View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

2

I

Higher Payout?
... Dividends rise more slowly than
other types of income, but
new elD guidelines may help.

Western Consumer Budgets
... A moderate budget for the
typical urban Western family
probably now costs over $12,000.
RCPC's-Transitional Step
... Regional check-processing
centers represent a step
towards new payments system.

Business Review is edited by William Burke, with the assistance of
Karen Rusk (editorial) and Janis Wilson (graphics).
Copies of this and other Federal Reserve publications are available from
the Administrative Services Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120.

2

•

Widows and orphans (and other
investors) got a lift recently when
the Committee on Interest and
Dividends (CID) eased its guidelines on corporate dividend payments. As a welcome side-effect,
this ruling helped check temporarily the downward slide of the
stock market, as stockholders
came to realize that higher yields
on their investments were at least
possible, even if price appreciation should continue to be a
mirage.
The new guidelines allow firms to
continue operating under the old
standard, which limits increases
in payments to no more than 4
percent over the prior year, but
they also provide a second option which bases current payments on historical payout ratios
for the last five years. The new
option provides that the aggregate cash payment per share in
1973, calculated as the percentage of per-share profits after
taxes in the last completed fiscal
year, cannot exceed the firm's
average payout ratio for the 196872 period.
The Economic Stabilization Act of
1970 included no provisions regarding dividend or interest
payments, but in the 1971 freeze,

the Secretary of Commerce requested the 1300 largest corporations to forego dividend increases temporarily. As the
freeze period ended, the CID set
the 1972 guidelines, requesting
firms to limit increases to 4 percent above the largest per-share
dividend paid during calendar
1971 or the fiscal years 1969-71.
The 4-percent guideline continued during Phase III, and that
option is still available to corporate managers, along with the
option to base their payments on
historical payout ratios. The new
option takes as the standard the
same span of years as is used for
monitoring profit-margin performance under the stabilization
program.

Why dividends lag
Dividend payments in the aggregate have lagged considerably
behind the growth of other types
of income over the past several
decades, especially in the most
recent period. In recent years
also, payouts have lagged far
behind earlier dividend growth.
These payouts were held down
by the poor performance of
profits during the sluggish 196971 period, and were also affected
by the CID gUidelines as the
economy moved out of recession.

3

Change (Percent)

o

1972

5

10

15

, Wages & Salaries
/' Social Security Payments

1971

1970

Dividend payments increase at slower pace than other forms of
income, such as wages, interest and social security

Between 1967 and 1972, dividends increased only 22 percent,
to $26.0 billion last year, as
against gains of 50 percent or
more in employee compensation
and personal interest payments.
Meanwhile, social-security and
other transfer payments actually
doubled. Except in 1968, increases of dividends were relatively small throughout this period. After several years'
sluggishness, dividends rose by
3% percent in 1972, roughly in
line with the guideline increase,
but in contrast, interest payments
last year increased about 7 percent, employee compensation 10
percent, and social-security payments 13 percent.
Dividend payments have closely
paralleled corporate profits over
time. (Both tripled in size over
the past two decades). Consequently, with profits rising only
19 percent between 1967 and
1972, dividend payments not surprisingly were held to a 22-percent increase.
The payout ratio meanwh ile has
fluctuated considerably, reflecting the tendency for corporate directors to adjust dividend
policy to profits performance
with a certain lag. In 1967, corporations paid out 46 cents for
every profit dollar, but the ratio
later rose as a consequence of

4

.1

I

I

I

modest increases in dividends
and sharp declines in profits. In
the 1970 recession year, the ratio
jumped to 63 percent-the
highest level of the past
generation-but then fell off
again in line with the recent
recovery in profits. In the first
quarter of 1973, the ratio fell to
40 percent, partly because of the
lag in adjustment to that profits
upsurge, but also because of the
payout limitation enforced by the
old CID guidelines.
Several different considerations
affect the dividend decisions of
corporate managers. According
to a recent Conference Board
study, most managers look first
at corporate earnings records,
present and prospective, when
deciding on the size of payout.
Th is involves an analysis of the
firm's cash flow and anticipated
need for funds. Also, corporations frequently are influenced in
thei r decisions by past dividend
practices, and this shows up in
attempts to maintain the continuity or regularity of dividend
payments, or to maintain a stable
rate of dividends per share.
Seven out of ten surveyed firms
targeted their payout at somewhere between 40 and 60 percent
of after-tax profits each year.
With profits now rising and CID
guidelines easing, all these policy
considerations would suggest a
substantial expansion of dividend
payments as time goes on.

