA would be matched by an
equal and opposite increase in the number of
pass4hrough certificates which SAMA would
"warehouse" for the government. However, in
the event that the government runs a budget
deficit at some future time, the pass-through
certificates would provide a method of financing
other than through SAMA. The government
could sell its pass-through certificates to the
public in an amount equal· to its deficit. This
would be non-inflationary because the funds
21

in government deposits at SAMA-financed,in
effect, by a money-creation process which would
represent a net increase in public liquidity in the
form of reserve money. Thus, the current procedure potentially could be far more inflationary
than the pass-through certificate proposal.

which the government would put into the economy would be matched by funds withdrawn via
public purchase of certificates from the government. This procedure can be contrasted with the
current situation, where any government budget
deficit would be financed by a simple reduction

VI. Summary and Conclusions
Saudia Arabia represents an interesting test
case of the role of monetary factors in inflation.
It would seem on the. surface to be the least likely
country to show any such influence, because: 1)
imports make up a very significant share of total
goods and services available, and 2) government
spending is the dominant source of changes in
domestic aggregate demand.
The first proposition suggests that developments in the rest of the world, rather than
domestic factors, largely determine the domestic
inflation rate. The second proposition suggests
that where domestic factors are involved, they
should be due to fiscal rather than monetary
policy.
This study has shown, nonetheless, that domestic monetary policy plays a significant role in
determining the domestic inflation rate. The
difference between the forces determining inflation in Saudi Arabia and in the world's major
industrial countries is only one of degree and not
of kind. For example, in Section 111, we showed
that identical equations can be used to explain
the Saudi Arabia and U.S. inflation rates. These
factors consist of 1) the expansion in the domestic money supply over the previous three-year
period, and 2) the current rate of inflation in
world prices, measured by export prices of the
major industrial countries. The only difference
between the Saudi and U.S. equations is the
somewhat greater influence of world prices, and
the somewhat lower influence of domestic mone_
tary developments, upon the Saudi Arabian
inflation rate. This. of course, is to be expected
because Saudi Arabia is a much more open
economy than the U.S. Nevertheless, Saudi
Arabia can significantly influence its domestic
inflation through control (if it chooses to exercise it) of its domestic money supply.
Three monetary aggregates represent potential candidates for targeting---M o (currency), M 1

(M o plus demand deposits) and M 2 (M 1 plus
quasi-monetary deposits). Our results suggest
that currency is the best of the three as a control
vehicle. M I and M 2 growth are both strongly
influenced by financial developments which are
not necessari~y associated with inflationary
pressures. They may instead reflect thegrowth of
financial intermediation and thus the financial
deepening of the Saudi economy. The demand
for currency, on the other hand, does not appear
to be strongly associated with financial development, but rather is related to transactions needs,
i.e., increases in aggregate demand.
To achieve stable domestic prices, policymakers should choose a target growth rate for currency which is roughly equal to the growth in the
real demand for currency-that is, roughly equal
to the growth in the nation's real income. Given
her vast wealth of oil in the ground and foreign
financial assets, Saudi Arabia's real-income
growth is primarily a function of the "absorptive
capacity" of the economy, which may be in the
range of 20 to 30 percent per year. This would
suggest that currency growth could be in the
same range without adding significantly to inflation pressures.
As explained in Section IV, the major factor influencing the growth of currency is government spending. Spending will lead directly to
increased currency issue unless there is a leakage
of spending, either abroad into foreign purchases
or domestically into purchases of financial assets. The relation between government spending
and currency is unique to Saudi Arabia, because
government revenue derives from oil sales
abroad rather than from domestic taxes. Government spending, when it leads to foreign purchases, is analogous to other countries' use of
domestic tax receipts to finance their spending.
But government spending, when not matched by
foreign purchases, is analogous to other coun22

