View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE REAGAN
ECONOMIC PROGRAM
James Tobin
Robert Hall
Presentation at Economic Seminar
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

San Francisco, California
May 1, 1981

This publication, a supplement to the San Francisco Federal Reserve Bank’s Economic Review,
is a transcript of the Economic Seminar presented at the Bank on May 1, 1981. The comments
presented here represent the authors’ personal views, and do not represent the views of the man­
agement of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. Copies of this publication are available on request to the Public Infor­
mation Section, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco CA
94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.

Table o f C ontents
Opening Remarks

4
John J. Balles and Michael W. Keran

The Reagan Economic Plan —

Supply-side, Budget and Inflation
James Tobin

The Reagan Economic Plan —

Discussion

5

15
Robert Hall

Comments by Speakers

19
James Tobin and Robert Hall

General Discussion

21

Opening Remarks
John J. Balles and
Michael W. Keran*
since in this way I get my intellectual batteries
recharged from time to time.
Our principal speaker today, as you know, is
Professor James Tobin, Sterling Professor of
Economics at Yale University. Professor
Tobin hardly needs an introduction to a group
like this; still, I'm going to give a few highlights. Throughout his long career - his first
published paper appeared 40 years ago this
month in the Quarterly Journal ofEconomics Professor Tobin has been interested in the
impact of public policy on the macro economy,
and especially on the twin problems of inflation and unemployment. (That first paper, for
example, concerned the impact of a general
wage change on employment and the price
level.) Over the years he's made distinguished
contributions in economics, always seeking to
maintain a balance between theoretical rigor
and empirical relevance-trying to avoid both
measurement without theory,' and theory
without empirical implications. This concern
with the real world, the political economy in its
broadest sense, has also made him a valued
advisor to presidents and to seekers of the
presidency. And as you well know, he served
20 years ago as member of the President's
Council of Economic Advisers. He's been particularly active in the area of macroeconomics
most relevant to the Federal Reserve-the
structure of financial markets, and the links
between the Fed's policy actions and the real
economy via the banking system. The moneymarket models we use today to guide Fed
policy owe a great deal to the pioneering work
of Tobin and generations of his students, many
of whom have found their way into the Federal
Reserve System. We're fortunate to have him
with us today to discuss the President's economic-policy package. Perhaps he'll also have
something to say about the role of the Federal
Reserve in dealing with the nation's economic
problems. I'm happy to introduce to you Professor James Tobin.

Keran. We would like to welcome you to
the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco's
Economic Series-a lecture series which has
been going on for the past seven and one half
years. The series has been designed to bring
together in one place people from diverse
backgrounds-academia, the business community and the financial community-with a
common interest in public-policy issues. We
hope that, with this joining of minds, we will
all learn something useful.
Today's seminar is a special one-partly
because we have not one, but two speakers.
The only previous occasion of this type was
four years ago, when we had a debate on the
monetafist controversy by Professor Franco
Modigliani, then President of the American
Economic Association, and Professor Milton
Friedman, who had just been awarded the
Nobel Prize in economics. Recently, on rereading the summary of that debate, I found
that it had an interesting and current ring to it.
Basically, the debate concerned whether
monetary policy should be used to stabilize the
business cycle, or used to reduce the inflation
rate. Four years ago, the Carter Administration clearly chose to use monetary policy to
work on the business cycle. Today, we have
another, new administration, which has
unveiled perhaps some of the most dramatic
and far-reaching economic proposals we've
had since the New Deal. And we're very fortunate to have two distinguished and
knowledgeable speakers to discuss the Administration's program.
Balles. Michael Keran has given me a very
easy and pleasurable assignment today - the
privilege of introducing our guest speakers. I
join Mike in welcoming our friends from the
business, banking and academic communities.
From my personal standpoint, it's a great relief
to be listening to rather than giving a speech,

a

*Mr. Balles is
and Mr. Keran is Senior Vice
President, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

4

The Reagan Economic Plan Supply-side, Budget and Inflation
Presentation by James Tobin
It's nice that you have a visitor from the East
every four years, at the beginning of a new Administration. I'd like to assure everybody that
the first art+cle I published, to which President
Balles just referred, was, like many of my subsequent ones, an anti-Keynesian paper.
A speaker who casts doubts on President
Reagan's Economic Recovery Program is
likely to be as unwelcome as a ghost at a wedding feast. After viewing the euphoria of the
joint session of Congress when the President
displayed his resilience and his oratorical
magic, I hate to be a wet blanket. I wish that
his was a cause to which I too could rally. I
would like to be enthusiastic about the dawn of
the New Beginning.
There are several ways in which we might
view the Program. We could examine its
micro-economics, how it reorders the nation's
priorities, reallocates the country's resources,
and redistributes income, wealth and power
among individuals, groups, and regions. These
may be the most important issues, the most
fundamental new directions. The Reagan
counter-revolution proposes to shift resources
from public sector to private sector, from civilian government to national defense, from the
Federal government to state and local governments, from beneficiaries of social programs to
the taxpayers, from the poor and the near-poor
to the affluent and the very rich. These proposals deserve to be considered in detail, item
by item, and evaluated in terms of their economic efficiency and equity.
However, the Administration bills and sells
its program primarily as a macro-economic
policy. The President and his spokesmen
appeal for support of their counter-revolutionary reallocations and redistributions not on
their intrinsic merits, but on the grounds that
they are necessary and sufficient to solve the
problem of stagflation. Here, we are told, is the
remedy, the only remedy, for high unemploy-

ment, high inflation, low growth, and lagging
productivity. We are asked to swallow the
micro-economic medicine not because it tastes
good but because it is good for what ails us. So
far, it appears, Congress, press, and public
readily accept the program as the necessary
remedy of our macro-economic ills.
It is the macro aspect of the program that I
propose to discuss, as is only appropriate at a
central bank. I'll begin by reminding you that
there is precious little evidence in international experience that successful macro-economic management is inversely correlated
with size of government, tax burdens, public
debt, and social transfers. Some countries
whose macro-economic performance we envy
have much larger public sectors, more
generous social welfare programs, greater tax
burdens, and higher budget deficits.
The Reagan recovery program, viewed as
macro policy, has a fiscal side and a monetary
side. Together they are projected to
accomplish the disinflation and the real economic growth shown in columns four and five
of my Table 1 and columns one and three of
my Table 2.
A neutral fiscal package
The fiscal policy, viewed from the standpoint of conventional aggregate demand
analysis, does not seem to be a significant factor of either stimulus or contraction over the
five years for which it is projected. It is important to judge the impact of fiscal policy against
what is and has been going on, last year and
this year, and not to use as a hypothetical
reference path President Carter's January
budget. The Carter budget, since it eschewed
tax cuts to offset fiscal drag, would have
tightened fiscal policy dramatically over the
next few years. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) compares the Reagan budget program with a more realistic baseline, the Carter

5

budget modified for 1982 and 1983 by some
business tax reductions and by a 10 percent
personal income tax reduction and by
unspecified tax cuts to maintain effective tax
rates constant after 1983. The CBO projections
show little difference between the Reagan
budget and this baseline in macro impacts. If
anything, the Reagan program is a little tighter
than the assumed baseline. Reagan spends less
and taxes
and the net effect is close to
neutraL
Actually the high employment budget
deficit (calCulated for, say, 6-percent
unemployment) declines slightly over the next
few years under the Reagan proposals, even
when the Administration's optimistic inflation
scenario is replaced by the more pessimistic
price forecasts of the CBO and private modelbuilders (see Table 3). These are conventional
Keynesian calculations, without supply side
optimism. (Neither do they apply to the
federal government the inflation accounting

we recommend to private businesses, which
would of course tell us that even the actual
budget is already balanced.)
The composition of the budget, as well as its
totals and its balance, affects its macro-economic impact. Under the Reagan program,
federal purchases of goods and services rise
because of the defense build-up. Transfers and
taxes fall. The changes in composition are
but I think they don't change the macro
story just told. For the same budget totals, the
shift to defense purchases is expansionary. On
the other hand, the shift of purchasing power
from liquidity-constrained transferees with
high marginal propensities to consume to
higher income taxpayers is moderately contractionary. Some economists believe that
defense is intrinsically highly inflationary and
cite with foreboding the fact that Reagan's projected build-up is comparable percentage-wise
to Johnson's Viet Nam spending binge. The
analogy is far from perfect. This defense build-