Billions of Dollars
Ratio Scale

60

40
20

o
1953

1956

1960

1964

1968

1972

Dividend payments closely parallel growth of corporate profits, but
payout ratio shows substantial fluctuations

5

Percent

Bonds favored
Nonetheless, for several decades
now, investors have been turning
to bonds rather than to stocks as
a source of current income. In
1953 dividend payments totaled
$8.9 billion, as against $11.8 billion in interest payments. But in
the second quarter of 1973, dividends were $27.3 billion (at an
annual rate) compared with $85.7
billion in interest payments.

8

Yield on-

6

Corporate Bonds (Aaa)

\
4

Common Stocks

2

Ol.-...I.-....&..--I-..........L........---IL-.L-...L..-..L_L-..I-....&..-..L_L-...I.-......--I'--J

1953

1956

1960

1964

1968

Dividend yield on stocks falls considerably below bond yield over
past several decades ... gap widens in recent years

I

JI

6

1972

One reason for the relative disenchantment may be the weakness of stock prices, at least over
the last half-decade. (After rising
almost 50 percent between 1%2
and 1967, the Standard and Poor
stock index increased only 19
percent over the past halfdecade). Related to this is the
fact that bond yields far outstripped dividend yields during
that period, making stocks even
less desirable.
It was not always thus. In 1953
dividends provided a 5.80 percent yield for the S&P stock index, while the corporate-bond
yield averaged no more than 3.20
percent. By 1967 these figures
were almost exactly reversed,
and since then the spread has
widened even more in favor of
bonds. By the first quarter of
1973, the dividend yield was only
2.78 percent, compared with a
7.22-percent bond yield.

Dividends slighted
During the market upsurge of the
past several decades, dividend
payouts seemed far less important to Wall Street money managers than potential increases in
earnings per share. In those
days, the securities that seemed
most attractive often paid nominal dividends or none at all;
according to one analysis covering the period 1960-70, the
most profitable firms paid out on
the average only 25 percent of
their net income, while the least
profitable paid out 60 percent in
dividends. Because of this emphasis on profits growth, investors and corporate managers preferred to see earnings piled back
into expansion or diversification
that would produce further increases in earnings per share. But
then, as the "gunslingers" era on
Wall Street came to an end,
investors began to adopt a more
traditional approach and showed
renewed interest in yields.
One stock-market study conducted at the University of Chicago indicates that dividends
have always comprised a large
part of the total return to investors. Over the 1926-65 period, the
average annual return amounted
to 9.3 percent, and over one-half
of this return came from dividends rather than price appreciation.

Higher payout?
The recent CID action may stimulate corporate directors to boost
dividend payments. In fact, the
Committee noted that "it was
guided primarily by considerations of equity" in easing payout
restraints-in other words, that it
was attempting to provide parallel treatment fo~ different types
of income. At the same time, the
continuation of the basic guidelines indicates that an upper limit
will be maintained on the size of
payout. Under the old 4-percent
guideline, total dividend payments this year could rise to
about $27.0 billion, whereas
under the new option, the upper
limit may be around $29.2 billion.

With Phase 4 controls now set in
place, industries generally may
have trouble maintaining profit
margins, because of the switch
from a percentage mark-up to a
dollar-for-dollar passthrough of
cost increases. Moreover, some
industries (such as transportation) that have considerable
leeway under the new formula
for boosting dividends are in no
position to do so because of their
lack of profitability. In any case,
the percentage of after-tax profits
paid out in 1973 is almost certain
to fall somewhat below 1972's 47percent ratio, simply because the
new formula applies to 1972 earnings instead of the much higher
projected 1973 profits.

