View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

■S'1- - *

V

t a.

[ f-c 'k j i ^ Y

i

(J

FEDERAL
RESERVE
HANK DF




Monthly Heview

In this issue

New Towns vs. Old Problems

Quotas on Foreign Steel

N ew Towns vs. O ld Problem s
. . . The U .S. will add about 100 million people by the turn of
the century . . . how many of them will new towns accom m odate?

Q u o ta s on Foreign Steel
. . . A new quota agreem ent covering foreign steel imports could
result in an I I-percent reduction in imports in 1972 alone.




Editor: W illiam Burke

July 1972

MONTHLY

REVIEW

New Towns vs. Old Problems
he passage of the Housing and Urban
Development Act of 1970 demon­
strated Congress’ concern over the continu­
ation of “established patterns of urban devel­
opment” and the impact of rising population
upon economic and environmental balance,
including the migration and growth trends
which reinforce existing disparities between
urban, suburban and rural areas. The legis­
lation envisioned new communities as one
device for a ch iev in g a more “balanced”
growth which would in turn “preserve and
enhance both the natural and urban environ­
ment.” This development thus climaxes a
renewed interest in “new towns” as a solu­
tion for long-standing urban problems.

T

New towns not new
Interest in new communities of course is
not new; evidence of town planning and con­
struction for special purposes has been found
in many places throughout the ancient world,
including India, Persia, Egypt — and espe­
cially Greece, where settlements in outlying
areas were established at least partly to ac­
commodate population increases in the prin­
cipal city-states. In the United States, one
of the earliest efforts to build a totally new
city—Washington, D.C.— involved the cre­
ation of a public agency which was empow­
ered to formulate a development plan and
to acquire 5,000 acres of privately held land
for resale to those who agreed to conform to
its land-use specifications. In laying out the
specifications of the nation’s capital, this plan
reserved substantial acreage for open space,
streets, parks and public buildings.



During and between the First and Second
World Wars, a number of new towns were
built for special purposes under government
sponsorship, such as Oak Ridge, Tennessee,
Los Alamos, New Mexico and Richland,
Washington (atomic bomb manufacture),
Norris, Tennessee (TVA), and Boulder City,
Nevada (Boulder Dam ). More recently,
interest in new towns has centered largely
on Reston, Virginia and Columbia, Maryland
—private ventures started in the late ’60s
and projected to accommodate populations
of 75,000 and 120,000, respectively, when
finally completed. By one recent count,
however, some 130 new communities of one
type or another (but at least 1,000 acres in
size) either have been proposed or are under
development in this country, and 5 8 of those
130 towns are in Twelfth District states.

Nonetheless, probably the most ambitious
of the new-town efforts during the postwar
period have centered in the United Kingdom,
where some 30 new towns have been built
with a high degree of governmental direction
and financial support. T he B ritis h new
towns, with an emphasis upon green belts,
community centers and other social amenities,
reflect the views of Ebenezer Howard (18501928), who sought in his day to combine
the “best” ingredients of urban and rural life

3

FEDERAL

e North glen ( Washington)
© Padilla Bay (Washington)
® Cedar Hills (Oregon)
& Somerset (Oregon)

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

in the West
(Actual ©r Planned)

Sea Ranch
M arincello
Foster Cii

d>e>

Redwood Shores,

Hawaii-Kai (Hawaii)
Mililani Town (Hawaii)

4



July 1972

MONTHLY

into new planned communities as an alterna­
tive to the squalor and congestion of the large
industrial cities.
Located at sufficient distances from exist­
ing towns to be as self-contained as possible
and not merely extensions of suburbia, the
new towns have been designed to siphon-off
population from London and other large
cities. They are expected to absorb a sig­
nificant portion of the 20-million increase
in the U.K.’s population projected by the
turn of the century.
Similar U.S. concern over the ability to
absorb future population growth has led to
renewed interest here in the new-town move­
ment. In particular, the 1970 legislation was
influenced by the National Committee on
Urban Growth’s recommendation that 100
new cities of 100,000 population each, and
10 new cities of 1 million each, be created
to accommodate 20 million of the additional
100 million people expected by the turn of
the century. Perhaps 3 Vi million of those
20-million new-town dwellers would be ab­
sorbed by the 58 new towns now being built
(or planned) in Western states.
W hat new towns?
“Variety” is perhaps the best word to use
to characterize new towns, or new commu­
nities. They come in all shapes and sizes,
from the 93,000-acre Irvine Ranch in South­
ern California with a projected population
of over 400,000, to the 2,600-acre new town
of Riverton, New York, with a projected
population of 25,000. There is, in fact, no
unanimity of opinion as to what actually
constitutes a new town, partly because they
exhibit such a wide variety of sizes, locations,
functions and land uses. (One observer has
described new towns as essentially “a vehicle
for defining and synthesizing a variety of pro­
posals for the improvement of specific prob­
lems of environment.” ) T he a rg u m en ts
commonly advanced on behalf of new towns