Table "1
Monetary Growth Targets vs. Reagan Projections of Inflation and
Real Growth Implications for Monetary Velocity
(percent per year, yearly averages)
(2)

(3)

(4)

Monetary
(M-18)
Growth

Velocity
Growth

Nominal
GNP
Growth

Price
Inflation

Real GNP
Growth

(6 M)
M

(~V)

(6SGNP)
SGNP

(6/)

(6 0)
0

6.1

2.2

8.9

9.0

-0.1

(1 )
Year

1980 actual

+

Announced Policy Implied by
Other Columns

+

(5)

Reagan Administration Projections·

1981

3.5 - 6

7.6 - 5.1

11.1

9.9

1.1

1982

3 - 5.5

9.8 - 7.3

12.8

8.3

4.2

1983

2.5 - 5

9.9-7.4

12.4

7.0

5.0

1984

2 - 4.5

8.8 - 6.3

10.8

6.0

4.5

1985

1.5 - 4

8.3-5.8

9.8

5.4

4.2

1986

1 - 3.5

8.3 - 58

9.3

4.9

4.2

'Office of Management and Budget, Fiscal Ycar IY82 Budxe! ReI'isiolls, March 1981, Table 6, p, 13.
Discrepancies between (3) and (4) + (5) are in original sources, and are due to second-order effects ( 6P.
P
quarterly compounding, and rounding.

6

£&)
Q'

up starts in an economy with a much larger
amount of slack than there was in January
1966. And it lacks the compulsion to disregard
costs and budget contraints that an actual war
provides.
No observer of the current political scene
can forbear comment on the ironies of the political parties' reversals of roles. Now the Republicans defend planned deficits against
Democratic attack, advocate tax cuts not just
to arrest recession but to sustain incipient
recovery, and resist Democratic proposals to
tilt tax reduction further toward businesses at
the expense of individuals. It was a Democratic President who deliberately declined,
ever since 1977, to recommend tax cuts to
compensate for fiscal drag and bracket drift,
and who sanctimoniously foreswore countercyclical fiscal measures to overcome the recent
reCeS~1I011. It is the Democrats in Congress who
now issue dire warnings of the inflationary

effects of stimulating the economy by three
years of tax reduction even when the
unemployment rate is 7 1f2 percent and capacity
utilization is barely 80 percent. It is the Republicans - some of them, it is true, without full
conviction in their new religion - who say
that it is idle and self-defeating to try to balance the budget by higher and higher effective
tax rates. The final irony is that it is a Republican budget, proposed by a President who is a
free enterprise hero, to which the securities
markets are currently registering a vote of no
confidence.
The budget is taking a bad rap from those,
whether liberal Democrats or conservative
investment bankers, who say it is a reckless
gamble to reduce taxes so much. To say this is
not to agree with extravagant Administration
claims that their package increases the national
propensity to save, but only to say that it
doesn't decrease it; clearly the tax cuts by

Table 2
Real Gross National Product and Unemployment, 1980-86
Reagan Scenario compared to Conventional Estimates
(1)

(2)

GNP (1980 $billion)
Estimated
Potential at
Reagan
Scenario
6% Unempl.

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986

2629
2658
2769
2908
3039
3167
3300

2746
2815
2886
2958
3032
3108
3185

(3)

(4)

Unemployment (%)
Reagan
Scenario

CBO
Alternative

7.2
7.8
7.2
6.6
6.4
6.0
5.6

7.2
7.8
7.9
7.8
7.7
7.5
72

(5)

(6)

Reagan
GNP
Scenario
(1980 $billion) GNP Relative
to
Conventional
Estimate for
Conventional
Reagan Unempl.
Estimate

2663
2802
2914
3001
3108
3217

998
988
.998
1.013
1.019
1.026

(I) and (3) Office of Management and Budget, Fiscal Year 1982 Budgcr Revisions, March 1981, Table 6, p. 13. GNP

converted to 1980 dollars by deflator projections given in same scenario.
(2) and (5) Author's estimates, assuming (a) Potential GNP grows at 2.5% per year, (b) Y' - Y=Y[.025(U-6.0)]

where Y' is potential GNP (2), U is unemployment percentage (3), .025 is the assumed Okun's Law coefficient,
and the equation is solved to give Y, "actual" GNP (5).
(6)

(1)/(5). For 1986, the Reagan scenario gives real GNP 2.6% higher than its unemployment projection would
indicate in a conventional Okun's Law calculation.

(4) Congressional Budget Office estimate of unemployment conditional on Reagan budget with less optimistic economic forecast. CBO, An Ana(vsis 0/ Presidelll Reagan's BudgeT Revisions for Fiscal Year 1982, Staff Working
Paper, March 1981, Summary Table 3, p. xviii.

7

themselves, without the expenditure cuts,
would diminish saving relative to GNP. Nor is
it to agree with Lafferite views that the tax cuts
will actually maintain or increase revenues.
That is most improbable, as I shall explain
below.
In judging the fiscal package to be more or
less innocuous in its macro-economic impact, I
am not endorsing it. I have serious
micro-economic and distributional objections,
but I will confine myself here to two

macro-economic reservations. First, I regret
that once again opportunities are being lost to
use tax reduction to gain ground on inflation.
We could cut taxes that directly boost labor
costs and prices, e.g. by reducing payroll
levies. We could go further and offer tax
inducements for disinflationary wage and price
behavior. Second, we could aim for a different
fiscal-monetary mix, one better designed to
foster capital formation and growth. In my opinion, that would involve a tighter budget

Table 3
The Federal Budget, 1980-84
Outlays, Revenues, Deficit, High Employment Deficit
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(6)

(5)

Budget Outlays ($billion)
Budget Revenues ($billion)
--Reagan
Estimates for
Reagan
CBO Estimates Estimates for
Estimates
for Reagan 6% Unempl. and Estimates
6% Unempl.
Scenario
CBO Inflation
and CBO
Inflation
580
655
695
732
770

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984

580
660
708
740
782

577
657
716
761
812

(7)

520
600
650
709
771
(8)

Deficit ($billion)

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984

554
662
710
765
827

C BO Alternative
Inflation Scenario
% increase
in GNP Deflator

10.3
9.2
8.6
8.1

(9)

High Employment Deficit ($ billion)

Reagan
Estimates

CBO Estimates
for Reagan
Scenario

Estimates for 6% Unempl. and
CBO Inflation

60
55
45
23

60
60
58
31

23

-I

11

-5
6
-4
-15

(1), (4), (7) Congressional Budget Office, An Analysis a/President Reagan's Budget Revisions/or Fiscal Year 1982, Staff
Working Paper, March 1981, Summary Table 1, p. xiii.
(2), (8) Reagan estimates plus subtotal for Alternative Programmatic Assumptions, Spending Rates, and Other Factors,
CBO, op, cit., Summary Table 4, p. xxi.
(6) CBO alternative inflation forecast conditional on Reagan program, op. cit, Summary Table 3, p. xviii. Compare
Reagan scenario column (4) of Table 1.
(3) Column (1) plus Total Reestimates from CBO Summary Table 4, lac. cit., less author's estimate of reduction in outlays due to difference between CBO unemployment projections in Summary Table 2 and 6%. In principle, column
(3) differs from (1) by adding outlays due to higher CBO estimates of inflation and interest rates and by subtracting
outlays, mainly unemployment compensation, due to projected unemployment rates above 6%.

