View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

library
FEDERAL
RESERVE
BANK OF




OCT

«mm

2 01969

mmni k f maw

SAN FRANCISCO

Monthly fleview

In this issue

Raising the Roof?
Putting Money into Bonds
Financing the Business Boom

September 1969




Etcsislng the ^©@1?
. . . The Administration has proposed removing the 41/^j-percent rate
ceiling on new Treasury bond issues; here are the pros and cons.

Putting M o n e y Into Bonds
. . . The Administration hopes to stimulate the lagging savings-bond
program by raising the interest rate on bonds to 5 percent.

Financing the Business Boom
.. . Financing requirements of the business-investment boom have
led to heavy reliance on external sources of funds since 1965.

Editor: W illiam Burke

September 1969

M O N THLY

REVIEW

Raising the Roof?
ver the past four years, the Treasury
has been unable to borrow any long­
term funds in the open market, and over the
past year, it has watched a declining sales
trend in its savings-bond program. The prob­
lem? Mainly, it is the 4 14 -percent statutory
ceiling on the rate of interest the Treasury is
permitted to pay on its marketable bonds and
nonmarketable savings bonds.

O

This ceiling prohibits the Treasury from
issuing any new securities of more than seven
years’ maturity which bear an interest coupon
greater than 4 14 percent. The rate limitation
does not apply to new shorter-term issues; on
these issues, the Treasury is able to set rates
in line with changing market conditions.
Today’s financial markets have made the
414 -percent ceiling unrealistic— an effective
barrier to Treasury borrowing, in the eyes of
many experts both inside and outside of
Washington. In the closing days of the 1968
Congressional session, the Senate approved a
bill to eliminate the legal interest-rate ceiling;
the bill died, however, when the House failed
to act. In June of this year, 67 of the na­
tion’s foremost economists issued a major
policy statement strongly urging elimination
of the ceiling. And in mid-July, the Nixon
Administration asked Congress to raise the
interest rate on savings bonds to 5 percent
and to remove entirely the 414-percent cou­
pon limitation on long-term U.S. Treasury
bonds. Thus, action may yet be taken on the
rate legislation now pending before Con­
gressional committees.
Several indicators point up the increasing
disparity which has developed between the
Treasury-bond rate ceiling and actual bond


market rates over the past two decades. Be­
tween 1949 and mid-1969, the market yield
on prime corporate bonds jumped from 2.66
to 6.98 percent, and the market yield on
existing Treasury bonds rose from 2.31 to
6.05 percent— while the ceiling rate on new
Treasury issues remained at 4.25 percent
throughout. Over the same time-span, the
average rate paid to depositors in savingsand-loan associations jumped from 2.40 to
4.67 percent—while the rate paid to holders
of savings bonds rose only from 2.90 to 4.25
percent, so that redemptions have exceeded
sales at a $750-million annual rate to date in
1969.

FEDERAL

176

RESERVE

BANK

Legal legacy
The 414-percent ceiling is a legal legacy
dating back to World War I. Prior to 1917,
the Secretary of the Treasury had little dis­
cretion in managing the public debt, and
every new offering of Treasury securities re­
quired specific congressional authorization
spelling out the particular terms and condi­
tions of each individual issue. But then, in
view of the Government’s heavy wartime
borrowing requirements, Congress granted
the Treasury broader power in determining
the terms of Treasury issues, although it still
insisted on retaining authority to set the in­
terest rate. In three successive Liberty Loan
Acts during 1917 and 1918, Congress set
the maximum interest rate payable on all
U.S. securities at 3 Vi percent, 4 percent, and
414 percent, respectively.
Treasury Secretary Carter Glass, antici­
pating further financing needs and feeling
constrained by the interest-rate limitation
during a period of rising market interest
rates, asked Congress in 1919 to grant the
Treasury more freedom and flexibility in
public-debt management. Congress acceded
to his request— but only in part. It removed
from the statutory interest-rate limitation
those U.S. marketable securities with matur­
ities of five years or less, but still kept the
4 14 -percent coupon ceiling on longer-term
securities. And there it has remained ever
since, although Congress recently (1967) ex­
tended the permissible maturity on Treasury
securities not subject to the ceiling from five
to seven years.
The Treasury first issued savings bonds in
1935, under an amendment attached to the
earlier legislation governing marketable is­
sues. The new provision enabled the Treas­
ury to offer nonmarketable securities at a
yield not to exceed 3 percent when held to
maturity. The ceiling has since been raised
three times, until the present 414-percent
limit was reached.




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

In May 1967, the Treasury issued a new
nonmarketable Government security — the
U.S. savings note (Freedom Share). Since
Freedom Shares mature in four-and-a-half
years, technically they are classified as notes
and are not subject to the 414-percent bond
ceiling. Freedom Shares, however, must be
purchased with a like amount of Series E
savings bonds. When first issued, the com­
bined E bond-Freedom Share package yield­
ed 4.39 percent if held to maturity. But the
yield on Freedom Shares was later raised
(June 1968) so that the effective combined
return now equals 4.54 percent.
No problem— until 1959
Throughout most of its history, the statu­
tory ceiling on long-term Treasury bonds did
not pose any particular problem. Until the
late 1950’s, in fact, prevailing market interest
rates were generally well below the 414percent limit, and when they were not, the
Treasury did not have any pressing need to
issue long-term bonds.
During the 1920’s, large budget surpluses
permitted the Government to reduce sub­
stantially the huge wartime debt, and thereby
precluded a need for additional bond issues.
In the 1930’s, interest rates were depressed
because of a sizable reduction in the level of
borrowing and a policy which provided a
plentiful supply of money. During World
War II and the early postwar period, interest
rates were maintained at artificially low levels
by the Treasury-Federal Reserve agreement
to peg long-term rates.
During the wartime period, moreover, se­
vere restrictions on the civilian economy
helped to create a massive backlog of demand
for consumer goods and services. When this
pent-up demand was released with the post­
war relaxation of controls, expenditures grew
faster than the available supply and inflation­
ary pressures rapidly mounted. So beginning
in 1951, the Federal Reserve, in an effort to

September 1969

MONTHLY

REVIEW

M<arlc@f yields rise s te a d ily over past two decades,
but ceiling rate on new Treasury issues remains at 4l/4 percent

inject an element of restraint into the econ­
omy, began cutting back on the reserves pro­
vided to the commercial-banking system.
Consequently, interest rates became more
sensitive to market forces, and moved almost
steadily upward for the remainder of the
decade, except during the recession periods
of 1953-54 and 1957-58.
By early 1959, interest rates started to
bump against and even to penetrate the 4Va percent ceiling, and so the Treasury found it­
self, as it finds itself today, confronted with
the inability to offer any new long-term
bonds. By the latter part of 1959, the battle
over the relative merits and disadvantages of
the statutory ceiling— whether to keep the
legal ceiling, raise it, or remove it entirely—
was in full swing. The verbal battle contin­
ued for a year or so, temporarily subsided in
the early 1960’s when interest rates edged off
somewhat, but was then resumed in late 1966
when inflation threatened, monetary policy
tightened, and interest rates climbed dra­
matically again.
An anachronism?
The critics regard the 4 Va -percent ceiling
as an anachronism. When current yields on
corporate Aaa bonds hover around 7 percent,



and when outstanding Government bonds
yield over 6 percent, a 4 Va -percent coupon
rate is obsolete. The 4 Va -percent coupon
compares so unfavorably with other market
interest rates that the Treasury has not of­
fered a new marketable issue since May 1965,
and instead it has been forced to rely exclu­
sively on short- and intermediate-term bor­
rowings to which the ceiling does not apply.
As a result, the av erag e m a tu rity of the
interest-bearing marketable public debt has
dropped almost 30 percent since mid-’65.
Heavy reliance on short-term debt has
inflationary implications for the economy. A
short-term instrument, by definition, is never
too far away from its maturity. As securities
approach maturity (which they inexorably do
with the passage of time), they become in­
creasingly liquid, more and more like cash.
After all, what is to prevent the holder of a
maturing issue from redeeming his securities
for cash, rather than rolling them over, and
then placing the p ro c e e d s in inflationary
spending channels?
Exclusive reliance on short-term debt in­
hibits the maneuverability of the Treasury in
managing the public debt. As the outstanding
debt becomes increasingly concentrated in
the short-term area, the Treasury is forced

