View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO

M

O

N




T

H

L

Y

R

I

V

I

E

IN

W

THIS

ISSUE

Help for Housing?
Home Away from Home
Growth and Muni Bonds

JULY

1967




Help for Housing?
. .. Herewith, a summary of proposals designed to reduce housing's
vulnerability to a recurrence of the 1966 experience.

Home A w a y from Home
...T ra ve lle rs spend about $1.5 billion a year at W e ste rn lod ging
places, as tourism and convention business flourish.

Growth and Muni Bonds
. . . G overnm ental units in the W e s t expanded their borrow ing at a
greater-than-national pace over the past half-decade.

Editor: W illiam Burke

July 1967

M O N TH LY REVIEW

Help for Housing?
the housing slump is still far
gage market. In fact, the recent improve­
from over, a number of recent devel­
ment has been accompanied by a vigorous
opments indicate that an upturn is in the examination of proposals — some old, some
making. Three years of fairly steady decline
new — designed to give special assistance to
brought U.S. housing starts last year to a
one sector or another of the housing industry,
level barely three-quarters of that reached
and thereby to reduce the vulnerability of
during the recent high of 1963. During the
housing to a recurrence of the difficulties
which
beset it last year.
first five months of 1967, however, starts in
the nation averaged 24 percent above the
T hese p ro p o sa ls ru n th e gam ut from
annual rate attained during 1966’s final quar­
entirely new arrangements — such as direct
ter — and in the West, where the level of
public subsidies to home buyers — through
activity last year was almost 60 percent below
extensions of earlier reforms, to slight modi­
that of the pre-slump period, the construction
fications of existing policies or institutional
pace early this year was 28 percent ahead
practices. Proposed reforms include the de­
of the late-1966 figure. Contract awards,
velopment of a broadened secondary market
building permits, and the flow of savings into
for mortgages, an administrative “rollback”
mortgage-lending institutions also picked up,
of interest-rate ceilings on time and savings
and (a t least tem porarily) mortgage rates
deposits, greater flexibility (if not the elimi­
declined and non-price lending terms eased.
n a tio n ) of ra te ceilings on governm entNevertheless, the turnabout has been nei­
insured mortgages, and diversified lending
ther so great, nor so far removed from the
powers for heretofore specialized mortgage
“crunch” of 1966, as to dispel memories of

last year’s traum atic experience in the m ort­
institutions.
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/

A

lth o u g h

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

Central mortgage bank?
Several of the most widely discussed mea­
sures to help housing would achieve this
objective indirectly, by improving the mort­
gage market. One such proposal would trans­
form the Federal National Mortgage Asso­
ciation into a central mortgage bank, with a
trading desk whose function it would be to
buy and sell, co n tin u o u sly , governmentbacked mortgages and possibly conventional
mortgages as well. A related proposal, orig­
inally advanced by the American Bankers
Association several years ago, would estab­
lish Federally chartered private corporations
to insure conventional mortgages and to buy
and sell loans in secondary market opera­
tions.
By acting as a clearing house of informa­
tion with ready bids and quotes, the trading
desk would bring prospective buyers and
sellers together and would thus enable mort­
gages to be traded more like corporate, mu­
nicipal and Treasury obligations. This, in
turn, should result in lower marketing costs
and, hence, lower costs to the borrower.

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

borrower, the description and appraisal of
the property, and a host of factors influenced
by individual state laws. (Legislation of this
type deals with ceilings on rates and fees,
limits on loan-to-value ratios, maturities, me­
chanics liens and even docum entation.)

C onsequently, a g u a ra n te e p ro v isio n
should substantially enhance the m arketabil­
ity of the mortgage, simply by making it un­
necessary for the investor to evaluate each
individual loan in his portfolio. However,
the provision of such a risk-eliminating guar­
antee presumably would have to carry a fee
if it were not to involve an implicit element
of subsidy.
Most observers foresee formidable obsta­
cles which could hamper FN M A purchases
and sales of conventional mortgages, because
of the wide variation in state laws and the
lack of uniformity in the conventional m ort­
gage. Overcoming these obstacles would re­
quire a considerable expansion of FN M A of­
fices and staff to handle the screening and
processing of the expanded loan volume. Be­
sides, more FN M A resources for the pur­
chase of conventional loans could m ean less
Full guarantees?
FN M A resources for the purchase of FHA
and VA loans, to the detriment of the lower
Federal Reserve Governor Maisel’s sug­
income and lower down-payment homebuygestion that investors be allowed full recourse
ers who rely so heavily upon these types of
against FN M A for any mortgages purchased
financing. Beyond that, there remains the
from it — in effect, a government guarantee
of whether a government agency
—
also should enhance the marketability question
of
should properly deal at all in non-government
mortgages, and thereby should contribute to
backed mortgages.
a greater supply of available funds and help
reduce the cost of borrowing. In fact, a guar­
Com pete with private lenders?
antee of this sort, whether made by FNM A
A n o th e r p ro p o sa l would have housing
or even by private firms, might be essential
agencies augment the supply of funds avail­
to the development of a broad and active
able for mortgage financing by issuing their
secondary m arket for c o n v en tio n al m ort­
own securities, specifically tailored to meet
gages, which account for three-quarters of all
the needs of special categories of investors,
mortgages outstanding. Conventional mort­
such as individuals and pension funds. (A t
gages are not characterized by the same de­
the present time pension funds have only
gree of uniformity as F H A ’s and VA’s but
about $6 billion of their $160 billion invested
vary rather considerably, depending upon