REVIEW

run the gamut from considerations of aes­
thetics and the environment to economic
efficiency and the implementation of various
social goals, with “balance” as the central
theme.
By its very nature, the totally pre-planned
new community can schedule the orderly
location, timing and sequence of develop­
ment by coordinating the construction of
housing, commercial facilities and commu­
nity infrastructure (utilities, transportation,
education, recreation and cultural facilities)
into a harmonious whole. Unlike the smallscale developer who is not responsible for
the environment in which he operates, the
new-town developer can and should be con­
cerned with the total environment and with
the optimum sequence of development. By
planning ahead and thereby guiding devel­
opment, he can avoid both the visible and
invisible costs of sprawl.
In contrast to the present patterns of
urban development, which are characterized
by a progressive spread of low-density build­
ing over the entire landscape, the cluster
development which is integral to new-town
proposals should result in an overall land
use which is not only ecologically balanced,
but more economical. Unit costs are lower,
for example, if 3,000 residences are built
sequentially on 50 acres than if the same
number are built in increments of 60 on 50
separate sites.
This is considered a particularly impor­
tant objective on the fringes of metropolitan
areas, where unprotected open lands and
agricultural areas easily succumb to the pres­
sures of expanding population. The largescale approach of new-town planning also
would overcome the problems associated
with urban-renewal and Model Cities pro­
grams, which are frequently criticized for
failure to achieve their expected impact be­
cause of concentration on relatively smallscale, fragmented projects.

5

FEDERAL

6

RESERVE

BANK

W hy new towns?
Although the U.S. does not yet have a
comprehensively defined national urban pol­
icy, new towns are considered a means of
implementing a number of specific social
goals which have emerged over the years.
These include an increased degree of popu­
lation decentralization and an in c re a s e d
degree of dispersion within existing metro­
politan areas, as well as the provision of
more and better job and housing opportu­
nities for minorities outside of the urban
ghettos. By siphoning off in-migrants who
would otherwise congregate in the cities,
new towns will help relieve the mounting
problems of congestion in the main urban
centers.
Present urban centers are believed by
many economists to suffer diseconomies of
scale. Conclusive proof is lacking, partly
because of the unavailability of adequate
measures of the full cost of such factors as
pollution and congestion, but some evidence
exists to support the view that per capita
costs of various public services (police pro­
tection, sanitation, education and transporta­
tion) are substantially higher in very large
cities than elsewhere.
In 1970, for example, per capita taxes and
expenditures for public services in cities with
populations of 1 million or more were double
th o se of c itie s in the 300-500,000 size
bracket, and over three times those of cities
in the 50-99,000 size category. In the view
of the New York Urban Development Cor­
poration, “Congestion New York scale saps
not only humans but their institutions, as the
almost daily crisis in local and metropolitan
services demonstrates.”
A related goal of many new-town projects
is a high level of self-sufficiency, which would
reduce the need for long-distance commut­
ing for work, shopping and recreation, there­
by helping to relieve congestion in the main
metropolitan areas. To the extent that they




OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

are self-contained, new towns may also make
it easier to establish a sense of community.
Their residents allegedly will be able to effect
a greater degree of community participation
and at the same time maintain an identity
that otherwise would be suffused in the social
vortex of the metropolitan core cities.
In addition, new towns might serve as
testing laboratories for urban innovations.
They provide a chance to experiment with
innovative designs in residential, commer­
cial and industrial architecture, as well as
with new transportation systems and new
methods of public administration and urban
management. In the process, they provide
an opportunity to develop solutions to the
problems affecting the core cities. On sev­
eral counts — economic, social and purely
structural — new towns thus can represent
an exercise in thinking in metropolitan terms.
Independents and satellites
Other features such as size and location
help to distinguish new towns from tradi­
tional builder developments. Size is one;
while a large subdivider or builder seldom
develops a single parcel of more than 1,000
acres and 2,500 units, new towns average
about 10,000 acres in size. A standard defi­
nition is at least 1,000 acres planned for a
minimum 3,000 to 4,000 residents and suffi­
cient supporting facilities, activities and uses
to constitute a complete community.
Yet another basis is location, or more par­
ticularly, relative distance from established
metropolitan centers. Depending upon their
im p le m e n ta tio n of certain specific goals,
four types of new town—independent, satel­
lite, peripheral and in-town— are recognized
by the Department of Housing and Urban
Development as eligible for various kinds of
Federal assistance.
© The independent or free-standing new
town is located beyond commuting distance
from another major urban center and is envi­

July 1972

MONTHLY

sioned to be relatively self-sufficient, with
an eventual population of 250,000 or more.
A city planned as part of a national-settle­
ment policy — such as Brazil’s capital of
Brasilia — would qualify as an independent
or free-standing urban entity, as would have
Salt Lake City or Fairbanks in their day,
had they been comprehensively planned.
Today, Lake Havasu City in Arizona
(new home of the London Bridge) and the
large Irvine Ranch project in Southern Cali­
fornia might qualify as independent new
towns. The latter project has allocated 1,000
acres of its 93,000 acres to educational
purposes, through the donation of land for
a local campus to the University of Califor­
nia, and has allocated 66 percent of the re­
mainder for residential purposes, 26 percent
for industrial-commercial uses, and 8 per­
cent for open space. It is expected that 90
percent of the jobs in the completed project
will be held by residents.
• Satellite new towns are located within
commuting distance of a major city, usually
on sparsely settled land devoted to agricul­
tural uses. (Most proposed new towns fall
into this category.) The p ro to ty p e s are
Reston, Virginia, some 20 miles from Wash­
ington, D.C., and Columbia, Maryland, mid­
way between Washington and Baltimore.
Reston’s population is expected to grow from
its present 10,000 to 75,000 on 6,800 acres;
Columbia’s from 15,000 to 120,000 on
18,000 acres.
Though different in architectural design
— Reston being rather advanced and Colum­
bia rather conservative— both communities
will have relatively high population densities,
but clustered in such a way as to leave vast
areas to open space. Housing is grouped in
“villages” separated by green belts, with
each village containing its own shopping
center and school, while attractive town cen­
ters accommodate high-rise office and com­
mercial buildings.