(5)
(9)

Column (4) multiplied by (1 + l.5(x-1)) where x is the ratio of column (2) Table 2 to column (l) Table 2, i.e.,
potential GNP to projected actual GNP. The elasticity of revenues with respect to GNP is assumed to be 1.5.
=

(3) - (5) Negative figures are surpluses.

8

policy compensated by a monetary policy that
would give us lower real interest rates.

two limits of the MIB target brackets.
There has never been a two-year period over
which the average growth of MlB velocity has
exceeded 5 percent. It would have to beat that
in each of the next five years, hitting 7, 8,
almost 9 percent to make the Reagan scenario
come true. These increases in velocity are
beyond historical experience, even in the
recent decade of unprecedented financial
innovation. Finance is one sector where
American technology remains the best in the
world, and the possibility of even faster
progress in economizing cash can't be completely ruled out. But if policy-makers were to
accept rescue from velocity miracles, or a fortiori from further regulatory changes, they
would be substituting shadow for substance,
appearance for reality. Although the Fed might
be tempted by any escape route from the credibility impasse they have painted themselves
into, I assume the Fed really means to do
literally no more than what their taFgets say,
and to do less if the spirit of the policy so dictates.
This translates, whether the Administration
realizes it or not, into significantly lower rates
of growth of dollar spending on GNP than the
official projections (column three). Of course,
another way to achieve high velocity growth is
to engineer even higher nominal and real
interest rates than those we're now suffering.
But they would surely be inconsistent with the
substantial recovery of real and nominal GNP
promised by the President (columns three and
five). On the other hand, if the inflation and
interest rate projections of the Administration
were realized, velocity would slow down.

Monetary policy: disinflation the Fed's job
I turn now to monetary policy, where the
greatest inconsistencies in the Reagan recovery program occur. The President and his Administration have assigned the Federal
Reserve responsibility for inflation. You take
care of prices, they say in effect, and we'll get
the economy moving again. Criticizing imperfect marksmanship of the past, the President
and his economic policy-makers order the Fed
to cut the rate of monetary growth in half over
the next five years. This was already the Fed's
policy, as anyone who listens to Paul Volcker
knows. Now he has Beryl Sprinkel and other
monetarists looking over his shoulder, if not
waiting in the wings.
The monetary targets of the Fed and the
Administration are shown in the first column
of Table I. The idea that money and prices can
be detached and delegated to central bankers
while Congress and the Executive independently take care of budget, taxes, employment, and output is the kind of fallacy that
makes exam questions for freshman economics, a fallacy now elevated to Presidential
doctrine. If Amtrak hitches engines at both
ends of a train of cars in New Haven station we still do have a railroad there - one engine
heading west to New York, the other east to
Boston, and advertises that the train is going
simultaneously to both destinations, most
people would be skeptical. Reagan is hitching a
Volcker engine at one end and a StockmanKemp locomotive to the other and telling us
the economic train will carry us to Full
Employment and Disinflation at the same
time.
This inconsistency is shown in Table I. The
third column is the official Administration
projection of nominal GNP, equal to the totals
of columns four and five, the Reagan scenarios
for inflation and real output growth. Subtracting the monetary targets of column 1 from the
dollar-GNP projections of column 3 gives the
implied growth rates of velocity of MI B, column 2. The two numbers correspond to the

Missing: a strategy for disinflation
As devastating as this inconsistency is to the
credibility of the President's program, the
scenario contains a more fatal flaw. This is the
division of nominal GNP, column 3, between
inflation, column 4, and real output growth,
column 5. It defies historical experience to
expect price inflation to subside as rapidly as
shown in column 4 while output recovers as
vigorously as projected in column 5.
Experience tells us the combination is a most

9

unlikely one, given the stubborn inertia of
existing patterns of inflation. Experience tells
us that disinflation requires recessions,
prolonged slack, and high unemployment.
What entitles this Administration to expect to
cut inflation in half while output is growing
faster than its sustainable potential for five
years?
The only answer that has trickied out of
Washington is an appeal to self-fulfilling
expectations. The public will read column 5.
Observing the decisive budgetary moves of the
new Administration, believing them to be the
proper medicine for inflation as advertised, the
public will act to make the predictions come
true. That means they will negotiate lower
wage bargains and slow down price increases.
Previous optimistic inflation forecasts from
the White House have not been self-fulfilling
or otherwise fulfilled, but maybe this time will
be different.
This is an expectations argument, but certainly not a rational expectations theory.
Rational expectations require a model that
makes sense, one that truly connects policy
actions to results. Rational expectations not
only generate but are generated from such a
model. In this case no such model exists, and
Robert Lucas and Robert Hall are as unlikely
as Lane Kirkland and Sam Church to believe
and act upon the advertised disinflation.
The two major English-speaking democracies are in conservative economic hands, but
the policies and public stance of Margaret
Thatcher in Great Britain are very different
from those of Ronald Reagan in the United
States. Their Prime Minister threatens
workers, managers, and plain citizens like an
authoritarian schoolmaster disciplining an
unruly class. You won't have jobs, profits or
prosperity until you stop inflating your wages
and prices. Our President promises disinflation
without tears, indeed with prosperity. He
encourages unions and managements to carry
on business as usual. After all, inflation is only
the government's fault, and all we citizens are
asked to do is to accept tax goodies and stop
indulging the poor. The Federal Reserve, it is
true, has been following a Thatcher-like policy

but in whispers. I am one of the thousand or so
Americans who hear and read Paul Volcker
and know that MIB is not an army rifle. I pay
attention to Henry Wallich too. I believe they
will do what they say they wili do, and I am
duly scared. If I were Lane
I would
take the monetary threats seriously and tell my
constituent unions to take it easy.
The Fed's muted threat is quite different
from Her Majesty's First
standing
up in Parliament and throughout her country
to say that she doesn't care how much
unemployment there is for how long, or what
is the real rate of growth or decline; she will
stick it through whatever the pain, however
long it takes to eliminate inflation. Reagan has
said nothing like that, and Volcker isn't well
known in Peoria or Spokane, in the shops and
offices where wages and prices are made.
Federal Reserve threats are heard in financial
circles all right, but the bond market does not
seem to be impressed. In summary, if the
Reagan anti-inflation strategy depends on
expectations, the Administration has done and
said nothing to make expectations work in its
favor.
Let there be no illusion. There is no way to
reduce inflation in this country so long as wage
increases proceed at 10 percent a year. There is
no possible miracle of productivity that can
validate such a trend in money wages. Our lost
2 percent per year productivity trend may reappear as mysteriously as it vanished. If we are
very, very lucky, policy to speed investment
and research and development might add
another half point or full point, not this year or
next but some years down the road. But with
the best of good fortune we would be left with
domestic core inflation of 7-8 percent unless
the money wage pattern is broken - and it
may be more difficult to break it when workers
can claim to have earned more via improved
productivity. We must also expect an adverse
trend in the terms of trade between American
labor and resource-based commodities
imported from abroad or produced within the
country. This may be equivalent on average to
a half point or full point of decline in worker
productivity.
10