Executives might be tempted for
reasons of their own to set a limit
on dividend increases. They realize that external funds could
dry up in the developing atmosphere of financial stringencydespite that fact that the corporate sector is usually the last to
be hit by tight money-and they
know also that many other uses
besides dividends exist for corporate cash, such as heavy capital-spending programs.

However, considerably more
leeway for higher dividends
would exist next year, if the new
formula were then applied to
1973 profits-and if the overall
profits trend were to remain favorable in the face of Phase 4
controls and perhaps also a decelerating economy. After-tax
profits jumped 26 percent, and
cash flow 20 percent, between
the first quarter of 1972 and the
first quarter of 1973. In view of
those increases, as well as the
usual tendency for dividend payouts to follow profits trends, dividends quite possibly may begin
to grow apace with other types of
income.
William Burke
7

I
I.
f
I

I

I

The intermediate (moderate)
budget for an urban Western
family of four amounted to about
$11,780 in the fall of 1972, and
with adjustment for rising prices,
the same budget probably would
have cost about $12,180 in the
spring of 1973. The figures represent population-weighted averages based upon labor Department budget estimates for major
metropolitan areas in the West.

Thousands of Dollars
Ratio Scale

18
HIGHER

1969

levels rise

half-decade

1971

1973

over

Based on the same survey data,
average budget costs for lowerincome Western families
amounted to $7,925 last fall,
while the average "higher"
budget costed out at $17,260.
(Again, with prices rising, the
same budgets this spring would
have cost about $8,170 and
$17,850, respectively.) The
Western lower-budget figure
recently has averaged about 5
percent higher than the figure for
all metropolitan areas nationwide, but the averages for intermediate and higher levels have
been almost identical for the region and the nation.
Budget levels rose substantially
in the half-decade between the
spring-1967 and autumn-1972
survey periods, reflecting sharp
price increases in various consumer categories as well as shifts
in personal-income and socialsecurity taxes. The average

8

lower-income family budget in
the West rose about 30 percent
over this period, while the intermediate and higher budgets both
increased almost 25 percent. (In
all cases, however, the increases
over this period were greater
nationally than regionally.) The
uptrend was not constant, but
moderated somewhat during the
1970-72 period, as a reflection
first of income-tax reductions
and then of controls on consumer prices.
The Bureau of labor Statistics
computes budget estimates for
an urban family of four: a 38year-old employed husband with
considerable work experience,
his non-working wife, a boy of
13, and a girl of 8. The budgets
are illustrative of three different
levels of living and provide for
different specified types and
amounts of goods and services.
The data show that food
spending declines relative to income, accounting for roughly
one-third of the consumption
budget at the lower level and for
roughly one-fourth at the higher
level. In contrast, these proportions are practically reversed for
housing and house-furnishings.
Roughly one-seventh of the total
is allocated to clothing and personal care at all three levels, and
for transportation (one-tenth of
the total) the proportionate differences between the levels are
also small.

I
I

I

I

Ii
Ii

I
~

't

I
!l

,
,

f

The manner of living represented
by the lower budget differs from
that in'the intermediate and
higher budgets primarily because
the family lives in rental housing
without air conditioning, performs more services for itself,
and utilizes free recreation facilities in the community. The life
style reflected by the higher
budget, in comparison with the
intermediate budget, represents
a higher level of homeownership, more complete inventories
of household appliances and
equipment, and more extensive
use of services for a fee. For most
of the items that are common to
all three budgets, both the quantity and quality levels increase
with rises in income levels.
In late 1972, family budgets for
the lower living standard were
above the national average in
most of the major Western metropolitan areas. The figure for
San Francisco-Oakland was 9
percent higher than the $7,510
average for all metropolitan
areas, while Los Angeles-Long
Beach exceeded the average by 4
percent and Seattle-Everett by 2
percent. San Francisco-Oakland
was third highest in the nation in
this lower-budget category, but it
was surpassed by two other
Western communities, Honolulu
and Anchorage, which were 21
and 48 percent above the national average, respectively.