177

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

to undertake more frequent refunding opera­
tions. By sheer necessity, the Treasury can
never be out of the financial markets for too
long a time. The Treasury is thus unable to
take advantage of favorable market condi­
tions to refinance the debt, but instead is
forced to borrow under whatever financial
conditions are prevailing at any given time.

178

Policy distortion?
A continuous stream of Treasury borrow­
ing can seriously complicate Federal Reserve
credit operations, especially during periods of
rapid business expansion when the Federal
Reserve may be trying to reduce the growth
in bank credit. Theoretically, the Treasury at
such times should reduce its offerings of rela­
tively liquid (that is, short-term) securities
and issue longer-term bonds instead. How­
ever, since an e x p a n sio n a ry , inflationary
economy is one inevitably marked by high
interest rates, the Treasury is trapped when­
ever interest rates pierce the 4 14 -percent
ceiling as they have today.
The Treasury simply cannot expect wouldbe investors to lend it long-term money at a
414-percent rate when investors can earn de­
cidedly higher yields on other instruments of
comparable risk. Thus the Treasury is thrust
into the short-term area — the volume of
liquid assets in the economy increases— and
the effectiveness of Federal Reserve creditrestraint operations is thereby reduced. So
with the Treasury constantly entering the
market, little elbow room is left for the effec­
tive pursuit of credit policy.
As the Treasury enters the market more
frequently, the probabilities are increased
that heavy Treasury financing will coincide
with private credit demands of a magnitude
that normally calls for restrictive monetarypolicy action. On some such occasions, the
normal response required by monetary pol­
icy may conflict with the need to maintain
sufficient reserves in the banking system to




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

avoid disorderly securities markets or the
failure of a Government issue. In these cir­
cumstances, the flexibility required by the
Federal Reserve in administering monetary
policy may be limited.
Undue reliance on short-term securities
clearly limits the Treasury’s debt-manage­
ment alternatives. The Treasury is barred
from seizing the opportunity to extend the
average life of what is becoming an increas­
ingly imbalanced public debt. Our debt will
undeniably endure for decades to come, so
it is impractical to prevent the Treasury from
borrowing funds for twenty-five or twenty
years or even ten. The Treasury is precluded
also from tapping some important sources of
savings, since managers of life -in s u ra n c e
companies and corporate and pension trust
funds, who are always looking for long-term
(not short-term) outlets for their funds, are
effectively blocked from purchasing most new
Treasury issues. Thus, in the final analysis,
debt management ceases to be an effective
policy tool.
Rate distortion?
The critics emphasize that interest rates are
basically determined by the changing forces
of supply and demand. The existence of a
ceiling, in itself, does not hold down actual
interest rates; when the level of rates exceeds
the ceiling that can be paid in a particular
sector, funds stop flowing to that sector and
flow around it instead, seeking the higher
earnings obtainable elsewhere. Similarly, the
removal of a ceiling will not result in higher
levels of interest.
Interest rates on short-term Government
securities, which are not subject to a statu­
tory-rate limitation, have historically moved
up and down with the business cycle. If the
ceiling were indeed influential in keeping a
lid on interest rates, then yields on outstand­
ing Government bonds also should be ex-

September 1969

MONTHLY

pected to stay below the 4 Va -percent level.
However, in today’s open market, long-term
Treasuries with unrealistically low coupon
rates are discounted in price to return yields
of around 6 percent. Thus, some substance
is lent to the contention of Senator Hugh
Scott: “No one has the wisdom to determine
the proper interest rate of U.S. issues —
neither the President, the (Treasury) Secre­
tary, the Reserve Board Chairman, nor the
Congress. Only the buyers and sellers of
bonds can set the price in the marketplace
— and it varies from day to day.”
The critics further contend that by forcing
the Treasury to conduct its financing exclu­
sively in the short-term area, the ceiling in
effect tends to drive up short-term interest
rates to a level considerably higher than
would have prevailed had the Treasury been
able to enter the long-term market as well.
Because the Treasury is competing for funds
in such a limited sector of the maturity spec­
trum, many short-term borrowers — such as
small businesses, consumers, and farmers —
will be faced with higher interest rates when
they try to borrow money. And for the same
reason, the interest rate the Treasury is forced
to pay on its short-term obligations may in
fact be higher than the rate it would have
paid had it been able to float issues in the
less congested long-term sector. These argu­
ments, however, would have to be modified
to the extent that the yield structure is deter­
mined by expectational factors rather than
by the market supply of debt instruments.
If the Treasury’s massive short-term bor­
rowing operations cause short-term interest
rates to rise relative to rates paid by savings
institutions, the troublesome problem of dis­
intermediation may arise. S avers w ill be
tempted to withdraw their funds from banks
and savings-and-loan associations and to in­
vest directly in higher-yielding, short-term
Government securities. If the outflow of sav­
ings is large enough, the savings institutions,



REVIEW

the major providers of home-mortgage credit,
will be forced to curtail their commitments to
acquire new mortgages. The homebuilding
industry thus stands to suffer considerable
damage.
Price control?
The 4 Va, -percent ceiling, in the critics’
eyes, is nothing more than a Governmentdecreed price control. The arbitrary, statu­
tory limitation is to ta lly c o n tra ry to the
fundamental principles governing a market
economy, whereby prices traditionally allo­
cate resources. History has taught us that
interference with the price mechanism can
only distort and disrupt the effective func­
tioning of economic forces. The ceiling fails
to recognize market realities, since in this
respect the Treasury is forced to base its
financing needs on economic and financial
conditions which p re v a ile d a half-century
ago.
The critics claim, too, that it is absurd for
Congress to repeatedly approve an increase
in the public-debt limit and not raise the
interest-rate ceiling at the same time. The
Treasury, although given the responsibility to
finance an enlarged public debt, is not pro­
vided with the requisite weapons to do so.
Again quoting Senator Scott, “It is like the
mother who gives her daughter an ample
clothes allowance, but enjoins her from pay­
ing more than $7.50 for a dress when the
cheapest dress she can buy is $10.00.”
Yet with all that, the Treasury has been
able to pursue some debt-lengthening opera­
tions despite the 4 Vi-percent limitation. The
first such step was the adoption of advanced
refunding (1960), which permits holders of
certain outstanding Government obligations
that will not mature for some time the option
of exchanging these holdings for new issues
of longer maturity. Another such step was the
recent (1967) extension in maturities, from
five to seven years, of Government securities

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

not subject to the 4 % -percent limit. Still, the
critics argue that these measures, however
ingenious, do not come face to face with the
immediate problem, since they do not furnish
the Treasury with the broad range of alterna­
tives that it needs for sound debt manage­
ment.