I emphasize the persistent inertial trend of
money wages in the central non-agricultural
"fixprice" sector of our economy, because no
lasting solution of our inflation is possible
unless it is brought much closer to the sustainable trend of productivity. In short runs,
especially month to month and quarter to
quarter, popular price indexes can vary widely

disinflation without a protracted dose of recession and economic stagnation, I believe it is
necessary to give everybody assurance that
everybody else is going to disinflate. Otherwise
the fear and suspicion of each group that it will
lose real and relative income lead it to stick to
the existing inflationary pattern. This makes
tough going for a Thatcher policy, and even
tougher going for a contractionary policy without a clear and credible threat.
For this reason, I have favored a preannounced schedule of gradually declining
standards for wage increases over a five-year
transitional period. Inducements to obey the
guideposts would be provided by payroll tax
rebates for employees in complying firms, and
for employers too if their percentage markups
do not rise. The guidepost schedule would be
consistent with a macro-economic disinflationary policy to which the Administration, Congress, and Federal Reserve would be solemnly
and visibly committed. Since nominal GNP
growth and wage-cost inflation would decline
in concert, there would be neither suppressed
demand-pull inflation nor the damage to real
economic performance caused by cutting
monetary demand growth while money cost
inflation proceeds unabated.
Such a policy clearly requires a consensus
among labor, business, and government, and
such a consensus clearly requires strong and
persuasive leadership by a popular President.
We lost that opportunity this year, just as we
lost the chance to follow a "cold turkey"
policy with some chance that inflation would
melt faster than previous statistical evidence
leads us to believe it will.

around this core inflation rate~ from the weight
of flexible prices loosely tied to U.S. wages. In
the next eighteen months, for example, the
volatile elements in the Consumer Price Index
might be favorable, and the Administration
might be able to point to some apparent successes in its battle against inflation. If
mortgage interest rates stay put or fall, the
housing component will contribute less to CPI
inflation news than in 1979-80. Perhaps we
have purchased a respite on the oil front by
selling Awacs to Saudi Arabia, as well as by
slowing down our economy and swallowing the
decontrol of domestic oil prices in one gulp
early this year. Our tight monetary policy, if it
does nothing else, is appreciating the dollar
against other currencies; this may be bad for
the U.S. export-import position but it lowers
dollar prices of some imports and world-traded
commodities. Food price prospects, always
uncertain, are not so favorable, given the end
of the grain embargo and the low level of world
stocks. My purpose is not to predict prices but
to warn that transient luck in the volatile elements of price indexes does not signify final
victory, any more than transient misfortune
justified panic about runaway inflation
acceleration in 1979-80.
At the beginning of my talk, I pointed out
that countries with enviable inflation records
in recent years are not invariably those with
Reagan-like fiscal policies. If the successful
countries have a common characteristic, it is
that they have some kind of handle on money
wage decisions.
Here in the United States whoever was the
victor in the November 1980 election had, I
thought, the rare opportunity to use the window of good feeling that Americans open at
the start of a new Presidential term to gain
control over our wage-price spiral. To engineer

Supply-side economics: no free lunch
But can't we take hope from the recent discovery that the economy has a supply side?
This remarkable revelation plays a big role in
the rhetoric that rationalizes the Reagan program, although, as I argued above, the fiscal
program as macro strategy does not really depend on Laffer-Kemp calculus. The official
macro-economic scenario does contain a small
bit of supply-side magic. Real GNP five years
out is somewhat larger, relative to the pro11

jected unemployment rates, than received
"Okun's law" wisdom would allow. (Table 3,
column 6) There appears to be on average an
extra half percent per year of real growth,
beyond what would normally accompany the
unemployment reductions shown. It is not
clear from what source these gains are supposed to come.
From labor supply? Supply-side wisdom is
that the upward drift of marginal personal tax
rates is drying up the supply of productive
labor. That there has been such a drift, particularly since
is undeniable, though it is not
as great as often alleged. The Brookings
Institution tax file permits calculation of the
federal marginal rate of personal income tax,
averaged over all brackets, faced by a breadwinner with spouse and two children: 1960,
18.8 percent; 1965, 15.9 percent; 1970, 18.2
percent; 1975, 18.0 percent; 1980, 21.6 percent. Yet it is hard to find evidence of a
weakened propensity to supply labor in recent
experience. Labor force participation, overtime hours of work, multiple job holding,
weekly hours of work corrected for changes in
industry mix - none of these indicators seem
out of line with trends and cyclical effects dating from the 1950s and 1960s. Believe it or
not, most of our seven million unemployed
fellow citizens really do want work, and there
are many "not in labor force" who do also.
Finally, I observe that although the Administration's tax bill reduces marginal rates for taxpayers, especially those in high brackets, its
budget cuts will seriously impair work incentives for low-income families and individuals
dependent on welfare, food stamps, and other
transfers.
In the belief that a Curve deserves a Theory,
I have derived rigorously a Laffer Curve based
on labor supply response to after-tax real
wages. Indeed, I have derived two Laffer
Curves, one for Tax Revenues and one for
National Saving (more precisely for Tax
Revenues plus Private Saving, which exceeds
National Saving by the amount of Government Purchases, assumed constant.) These
are pictured in Figure 1, which also contains a
rather cryptic, but I hope sufficient, explana-

tion of their derivation. The important
parameters are the Cobb- Douglas elasticity of
output with respect to capital, a, and with
respect to labor, I-a, and the elasticity oflabor
supply l/f3. In the numerical example, I took
both a and 1/f3 to be 1/3. That is a generous
estimate of labor supply response; the consensus guess is no higher than 1/6. With these
values my LatTer Curve peaks at a wage tax
rate of 5/6. The National Saving Curve
involves also the marginal propensity to consume, which I took in the exercise to be .4 for
capital income and .8 for after-tax labor
income. The peak of this second, and more
economically significant, Laffer Curve is at a
tax rate of 3/4. I doubt that we are on the
wrong slope of either Laffer Curve now, and I
hope we don't go there.
A more credible supply-oriented policy is to
stimulate non-residential fixed investment, in
the hope that accelerating the growth of capital
relative to output and labor supply will raise
productivity. As one of the Kennedy team that
originated the Investment Tax Credit in 1962,
I have some sympathy with this goal. Clearly I
do not have time to discuss adequately the
Reagan Administration's investment stimuli,
so I will confine myself to four short remarks.
First, as I stated earlier, I regret that we cannot adopt a mix of macro-economic policies,
fiscal and monetary, that would shift the composition of output toward capital formation.
Why can't we? The main reason is simply the
monetarist dogma embraced by the Administration, to which the Federal Reserve is
hostage. This locks us into a particular path of
a particular monetary aggregate, invariant to
fiscal policy and other macro-economic circumstances.
Second, there are ways to provide investment incentives in the taxation of business
that do not make a shambles of economic efficiency and tax equity, as the present proposals
for accelerated depreciation do. If the intention
is to make amends for the overstatement of
taxable profits due to historical cost depreciation, there are straightforward ways of doing so
without freezing into the tax code a depreciation system that will still be there if and when
12

Reagan budget, pervaded as it is by the
ideology that only private business capital is
productive.
The outlook, I am afraid, is for continued
stagflation, with disappointing results on all
fronts - inflation, unemployment, real output, interest rates, and capital formation. We
will unwind the Great Society, redistribute
income regressively, withdraw the Federal
commitment to the environment, and we will
have little or no macro-economic progress to
show. The Program will not fulfill the promises
that have led the country to support it. I wish I
knew what will happen when the Administration, Congress, and public confront this
reality.

inflation abates. Anyway, this investment disincentive is offset, partially or fully, by another
inflation distortion in the tax code, the deductibility of nominal interest.
Third, whatever investment incentive is
enacted now should be effective immediately.
Its impact is diluted by a gradual phase-in such
as the Administration proposes, because this
gives an inducement to delay investment projects.
Fourth, plant and equipment is not the only
social capital. If we wish as a society to make
better provision for the future, we should also
be concerned with the preservation and
improvement of human capital, natural
resources, and public sector facilities and
infrastructure, all of which are sacrificed in the

Figure 1
Laffer Curves
National
Saving

Tax
Revenues

0 ...-Tax
-- - - - - -T**
- -T*- - - - -.........
Rate T
a

= capital share of output

~ = labor supply elasticity

CK = marginal propensity to consume capital income
Cw = marginal propensity to consume labor income
T* = a +
1+,8

T** = 1

(1 +,8)
13

1- a
(1-a)+C Ka)

Figure 2
Derivation of Laffer Curves
Output
Y ::; KUN 1

Output,
WageBilll

G

u

After lax
Wage Bill

N1+ f3

;-

A

S

Increasing T

~

".