Difference From U.S. Metro
(Percent)
8

_ San Francisco

6

4

2

o
-2

/'

San Diego

-4

-6

LOWER

~ono."lll"

INTERMEDIATE

pay more at lower
San Francisco

In the intermediate- and higherbudget categories, only San Francisco-Oakland, of the major metropolitan areas, exceeded the
national average. (Again, however, Honolulu and Anchorage
were by far the highest-cost areas
in the nation.) The Bay Area's
intermediate budget was 6 percent above the national figure of
$11,730, and its higher budget
was 5 percent above the $17,110
nation-wide; on the other hand,

bUdg~:;t

but pay less at

Bay Area living costs fell considerably below costs in such
major Eastern centers as Boston
and New York.
Food-spending patterns last year
varied somewhat from the national pattern, in all three budget
categories. Seattle paid higherthan-national food costs, and San
Francisco was about average,
while Los Angeles and San Diego
9

paid somewhat below-average
costs in all categories. On the
other hand, Honolulu was the
highest-cost area in the nation,
paying 15-20 percent more for
food at all income levels; and
Anchorage was also considerably
above average.
Housing spending was much
higher in the West in the lower
budget, but generally in line with
the national average at intermediate and higher levels of living.
In the lower category, Los Angeles was 10 percent more costly
and San Francisco 20 percent
more expensive-and Anchorage
was twice the national average.
In other budget categories, San
Francisco homeowners paid
somewhat above average and
Anchorage and Honolulu far exceeded the national average, but
homeowners in Los Angeles, San
Diego and Seattle remained
closely in line with the national
housing-cost figures.
Western families in San Francisco
paid somewhat more than average for clothing and personal
care, in all budget categories, but
the Los Angeles and Seattle figures were roughly in line with
the national averages. As for

10

-10

Difference From U.S. Metro
(Percent)
-5
0
5
10

..,...----,r----,---..__--,--

-10

Difference From U.S. Metro
(Percent)
-5
0
5
10

Los Angeles -

San Diego- - San Francisco - - - Seattle - -

FOOD
(Intermediate)

HOUSING
(Intermediate)

Westerners of moderate income generally pay less for food and
housing than other metro residents-except in San Francisco

transportation costs, families in
the largest Western centers paid
somewhat more than average in
the lower-budget category, but
little if any above average in
other categories, except again for
San Francisco. Medical costs
were another story; in all three
budget categories, Los Angeles
families paid about 20 percent
more than the national average
for medical care, and San Francisco and San Diego families paid
about 10 percent more.

r

A major transitional step towards
the payments system of the future has been taken with the
development of a nationwide
network of facilities for the overnight processing and settlement
of checks-the regional check
processing centers (RCPC's). In
the San Francisco Federal Reserve District, this step encompasses the opening of RCPC's
this summer at the Seattle, Portland and Salt Lake City branches
of the bank. (Los Angeles and
San Francisco are scheduled to
open centers later in the year.)
Nationwide, the Federal Reserve
System may soon have close to
50 such centers in operation,
mostly at existing locations-12
head offices and 24 branchesbut also at some newly developed sites.
The Federal Reserve Board of
Governors issued guidelines in
early 1972 authorizing Reserve
Banks to operate regional checkprocessing centers in "communities whose trade, business and
financial activities are substantially related". The objective was
to ensurethat most of the 62
million checks written every day
be cleared and paid by the
opening of business the day following the deposit of those
checks.

An RCPC accepts from participating banks in its clearing region all checks written on
other banks in the region. It
also accepts from Federal Reserve member banks all checks
drawn upon banks outside their
region. In addition, it accepts
from participating banks all U.S.
Government checks, postal
money orders and other items
payable at Federal Reserve offices, regardless of origin.
Huge workload
The Federal Reserve's emphasis
on the development of a
speedier and more efficient
check-handling and clearing
system comes from the realization of the huge size of the
present workload-some 25 billion checks transferring about
$13 trillion annually-and from
the expectation that this workload will double by the end of
the decade. (The Federal Reserve
processes about 30 percent of
the nation's checks, and commercial-bank facilities handle the
rest.) For the same reasons, the
System believes that an improved
check-payments system should
be regarded as a transitional step

11

a

towards the use of electronic
transfers rather than checks for
transferring funds. System guidelines thus specify that each RCPC
should be provided with an automated clearing and telecommunications ability, to provide a basis
for a system of electronic transfers.

process is ideally accomplished
when the crediting and debiting
effects are simultaneous, and
when the shipping, sorting, accounting, and processing procedures can be performed between
the close of business one day
and the opening of business the
next day.