180

Case for the defense
As cogent and sensible as the critics’ argu­
ments undeniably are, they are not lacking a
reply from the defenders of the present ceil­
ing. But admittedly, the arguments in de­
fense of the 4 V4 -percent ceiling are con­
siderably less numerous and perhaps less
substantive than those of the critics.
The main justification for maintaining the
4 Va -percent ceiling is the assumption that it
effectively keeps interest rates down. In es­
sence, the defenders contend that removal
of the statutory limitation would promptly
cause other long-term interest rates to rise.
In the words of Congressman Wright Pat­
man, “If you raise the rates on U.S. Govern­
ment securities, that will raise all other in­
terest rates . . . Removing the 1918 ceiling
is unwise and unwarranted . . . Y o u cannot
raise Government rates and not raise other
rates.”
If the average interest rate paid on Gov­
ernment securities were to increase, Congress
would increase the cost of servicing the na­
tional debt and the consequent cost to the
taxpayer. Removing or raising the ceiling is
seen as casting an irrevocable vote for higher
interest. Consumers, farmers, businesses and
the Government will all be forced to pay
more for the money they want; only the
banks and the big-money moguls will stand to
gain. Moreover, if the rate on Government
bonds were made sufficiently attractive, in­
vestors would be tempted to take their funds
out of savings accounts and put them into
Government bonds— and homebuilding activity subsequently would be hampered.




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

Defenders of the status quo feel that the
Treasury has already done harm merely by
requesting removal of the ceiling. This re­
quest, they declare, will be interpreted by
the market as a conviction on the part of the
Treasury that even higher interest rates are
foreseeable in the near future— and will thus
be an invitation to the market to react ac­
cordingly.
The 4 Va -percent limitation has been on
the books for a long time, the defenders point
out, and it has provided a desirable element
of Congressional control over Treasury fi­
nancing. Moreover, what if interest rates
should decline? By paying a higher rate on
bond issues at this time, the Treasury would
be obligated to these high rates for many
years. The Treasury should wait until rates
decline somewhat before considering any
long-term financing. And even if Congress
were to remove the ceiling, the Treasury
probably would not, under present market
conditions, offer any large volume of long­
term securities, because of fear of overbur­
dening that segment of the market. So, the
defenders ask, why all the fuss?
It is now up to Congress to assess the con­
tending arguments and decide on the ap­
propriate ceiling rate— if any— on the Trea­
sury’s marketable bonds and savings bonds.
The legislators could decide to retain the
present ceiling, because of a laudable desire
to check the growing cost of financing the
Treasury’s debt, or because of an impression
that ceilings on rates do, indeed, keep interest
rates low. But they could just as well decide
to lift the limit completely, because of the
greater logic of the argument that ceilings are
as likely to raise as to lower the actual interest
rates paid in the nation’s financial markets.
Money after all, tends to be like water, in
that it flows round the obstacles placed in
its path.
Karen Kidder

September 1969

M ONTHLY

REVIEW

Putting Money into Bonds
A fter a third of a century of glancing at

billboards, reading magazine ads, and
listening to TV commercials, Americans have
become readily familiar with the message,
“Buy U.S. Savings Bonds.” Their response
has varied over the years, depending on the
strength of their patriotic desire to assist war­
time financing or their personal desire to
participate in a systematic savings plan—or,
as in the present instance, depending on their
willingness to keep savings in this form when
they can get a higher return on their money
elsewhere. But, although most individuals
have become well aware of the program in
this sense, relatively few realize the still
enormous magnitude of the program or its
still significant role in the nation’s financial
system.
The greatest interest in savings bonds de­
veloped during World War II— in 1944,
the popular Series E bond posted gross sales
of $12.4 billion and redemptions of $3.0
billion. In the postwar period, however,
gross sales and redemptions have both moved
within a narrow range of $3 to $5 billion—
in 1968, the figures were $5.0 billion and
$4.9 billion, respectively. (The figures in­
clude the new Freedom Shares as well as
the standard Series E and H bonds.) Total
outstandings are now over $52 billion—
about 10 percent below the end-1950 peak
— and savings bonds thus account for almost
one-fourth of the $229-billion publicly held
Federal debt.
W hat they buy
From the individual saver’s viewpoint,
savings bonds differ significantly from Treas­



ury marketable bonds. Their price never
fluctuates; savings bonds are always redeem­
able at a price fixed in advance by the Treas­
ury. Their interest rate never declines; in
fact, when the Government decides to raise
rates to attract more lenders, it raises rates
on previously issued bonds as well. More­
over, the interest rate increases as a bond
matures; the typical Series E bond pays
2.24 percent if redeemed at the end of a
half-year, but it pays 3.75 percent when held
for three years and 4.25 percent when held
to maturity of seven years— and after ma-

Savings-bond program remains
relatively stable after World W ar II
Billions of Dollars

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

turity it continues to earn the last and highest
interest rate.
From the viewpoint of the borrower, the
Federal Government, savings bonds also
differ to some extent from Treasury market­
able bonds. With marketable bonds, the
Government generally borrows large amounts
from a fairly small number of large institu­
tions. When the Government decides how
much it requires, it sets the terms on each
issue with an eye towards current market
conditions, and it does not pay off its bonds
until they mature or are refunded. (Indi­
vidual purchasers of course can resell in the
open market.) But with savings bonds, the
Government usually borrows small amounts
from large numbers of individuals. More
important, savings-bond transactions are not

OF

SAN

F R A N C IS C O

subject to close control; when the Govern­
ment sets the terms, it cannot be certain how
much the individual will buy, nor how much
(or how soon) he will redeem for cash.
Towards the wartime peak
Although the present savings-bond pro­
gram dates back to the early days of World
War II, its roots can be traced farther back
to the Second Liberty Bond Act of 1935, or
even to the Postal Savings Act of 1910.
Around the turn of the century, Americans
were not blessed as they are today with a
wealth of reliable banking services, and
many people consequently were convinced
that depositing savings in the average finan­
cial institution was a form of Russian roulette

Demise of the Immigrants' Bank

182

The millions of European immigrants and American farmers who poured into
U.S. cities around the turn of the century were anxious to find a safe place to bank
their earnings, so in 1911 the U.S. Government established the Postal Savings
System in order to meet their needs. But the children of that generation in recent
years have shown a marked preference for banks and other financial institutions,
and the Government accordingly closed the postal savings window two years ago.
The heyday of the system came during the Depression and World War II,
when prospective depositors were won over by the combined appeal of safety, con­
venience, and a 2-percent return. In 1947, the peak was reached with 4.2 million
depositors holding deposits of $3.4 billion. But the system thereafter ran downhill;
when the window banged shut in June 1967, only about 600,000 depositors were
left, and their accounts totaled only about $60 million. In fact, almost one-third of
the accounts then on the books had been inactive for 20 years or more.
The postwar decline came about as the original advantages of the system were
matched or exceeded by those available elsewhere. Safety was no longer a factor,
in view of the adoption of deposit insurance by commercial banks and savings-andloan associations. Convenience too was no longer a factor, in view of the extension
of banking hours and the availability of bank-by-mail services. And the 2-percent
deposit rate lost its attractiveness, especially during the present decade, as sharply
higher rates were posted on bank deposits, S&L shares, and savings bonds.
Throughout its history, most postal-savings depositors were city dwellers
rather than rural or small-town inhabitants. First-class post offices handled almost
85 percent of total deposits two decades ago— and almost 95 percent of total
deposits in the final years of the program. The smaller post offices in outlying areas
handled only a small portion of the total business during this period.