tries' use of the budget-deficit mechanism
finance their spending.
Saudi Arabia, like many other developing
countries, ·dm finance· only a· relatively . small
amottnt of its government "deficit" from domestic savings because of the rudimentary nature of
its financial system.· In these circumstances, the
central ba.nk must monetize most of the
"deficit"~Which in Saudia Arabia's case means
all government spending that is not diverted into
foreign purchases (including purchases
the
private sector).· This situation occurs even
though the government budget is in surplus
standard accounting rules.
The process described above can be explained
in terms of the SAMA balance sheet. Government spending will be reflected in a decline in
government deposits atSAMAWhich if matched
by an increase in foreign purchases will lead to an
equal decline of SAMA foreign assets. This will
neutralize the effect on the currency issue. If not
matched by an increase in foreign purchases, the
deposit decline will lead to a rise in SAMA's
other liabilities, either in the form of currency or
bank reserves. If matched by an increase in bank
reserves,· the deposit decline will reflect the
financing of government spending by the de
facto mobilizing of private domestic financial
assets. (Bank reserves at SAMA would rise
because of a rise in bank deposits from the
public.) Finally, if not matched by a decline in
foreign assets or increase in bank reserves, the
government-deposit decline would necessarily
lead to a rise in SAMA's currency issue.
Until now, SAM A has relied upon changes in
reserve requirements as its major monetary tool.
With this weapon, it influences the currency issue

For example, a rise in reserve requirementscausescommercial banks to increase their
demand for reserves, and thus sterilizes
IS

weaken the banking
playing its
process of
Indeed, de
facto reserve requirements are now between 40
and 50 percent, so that it would
to use
this tool any further to control the currency
issue.
In this situation, we make three specific proposals designed to improve Saudi Arabia's program of currency control, and hence of inflation
control.
I. Set a target growth of currency equal to the
real growth rate of the economy.
2. Control government spending. so that it
conforms with the targets established for currency growth.
3. Encourage private purchases of foreign
assets in amounts which are consistent with the
economy's domestic financial needs, through the
development of such techniques as pass-through
certificates. (See Section V.)
Reducing inflation is never an easyorcostless
task,
Saudi Arabia or any other country.
However, the costs of inflation are very high.
Policy makers at the highest level of government
must determine for themselves whether the benefits of reduced inflation are worth the costs
involved.

23

Appendix
Alternative MeaSUres of Money and Inflation
reason for the difference is clear. M j and M 2 have
grown more rapidly than currency, and thus the
coefficient which describes how a I-percent
change in money affects inflation will be lower
for M 1 and M 2 than for currency. The theoretical
reason concerns the added financial demand for
M j and M 2 , which has been greater than the
purely transactions demand for currency. Thus
the same increase in M j and M 2 would have a
smaller
on inflation.
If we were confident that the coefficient value
would remain constant in the future, we could
use M 1 or M 2 as a monetary target. However,
such confidence is unwarranted because of the
actual and potential variance in the financial
demand for M j and M 2 , as described in Section
II. Added variance would increase the variance
in the coefficient relating money to inflationand thus would increase uncertainty regarding
targeted money growth and hence inflation.
Even the currency coefficient is biased downward, not because of financial demand but
because of a substantial but unmeasurable rise in
transactions demand since 1974. In the case of
currency, we can assume on theoretical grounds
that the appropriate coefficient value will be
l.O-which we cannot do in the case of M 1 and
M 2 • Consequently, currency is the best monetary
indicator.

The evidence presented in Section II suggested
that currency was the best monetary aggregate
for monetary control, because its demand. was
more stable than the other aggregates, MI and
M 2 • In Section III, we showed thatthe relationship between changes in currency and inflation
was statistically significant. Below we present
identical equations for M j and M 2 •

M j and Inflation
•

(CPI)

4

= -3.2 + k
(3.7)

•

0.45 (Pw)
(6.7)

12

•
0.52 (M j )
(15.4)

12

•
0.57 (M 2)
(15.4)

+k

2

R = .93 DW = 1.63
SE = 3.27 DF = 35

M 2 and Inflation
•

(CPI)

4

= -5.4 + k
(5.7)

•

0.51 (Pw)
(7.8)

+k

R 2 = .93 DW = 1.63
SE = 3.25 DF = 35

In terms of overall statistical properties, the
M j and M 2 equations are only slightly inferior to
the CUfiency equation. However, the key cliffer-.
ence is in the value of the coefficient-.52 for M 1
and .57 for M 2 , compared with the significantly
higher .70 value for currency. The statistical

24

mand deposits and, therefore, the demand for the M1
measure of money.