REVIEW

Riverton, New York, being developed by
a consortium including Reston’s original de­
veloper Robert Simon, is one of three satel­
lite new towns thus far declared eligible for
Federal support. Planned for development
over a 16-year period, the new town will
eventually accommodate 25,000 people on
2,560 acres of land near Rochester. About
40 percent of the land will be allocated to
housing, 22 percent to commercial and in­
dustrial uses, and 24 percent to recreational
and open space— including a golf course, 12
indoor and outdoor swimming pools, three
lakes and a riverside marina. In Riverton,
14 miles of walkways (tunneling under or
bridging roads) will link schools, residential
areas, shopping centers and industrial parks.
A rapid-transit link to nearby Rochester will
be developed on the existing Erie-Lackawanna rail line, and between 30-40 percent
of the 8,000 residential units will be for lowand moderate-income families, including the
elderly. The developer also plans to offer
prepaid health care and medical insurance
for residents.
Other types of towns
• Peripheral (“in-filling” ) new towns are
established either on the edge of existing
metropolitan areas or within the suburban
fringe on lands that for one reason or another
have been utilized for agricultural, military,
or other purposes. In effect, peripheral new
towns represent efforts to accommodate, with
appropriate planning, over-spill from either
the central city or existing suburban areas.
One example is Foster City, built on 2,600
acres of reclaimed tidelands in the south­
western portion of San Francisco Bay, and
designed to accommodate a population of
35,000 in a community of high-rise apart­
ments, garden apartments, townhouses and
single-family residences with some commer­
cial and industrial activity.
• In-town new towns are closely related
to peripheral new towns and essentially rep-

7

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

resent a form of urban renewal; that is, major
developments designed to revitalize innercity areas. One such project will create two
new towns on Welfare Island in New York’s
East River, with 5 ,0 0 0 u n its of mixedincome housing and an ecological preserve
— and no automobiles allowed. It is spon­
sored by the New York (State) Urban
Development Corporation, which has broad
powers to condemn and acquire land, to
override local zoning and building codes and
to float its own debt obligations.
Another project under the same sponsor­
ship eventually will generate 35,000 jobs
and house a mixed-income population of
60,000 in a new town to be built over the
storage and repair yards of the Long Island
Railroad in Queens. Lower levels of the
new community will be allocated to parking,
vehicle circulation, and industrial space, and
the top levels to office buildings, a shopping
center and residential buildings.
Although the foregoing classification is
based upon relative distance from major
urban centers, virtually all of the new towns
thus far initiated or planned in this country
happen to be located within the general
orbit of the fastest growing metropolitan
regions — witness the heavy concentration
in Southern California. This trend of course
conflicts with one of the major purposes of
new-town development—population disper­
sion— but it is understandable in view of such
factors as access to transportation facilities,
the availability of adequate supplies of land,
labor and other resources and, not least of
all, the potential for population growth it­
self. Some of the problems encountered in
the development process may be understood
by looking at the developers themselves.
W ho are the developers?

8

In contrast to the British and European
experience, the American new-town move­
ment has (to date) received its greatest




OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

organizational and financial support from
private enterprise rather than from the pub­
lic sector. Motivated by the profitable in­
vestment opportunities in “environmentally
constructive ends” — which may include a
20-percent (or more) pre-tax return on in­
vestment — large landowning and develop­
ment firms, building firms, oil companies,
industrial corporations, insurance companies
and commercial banks are to be found in the
forefront of the new-town movement.

One major type of developer is the large
landowning firm, such as the Irvine Ranch
Company in California. Originally involved
in ranching, citrus and extractive operations,
the Irvine Company has turned to new-com­
munity development to take advantage of
the increased value of its land holdings
brought about by the growth of the Los Angeles-San Diego area. Similarly, Goodyear
Rubber Company has undertaken develop­
ment of its 13,000-acre L itc h fie ld Park,
Arizona, project on land originally bought in
1916 for growing cotton to be used in tire
manufacturing.
Other large Western landowners, such as
Leslie Salt Company, W e y e rh a u se r and
Boise Cascade, have gotten into community
development to obtain a multiple and more
profitable use of their land holdings. In some
cases, holding periods of 50 years or more
have kept the book value of lands well be­
low their present market value, offering the

July 1972

M O N T HL Y REVIEW

potential of major capital gains over time.
Large national corporations have become
increasingly interested in new-town develop­
ment. Westinghouse has plans for new towns
in Florida and California to serve as markets
for large-scale testing of new products. Other
companies, such as IT&T (through Levitt &
Sons, its building subsidiary) and the Penn
Central (through Macco Realty, its South­
ern California land-development subsidiary)
are entering the field as part of their diversifi­
cation efforts.
Oil companies are now major investors,
being interested as they are in the riskshelter benefits of land development stem­
ming from property-tax and capital-gain tax
legislation. Sunasco (Sunset International
Petroleum), which has acquired a number of
building firms and now derives the largest
part of its income from real estate, currently
is involved in the development of three new
communities in California. Gulf Oil, after
investing heavily in Reston, has now as­
sumed control of that prototype community.
With the experience of some prototype
new towns in mind, some observers have
concluded that considerable public support
will be required to maintain the momentum
of the new-town movement, in view of the
heavy “front-end” costs which must be borne
by the developer before cash flow turns
positive. These costs arise from the neces­
sity to finance land acquisition, site develop­
ment and improvement, and essential in­
frastructure during the lengthy period before
any appreciable cash flow develops from
land sales, home sales, and commercial and
industrial leases.
The cost of land acquisition alone for a
10,000-acre new town may approximate
$15 million, entirely apart from outlays for
financing costs and infrastructure. As for
the latter, the cost of Reston’s roads, sewers
and water lines amounted to $14 million,
while in one California development, a 5