September 1969

M O N TH LY

—but without the usual peaceful prospect
of eternal bliss.
Widespread agitation arose to protect the
little man from the vagaries of financial for­
tune, expressed for example in the platform
of the little man’s party— the Populist Party
— as early as 1892. Eventually Congress
acquiesced in these demands by making it
possible for individuals to save through the
U.S. post office, and it thereby permitted indi­
vidual savings to act as investment funds
rather than mattress stuffing.
One form of postal savings, the postal
savings bond, was discontinued in 1935 and
replaced by the U.S. savings bond. This new
savings instrument was made available for
sale at post offices, was immediately redeem­
able, and carried the full credit of the U.S.
Government. This new instrument thus dra­
matized safety, since it provided a safe place
for individual holdings when faith in other
financial instruments had all but collapsed.
The savings bond also dramatized prefer­
ential treatment for the small saver. He could
count on a 2.9-percent rate if he held the
bond to maturity— a significantly higher rate
than was available on other instruments at
that time. To emphasize the program’s smallsaver orientation, the Treasury offered higher
yields on the series aimed at small savers
than on other series of bonds, and it also set
a ceiling on the amount that could be sold
annually to any investor.
Because of the depressed conditions of the
1930’s, initial sales of the U.S. savings bond
were less than startling. With the war-time
prosperity of the 1940s, however, the savings-bond program reached its full maturity.
Seeing the anti-inflationary possibilities of
a program that could channel substantial
amounts of war-inflated incomes out of the
spending stream, the Treasury moved ag­
gressively to sell savings bonds, not only
through the post office but also through banks
and payroll-savings plans. The bond drives



REVIEW

In v esto rs re d u c e bond holdings as
attractive yields appear elsewhere
Percent

of this period were fantastically successful;
outstandings jumped from $6 billion in 1941
to $48 billion in 1945, and eventually
reached a peak of $58 billion in 1950.
Down from the peak
Savings bonds have never since reached
such a high level of popularity. Although
outstandings have actually increased during
the present decade after drifting downward
during the previous one, they now account
for only about 8 percent of publicly-held
liquid assets as against 23 percent in 1946.
To a large extent, this reflects the fact that
the individual now has considerably more
attractive (and legal) outlets for his funds
than he had during World War II.
This development also reflects the fact that
other savings instruments are now consider­
ably safer than they used to be, and offer a
higher return as well. Although savingsbonds rates have risen, rates on other instru­
ments have increased even faster, so sales of

183

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

savings bonds have gone down while redemp­
tions have gone up. Over the postwar period,
the average rate of return on savings bonds
held to maturity has risen from 2.90 to 4.25
percent, but the rate on one competitive
instrument, savings-and-loan shares, has
jumped from 2.20 to 4.67 percent.
Savings-bond sales, especially in the early
postwar period, also declined because of a
strong consumer preference for goods rather
than savings. During World War II, the
sales attractiveness of savings bonds was
aided by the overall shortage of consumer
goods as well as by patriotic motives. As
these factors weakened in the postwar period,
households helped to fuel the postwar infla­

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

tion, not only by reducing their savings rate
but also by cashing in their bonds for con­
sumption purchases. The ease of bond
redemption, which had been considered es­
sential for the purpose of attracting small
savings, was thus something of a hindrance
during the inflationary episodes of 1946 and
1950— and 1969.
Combating the decline
The Treasury has taken several steps in
the last several years to obtain the small in­
vestor’s cooperation in its specific task of
financing Government operations and in its
more general task of fighting inflation. First
of all (May 1967), the Treasury introduced

Bond Program

W e s t e r n
The West has posted a weaker-than-national bond sales performance in recent
years, perhaps reflecting the wider gap between savings-bond rates and rates on
competitive instruments in this region. Western banks and savings-and-loan associ­
ations have consistently offered higher returns on savings instruments than their
counterparts elsewhere, while savings-bond salesmen of course have offered the
same rate nation-wide. So while individual Western savers deposited substantial
amounts of savings in Western financial institutions last year, they purchased only
$586 million in savings bonds, or less than 12 percent of the U.S. total. In contrast,
Westerners accounted for over 16 percent of total personal income during 1968.
M illions of Dollars

184



District Shars (Pereont)

September 1969

M ONTHLY

a new and higher-yielding instrument into
the savings-bond program.
The U.S. savings note (Freedom Share),
of which $494 million worth were sold in the
first two years of operation, is actually a
short-term savings bond, although it differs in
some respects from the popular Series E
bond. It pays 5 percent after four and one
half years instead of 4.25 percent after seven
years. Moreover, it is only purchasable with
an E bond of equal denomination— so that
the effective rate of the two together is low­
ered to 4.54 percent at maturity. Also, to
emphasize the Freedom Share’s intended role
as an anti-inflationary weapon, each note
must be held for one year before becoming
eligible for redemption.
Then, as already noted, the Treasury
asked Congress this July for legislation to
permit the payment of a 5-percent rate on
regular savings bonds which are purchased
after June 1 and are held to maturity. (Bonds
cashed in prior to maturity would also earn
higher rates than they do now.) In the pro­
posed legislation, the original maturity of
the Series E bond would be shortened to five
years ten months from the present seven
years, while the Freedom Shares would con­
tinue on sale for a six-month transition pe­
riod. This Treasury proposal would make
savings bonds competitive once again, in
terms of rates, with other savings instruments,
but for that very reason it has aroused oppo­
sition from savings-and-loan associations and
other segments of the financial community.
Marketing effort
The marketing of savings bonds and sav­
ings notes involves the cooperation of a num­
ber of public and private agencies. The
advertising industry, for instance, contributed
$62 million in services in 1968 to disseminate
the savings message through publications,
radio-TV, and mass-transit ads. Many na­
tional and regional corporations conduct
their own bond-sales campaigns, and some



REVIEW

16,000 banks and other financial institutions
maintain special windows to sell and redeem
bonds. For its part, the Treasury spends on
bond-sales administration the bulk of the
total amount required to administer the en­
tire public debt, aside from interest payments
themselves.
Business firms participate in this program
for a number of reasons. Patriotic and pub­
lic-service motives, of course, are important.
In particular, TV and radio stations are ex­
pected to carry some public-service ads, in
light of their function to operate in “the pub­
lic service, convenience, and interest.”
Business firms also promote savings bonds
for personnel reasons. Corporations utilize
bond sales in conjunction with employee savings-and-pension plans, and frequently they
promote bond sales as a thrift measure be­
cause they consider that savings-conscious
employees are better employees.
Commercial-bank role
Commercial banks are also active promot­
ers of the savings-bond program. They sell
and redeem bonds at tellers’ windows. They
offer both payroll savings to employees and
savings plans to customers (through deduc­
tions from savings accounts), and they often
handle the accounting and inscription work
on bonds sold through business payroll plans.
Substantial bank participation of this type
provides services both to business firms and
to the Federal Government.
The bank service to business naturally
brings in deposits. The handling of large
payroll-savings accounts can be costly, but
the earnings made by banks on such deposits
are frequently sufficient to cover handling
costs. Besides, the services offered in han­
dling payroll savings can be useful in attract­
ing new business deposits.
The bank service to customers does not
necessarily bring it more business, since U.S.
savings bonds compete with credit instru­
ments offered by the banks themselves, such