The present system of check processing typically involves two or
three banks between the time a
check is deposited and the time
it is presented for payment.
During this period, uncollected
funds are not available to the
checks' depositor-nor to his
bank for loans or investments.
The aim of regional centers is to
reduce the number of times a
check is handled. Each RCPC
serves a specific geographic area,
processing checks written and
deposited within the area/The
system builds upon the fact that
about 70 percent of all checks
remain within the metropolitan
area in which they originate.

The new system will bring about
an earlier receipt of funds due to
individuals and businesses, as
well as an earlier payment of
funds that they are transfering to
others. To assist this development, the Federal Reserve revised its Regulation J in November 1972 to promote faster
check collection. This amended
regulation requires all banks to
pay in immediately available
funds on the day when checks
are presented. Previously, banks
located outside cities containing
Federal Reserve offices (and
other designated areas) had paid
the Fed for checks presented in
funds collectable one or more
days after presentation.

From credits to debits
With RCPC's, the Federal Reserve
in a sense converts an inflow of
credits into an outflow of debits.
The checks that a regional center
receives are credits to the bank
which sends them into a center,
so that when these items are
resorted and rebatched they
leave the RCPC transformed into
charges on other banks. The
b

Interface with the banks
Federal Reserve banks, when
operating RCPC's, will expand
the overnight check-settlement
arrangements they have maintained for years with banks in
major metropolitan centers. In
addition, new RCPC's are envisioned as operating in areas not
reached by existing Fed offices,

wherever check volume and the
absence of alternative facilities
make additional Federal Reserve
services essential. The system is
designed to tie-in with commercial-bank processing centers,
where checks from a number of
correspondent banks are sorted
and otherwise made ready for
clearance.

I1i

The Federal Reserve's role is to
serve as an interface among all
banks in the nation. However, it
is concerned only with "transit"
items, not with the internal work
of check sorting and accounting
for individual banks. Commercial
banks increasingly are using their
own or contractual electronicprocessing units for their internal
check-processing operations.
The resultant economies in the
Federal Reserve's check-handling
program should show up eventually in reduced costs of personnel, transportation and equipment, considering as a whole all
private and public check-processing costs. Savings could develop, for example, by reducing
the number of times a check is
reintroduced as a document in
electronic processing operations.
Similarly, savings could result by t
reducing duplicate transportation
facilities between sites, and also
by eliminating unnecessary and
circuitous movements of checks.

12

d

, Regional variation
., Operating arrangements at dif[ ferent clearing centers may vary
~. somewhat, because of the substantial differences that exist in
banking structure, population
density, the volume of check
!
traffic, and the geographic and
topographic influences on transportation routes. In the latter
regard, the size of an RCPC service area is determined chiefly by
the time required to pick up
during an afternoon the day's
volume of checks deposited in
participating banks, to bring
these to a clearing center for
processing and settlement during
the night, and to deliver them
early the next morning to banks
against which checks were drawn
the .day before.
As for banking structure, the
workload of the San Francisco
Federal Reserve Bank is eased
because the states in this district
generally contain a relatively
small number of statewide
branch systems, rather than a
large number of unit banks. The
big branch systems, in effect,
have set up their own regional
clearing centers, so that the Federal Reserve's task in many cases
consists simply of integrating its
new RCPC's with ongoing commercial-bank systems.