mile access road alone cost $1 million.
Serious problems can arise unless the de­
velopment plan carefully keeps construction
in phase with return cash flow, which means

that housing availability must be kept in
phase with job opportunities, and hence with
commercial and industrial dev elo p m en t.
Costs mount also as a consequence of the
delays that result from dealings with local
authorities over such matters as zoning and
building-code requirements.
The developer usually provides between
5 and 20 percent of the total prospective
development cost as his equity investment,
with the proceeds being used for land ac­
quisition, architect and engineering fees and
general overhead. Thus, reliance upon ex­
ternal financing can be both very substantial
and costly.
The enormous cost of new-town ventures
thus helps explain why virtually all of their
backers are large firms, and it also helps to

9

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

explain why most new-town proposals are
still just that — proposals. Even some large
firms have discarded their original plans to
enter the field, discouraged by the difficulties
of large-scale land acquisition, by the dif­
ficulties encountered in securing the approval
of local authorities with frequently overlap­
ping jurisdictions, by the high cost of pro­
viding the essential infrastructure, and by
the long gestation period required for a pos­
itive cash flow to develop. (Some economic
models developed in connection with specific
new-town proposals estimate that full de­
velopment requires eight years or more.)
Consequently, Congress has passed legisla­
tion to assist new-town development because
of its conviction that such ventures are
merited in terms of helping to restructure the
nation’s future urban growth.
Federal support

10

To implement the 1970 legislation, a new
Community Development Corporation was
created in the Department of Housing and
Urban Development, with the assignment of
determining eligibility standards for newtown proposals and of serving as a vehicle
for extending various forms of assistance. As
to eligibility criteria, a new town must be
of one of the four types noted above, and
in addition, must be “a well planned and
harmonious whole . . . economically sound
. . . and an attractive place to live, work and
play.”
Ample provision must be made for open
space, as well as for “most, if not all of the
basic activities and facilities normally as­
sociated with a city or town,” including
residential, industrial, commercial, educa­
tional, religious and cultural activities. In
addition, the new community must offer
equal opportunity for minority-group em­
ployment, and must provide “substantial”
(but unspecified) am o u n ts of low- and
moderate-income housing during each phase




OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

of residential development.
Financial a ssista n c e to qualified new
town-developers may take several forms, in­
cluding up to $500 million overall in debt
guarantees. A limit of $50 million is placed
on any single project, but otherwise the debt
guarantees may cover up to 100 percent of
the real-property and development costs in­
curred by public-development agencies, and
85 percent of the costs incurred by private
developers. The act also calls for $250 mil­
lion in loans and grants to help defray the
cost of interest payments for a period up to
15 years.
In addition, $168 million (through fiscal
1973) is authorized in loans and grants to
help defray the cost of schools and other
essential public services during the initial
stages of community development, and in
special planning grants to help cover plan­
ning costs and technological innovations
such as antipollution c o n s tru c tio n tech­
niques. Finally, additional funding is avail­
able through 13 existing Federal agencies
for sewers, water supply, open space, mass
transportation and other public facilities.
Altogether, about $1 billion in assistance
may become available to reduce the risk to
developers resulting from their heavy frontend costs. To date, Congress has failed to
appropriate any funds in support of the loan
and grant measures, but the debt-guarantee
program is well underway. Thus far, HUD
has made $227 million in debt guarantees
in support of ten projects designed to ac­
commodate over 630,000 people by 1990,
and the volume of applications for assistance
is rising rapidly. None of the ten projects
are in the West, however.
With adequate Federal funding, the newtown movement could witness a major up­
surge during the nex t d e c a d e , as private
developers become attracted by the profit
potential on projects in which a large part of
the risk is borne by the Federal government.

July 1972

MONTHLY

Still, Federal assistance is not without its
costs, and some observers question its ef­
fectiveness in terms of implementing the ob­
jectives which new towns are designed to
achieve.
Problems of Federal support
For one thing, the cost of filing a detailed
application for HUD assistance is consider­
able— as much as $500,000, according to
one study of the San Francisco Bay Area —
and the amount of red tape involved is sub­
stantial. More importantly, while Federal aid
can alleviate some fundamental problems
such as developers’ heavy front-end costs,
it is not presently designed to cope with
other factors equally critical to the success
or failure of a new-town venture — loca­
tion, zoning, and the rate of sale of de­
veloped properties. Land, for example, must
be acquired or tied up through purchase or
purchase options before applying for Fed­
eral aid, without any certainty that aid will
in fact be provided. And while the new
legislation stresses the importance of newtown location, it provides no means for
guiding the choice of location; the initiative
ultimately rests with the developer.
A related problem concerns the degree to
which Federally imposed criteria for newtown assistance can be blunted, if not en­
tirely thwarted, by local-government author­
ities. The typically fragmented structure and
nature of local governments may, in fact,
effectively preclude the kind of metropolitan
planning and land-use control which is neces­
sary to control growth on an area-wide basis.
For this reason, many observers empha­
size the importance of state public-develop­
ment corporations which have both broad
powers and access to Federal funding, such
as the Urban Development C o rp o ra tio n
established by the New York State legisla­
ture. The NYUDC has the power to con­
demn and acquire land, override local zon­
ing and building codes, raise funds through