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

as savings certificates and passbook-savings
deposits. However, to the extent that savings
bonds do not compete— that is, to the extent
that savers intend to save a certain amount
in bonds anyway— bank handling of bonds is
useful for attracting new business. For that
matter, some of these handling costs are
borne by the Treasury, which reimburses
banks 10 to 15 cents for every bond redemp­
tion. (Total reimbursements in fiscal 1968
were over $13 million.)
The cost to banks of performing services
for the Treasury is partly offset by the gain
from TT&L accounts — Treasury tax-andloan accounts. These deposits, which are
the repository of the large balances accumu­
lated from public tax payments and loan sub­
scriptions, can be quite profitable to banks.

186

W ho buys bonds?
There remains the individual bond-buyer,
the customer around whom the entire pro­
gram revolves. To what extent is he influ­
enced in his purchase and redemption deci­
sions — aside from patriotic motives and
general consumption-savings considerations
— by considerations of safety, liquidity,
taxes, and interest return?
Savings bonds, of course, offer complete
safety of principal as well as easy redeemability. Over the years their stable value and
guaranteed return — and a return which has
been raised on several occasions — have
proved attractive to certain classes of savers,
and this attractiveness has been sufficient to
overcome the tax and yield advantages of­
fered by other instruments. The conservative
saver who wants to be sure of his investment
will always find a useful haven in savings
bonds.
Savers in high tax brackets, who are inter­
ested more in tax savings and after-tax yield
than in seceurity or liquidity, often prefer
municipal bonds to savings bonds. The latter
offer certain tax advantages — exemption
from state taxes and deferral of Federal taxes




OF

SAN

FR A N C ISC O

until redemption. But in view of the rela­
tively low level of state tax rates and the
Federal tax exemption on municipal bonds,
tax considerations do not make savings bonds
especially attractive to high-bracket indi­
viduals.
Savers primarily influenced by yield con­
siderations have tended, in the recent past, to
ignore savings bonds in favor of such alterna­
tive' instruments as S&L shares and bank
savings deposits. After all, the latter instru­
ments are also safe, since savings institutions
are insured and regulated, and they are liquid
as well, since prior-withdrawal notices are not
enforced. Even in the short run, they offer
a higher yield than savings bonds— a higher
yield, say, than the combined E bond-Freedom Share rate of 3.57 percent after one
year. It is this consideration, of course, which
has led the Treasury to propose lifting the
rate ceiling on savings bonds.
The small saver nevertheless remains the
best target for savings-bonds promotion. In
fact, over half of the total volume of sales
is made through payroll-savings plans geared
to the small saver. (Participation rates in in­
dividual firms vary from 1 to 100 percent,
with an average participation rate of roughly
25 percent.) The only major drawback to
this type of marketing is in the high rate
of redemption, since, in some recent years,
roughly half of the small-denomination bonds
have been redeemed in the first year after
purchase.
Despite the present disadvantage in rates,
savings bonds continue attractive to many
savers— witness the $52 billion in bonds now
outstanding. For reasons of safety, liquidity,
and, not least, patriotism, millions of small
savers will continue to participate in this
major savings program. And, assuming ap­
proval of the Treasury’s proposal for an
increase in rates, the worrisome trend in bond
redemptions should be reversed.
Arthur Darling

September 1969

MONTHLY

REVIEW

Western Digest
Alaska Opens Oil Bidding
Alaska sold $900 million in oil leases — the largest such sale in history —
for 451,000 acres of petroleum-rich Arctic land on September 10. Contracts will
run for ten years on the leases, which cover about one-third of the state’s total
holdings in the North Slope area. Alaska, moreover, will obtain 12V^-percent
royalty payments on the leases. . . . About $180 million in deposit checks on the
bids were flown immediately from Anchorage to New York and other financial
centers, to permit immediate cashing and investment of the proceeds. Under state
law, proceeds from the leases can be invested only in U.S. Government securities.
Farm Output to Decline?
Farm experts expect a slight decline in Western field-crop output this year,
mostly because of a sharp 11-percent drop in wheat production. Cotton production
may fall slightly, reflecting a lower level of yields rather than any cutback in acre­
age. . . . Output of processing vegetables may drop more than 20 percent, because
of a sharp cutback in tomato production, while output of fresh summer vegetables
may also decline, but by a far smaller amount. Production estimates for deciduous
fruits, however, indicate an 11-percent increase over last year’s harvest. Substantial
increases are expected for apples, cherries, apricots, peaches, pears, and grapes.
Pacific Air Fares to Decline
American, Japanese, and British airlines agreed on an 8-percent reduction in
Pacific passenger fares (subject to Government approval), beginning this October.
. . . A round-trip tourist ticket between New York and Tokyo will now cost $879,
down from the present $960, for the summer peak period. However, the airlines
will also offer lower fares for offpeak periods, including a new round-trip group fare
of $600, effective next January.
Lumber Prices Stabilize
An improved inflow of orders and a stable level of production permitted the
Northwest lumber industry to halt its severe four-month-long price decline in mid­
summer. But despite the August upturn, ranging as high as $7 per thousand boardfeet for Douglas fir lumber and as high as $9 per thousand square-feet for sanded
plywood, prices in both categories remained well below levels prevailing a year ago.
. . . The industry’s price outlook is still clouded by the relatively bleak short-term
prospects of the residential-construction industry. On the supply side, moreover,
the processing of perhaps 5 billion board-feet of timber blown down by Hurricane
Camille should also depress prices somewhat.




FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

Financing the Business Boom
he financial system in recent years has
been faced with the task of supplying a
record volume of funds to finance record
levels of corporate investment. Business in­
vestment needs have resulted in a series of
new peaks in financing activity. But in at­
tempting to meet its goals, the corporate sec­
tor has had to bid away funds from others,
and this has been accomplished only with
increasing difficulty and cost. Thus, strains
have appeared in the financial system — evi­
denced by a record rise in interest rates and
by a slowdown in the investment growth rate.