FOOTNOTES
1. For example, if the price of oil were expected to
appreciate by 5 percent per year, then a risk·free
interest rate of 5 percent would just matchtherat~ of
return between oil in the ground and money in the bank.
Changes in the inflation rate do not affect this calculation as long as the price of oil and the rate of interest are
calculated in the same currency, such as the U.S. dollar.

5. These criteria are not mutually exclusive. Instability
in the public's demand for money can reduce the
central bank's ability to control the money sl.lpply,
depending on th~ definition chosen. For example, if the
demand for deposits unexpectedly increases relative to
the demand for currency, the money multiplier ~~tween
central-bank assets and the total money stock will
change in an unanticipated way. This would impair the
central bank's ability to control the money-supply
measure which includes deposits.

2. Because oil revenues accrue only to the government, the only way to increase real income of the public
is by increasing the prices of the things they sell, or by
decreasing the prices of the things they buy. For the
country as a whole, this requires a rise in the price of
domestic (or non-traded) goods relative to the price of
foreign (or traded) goOds. There are only two waysthis
can happen: 1) exchange rate appreciation, which
would transfer real purchasing power from the government to the public by reducing the domestic currency
valuebf government oil revenue, and increasing the
foreign purchasing power of privately held domestic
currency; or 2) government spending with a fixed exchange rate, achieved either by (a) government transfer
payments to individual Saudis with no increase in direct
government purchases of goods and services, or (b)
government spending via purchases of goods and services.
Both of these approaches would increase the nominal purchasing power of the private sector and, given an
inelastic supply of domestic non-tradeables such as
land, drive up its price. Because foreign (or tradeable)
goods have an elastic supply, the price would not rise
except as scarce domestic (I.e., Saudi Arabia) resources
are added in the process of delivering imports to the
public. Alternative 1 could be achieved without inflation. Alternative 2 would lead to some domestic inflation. The actual approach followed in Saudi Arabia is
closest to 2b \Nith some elements of 2a. ,.d,!ternative
number 1 apparently has been rejected because, while
it would have increased total real income, most of
the benefit would have gone to those with the greatest
wealth. This was considered undesirable, as it would
not contribute to reducing the inequality of income
distribution.

6. This measure of money could also reasonably be
called M3 because in the International. Financial Statistics OFS), the "other deposit" category pr "quasimoney" represents deposits of. all financial institutions.
However, non-bank financial institutions are relatively
minor in scope in Saudi Arabia, or statistics are not
available on their deposit balances. The latter in.cludes
such important financial institutions as moneychangers, as well as banks located outside Saudi Arabia which accept deposits and make loans in riyal".inside the country.
7. The legal system of Saudi Arabia is based onastrict
interpretation of the Islamic Law, in which all interest
payments are considered usury.
8. The legal Prohibition of interest payments means
that interest-rate data are not available. Real income
data are available only on an annual basis from 1970 to
1976.
9. Banks have both responded to and helped develop
this new financial wealth preference by opening new
branches in many of the towns and villages where there
were no financial institutions in the past. This has
helped to breakdown the old suspicion of banks in.the
minds of many People,whofind that deposits are more
secure than domestic stores of gold and silver, and
equally convenient when needed. There has, of course,
been a substantial increase in the absolute quantity of
traditional forms of real wealth, but because of the large
increase in total wealth this is consistent with a morethan-proportionate increase in new financial forms of
wealth. Judging by the stable ratio of currency to
income, relatively little of this switch in asset holding is
going into currency.

3. The assumption of a unitary transactions demand
for money is not unreasonable on the basisof long-term
U.S. data which underlie most of the work on this
subject. Post-World War II data, especially data for the
decade since the mid-1960's, suggest a less than unitary transactions demand for money. See David Legler's "The Demand for Money" for a further discussion
of this issue. John Scadding has shown,however, that
the Post-WWII result may be specious. The period is
one of higher average inflation~and, therefore, higher
interest rates which tend to reduce the transactions
demand for money. However, Scadding shows when
you account for the increased implicit interest paid on
money balances, you get a transactions demand coefficient which is close to one, even With post~WWH data.