REVIEW

the flotation of general obligation bonds,
undertake the construction of transportation
and other public utilities, and sell developed
land to new-town builders. With these pow­
ers, the NYUDC plans to channel one-third
of the Empire State’s growth into new towns
during the rest of the century.
Other locational incentives might take the
form of land-acquisition loans or grants,

actual land grants by state agencies, and
various fiscal incentives such as propertytax deferrals, investment tax credits, and
a c c e le ra te d -d e p re c ia tio n allowances on
structures built in publicly designated newcity areas. In addition, some observers ad­
vocate the establishment of National and
Regional Urban Development Banks, which
would be empowered to make land purchases
and development loans with funds derived
from the sale of security issues or from
private bank loans.
Self-sufficiency and efficiency
Still, a number of fundamental problems
remain, including the question of whether the
commonly stated objectives of new-town
development are fully compatible with one
another. For example, is a relatively high
degree of self-sufficiency compatible with
the advantages of efficiency, which derive
from specialization? Or is it even attainable?

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

It is significant that virtually all of the pro­
posed new towns in this country are located
within the orbit of existing large metropolitan
centers.
By definition, existing large urban centers
not only afford the widest range of opportun­
ities — economic, social and cultural — but
they are also the primary sources of the labor
skills and materials upon which new-town
developers must rely in implementing their
projects. They also are the major outlets for
the products of the major national firms,
who take transportation costs and other mar­
ket factors very much into account in decid­
ing upon the location of their facilities.

12

Thus, while open land in rural areas may
be less expensive and easier to assemble in
large parcels for development, land improve­
ment and other development costs may be
relatively higher in these areas, due to the
cost of transporting to the site the skilled
labor and materials which are not available
locally. F u rth e rm o re , even in the most
h ig h ly -d ev elo p ed new tow ns here and
abroad, the goal of a high degree of self-con­
tainment has proven elusive. A considerable
proportion of their residents still commute
to nearby urban centers for employment and,
at least in Reston and Columbia, still depend
overwhelmingly on automobiles rather than
public transportation for their transportation
needs.
Closely related to these considerations is
the fundamental question of economic ef­
ficiency — the question of whether external
economies or diseconomies characterize ex­
isting urban c e n te rs and p ro je c te d new
towns. For example, to what extent do ex­
ternal economies in metropolitan centers
offset the external diseconomies which result
from pollution and congestion? (An example
of the former would be the provision by a
city of parks and recreation facilities which
are utilized without charge by suburbanites;
an example of the latter would be industrial




OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

development which creates traffic and pollu­
tion problems for a neighboring community.)
While considerable evidence points to the
existence of diseconomies in existing large
cities, there have been very few empirical
studies of the problem, partly because no
accounting system exists which would make
possible the accurate measurement of social
benefits and social costs.
Consequently, the continued location of
income-generating activities in large urban
centers might indicate that the marginal ben­
efits exceed the marginal costs incurred by
those who make this decision — but it may
also reflect a rational response to a pricing
system that (1) does not measure the total
(or social) cost of such externalities as pol­
lution and congestion and that (2) requires
new firms and residents to bear only the
average, rather than the higher marginal cost,
of entry. Under these conditions, firms might
continue to locate in large urban-core cities,
where operations at least appear profitable,
even though the resulting net social product
(taking diseconomies into account) is less
than that which would be generated by an
alternative location. Still, the increasing ten­
dency of business to locate in the suburbs
suggests a recognition of the diseconomies
attendant to operating in the central cities.
In any event, the proper measurement of
efficiency would require an accounting and
pricing system that takes all v alu es in to
account, including the so-called intangibles
and amenities. Such a system does not yet
exist, and even if it did, the problem of
calculating the costs of switching from one
urban form to another — from existing cities
to projected new towns — would still be
formidable.
Social balance
Another problem with achieving com­
patibility among the various new-town ob­
jectives centers on the question of social

MONTHLY REVIEW

July 1972

Mew tow ns mciy house only one-fifth
of nation's 100 million new residents
M illio n s

Projected
N e w T ow ns
Other
Population
Centers

Central Cities

100

O utside
Central Cities

Non­
metropolitan
A reas

0

1970

2000

balance, that is, the accommodation of a
representative mix of socio-ethnic and in­
come groups within the community. As noted
previously, the provision of equal job op­
portunities and adequate low-and middleincome housing rank high among the eligibil­
ity criteria g o v ern in g F e d e ra l financial
assistance to new-town developers.
Reston and Columbia have achieved some
success in achieving racial mix, as minorities
(in this case Blacks) account for about 7
and 15 percent, respectively, of their resident
populations. As for the income mix, the
available evidence indicates that median in­
comes are quite high (about $20,000), and
that the income of minority residents is well
above the median of minority groups gen­
erally, partly because these residents include
a significant number of well-paid profes­
sionals. In fact, new-town homes for the
most part have been considered luxury
items, well beyond the reach of the typical
low- or moderate-income worker.
By definition, new towns lack an inven­
tory of the older, cheaper units which now



house most of the urban poor. In the absence
of very substantial subsidies exceeding what
is now available through FHA 235-236 pro­
grams, new-town developers probably could
not produce substantial amounts of new
housing for that income category. In short,
attempting to house low-income groups in
new towns may prove to be a relatively costly
and inefficient way of providing them with
decent housing — more costly at least than
refurbishing older units in the inner cities.
However, if the problem of financing lowincome housing were to be solved, new
towns could offer a potentially significant
increase in job opportunities to minorities,
whose problems have been compounded by
the tendency of employers to leave the cen­
tral cities for the suburbs.
Beyond that, the emphasis of new-town
planners on aesthetics and the environment
is essentially a matter of interest only to the
relatively affluent. (For this reason, measures
of efficiency as applied to alternative urban
forms may have to take explicit account of
differing class biases.) New-town residents
concerned with the amenities thus may be
unsympathetic to the developer’s efforts to
make the community self-contained (and
profitable) by the inclusion of an incomeand tax-generating industrial base.