T

188

Private investment expenditures have
played a key role in the massive expansion
of the economy since 1961. New investment
in plant and equipment — and in residential
housing and inventories—has both sustained
and reacted to the growth of the national
economy. Larger investm ent has helped
stimulate economic activity, and greater eco­
nomic activity in turn has stimulated more
investment. The success of previous invest­
ments has reinforced optimistic expectations,
and the pressure on existing capacity has
justified further investment. Altogether, be­
tween 1961 and the first half of 1969, a 78percent increase in GNP was accompanied
by a 92-percent increase in private invest­
ment, from $72 billion to $137 billion per
year.
Prior to 1965 — the dividing point of the
decade in more ways than one — the econ­
omy was recovering from the minor reces­
sion that ended in 1961. Some slack still
existed in the economy, and new investment
was being financed with little trouble. But
by late 1965, demand was beginning to press
upon productive capacity. Continued heavy




investment demand was now competing not
only with private consumption but with in­
creased spending by government, primar­
ily defense spending, but also state-and-local
government spending. The following article
concentrates on investment by non-financial
corporations, whose capital expenditures
make up approximately four-fifths of gross
domestic investment.
Business needs
Until 1965, the increase in business invest­
ment spending had been gradual. Non-financial corporations increased their capital ex­
penditures from $37 billion in 1961 to $54

September 1969

M ONTHLY

billion in 1964. Then, in the latter part of
1965, the rate of corporate capital spending
picked up. The biggest jump was centered
in the plant-and-equipment component. This
category alone jumped by $8 billion in that
year, and repeated with an $ 11-billion in­
crease in 1966. With expenditures on resi­
dential construction and inventories added
in, total capital expenditures by non-financial
corporations reached $64 billion in 1965 and
$81 billion in 1966.
This pace was not sustainable, and in 1967
the level fell back to $75 billion. There was
a recovery in 1968, when corporate capital
spending returned to $79 billion for the year
as a whole. For the last quarter of that year,
expenditures ran at an even higher pace as
business investment accelerated again, and
new records were marked up in the first half
of 1969.
By the second quarter of 1969, capital ex­
penditures were at a $90-billion annual rate,
over $10 billion above the rate in the same
period of the preceding year. As in the 196566 upswing, plant-and-equipment expendi­
tures led. Spending in this category jumped
from $66 billion to $77 billion (annual rates)
between second-quarter 1968 and secondquarter 1969.
It is clear that the expansion of capital
spending by non-financial corporations was
not consistent over the whole period of ex­
pansion. It moved somewhat unevenly, with
the biggest expansions being concentrated in
two periods, the first occurring in 1965-66,
and the second beginning in mid-1968 and
continuing to the present. It is also clear that
expenditures on plant and equipment made
up the dominant element in these expansions.
Of the other categories of corporate capital
expenditures, spending on residential con­
struction was the least important. Beginning
in 1961, this rose steadily from $2 billion in
1961 to an annual rate of $4 billion in the
second quarter of 1969, with the year-by­



REVIEW

year changes always being less than $1 bil­
lion.
The remaining category, changes in in­
ventories, was the key source of demand at
certain times during this prolonged expan­
sion, although the annual totals tend to ob­
scure this role. In the fourth quarter of 1966,
in particular, inventory accumulation reached
a peak of $18 billion (annual rate) — 21
percent of the current level of capital expen­
ditures — but by the second quarter of 1967,
inventory spending was back to an annual
rate of $3 billion. With the exception of that
brief period, fluctuations in inventories have
been relatively small, but within that period,
they were definitely a major source of in­
stability.
Business funds: internal
Record levels of capital expenditures in
turn imply record levels of financing, and it
is on the financing side that the strains have
been clearest. Corporations normally can
count upon financing the larger part of their
capital expenditures from internal sources,
that is, retained earnings plus depreciation
allowances. Some corporations are able to
finance all their needs internally but, in the
aggregate, corporate investment usually ex­
ceeds the volume of internal funds, so that
corporations must rely to some extent upon
external sources as well.
In the first half of the decade, internal
sources were sufficient to supply about 94
percent of non-financial corporations’ capital
expenditures. With the acceleration of the
rate of investment, however, the gap between
c a p ita l e x p e n d itu re s and internal funds
widened rapidly. In 1965, the percentage of
capital spending financed internally was 88
percent and in 1966, 76 percent, as capital
spending outran internal funds. Over the next
two years, as the rate of investment slowed
its climb, the percentage internally financed
varied between 80 and 82 percent. Then with

189

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

C@rp©r€§fl®msa flow of internal
funds fails to match investment needs
Billions of Dollars

190

the resurgence of capital expenditures in late
1968, the gap again widened, so that internal
sources were only able to supply 70 percent
of total capital spending in the second quarter
of 1969.
This decline in the share of investment
supported by internal funds was not due to
any general decline in internal funds. In
1964, corporate retained earnings and depre­
ciation allowances totaled $51 billion; by
1968, they totaled $63 billion, or 24 percent
higher. But a 24-percent increase in such
funds was far from sufficient to meet corpo­
rate needs. A glance at the two types of
internal financing may indicate some of the
difficulties.
Capital consumption (depreciation) allow­
ances provide the largest source of internal
corporate funds. These allowances depend
upon the previous level of corporate invest­
ment, which determines the size of the poten­
tial capital stock that can be depreciated, and
they also depend upon tax laws, which set
limits on the rates of allowable depreciation.
Therefore, the steady growth of plant-equip­
ment spending increases depreciation allow­
ances. (In 1961, they were $25 billion; in
1965, $35 billion; and in 1968, $44 billion.)
Generally they have grown at a steady pace,




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

around 7 percent each year prior to 1965
and from 8 to 9 percent thereafter. In addi­
tion, the Federal government has shifted the
amounts allowed under the tax laws in an
attempt to influence depreciation and in turn
investment. These efforts have p ro d u c e d
some changes, but nevertheless year-by-year
fluctuations have been quite small except in
the beginning of the decade.
Depreciation allowances generally have
varied between 71 percent and 63 percent
of total internal funds. But this variation is
attributable primarily to the quite volatile
fluctuations in the other component of inter­
nal funds, net retained profits.
The volume of retained corporate profits
depends, first of all, upon gross (before-tax)
profits, and then on the level of corporate
income taxes. The final element in determin­
ing the amount of retained earnings is the
proportion of after-tax profits paid out in
dividends to shareholders. Each of these fac­
tors must be examined in turn to explain the
sharp fluctuations in retained profits.
Profits before taxes increased in line with
the growth of the economy in the early part
of the decade, and then accelerated with a
$ 6-billion gain in 1964. They then grew fur­
ther in the two following years, with a record
$8-billion increase in 1965 and a further
$6-billion gain in 1966. The upward trend
was broken in 1967 when gross profits fell
$4 billion, but the upward movement was
resumed in 1968 with a $7-billion gain.
Changes in Federal corporate-tax rates
have had a definite impact on the flow of
internal finance. With the passage of legisla­
tion reducing Federal income taxes, the per­
centage of gross profits taken by taxes fell
from approximately 47 percent in 1963 to
below 44 percent in 1964. As a result, some
$2 billion was freed from tax payments and
became available for corporate expansion.
The imposition of the surcharge on cor­
porate profits and personal incomes reversed