10. The discussion in this paragraph assumes tharallof
the increase in the observed reserve ratio is due to a
change in de facto reserve requirements. Alternatively,
it could represent a change in desired excesS reserVes
of the banking system. The available data do notallow
us to discriminate between these alternative hypoth~ses,bec<luse required reserves vary with each
parlk's capital-deposit ratio. HO\Jllever,. circumstantial
evidence sl.lpp()rts the .reserve •requir~rnent~.x.plana­
tion.· TypfcallY,tye •demaj1d for excess reserves in-

creases in a period of increased risk and economic
uncertainty. ThiS was the U.S. experience during the
GreatDepression oHhe1930's.But this hardly describes the economic experience of Saudi Arabia in the
1970's.

4. two recent regulatory changes in the U.S. have
substantially affected the demand for money: (1) the
November, 1975, regulation which permitted corporations to hold savings deposits, and (2) the November,
1978, regulation which permitted individuals to make
automatic transfers between their demand and savings
deposits. Both actions reduced the real demand for de-

11. This relationship can be restated in the familiar
Fisher equation of exchange:

MV

25

PT

Money (Ml times velocity (Vl equals the price level (Pl
times volume oftransactiof1StTJ.Rearrangingtheterrns
and taking the rate of change would give the f(jlloWing
transformed equation:

p= M+V
By assuming unity forT, the transactions demand, then
V can be considered the financial demand for money.
This is substantially the same equation as presented in
the text.
12. Because of the unique characteristics of Saudi
Arabian.data, year-over-year changes rather than
quarter-to-quarter rates of change are used inmeasuring all time series in this paper. Saudi Arabia follows the
lun.ar calendar with 12 months, but its year is 1.1 days
shorter than the Gregorian calendar year. There are
procedures which allow for transformation oftheHijrayear statistics into Gregorian-year statistics. However,
seasonal variations in Saudi Arabia are largely related
to religious observances-such as Ramadan, which
occurs in the same month each year in the Hijracalendar, but which may shift from summer to winter when
corrected to the Gregorian calendar. The standard
seasonal adjUstment programs have difficUlty dealing
with such "floating" seasonals. Also, seasonal dummies
cannot be used in the non-seasonally adjusted data
because seasonal changes move from year to year
when translated into the Gregorian calendar, This
violates the assumption that the coefficient values are
constant over the sample period. Tlie orilyeffecti"e
seasonal-adjustment technique in this case is yearover-year changes. This procedure allows for the gradual movement of the (statistically significantl seasonal
religious holidays, and does less violence to the assumption of stable coefficient values over the sample
period. While year-over-year percent changes have
problems of their own, they represent less severe constraints than quarter-by-quarter percent changes.
13. Between December 1~70 and December 1973, the
riyal appreciated by 5 percent, i.e., from 4.50 riyal~per
dollar to 4.28 riyals per doliCir. From December 1973 to
December 1977, the riyal appreciated an additional 3.2
percent to 4.148 riyals per dollar. These changes are
small relative to the 100-percent increase in the dollar
price of internationally-traded goods between 1970 and
1977.
14. Michael W. Keran, "Stabilization Policies in a World
Context," Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
Economic Review, Fall 1976.
15. In this equation M1 is the U.S. money supply (currency plus demand deposits). DUMisadummyvariCible
to account for the period of price controlsfrorn 1971.4
to 1972.4.
16. One of the authors
sis for Saudi
See
The Money
5 and6 (1970l, Universitv
17. The evidence behind this proposition is dis<:ussed
below. Chart 6 shows the strong associationpetween
RM and currency, while ChCirt 7 shows the link between
RM and M2.The major exception is 1973, which is
explained below.
18. The concept of reserve money has a long history in
monetary analysis. Irving Fischer (1896) called it simply