Nor have the new towns been altogether
successful in instilling a sense of identity
and participation among their residents.
(“New Town blues,” a phenomenon first dis­
covered among residents of the British new
towns, has been found to affect American
new-town dwellers also.) Otherwise, surveys
indicate that new-town residents generally

13

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

are satisfied with what their communities
offer, even though they are beginning to
experience some of the woes that affect the
rest of urban America.

14

Other problems
On yet other counts, critics question the
ability of new towns to meet their stated ob­
jectives. For one thing, new towns might
actually exacerbate environmental problems
by contributing to a leap-frogging urban
sprawl, since virtually all of the proposed
new communities are to be located within
the orbit of existing metropolitan centers.
As for pollution control, it may be easier
(and much less costly) to take pollution
away from the people where the problem
is the greatest — in the large urban centers
— than to take people away from the pollu­
tion problem.
Moreover, questions may arise about the
potential of new towns as urban laboratories,
simply because of the limit imposed on ex­
perimentation by the inherent riskiness of
new-town development. With adequate pub­
lic assistance, some potential for experi­
mentation would still appear possible, includ­
ing such innovations as pre-fabricated and
modular-type housing, but cost factors might
limit the private sector’s experimentation for
the foreseeable future.
Other questions arise concerning the ef­
fectiveness of trying to control the nation’s
population growth — a projected increase of
100 million by the end of the century — by
simply creating 10 new cities of 1-million
population and 100 new cities of 100,000
population. Critics note that the 20 million
people accommodated by th e p ro p o se d
new towns would represent only 20 percent
of the total population increase over the
period — and only 7 percent of the total
population — so that existing cities would
have to absorb the remaining 80 percent of
the projected growth. (It is assumed that
the size of the rural population would remain




OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

relatively unchanged.) Indeed, if each of the
smallest 200 metropolitan areas in the nation
were to absorb an additional half-million
people, the projected 100 million increase in
population could be accommodated without
any of the 200 areas exceeding 2.5 million
in size — and without the creation of any
new towns at all.
Critics of the new-town movement con­
tend that it would be enormously expensive
to achieve a truly massive redistribution of
population — that is, enough of a redistribu­
tion to make a real difference in terms of
economic, social, environmental and geo­
graphical balance. The total cost might be
considerably less, and the likelihood of suc­
cess increased, by programs aimed at direct­
ing growth towards existing cities with pop­
ulations of from 250,000 to 500,000.
Unlike totally new towns, these “growth
centers” already have a well developed in­
frastructure; unlike the major metropolitan
areas, they are not overwhelmed (at least
not yet) by the vicious circle of urban prob­
lems. The Presidential Commission on Pop­
ulation and the A m e ric a n F u tu re (the
Rockefeller Commission) consequently has
e m b ra ce d recommendations favoring the
channeling of population towards medium­
sized growth centers.
A final obstacle — perhaps the major ob­
stacle — to the new-town movement is the
absence of a well-defined national urban
policy. According to this line of thought,
formulating and carrying out such a policy
would require an unprecedented degree of
cooperation among the Federal government,
the state and local governments, and the
private sector.
Yet the fragmented nature of the govern­
mental s tru c tu re and policy-making ap­
paratus in this country — the pluralistic
system which emphasizes decentralized deci­
sion-making and local autonomy — works
against concerted action. Rather, it is more

July 1972

MONTHLY

conducive to an ad hoc, cautious approach
to urban problems, which in itself reflects a
widespread lack of agreement as to just what
urban problems require what solution, in
what order, and in what way.
W hat future?
What then is the future of the new-town
movement? Any solid conclusions are im­
possible, simply b e c au se of the lim ite d
American experience with new towns; thus
far, very few have come to fruition, and the
empirical basis of any definitive assessment
is lacking. In view of the magnitude of the
problems, however, private enterprise alone
is not likely to play a major role in develop­
ing new towns with the broad socio-eco­
n o m ic -e n v iro n m e n ta l c h a ra c te ris tic s
envisioned by their creators. Moreover, the
various public programs which have been
initiated in support of new towns thus far
appear to be inadequate to the implementa­
tion of their stated objectives.
Given the pluralistic nature of the deci­
sion-making apparatus in this country, the
success or failure of the new-town move­
ment may ultimately be determined at the
state level. In other words, many of the
more serious problems faced by new-town




REVIEW

developers, including the problems of land
acquisition and conformance with local zon­
ing and building codes in overlapping or
contiguous jurisdictions, might best be re­
solved by state-development agencies such
as the NYUDC, with wide powers to over­
come such local restrictions.
Furthermore, state agencies would appear
to be in a particularly favorable position to
assure that urban growth — including the
creation of new towns — is accomplished
with an eye to region-wide environmental
balance. (This consideration is particularly
important in the West, where individual
states typically encompass large, geographi­
cally diversified areas.) In addition, statedevelopment agencies with broad powers and
well formulated land-use plans would be
eligible (as is already the case) for Federal
new-community assistance on preferential
terms, and would be able to maintain a rea­
sonable balance between the demands of a
n a tio n w id e population-growth policy and
their own regional interests. The success of
the new-town movement thus will depend on
a host of private and governmental initia­
tives, and not least of all upon effective action
at the statewide level.
Nonna Noto and Verle Johnston

15

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

Qyotas @ei Foreign Steel

ost major foreign producers of steel
agreed this past May to a new threeyear plan restricting their export of steelmill products to the United States. The agree­
ment, which could result in an 11-percent
reduction in imports in 1972 alone, tightens
somewhat a quota arrangement which was
in effect during the 1969-71 period.