September 1969

MONTHLY

that gain, so that corporations in 1968 be­
came confronted again with pre-1964 style
tax levels. Thus the percentage of gross earn­
ings going to corporate-profit taxes increased
from 43 percent in 1967 to over 48 percent
last year. The new taxes absorbed almost $4
billion in funds in a year when corporate
investment was going up by $6 billion.
The third element in this picture is cor­
porate dividend policy. The usual pattern is
for dividends to reflect fluctuations in profits
with some time lag: dividends are increased
only after a new higher level of profits is
well-established, but then when profits fall,
dividends are lowered only with reluctance.
This lagged response is evident, for example,
after the 1964 jump in profits and the later
decline. The percentage of after-tax income
going to dividends fell from 49 percent in
1963 to under 43 percent in 1964, and it
remained near that level until 1967. Then
the ratio jumped to 46 percent, and it rose
again in the following year to 50 percent —
at which point the ratio was back to what it
was in the recession year of 1961. In 1969,
the percentage of after-tax profits paid out
in dividends rose even further, reaching 55
percent in the second quarter of the year.
As a consequence of these various trends,
net retained earnings helped stimulate the
mid-decade upsurge in investment, since cor­
porations had a greater flow of internal funds
available for a time. Between 1964 and 1966,
retained profits supplied 35 to 37 percent of
internal finance, compared with under 30
percent in the early ’60s. Then in 1967, as
gross profits slipped and as dividend pay­
ments continued to rise, this source provided
only 33 percent of internal funds. In 1968,
with the imposition of the surcharge, retained
profits fell even further to 30 percent of in­
ternal funds, and by second-quarter ’69 the
ratio slipped some more to 25 percent.
By previous standards, the increases in the
dollar amount of internal funds in 1965 and



REVIEW

1966 would have been more than sufficient
to meet non-financial corporations’ needs, but
they turned out to be insufficient because of
the still more rapid increase in capital ex­
penditures. The result was heavier depen­
dence upon external funds as the gap widened
between capital expenditures and internal
sources of funds.
From $2 billion in 1964, the gap widened
to $8 billion in 1965 with the acceleration in
in v e stm e n t e x p e n d itu re s — and it then
jumped to $18 billion in 1966. The situation
improved somewhat in 1967 with the slow­
down in investment, but sluggish business
also meant a fall in profits, so that capital
expenditures remained some $14 billion
above the amount provided by internal
sources. Demands for external funds then
jumped in 1968-69 as investment picked up
and as internal sources failed to meet financ­
ing needs; in 1968 the difference was $16
billion, and the situation was even worse in
1969.
Business funds: external
As capital expenditures outran internal
funds, the obvious result was heavier reliance
upon external sources. Although external
funds may pay for other things than capital
expenditures — for example, the accumula­
tion of financial assets for liquidity or income
— the link between the capital-expenditures
deficit and the volume of external financing
is apparent.
Between 1961 and 1964, when capital ex­
penditures were still rising slowly, the deficit
never accounted for more than 27 percent
of net external funds raised by nonfinancial
corporations. In other words, the bulk of
new outside funds went toward the acquisi­
tion of various financial assets. But after
1965, the situation changed. In the next
four years, the capital-expenditures deficit
accounted for an average of 58 percent of
total external financing, and in 1966, the year
of the monetary “crunch,” it absorbed 83

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

Businesses rely heavily
on external sources of funds
Billions of Dollars

192

percent. In first-half 1969, another period
of heavy financial demands and heavy capital
expenditures, the deficit averaged 76 percent
of a record level of external financing.
The other side of the coin is a substantial
jump in the dollar volume of external financ­
ing. Between 1961 and 1964, total external
funds raised in each year varied from a low
of $9 billion (1961) to a high of $13V2 bil­
lion (1964). Thereafter, the dollar volume
climbed rapidly; in 1965, external funds
jumped to $19 billion, and in 1967, they
reached $28 billion. After a decline in 1968
to $26 billion, the volume averaged $37 bil­
lion (annual rate) in the first half of 1969.
It is thus clear that the rapid growth of capi­
tal expenditures since 1965 has been the
principal factor behind the increased corpo­
rate reliance upon external sources of finance.
Not only has the total volume of external
finance increased sharply over the period
1965-69, but the pattern of external sources
has also shifted. Bank borrowing (exclusive
of mortgages) has become more important
and has remained a major source of funds
into 1969. To begin with, bank loans jumped
from under $4 billion in 1964 to over $9 bil­
lion in 1965, and came to represent the larg­
est single source of external funds in that




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

year. Bank borrowing still remained heavy
in 1966, at $7 billion, despite the tightening
of monetary policy — and in 1967, at $5 bil­
lion, despite greater corporate reliance upon
direct issues of securities. And of course the
pace was again heavy later on, with $7 billion
in bank borrowing in 1968, and an average
annual rate of $9 billion in the first half of
1969.
Overall, the principal means of raising
funds has been the issue of new corporate
bonds in the capital markets. (Issues of com­
mon stock have been of relatively minor
importance.) In 1965 net bond issues were
at $5 billion. They then doubled in 1966 to
$10 billion, despite a restrictive monetary
policy, and with the easing of interest rates
in 1967, they rose to $15 billion. Then, after
a slight decline in 1968, bond sales were run­
ning at a heavy $ 12-billion rate in early 1969.
In brief, since late 1965 corporations have
met almost 50 percent of their external fi­
nancing needs through bond sales.
In terms of gross proceeds from bonds, the
upward trend is even more striking. In 1965,
the total amount of new corporate (including
financial) bond issues totaled $14 billion,
and in 1967 it reached a peak of $22 billion.
By 1968, gross proceeds reached $17 billion,
and in the first half of 1969, they totaled over
$9 billion.
New gross issues of common and preferred
stock have also been rising. In 1965, these
totaled just over $2 billion. In 1968 they
approached $5 billion, and they amounted to
$4 billion in the first half of 1969. However,
many of these new stock offerings were used
to replace existing stock and, on a net basis,
their actual importance was much smaller
than the gross figures indicate. Still, the same
can be said of bond proceeds. A rising pro­
portion of new bond issues were convertible
into common and preferred stock and there­
fore were potential stocks and not purely
debt instruments. In the past two years,

September 1969

M ON THLY

approximately one fifth of bond proceeds
were in convertible issues.
Net financing through stock issues amount­
ed to $1 billion or less in every year of this
decade except 1967 — and in 1968, in fact,
there was net retirement despite a record
gross volume of new stock issues. Thus, as
a net source of external finance, stocks have
been relatively unimportant in most years.
In the search for new sources of funds, cor­
porations have begun to exploit an old yet
relatively neglected type of debt instrument:
commercial paper. C o m m ercial p a p e r is
simply short-term unsecured debt. The un­
secured nature of this security has restricted
its use in practice to prime borrowers —
borrowers with a minimal risk of default —
so that commercial paper tends to be issued
mainly by the larger corporations. For these
corporations, the issuance of paper through
dealers has become an attractive alternative
source of funds, especially as corporations
find bank finance both increasingly scarce
and increasingly expensive. (Financial cor­
porations usually issue their commercial
paper directly). Altogether, commercial
paper has provided an additional $1 to $2
billion a year since 1965, or more than
double the amount raised through stock
issues.
Overall, the expansion of business invest­
ment financing has relied heavily upon out­
side debt financing, not new equity. The prin­
cipal sources have been corporate bonds,
bank loans, mortgages, and commercial pa­
per, in that order. With this heavy depen­
dence upon the financial markets in a period
when the economy is operating near full
capacity and when governments and consum­
ers are also competing strenuously for funds,
the costs of such financing — that is, interest
rates — have reached record-high levels.
In the first half of 1969, corporate Aaarated bonds were bearing yields above 7 per­
cent; prime commercial paper went above