Pre-Tax
Wage Bill
(1 - a) Y

A
N

)110-

Labor Supply and Employment

AB: Workers' Consumption BC: Workers' Saving
CD: Workers' Taxes
DE: Capitalist Taxes
EF: Capitalist Saving
FG: Capitalist Consumption
BF: Taxes and saving available for
government purchases and private
investment (G + I)
CE: Tax Revenues

14

The Reagan Economic Plan
Discussion

Robert Hall

Balles. The discussant for Professor Tobin’s presentation, presumably giving the other
side o f the story, is Professor Robert Hall, Professor o f Economics at Stanford and also a
Hoover Fellow. He holds a joint appointment at both institutions; he is, as well, a member
o f the Brookings’Panel on Economic Activity and head o f the National Bureau’s business
cycle dating project. His research projects are many and varied, but he has been particularly
interested in the microeconomics o f labor markets and in the influence o f those markets on
the employment and inflation process. Em informed that he’s currently editing a book on
inflation for the National Bureau. At various times, he’s investigated the impacts o f govern­
ment tax policies, both on the level o f business investment and on the supply o f labor.
Hence, he is very well-qualified to comment on the likely supply-side impact o f the Presi­
dent’s policy package as well as other matters brought up, or perhaps not brought up, by
Professor Tobin. So let’s welcome Professor Hall.

Let me start by saying that in no sense am I a
spokesman for the President’s program. The
closest I came to participating in the formula­
tion of the policy was serving as a member of
the Task Force on Inflation, which made its re­
port last November. Since then, I have been an
academic on the sidelines.
What do economists and the public think is
wrong with the American economy today? In
the first place, the economy suffers from dis­
appointing real growth. The disappointment
dates back to 1973 in its worst form, but
actually real growth as we knew it in the 1960s
came to an end in 1969. Since then, periods of
growth have alternated with severe recessions,
and, over the whole period, net growth has
been weak. The past few years have been
especially bad. And the prospect for the econ­
omy today is for continuing disappointments
in real incomes and real growth. As I under­
stand it, the administration is very, very con­
cerned with the growth issue.
The second problem, first on the public’s list
but second on mine, is inflation. People are
very tired of struggling with a dollar that loses
some 10 percent of its value every year. The
public has been clear about its desire to end
inflation. There is a very strong political com­
mitment to end inflation. We as economists

have an obligation to say, how can we do it?
The third item on my list is excess govern­
ment control over the use of resources in the
economy. There is simply too much interven­
tion in various forms — regulation, taxing, and
spending. A particular form of excess govern­
ment intervention is the heavy taxation of the
return to savings. There is virtually a crisis in
the taxation of one of the most critical chan­
nels of savings and investment, equityfinanced purchases of plant and equipment by
corporations. Those transactions are taxed in
the U.S. economy today at rates of something
like 60 or 70 percent, which is simply
excessive. On the other hand, as Professor
Tobin points out, we have another problem
today, that the tax system subsidizes tax
shelters, because of the deductibility of
interest. The tax system is completely out of
kilter as a result of inflation, and we need to do
something about it.
That’s my short list of things that are wrong
with the economy. Let me turn now to what we
shouldn’t do about it, and here you will find
me in agreement with what Professor Tobin
just said. The leading example of what not to
do with the economy today is what the British
are doing. Let me review the elements of the
British macro policy as I see them. In the first
15

regulations which the people don’t want,
which have an unfavorable effect on the pub­
lic’s spendable real incomes. We should make
a list of all the rat holes that the government is
pouring money into today, and we should
eliminate them. If you go through the budget
proposals of the Reagan Administration, you
will find that the character of the expenditure
reductions is largely, though not exclusively,
elimination of rat holes. One can give count­
less examples. One which has been quite pro­
minent is the Export-Import Bank — a good
example of a program which simply does not
have a proper role in a well-run economy. It
certainly does not benefit the poor, and is
something which should be dispensed with.
Well, there are many, many things in the
budget that should be dispensed with. My per­
sonal list would be considerably longer than
the one the Administration has come up with.
Furthermore, my cuts would be larger in those
cases where the Administration has suc­
cessfully identified a rat hole and then said,
our way of dealing with the problem is to cut
the budget by twenty percent. Having found a
rat hole, I think we should simply stop pouring
anything down it. Whole segments of the
budget — like the Energy Department — are
just collections of rat holes. Together, they
consume a non-trivial fraction of real GNP.
Let me be very clear that I do not include in
this category the types of expenditure which
have virtually eliminated poverty in the
United States over the past twenty years. I am
very happy to see that anti-poverty programs
like AFDC, supplemental security income,
and food stamps have not been gutted. Though
these programs are not completely satisfac­
tory, they represent a very important step for­
ward in improving the distribution of income
in the most important way, by helping those at
the very bottom. The President has been very
clear on the need to retain anti-poverty expen­
ditures. I think it’s very unfortunate that a
large number of opponents of the package
have described it incorrectly as aimed pri­
marily at eliminating expenditures on behalf of
the poor. That’s simply not correct. There are,
of course, some attempts to improve the per­

place, the British have brought about a sharp
reduction in money growth. And that has
brought with it the usual symptoms of a finan­
cial crisis, including high interest rates, over­
valued currency, and the like. Second, govern­
ment expenditures are continuing to rise.
That, I think, is the central problem they are
facing. They simply do not have a handle on
the budget in Britain. Part of the budget prob­
lem takes the form of direct government
purchases of goods and services, including the
continuing sad story of deepening government
involvem ent in operating governm ent
enterprises, in spite of Margaret Thatcher’s
commitment to free enterprise. Another
important source of budget strain comes from
transfers, which have risen because of the
reduction in real activity and employment.
Finally, under the influence of, I think, a very
basically incorrect interpretation of supply side
arguments, the British have sharply raised
commodity taxes and sharply cut income taxes
at the same time. The net effect on the budget
from these two moves was not large but it
brought about a sharp increase in inflation.
There is a large amount of feedback from the
cost of living index to wages and transfers in
the British economy. And the worsening of
inflation has not been offset by any supply side
response, either in theory or in fact. A funda­
mental supply side analysis says that the incen­
tive to work depends on the ratio of take-home
wages to prices. That’s not affected by a move
which increases take-home wages but also
increases prices.
Let’s not do what the British are doing. I’m
happy to see that, by and large, the Reagan
Administration is not moving in the British
direction. None of the three elements that Fve
listed in the British example exist in the pro­
posed policy of the Administration. So what
should we do? Again, I have a list, and it
differs from the Administration’s policy only
in one of its elements.
In the first place, we need to limit govern­
ment expenditures. Here, I think, is probably
the largest disagreement with what Professor
Tobin has said. There are a great many federal
spending programs, transfer programs, and
16