M

President Nixon hailed the agreement as
“a welcome development . . . which will
enable domestic steel producers to make
their plans with confidence that imports will
not be disruptive to the domestic market,”
and he added, “it will help preserve the
jobs of American steelworkers.” Spokesmen
for the domestic steel industry echoed the
President’s sentiments, but spokesmen for
the consumer movement took a completely
different line. Consumers Union sought an
injunction against the agreement in a Wash­
ington Federal court, charging that it con­
stituted a “per se” violation of the Sherman
Act, since it permitted “artificially high price
levels” through its limitations on U.S. sup­
plies of foreign steel. Wholesale prices of
steel-mill products jumped 20 percent dur­
ing the period of the last quota arrangement,
or almost twice as fast as the average for all
industrial commodities.

16

In letters of intent to the Secretary of
State, producer federations in the Common
Market countries (acting through the Euro­
pean Coal and Steel Community), Japan
and the United Kingdom agreed to limit
their steel imports to the U.S. this year to




14.5 million tons. Japan and the Common
Market each would account for 6.5 million
tons, and the U. K. for the other 1.5 million
tons. (In 1971, their shipments were 6.9,
7.2, and 1.4 million tons, respectively.) Non­
signatory producing c o u n trie s, such as
Canada and Sweden, would be expected to
hold their shipments below 1.8 million tons,
down from 2.9 million tons last year. Total
imports thus could fall to 16.3 million tons
in 1972, from last year’s record high of 18.3
million tons.

Qu@ta agreem ents act to brake
sharp upsurge in imports

I9 6 0

1 96 5

1970

1 97 2

1974

July 1972

MONTHLY

REVIEW

Reduced market share

AS1 major producing countries

If the “voluntary” agreement holds up,
foreign steel will account for a much reduced
share of the American market this year.
Domestic producers could ship perhaps 96.0
million tons this year — assuming the stan­
dard forecast of a 10-percent increase over
1971 production levels — with perhaps 93.2
million tons of that total going to domestic
buyers. Thus, with 16.3 million tons of im­
ports, total domestic consumption might
reach 109.5 million tons. At that level, im­
ports would account for 14.8 percent of the
U.S. market — down from 17.9 percent last
year, but still higher than any other year
except 1968.
Although the agreement permits increased
imports during the remaining years of the
three-year pact, total imports by 1974 could
still fall 7 percent below the 1971 peak of
18.3 million tons. In 1973, Japanese pro­
ducers are expected to limit their export in­
crease to 2.5 percent and European pro­
ducers (including the U.K.) to 1.0 percent;
in 1974, all producers are expected to adhere
to the 2.5-percent growth limit.
The new agreement thus generally fol­
lows the pattern set by the 1969-71 agree­
ment, with sharp reductions in the first year
of the pact followed by limitations on growth
in the succeeding two years. The old agree­
ment envisaged a 14-percent overall reduc­
tion between the pre-pact year (1968) and
the third year of the agreement (1971), with
a 22-percent cut in the first year followed by
5-percent increases in each of the next two
years.
Imports of steel-mill products actually
conformed quite closely to the quota restric­
tions during the first year of the old threeyear agreement, falling from a high of 18.0
million tons in 1968 to only 14.0 million
tons in 1969 and 13.4 million tons in 1970.
This decline reflected in part the general
compliance with the quota agreement, but

exceed quotas during 1971




M i ll io n s of T o n s

0

2

4

6

8

it also reflected the slowdown in the U.S.
economy and the boom in foreign markets,
which tended to divert steel to the faster
growing markets overseas. In 1971, however,
imports jumped sharply above the 15.4 mil­
lion ton quota to a record high of 18.3 mil­
lion tons, as steel users in this country built
up their inventories as protection against a
possible strike.
During all three years of the agreement,
the p e rfo rm a n c e of individual countries
varied with regard to compliance. Japan ex­
ceeded its quota in both 1969 and 1971, and
Common Market countries far exceeded
their quota in 1971 after falling considerably
below quota in earlier years. Non-signatory
producing countries exceeded their implied
quotas in all three years, and by a very con­
siderable margin in 1971.
Less specialty steel
Last year, foreign producers exceeded
their quota limitations most sharply in the
high-quality, low-volume categories, such as
stainless steel (34 percent over quota), and
tool and other alloy steel (59 percent over
quota). These categories still represented
only 3.3 percent of total steel imports, but
the high prices of specialty steels enabled
foreign producers to boost their revenues

17

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

from U.S. trade by more than the propor­
tionate increase in their total volume of ship­
ments to this country. This increase in the
mix of higher-value products, along with the
general increase in steel prices, enabled for­
eign producers to maintain total receipts
from U.S. sales almost even between 1968
and 1970, even in the face of a 25-percent
reduction in overall volume — and helped
bring about a new peak in dollar receipts as
tonnage soared last year.