REVIEW

8 percent; and the bank prime rate reached
8 V2 percent. To some extent, these rates rep­
resent some allowance for inflation by lend­
ers, but for the most part they are the result
of and are a measure of pressures on the
financial markets.
The long-term corporate bond rate is per­
haps the most satisfactory indicator of the
link between financial pressures and invest­
ment expenditures, since it is less influenced
than others by short-term money-market dis­
turbances. This rate had remained relatively
unchanged in the early part of the decade,
and only began to creep upward in the last
half of 1965. The initial upswing of rates
peaked in late 1966, as restrictive monetary
policy took hold and as the pace of domestic
spending slowed. The corporate Aaa-bond
rate on new issues touched 6 percent in Sep­
tember 1966, declined somewhat in early
1967 as the business situation eased, but then
began to climb again — and, except for an­
other pause in late 1968, climbed sharply
until passing the IV 2 -percent mark in the
first half of 1969.
Still, there was no immediate slackening
of borrowing, as corporations accepted these
high interest rates as the necessary price of
carrying out their investment plans. The need
to expand capacity, the expectation of in­
creasing profitability, and the fear of inflation
apparently made these rates an acceptable
price for obtaining external funds.
Managing corporate funds
To finance their capital expenditure pro­
grams, corporations have been forced to
develop new sources of finance, but they have
also turned to economizing on the funds im­
mediately at their disposal. One alternative
has been to reduce the proportion of capital
going to inventories; the other has been to
reduce the amount of funds allocated to fi­
nancing day-to-day operations, that is, the
liquid assets of the corporation.

FEDERAL

194

RESERVE

BANK

As for the first, businesses have moved
toward reducing inventories relative to their
sales. The inventory-sales ratio for all busi­
nesses had shown a falling trend at least to
1965, when it reached a low point of 1.43,
and then a re v e rs a l u n til 1967, when it
reached a figure of 1.56. But by mid-1969,
the inventory-sales ratio was at 1.52 — the
same level recorded in 1962. Since there were
no long-term reductions in the relative size
of inventories, corporations have not been
able to economize on funds allocated to in­
ventories.
On the other hand, corporations have suc­
ceeded in reducing their inventories of finan­
cial assets. They have reduced the propor­
tion of their resources held in liquid assets,
and they have also begun to manage their
assets more effectively to maximize the yield
on them.
For some time, corporations have been
cutting back on the amount of assets tied
up in liquid assets. This trend reflects im­
proved management techniques and attitudes,
but it also reflects the pressure of money
costs, which has intensified their efforts to
reduce liquid assets towards the minimum
essential for day-to-day operation. Corpora­
tions have increased their total financial as­
sets, of course, but they have increased their
liabilities even more, and the result has been
a steady fall in corporations’ liquidity posi­
tions. This trend had become apparent be­
fore the boom of the mid-decade. Between
1961 and 1965, the ratio of liquid financial
assets to total liabilities dropped from 24 to
20 percent. Moreover, this liquidity ratio
has continued falling, until it reached 16 per­
cent in mid-1969. With their difficulty in
raising funds, corporations have obviously
concentrated on using efficiently whatever
financial resources have been at their dis­
posal.
These efforts to manage liquidity positions
more efficiently have shown up also in a




OF

SAN

F R A N C ISC O

changing mix of assets, reflecting the response
of corporate treasurers to changing yields.
The most obvious change has been not just
a reduction in the dollar volume of liquid
assets, but also a decline in the proportion
of such assets held in currency and demand
deposits. In 1961, cash and demand deposits
stood at $34 billion and were 55 percent of
all liquid assets; by the end of 1965, they
totaled $28 billion and were 40 percent of
liquid assets. But the incentives to conserve
on cash assets have since intensified even
further, apart from the temporary period of
cash accumulation which followed the 1966
monetary “crunch.” By June 1969, currency
and demand deposits were down below $27
billion and were no more than 35 percent of
total liquid assets.
Corporations have been able to conserve
on cash partly because of the growth of suit­
able alternative assets. Foremost among these
has been the large-denomination certificate
of deposit, the bank CD. With this alternative
available, corporate treasurers have shifted
funds which were previously in demand de­
posits into the time-deposit category, thus
obtaining both a high rate of interest and an
individual tailoring of maturities.
Corporate time deposits thus have grown
steadily, both in dollar amounts and in rela­
tive terms. As recently as 1961, corporate
time deposits were below $5 billion, but by
1965 they were $19 billion— exceeding cor­
porate holdings of Treasury securities for the
first time— and by the end of 1968, they
reached a peak of $25 billion, or 31 percent
of corporate liquid assets. By mid-1969, how­
ever, the corresponding figures dropped to
$20 billion and 27 percent, respectively, re­
flecting a combination of financial pressures
and interest-rate ceilings on CD’s below those
available on alternative investments.
Another alternative has been developed
through the rediscovery of the commercialpaper market. In the last several years in

M O N THLY

September 1969

particular, more corporations have turned
to the issue of commercial paper to finance
their needs, and more corporations have been
buying commercial paper instead of CD’s.
Throughout most of this period, the yield on
commercial paper has been regularly above
the CD rate, and also above the rate on
equivalent Treasury securities. Before 1965,
there had been a small rise in corporate hold­
ings of open-market paper. (For non-financial corporations, this category is largely
commercial paper.) The subsequent expan­
sion of this market has been financed largely
by the acquisitions of corporations, not by
those of financial institutions.
In 1965, non-financial corporations had
almost $7 billion in open-market paper, or
less than 10 percent of their liquid assets.
Following three years of expansion, corpora­
tions were holding $14 billion of this paper,
or 17 percent of their liquid assets. Finally,
at mid-1969, corporate holdings of openmarket paper jumped to $17 billion, at a
time when their time deposits were falling by
$5 billion. This sharply illustrates the sensi­
tivity of modern corporate treasurers to alter­
native yields, since in this period the com­
mercial-paper rate passed 8 V2 percent, or
2!4 percentage points above the ceiling on
longest-term CD’s.
The Treasury securities market has also
felt the impact of greater corporate sensitivity
to the alternative costs of holding liquid as­
sets. In 1961, corporations held $19 billion
in U.S. Government securities; at the end of
1968, their holdings were down to under $14

REVIEW

billion. Then in the first half of 1969, nonfinancial corporations unloaded some $8 bil­
lion, at which point their ratio of Treasury
securities to total liquid assets was down to
8 percent, as against 32 percent in 1961.
In sum, the corporate sector has played a
key role in the current economic expansion
by pushing through a massive program of
capital expenditures. Investment in capital
goods, while it has lain the foundation for
future growth by building up the economy’s
productive capabilities, has also been a
source of demand upon existing capacity.
Prior to 1965, this dual aspect of investment
created no conflicts, since the economy con­
tained unutilized resources which rising in­
vestment could employ. But with the return
to more-or-less full employment and a con­
tinued buildup in demand by all sectors of
the economy, some stresses began to appear.
Corporations in recent years have faced
the task of raising funds in the face of a slow­
down in the growth of internal funds and an
increase of monetary restrictions in the na­
tion’s financial markets. They have responded
by managing their liquidity positions more
closely and by tapping new sources of fi­
nance. The price of all this, however, has
been a higher level of interest rates. Yet the
achievement of a rapidly growing volume of
investment reflects both the flexibility of the
nation’s financial markets and the increased
financial skills of the nation’s corporate
treasurers.
Robert Johnston

Publication Staff: R. Mansfield, Artist; Karen Rusk, Editorial Assistant.
Single and group subscriptions to the M onthly Review are available on request from the Admin­
istrative Service Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 400 Sansome Street,
San Francisco, California 94120