reduced; certainly that was the case with the
capital gains reduction. And a fairly small frac­
tion of total income actually flows through
people’s income tax returns. In spite of high
apparent marginal rates, it’s a curious fact of
the U.S. economy that only 11 percent of per­
sonal income is paid to the federal govern­
ment as personal income tax. I agree com­
pletely that the evidence that people work
harder when they are taxed less is not nearly
strong enough to support the notion that
revenue would respond favorably to a tax cut.
What the reduction in capital gains rates sug­
gests is that people’s incentive to avoid taxes
would be dramatically reduced by cutting top
marginal rates, and that would mean that
revenue at least would not fall nearly as much
as a simple calculation might suggest.
Although I am skeptical about the strength
of the supply response to reduced tax rates, I
endorse tax cuts as a way to restore real
growth. Perfectly standard macro analysis, in
which labor supply is exactly inelastic with
respect to real wages, will tell you that tax cuts
are expansionary. The idea that was pushed
very hard and successfully in 1961 through
1964 is correct today. And it seems to me that
it should be pushed today. One doesn’t have to
believe in an exotic labor supply function to
take the view that the time has come for tax cuts.
I also favor tax cuts as by far the best way to
keep expenditures under control. It seems to
me that the reason that government expen­
ditures haven’t swollen worse than they have
is Congressional fear of deficits. If we don’t
have a tax cut, there will be that much more
room for pouring money down rat holes,
which is not something I’d like to see happen.
The last topic on the fiscal side is investment
incentives. As I said at the outset, heavy taxa­
tion of some kinds of investment income is
one of our worst current problems. The Presi­
dent’s proposal for accelerated depreciation —
the 10-5-3 plan — is very much a stimulus to
investment through reduced taxation of its
return. I don’t think it is the best way to cut
taxes on investment, however. I would far
rather see the following combination of
changes: On the one hand, allow an immediate

formance of transfer programs, but it seems to
me that one can correctly characterize most of
the expenditure cuts as eliminating rat holes.
President Reagan has also proposed large
increases in military spending. I don’t feel
qualified to judge the desirability of this move,
but I think that economists do have one very
important thing to say with respect to military
expenditures — macro policy is capable of
delivering full employment and price stability
for virtually any level of expenditures. Here I
agree completely with what Professor Tobin
said. There are good examples of economies
which have much larger public sectors than
ours, and have full employment and price
stability. If necessary, we could support a
much larger military establishment than we
have now without automatically creating any
significant macro-economic problems. Of
course, resources available to the private sec­
tor for investment and consumption would
necessarily be less in an economy that was
devoting a large amount of its output to mili­
tary or other government purposes. Within
that limitation, the total level of output and the
behavior of prices are things that policy can
control. An increase in government spending
is not by itself a threat to the performance of
the overall economy. Nor is a decrease in
spending. We ought to be able to design macro
policies that handle any of these contingencies.
One of the most controversial features of the
President’s program is substantial reduction in
tax rates. I emphasize that what’s being pro­
posed are rate reductions, and not necessarily
revenue reductions. One does not have to
accept the labor supply rationale of the Laffer
curve to entertain the proposition that a tax
rate reduction could increase revenue. A very
good example of that is the reduction in capital
gains tax rates that went into effect in 1978. In
a recent study, the Treasury concluded that
revenue remained about the same as a result of
a large reduction in tax rates. Rate reductions
can stimulate revenue because people have a
good deal of discretion about how they arrange
their affairs and how they fill out their tax
returns. When tax rates go down, the incen­
tives to shelter income are dramatically
17

rapidly; we’d love to raise real growth to these
exceptional rates year after year. We can’t pro­
mise either. What we can promise through the
use of a sensible long-run monetary policy is
column 3. We can promise to use monetary
instruments to keep nominal GNP growth at a
reasonably high level, that is, not undergo
sharp recession, and yet, reduce this growth
gradually to a non-inflationary level. What I
don’t want to see, and what I am afraid I am
hearing more and more from the Administra­
tion, is that money growth will stick, come hell
or high water, to the predetermined target of
column 1. We can see from the table that col­
umn 1 does not mesh with column 3. I
couldn’t agree more strongly with Professor
Tobin’s comments on this contradiction.
There’s simply nothing in the economy that’s
going to give velocity growth as high as is sug­
gested by column 2. Furthermore, to the
extent that a policy is successful in bringing
inflation to an end, it will also gradually reduce
interest rates. Tower interest rates should
cause velocity to fall, so the problem is even
compounded relative to Professor Tobin’s dis­
cussion.

write-off of all corporate investment — this
would be the ultimate extension of accelerated
depreciation. On the other hand, we should
deny all interest deductions under the corpor­
ate income tax. That combination of proposals
would provide even more stimulus than 10-53, and it would eliminate the inefficient sub­
sidy we now pay to leveraged investment as
well. In the long run, such a tax has a zero
effective rate on a corporation that has no
monopoly earnings. In a sense, it amounts to a
proposal to abolish the corporate income tax,
which I don’t think would be a bad idea. Even
with 10-5-3, the corporate income tax would
become a very small part of the federal
revenue picture. The big engine of revenue in
the U.S. economy in the future will be the
payroll tax — not the corporate income tax and
not the personal income tax.
With respect to monetary discipline, what is
needed is the establishment of a long-run
framework for monetary policy. We need to be
able to promise a move toward monetary
stability, and therefore to price stability, over
the next half-decade or decade. We need a
convincing way to express that policy. It’s not a
matter of adopting a harsh reduction in money
growth over the next 12 months. Rather, we
need a way to promise the American public
that we will not push the economy too hard at
any one time, but we will push it to long-run
price stability. So far, the Administration’s pro­
posals have not been in the form I would like
to see — there has not been a strong an­
nouncement of a long-run monetary frame­
work. Partly this is a recognition of the indepen­
dence of the Federal Reserve System, and a
reluctance for the President to appear to be try­
ing to dictate to an independent branch of
government what it should be doing.

One of the things I like most about the new
Administration is its commitment to strong real
growth. To the extent that policy is successful
in bringing growth, the economy will need
more money. We shouldn’t be afraid of money
growth, if the reason we need it is growth in
real GNP. The strict target of low money
growth of column one just doesn’t make sense
in a rapidly growing economy. We can get out
of the box by announcing a nominal GNP
target instead of a money growth target. So far,
the A d m in istratio n ’s position has been
incomplete in this area.
Taken together, the policy of reduced
federal command over resources, lower tax
rates, and investment stimulus adopted by the
Administration promises progress in solving
economic problems. If coupled with a good
long-run framework for monetary and price
stability, it would be a very large step forward
in economic policy making.

What should the Fed be doing? The type of
announcement I would like to see would state
the target of monetary policy in terms of a path
of nominal GNP. Take column 3 in Table 1 of
Professor Tobin’s handout and say, this is
what monetary policy will achieve. We would
love to accomplish what is shown in columns 4
and 5. We’d love to get inflation down that
18

Comments by Speakers
Professor Tobin:

tween themselves and British conservative
policy, now that it appears that Thatcherism
isn’t succeeding too well.
Third, the claim that taxes take as much as
60 or 70 percent of net income generated by
non-financial corporations seems a considera­
ble exaggeration. Summers and Feldstein have
cited figures of that magnitude as estimates of
marginal rates. But they seem to be well above
any estimates of average tax rates, and I
suspect dubious as marginal rates as well. And
they’re really not consistent with what Bob
Hall said himself, when he observed how little
income appears on income-tax returns. That’s
certainly true of interest income, dividend
income, and pension and annuity income —
those kinds that reflect corporate-income pay­
ments.
Fourth, I think it’s a great mistake, both in
the Reagan tax program and in previous tax
legislation, to correct inflation-generated dis­
tortions in the tax system by introducing other
kinds of distortions. Why not meet head-on
the non-neutrality of the tax system with
respect to inflation? The problem may be
historical cost depreciation, but we’re going to
be stuck with 10-5-3 for the rest of time no
matter what the inflation rate after Bob Hall
gets inflation down. The 10-5-3 plan, at that
time, will no longer be justified as compensat­
ing roughly for inflation’s exaggeration of tax­
able income. It would be better to have some­
thing like the Auerbach-Jorgenson plan,
which would give the full present value of de­
preciation on a new investment right now,
computed at a real interest rate of 4 percent or
some arbitrary reasonable number. This plan is
automatically neutral with respect to inflation.
I also agree with Hall on eliminating the tax
deductibility of interest costs.
Fifth, we cannot be sure as economic
theorists that shifting taxation from capital
income to wage income is a useful method of
increasing saving and investment. The lifecycle model tells us that the aggregate supply
of saving is scaled to after-tax wage income.