"money"; James Tobin (1960l called it the "demand
debt of the government"; Milton Friedman and Anna
Schwartz (1963l called it "high-powered money"; Karl
Brunner and Allan Meltzer (1968) called it the "monetary
base." The IMF uses the term "reserve money" in its
monthly statistical publication from which the data in
this article are drawn.
19. Michael W. Keran, "Towards an Explanation of
Simultaneous Inflation-Recession," Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, Economic Review, Spring 1975.
20. The Ministry of Petroleum and the Ministry of
Finance jointly prepare estimates of the government's
annual revenue, on the basis of data they receive frorn
oil companies and the government's policy regarding
quantity of oil production. Since the budget is always
balanced, then anticipated revenue must equal anticipated expenditure. However, actual expenditures may
fall below expectations, because of procurement delays caused by such factors as manpower bottlenecks.
The end result is a surplus in the budget, which is added
to the General Reserve and thus leads to a rise in
government deposits. In recent years, the gap between
anticipated and actual expenditures has narrowed, but
it is still positive.
21. In contrast to the first two leakages, this would have
less than a one-to-one impact on reserve money; that is,
R1 ,000,000 of government spending leading to an equal
increase in deposit savings would increase bank reserves by only about R500,OOO, because the marginal
reserve requirement is about 50 percent. The remainder
would eventually go into currency holdings, as the bank
receiving the deposits loaned them out.
22. On several occasions, SAMA has used another
monetary tool-direct loans to commercial banks
through transfer of government deposits. In 1961,
SAMA transferred SR 25 million of government deposits from its Banking Department to the commercial
banks, and in 1964, it reversed this process by withdrawing SR 26 million of government deposits from the
commercial banks. See The Money Supply Process in
Saudi Arabia (Ch. 7) for further discussion of this
monetary tool.
23. Reserve requirements were originally established
in December 1957 at 15 percent of total deposits (demand plus time), The ratio was lowered to 10 percent in
May 1962, but an additional liquidity ratio of 20 percent
was then added, with the funds to be held in theformof
vault cash, deposits with SAMA, or deposits with foreign banks. In November 1966, the reserve requirement
on time deposits was lowered to 5 percent-Finally, in
June 1976, the statutory reserve requirement was
raised to 15 percent on both time and demand deposits.
24. In private correspondence and discussion, Dr.
Omar Chapra (Economic Advisor to SAMA) makes this
point explicitly. "The crux ofthe money supply problem
is not that SAMA is unable to influence the quantity and
quality of bank credit, but that changes in such credit
have constituted such a small proportion of total
credit."
25. In one sense the change in reserve requirements is
constantly working-there is a permanently lower level
of money and thus prices. However, from the point of

view 0fr)1on.(;ltar¥cont~OI, each change in reserve
requirements is a single influence on the rate of change
of money and thus on the rate of inflation.

tween foreign contractors and SAMA, in the latter case
would earn something on the spread between buying
and selling rates for riyals. With riyal-denominated
contracts, there would bean inCrease inreservemoney equal to the earnings on these transactions. This
would not occur if contracts were denominated in foreign currencies.

26. This wquldappear to be the reverse of the behavior
of most other central banks, where currency is accommodated and bank reserves are controlled. However,
emphasis should be put on the word apparent. There is
no technical reason why any central bank could not
target and control currency growth. But it is generally
not desirable to do so, because: 1) the public in most
countries treat currency and various classes of bank
deposits as highly substitutable in terms of usefulness
in meeting transactions needs, and 2) the financial motive for holding deposit balances is a relatively stable
and predictable function of income and interest rates.
On both counts, it makes more sense to control an M1
or M2 measure in countries which show these characteristics. In Saudi Arabia, however, neither of these
conditions holds and, thus, it makes more sense to
control currency.

28. Some contracts are currently denominated in both
foreign and domestic currencies. The government and
the contractors denominate a certain percentage in
local currency to cover the contractor's estimate of his
local expenditure, and the rest is denominated in foreign currency.
29. An earlier version of this proposal was suggested
by John Scadding, 1978 Visiting Scholar at the Federal

Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
30. The foreign-exchange risk would be borne by

SAMA, which would have both a foreign-asset and a
local-currency liability. However, SAMA would experience no greater risk than it currently does in having its
assets in foreign exchange and its liabilities (largely
government deposits) in local currency.

27. The only difference between riyal- and foreigncurrency denomination of contracts from a monetary
point of view would be the different impact on commercial banks. The banks, acting as intermediaries be-

The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco's Economic Review is published quarterly by the
Bank's Research and Public Information Department under the supervision of Michael W. Keran,
Senior Vice President. The publication is edited by William Burke, with the assistance of Karen Rusk
(editorial) and William Rosenthal (graphics).
For free copies of this and other Federal Reserve publications, write or phone the Public
Information Section, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco,
California 94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.

27