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

in alloy-steel shipments between 1972 and
1974, but for continued cutbacks in stainlesssteel shipments.
Some problems may arise in reducing
total imports of specialty steels, however.
The European producer associations which
negotiated the agreement account for only
about two-thirds of European specialty-steel
shipments to the U.S., but spokesmen for
these associations stated that they “will use
their best efforts” to induce non-participat­
ing firms in Common Market countries to
abide by the quota limitations. More im­
portantly, non-signatory nations may have a
considerable impact on the market, at least
in the stainless-steel category. Canada and
Sweden, who a c c o u n te d for almost onefourth of U.S. stainless-steel imports in 1971,
have been exceeding last year’s pace so far
in 1972, and thus may offset much of the
cutback agreed to by other producers.
Less steel in the W est

18

Not surprisingly, the new agreement calls
for the sharpest reductions in trade to occur
in these specialty-steel categories. Between
1971 and 1972, the Common Market (in­
cluding the U.K.) and Japan are expected to
reduce their alloy-steel shipments from 324,000 to 254,000 tons, and their stainlesssteel shipments from 147,000 to 106,000
tons. The agreement calls for some increase




The new agreement attempts to curb fur­
ther foreign penetration into each of the
regions of the U.S. — especially the West,
which now buys almost one-third of its steel
from foreign sources. (The foreign share of
the District steel market jumped from 9 to
31 percent between 1961 and 1971, while
the import share in the rest of the nation
rose from 5 to 17 percent over the decade.)
Henceforth, the foreign signatories will at­
tempt to maintain the same proportionate
geographic distribution of shipments as they
maintained on average during the 1969-71
period, although some year-to-year fluctua­
tions are permitted. Japanese producers spe­
cifically agreed to ship no more than onethird of their total U.S. shipments to the
Pacific Coast customs region, in conform­
ance with the 1969-71 average pattern.
The terms of the new quota agreement are
somewhat more favorable to the domestic
industry than those of the original pact,

MONTHLY

July 1972

Japan sharply increases
its share of Western U.S. market
Millions of Tons

especially from the standpoint of the over­
all growth mix of steel products and geo­
graphical market penetration. Its overall
effectiveness could be reduced by the volun­
tary rather than mandatory nature of the
program and by the non-participation of
some important producing countries — just
as in 1971, when imports were almost 19
percent over quota. Still, the agreement
promises to reduce considerably the foreign

REVIEW

competition to domestic producers; in the
first quarter of 1972, even before the pact
was signed, steel imports had already de­
clined to the levels permitted under the
agreement, and the downward trend con­
tinued in April.
Nonetheless, the legality of the agreement
will remain unsettled until the courts rule
upon the validity of the Consumers Union
suit. In seeking an injunction, Consumers
Union charged that the agreement represent­
ed an antitrust violation, since it was a “con­
spiracy” between Administration officials
and foreign and domestic steel interests for
“unreasonable restraint” of trade. The suit
also alleged a violation of the 1962 Trade
Agreements Act, because there were no
Tariff Commission investigations, p u b lic
hearings, and findings of serious injury to
domestic industry prior to the agreement.
The next move is uncertain. But if con­
sumer interests were to succeed in keeping
open the channels of trade by blocking this
arrangement, producer interests might seek
redress by persuading Congress to enact
mandatory quotas on the steel trade.
Yvonne Levy

Publication Staff: Karen Rusk, Editorial Assistant; Janis Wilson, Artwork.
Single and group subscriptions to the M onthly Review are available on request from the
Administrative Service Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco, California 94120



FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

Publications Available
The China Trade (40 pp. 1972)— An analysis of two centuries’ trade between China
and the West. The study describes the development of trade under Western auspices
during the 19th and early 20th centuries, and then describes the completely different
trading environment existing today. After analyzing the structure of China’s current
imports and exports, the study concludes with estimates of the future magnitude of
the China trade.
Silver: End of an Era (32 pp. 1972)— A revised version of an earlier study of the
politics and economics of the silver industry. The study describes a century of silver
legislation (leading up to the recent demonetization), the development of the
Western mining industry, world coinage and industrial demand, and the sharp price
fluctuations of the past decade.
Nation-Spanning Credit Cards (12 pp. 1972)— An analysis of the rapid growth of
bank credit cards, with emphasis on the nationwide coverage recently obtained by
two major card plans. The study describes the advantages to cardholders and
merchants from widespread credit-card usage, technological developments enhancing
the spread of a general electronic-payments system, and the increasing profitability
of card plans with the growing maturity of the industry.
W all Street: Before the Fall (36 pp. 1970)—An analysis of basic stockmarket de­
velopments of the past 15 years. The booklet describes the supply and demand
factors underlying general price trends, and analyzes the industry’s operational
problems and the expanded role of institutional buying in recent years.
Calibrating the Building Trades (20 pp. 1971)— An analysis of the unique features
of the construction industry and their effect on construction wage trends. The study
describes the Administration’s development of an “incomes policy” tailored to that
specific industry.
Aluminum: Past and Future (64 pp. 1971)— An analysis of the long-term growth of

the aluminum industry, with its eight-fold expansion in consumption over the past
quarter-century. The study describes the locational factors responsible for the
national and international spread of the industry, and analyzes the reasons for recent
fears over the industry’s sharp expansion of capacity.
Copper: Red Metal in Flux (56 pp. 1968)— An historical study of the copper in­

dustry, with emphasis on the growth of Western producers. The report describes
copper’s response to the competitive inroads of other materials in traditional copper­
using industries.
Law of the River (16 pp. 1968)— An analysis of present and future sources of water
for the Pacific Southwest. The report describes how Southern California and Arizona
are looking beyond the Colorado River to meet their 21st-century needs for water.

Individual copies of each publication are available on request, and bulk shipments
are also available free to schools and nonprofit institutions. Write to the Administra­
tive Service Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco, California 94120.