I knew that Bob Hall was a good macro econ­
omist, so I’m not surprised that he tried to
shift the debate—or shall we say, the discus­
sion—to the micro side of the budget program.
Just a couple of comments: First, I don’t think
it’s fair to say that the Administration has not
committed itself to column one of Table 1.
The President’s message in the budget-revi­
sion document states that the growth of money
stock must be cut in half over a period of time.
Although Hall interprets the inconsistency as
delicate respect for the independence of the
Federal Reserve, another interpretation is that
the Administration is setting up the Federal
Reserve to receive the blame for the inconsis­
tencies of the program. In case the inflation
rate doesn’t go down as advertised, the failing
would be the Fed’s because it had been
assigned the responsibility. In case the recov­
ery falls short, failure to finance it could be the
Fed’s failing too.
Second, I want to stress the need for a con­
certed policy directed to an agreed path of
nominal income, or money spending on GNP
(column 3). I was glad that Bob Hall endorsed
nominal income targeting. But it should be the
policy of the Federal Government as a whole,
fiscal and monetary together, consistent as be­
tween the two. Similarly, in Congress, we need
a concerted approach to macroeconomic
strategy as between the various committees—
those on the one hand that oversee monetary
policy, and those on the other that oversee
budget policy. We’ve had too much compartmentalization both in Congress and in the Ad­
ministration, as if the two areas of macro
policy weren’t connected with each other.
Desirable as an MV target policy may be com­
pared to concentrating on M1B (column 1), I
am skeptical that it will succeed without con­
siderable pain and damage to the economy,
and without the help of an incomes policy to
bring about a reduction in wage and cost infla­
tion consistent with the scheduled monetary
disinflation. It is interesting, by the way, to see
the distance conservatives take pains to put be­
19

the owners of common stock. All of the pro­
ceeds are then invested in a plant. There’s no
investment credit involved. There is no
leverage, no borrowing in the debt market, so
there is no deduction for interest. The com­
bination of the 46-percent statutory corporate
income-tax rate, 40-percent marginal personal
income-tax rate, and historical cost deprecia­
tion at 10-percent inflation gives a total effec­
tive rate of 60 to 70 percent, which is
excessive.
The big problem with the tax system is the
coexistence of these high rates with negative
rates on other types of investment, notably
those with high leverage and large interest
deductions. That’s why, when you add every­
thing together, the average tax rates on all
types of investment turn out not to look very
high. So the evidence Jim referred to does not
contradict my point that some critical types of
investment are highly taxed. The problem with
the tax system—entirely attributable to infla­
tion—is that it deals very harshly with equityfinanced investment and very, very generously
w ith lev erag ed in v e stm e n t. You find
individuals going out and leveraging them­
selves like crazy, borrowing everything they
can to create tax shelters—and corporations,
who are reluctant to leverage, incurring very
heavy tax rates and therefore finding that the
current environment is not very favorable for
investment. The problem needs to be solved
by eliminating the subsidy to leveraged invest­
ments and reducing the taxation of equityfinanced investments. The two together don’t
have large revenue implications, because we
could get the revenue by eliminating subsidies
of leveraged investments and applying the
revenue to reduced tax rates on equityfinanced investments.
Unfortunantely, 10-5-3 is not the best way
to make this kind of a change. I understand the
Administration is at least considering some
more fundamental tax reforms to be proposed
after Kemp-Roth and 10-5-3 go through.
There are some very badly needed structural
reforms that would improve the incentive for
plant and equipment investment by corpora­
tions.

Whether a shift in taxation from capital
income to wage income will actually increase the
amount of saving depends on the interest
elasticity.
Finally, about ratholes: It’s not really true
that all the items in the Stockman hit list are
ratholes, that none touch the truly needy or
those that should be protected by “ safety
nets” . A lot of them have to do with welfare,
with food stamps, with Medicaid. One conse­
quence of the cuts is to turn these people over to
the tender mercies of the states, not all of which
are as benign as California, Connecticut, and
Massachusetts. Also, inconsistent with the
spirit of the program as a whole, the marginal
tax rates of the poor and near-poor and work­
ing-poor are going to be increased by the
emphasis on keeping all but the truly needy off
the rolls. The sacrifice of benefits involved in
earning additional income is going to be much
larger than under present programs. Things
like aid to “ federally impacted” school dis­
tricts and export-import loans are examples of
ratholes, where we would all agree—both on
efficiency and equity grounds—that cuts are
justifiable. But by no means all Stockman’s
cuts are of this nature. Moreover, we could
compile a list of items that deserve to be cut
but have been spared. Consider tax expen­
ditures, which are basically open-ended
appropriations by the Federal Government to
use resources at the discretion of tax-payers,
often for doubtful purposes that would get the
axe if they were on the other side of the budget
ledger. We can’t debate budgets this after­
noon, but I don’t think an inspection of the
program would justify what Bob said about it.

Professor Hall:

Let me just discuss one topic, the taxation of
savings and investment. As Jim said, the
average rate of taxation of investment income
is not as high as the example I gave of tax rates
of 60 or 70 percent. It may help if I elaborate
upon the example where rates are at that con­
fiscatory level. A corporation issues new stock
bought by individuals who are in the 40-per­
cent marginal tax bracket, which is typical for
20

General Discussion
of national product, it would take some time
before that shows up in additional produc­
tivity. Even then, the additional productivity
growth will be small compared with the rate of
inflation that we have to cope with. So there’s
no supply-side miracle that will make those
predictions come true in the scenario.
H all. One of the things we were careful to
do in writing the inflation task force report was
to warn the President that although these
policies were good in the long run, there was
going to be a very soft economy in 1981. That
was a group of a dozen knowledgeable
macroeconomists trying to make a forecast.
Like many forecasts, this one has turned out
so far to be quite wrong, and now there is the
danger that people are going to say that the
new policy has been miraculous. There is no
reason to link the surprisingly strong perfor­
mance in the first quarter to the new policies—
oil decontrol is the only one put into effect
during that quarter. A very important lesson of
macro-economic experience is that you must
not argue from the quarter-to-quarter changes
in any variable. It would be a very serious
mistake to make exaggerated claims for supply-side policies just on the basis of one
quarter. We could have a very bad second or
third quarter this year, and I wouldn’t want to
say that signalled the failure of supply-side
policies any more than I would want to say the
first quarter shows the success of the policies.

Q. The first-quarter GNP estimates didn’t
look anything like the OMB estimates, what
with the reduced rate of inflation and sharply
higher real rate of growth. Perhaps the Admin­
istration’s decontrol of oil prices had some
thing to do with this, since petroleum is such a
major factor in economic activity. I’d like to
ask both gentlemen to comment on the extent
to which supply-side economics may bail the
Reagan Administration out of the quandary
that they seem to feel exists on the tightmoney side.
Tobin: I think it’s a good idea to decontrol
oil prices. But I don’t know how much that had
to do with the first-quarter surprise in real out­
put and prices. I doubt it was the major factor.
But whatever truth may be there, it’s not
something that you can do every month and
every quarter from now until 1986. It can’t be
counted on to produce miracles all the time. I
just don’t believe there’s any overall produc­
tivity miracle or supply miracle capable of
bringing about any substantial reduction in the
rate of inflation over the next few years.
There’s an illusion in some of the rhetoric
about this—a fallacy of composition. Murray
Weidenbaum (Chairman of the Council of
Economic Advisers) was quoted as saying that
inflation is too much money chasing too few
goods—so we’re just going to get more goods
in the market, and with the same amount of
money chasing those goods, the price will go
down. And Mr. Laffer says that in an apple
market, if you get a lot more apples offered for
sale, the price goes down and that’s all we’re
talking about for the real economy. I think
Jean Baptiste Say had something to say about
this a long time ago. Additional supply also
creates additional demand, maybe not one for
one, but 0.9 for one or something like that.
You don’t get a big reduction in excess
demand, you don’t get much excess saving or
net excess supply from aggregate supply
increases, desirable as they may be for their
own sakes. There is no solution there to the
inflation problem. Even if we were to have a
considerable increase in the investment share