t

i

Under the San Francisco District's plan, an RCPC will be set
up at each existing Fed office.
Because of the vast geographic
size of the areas served by each
of these offices, existing transportation arrangements may preclude the timely presentment of
checks to payor banks in certain
remote locations, meaning that
there will be a small number of
two-day cash-letter delivery
points. The operational plan calls
for each RCPC to red uce the
number of these two-day points
by improving transportation arrangements. All costs of each
RCPC, except for transportation
costs of incoming cash items, will
be borne by the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco.
The schedule generally calls for
incoming work to arrive at the
RCPC late each evening, although some offices (especially
Los Angeles) should encounter a
substantial inflow of items at
other times throughout the day.
These items would be processed
and ready for dispatch early in
the next working day. Outgoing
items would be delivered before
noon of that day, except for a
few remote areas with next-day
delivery. Prior to the start-up of
operations, however, several
important preliminary steps are
necessary-for example, conducting orientation meetings for
participating banks, organizing
13

,

I
~I

E

air and surface transportation
routes, and realigning workshifts
to permit three-shift operations
(see note).
Demise of the check
The development of regional
check-processing centers and the
future development of an electronic payments system are tied
in with the overwhelming success of the written check, which
has been so successful an instrument that it now threatens to
engulf the payments system. The
check's usefulness to the
banking industry has increased
because it is highly compatible
with advanced technology, typified by magnetic-ink encoding
and machine-handling techniques. Similarly, its usefulness
to individual users has increased
because it is an inexpensive,
highly efficient and convenient
means for conducting the bulk of
financial transactions.

14

last year, individuals and institutions wrote more than 2S billion
checks, against 94 million accounts with balances aggregating
$192 billion. The check volume
by the end of this year could
amount to over 27 billion pieces,
and with volume increasing by 7
percent annually, the total could
double within a decade. (Those
are volume figures; in dollar
terms, the total could rise one
and one-half times in just half
that time.)

While the volume should increase because of the growth of
the national economy and the
growth in the number of check
users, the complexity should also
increase because of the laborintensive nature of the checkpayments system, involving an
inordinate amount of expensive
processing and physical transfers
of paper. The paper glut may
take its toll in the shape of suddenly rising user and purveyor
costs, sharp reductions in productivity for making financial
transactions, and all the other
problems that could result from
an overloaded system of payments.
Towards electronic payments
In the long-run, the check cannot
survive in an increasingly complex economy which is growing
rapidly in both real and money
terms. The requirements of an
ever-larger and more complex
payments mechanism dictate a
move,away from dependence on
paper payments and towards
complete reliance on electronic
transfer of funds and electronic
accounting for those transfers.
Thus, the development of RCPC's
provides only a short-run structural solution to the payments
problem; in the long-run, an
operational solution is required
through the expanded use of the
Federal Reserve's electronic
communications network.

Some widely reported experiments in electronic funds transfers are already underway. In
California, the banks and
clearing-house associations in
San Francisco and los Angeles,
with Federal Reserve support,
have developed a system of electronic transfers-the California
Automated Clearing House Association (CACHA). This system
permits an individual bank's customers to authorize employers to
deposit their paychecks automatically into checking accounts
every payday. In addition, individuals are encouraged to authorize payments by banks of
their recurring predictable billsmortgage and other loan payments, utility bills and insurance
premiums. Commercial banks in
Georgia meanwhile have developed a system with even greater
potential for reducing check
usage.

Already individuals account for at
least half of all checks written,
and this proportion could increase as more households make
more purchases out of higher
incomes. The obvious solution is
to provide for accounting and
payments for purchases through
the use of electronic point-ofsale terminals. The credit card, or
a similar means of activating electronic transfers, should playa
major role in this development.
Finally, the new RCPC's and the
expanded check-clearing arrangements already developed in
a number of metropolitan centers should become the nuclei of
an interconnected regionalcommunications network for
handling wire transfers of funds.
In any event, the payments
mechanism increasingly should
evolve in the direction of a
system wher.e the credit to a
payee's account is made at the
same time that a payor's account
is charged. The expansion of the
RCPC network, with its emphasis
on the speeding up of check
payments, is a necessary step in
this evolution, as the Federal
Reserve moves its weekly workload of 150 million checks to an
overnight-settlement basis as rapidly as is economically feasible.

William Burke

I

I

I
I
i

15