Q. Professor Tobin said that there were a
lot of ratholes that the Reagan budget cuts
don’t touch, and he referred to tax expen­
ditures. Now I don’t regard those as ratholes,
because all they do is let me keep my money,
in the sense that the government has a tax
expenditure by letting me keep 70 percent of
the income I earn. But in terms of actual
budget cuts, what would he like to see that
President Reagan is not talking about?
Tobin: Examples that I might think of off­
hand are elimination of subsidies for ship
building and ship operation under American
flags, and a much more thorough-going attack
21

which are quite powerful, have not been very
clear on what they think should be done with
the money supply; only the monetarists have
spoken up in any very detailed way on this
issue. I don’t think it would be fair to say that
monetarism has completely taken over the
Administration. The disagreement which
resulted in the clear inconsistency between the
real-growth and inflation targets on the one
hand, and the money-growth targets on the
other hand, represents a very important con­
tinuing split in the Administration. I don’t see
any immediate sign that that’s going to be
resolved.

on agricultural price supports than the minor
compromise on dairy price supports that has
received so much attention and praise. I think
we eventually have to tackle the over-indexing
of social-security payments and develop a
more sensible index for that purpose. That’s
the middle class’ favorite program, and one
not touched by the Reagan Administration up
to now. I could also think of some things that I
might like the Federal Government to spend
more money on. I don’t agree, by the way,
about tax expenditures. Deductible expen­
ditures at the initiative of the taxpayer should be
regarded as having something to do with the
allocation of resources by government fiscal
policy. Stockman and Reagan say that govern­
ment should not subsidize humanities, non­
commercial broadcasting, the arts, and socialscience research because the private sector can
do so out of tax-deductible contributions. But
that’s open-ended, and leaves the whole deci­
sion process up to the taxpayer. In a pluralistic
society, I would like to have some of each.

Q. Some of the big “ Keynesian” model
builders, such as Data Resources Inc. (DRI),
show 6-percent velocity growth over the next
several years. They forecast money growth
along the lines of what the Fed is targeting, yet
they see 10-percent inflation continuing along
with 3-percent growth. So they still get 13-per­
cent nominal GNP and then 6-percent
velocity.
Tobin: They say the Supreme Court reads
the election returns, and I’ve observed that to
be true also of econometric model builders.

Q. Professor Hall mentioned that there’s a
difference in opinion in the Reagan Adminis­
tration-one group that wants to reduce the
money supply year after year (who favor col­
umn one), and another group that wants to see
a less dramatically declining rate of nominal
income growth (who favor column three). It
seems to me that most of the public statements
have come from the people backing column
one. What people are backing column three,
and what are their prospects for success?
H all. The work I did in the fall brought me
into contact with supply-siders in a way that
university life had not, and I found that the
following general line of thought prevailed:
Anti-inflation policy in general and monetary
policy in particular needn’t be the major thrust
of policy. Rather, budget policy in its various
forms should be the major thrust, and prob­
lems of inflation and money creation will take
care of themselves if the budget can be
brought under control. The monetarists, on
the other hand, wanted to put most of the
emphasis on controlling money growth. The
supply-side forces in the Administration,

Q. Almost everyone agrees that the Ad­
ministration’s program has nothing to do with
inflation, yet it’s sold to the public with the
promise that it will take care of inflation.
Actually, what the program will do, in effect, is
to change the budget composition—the nature
of the role of government expenditures and
the role of taxes. With regard to tax policy, I
would emphasize that the problem is really
both one of tax structure and one of level.
Now, Mr. Hall at times refers to the need for
revising the tax structure, and at other times to
the need for cutting taxes. Should we not be
careful about mixing up these statements? To
restate the point, is capital-gains tax reduction
an appropriate analogy for income-tax reduc­
tion?
H all. I was only giving an example, in
which taxpayers under the existing tax law
have great discretion about how to conduct
their affairs. Capital-gains taxation is an

22

be used to stabilize the growth of nominal
GNP, I am prepared to defend the use of the
monetary instrument alone for this purpose.
We should adopt a specific target path for
nominal GNP and stick to it. Every time
nominal GNP gets a little higher than the path,
we should push it down using the appropriate
monetary contraction; and if we get a little bit
below, as we might during a recession, then we
should push it up through monetary expan­
sion. According to my research, manipulation
of monetary instrum ents could stabilize
nominal GNP quite well. The policy could
work in a number of ways, and might even
involve the use of an interest-rate rule. Let me
give you an example—I am not saying that this
is the best of all policies, but here is an exam­
ple of a policy that I think would have a
reasonable chance for success. The Treasurybill rate is to be pegged one percentage point
above the rate of inflation for each percentage
point that nominal GNP is above the target
path, and correspondingly below inflation
when nominal GNP is below target. So if
nominal GNP is, say, five percentage points
above target, then the Treasury-bill rate
should be five percentage points above the rate
of inflation. History has shown that it’s a con­
tractionary move for the Fed to set the Treas­
ury-bill rate or other short-term interest rates
well above the rate of inflation. Similarly, it’s a
very expansionary move, as we learned in the
late 1960s, to hold the Treasury bill rate below
the rate of inflation. This interest-rate policy
would be very easy for the Fed to carry out; it
doesn’t get into any of the difficulties that peg­
ging monetary aggregates does. And it’s based
on a nominal GNP goal. It’s a feedback rule
whose effect is to keep nominal GNP, plus or
minus a percent or two, on a prescribed track.
And it does what the Fed likes best, namely
stabilizing short-term interest rates. It gives
the Open Market Committee a formula to
determine the target interest rate. It would
accomplish exactly what I have advocated as
the general principle of monetary policy, keep­
ing nominal GNP on a predetermined growth
path, instead of keeping a monetary aggregate
on a predetermined path.

extreme case because taxpayers can choose
when to realize their gains. I don’t want to say
that the negative relation between tax rates
and tax revenues automatically applies to the
case of labor supply, but again the fact that an
awful lot of wage-type income manages to
escape taxation one way or the other is an
important fact. It suggests that there are dis­
cretionary tax shelters and the like which could
respond in a sharp way to tax rates. But that’s
only a guess. We really don’t know the answer
to the question.
Tobin. I want to comment briefly on this
shift of the supply-side view about tax
revenues from economic effects to pure taxevasion effects. There is a certain danger in the
idea that we must reduce taxes because they’re
being evaded, and keep reducing them until
we diminish the incentive to evade to the point
where more will be actually paid. If you
thought of the process as a game, considering
the precedents set in that sequence of events,
we would end up having no distortion by hav­
ing no taxes. But maybe we should consider a
trade-off between rate cuts on the one hand,
and appropriating more money to the Internal
Revenue Service on the other. And maybe we
should fix up the tax system so that we don’t
have so many of these shelters built into it.
Balles. Professor Hall made a statement
that he would warn against the adoption of col­
umn one in Professor Tobin’s table; that is, a
mechanical year-by-year half-point reduction
in money growth until you got to a point, at the
end of that period, where it was cut in half. He
also said he thought that we needed a strong
announcement as to what monetary-policy
aims would be. Since this is a central bank, and
since I am involved in monetary policy,
perhaps we could conclude with his advice to
us about what those strong announcements of
monetary-policy aims should be.
Hall. I presented a proposal to the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve last fall to
make nominal GNP rather than the money
stock the central focus of monetary policy.
Although I agree with Jim Tobin’s comment
that all policy, not just monetary policy, should
23