140
the location and credit rating of the individual
in mortgages.) In fact, both FN M A and the


July 1967

M O N TH LY REVIEW

Upturn begins, but housing
still has far to go on recovery road
T h o u i Q u d * o f D v t l l i n g U n it s

Federal Home Loan Bank Board already
have the authority to m arket long-term obli­
gations. Some observers argue that a greater
exercise of this authority — by FN M A to
raise more money with which to purchase
FH A mortgages, and by the FHLB to in­
crease its advances to member S&L’s for
expansion purposes— would do more to iron
out sharp fluctuations in the availability of
mortgage funds than would the creation of a
central mortgage bank.
The U.S. Savings and Loan League, for
example, contends that a central mortgage
bank could hamper home finance by drawing
funds away from the thrift institutions which
are engaged in mortgage lending — S&L’s,
mutual savings banks and commercial banks.
Actually, FN M A ’s increased volume of openmarket offerings last year did help to push
up interest rates, and to some extent prob­
ably diverted savings from thrift institutions.
The mortgage bank, it is argued, apart
from offering added competition to other
mortgage institutions in bidding for the sup­
ply of loanable funds, might well accumulate
a substantial volume of funds during periods
Digitized forof
FRASER
monetary ease, but might still find it diffi­


cult during tight-money periods to attract
enough money at interest rates that builders
and borrowers could live with. Even so, a
properly functioning mortgage bank by defi­
nition would not contribute to overbuilding
during periods of ease because it would be
careful not to flood the m arket with low-cost
loanable funds. If it were to float longer-term
obligations during such periods it could then
make the funds available to borrowers on fa­
vorable terms during periods of general credit
restraint and higher interest rates.
G reater flexibility in rates —
But while housing analysts disagree about
the need for special mortgage facilities to im­
prove viability of secondary markets, they
agree almost unanimously about the need for
greater flexibility in FH A and VA interestrate ceilings, so as to avoid the heavy dis­
counts which characterized last year’s m ort­
gage market. Three successive increases in
the FH A ceilings in 1966, from 5 lA to 6 per­
cent, failed to keep pace with rising market
yields generally, and consequently failed to
attract the funds of private investors, so that
discounts around the country averaged close
to 10 points in some areas last fall.
Discounts— which are the means by which
the m arket adjusts to administered rates —
under some state laws must be computed as
part of the interest rate subject to rate ceil­
ings, even if they are paid by the builder or
seller. This constraint, of course, further im­
pedes the flow of funds into mortgages. Just
what the reaction of the market would be to
a “freeing” of administered rates at a time
when market rates are rising and discounts
on mortgages are deepening, however, is
somewhat uncertain.
The supply of housing might increase as
sellers are relieved of the burden of absorb­
ing discounts. If buyers are themselves eager,
of course, mortgage rates may rise even in
a situation of relative ease in the housing
market. At the same time, if buyers are re-

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

luctant and resist a shifting of discounts from
the seller, rates themselves might even soften.
As the president of the Mortgage Bankers
Association has pointed out, if administered
rates had been free to move higher in 1966,
borrowers at least would have had a greater
opportunity to borrow mortgage funds.
— and flexible rates on outstandings
Another proposal would tie the rates on
outstanding mortgage loans to some other
market rate, or index of rates. As interest
rates rose, the cost of the homebuyer’s pre­
viously borrowed funds would rise, and as
market rates declined, the cost of his m ort­
gage loan conversely would be reduced. The
adjustment could be made in the loan m atur­
ity rather than in the monthly payment.
Supporters of this approach argue that a
flexible rate would preclude home buyers
from “holding off” at a time of high yields
generally, because they would know that they
could also “benefit” from a future decline in
rates. Mortgage demand and housing activity
would then be smoothed out over the cycle,
and the mortgage lender happily would not
find himself in an earnings squeeze during
periods of general credit restraint and rising
yields.

M o r t g a g e flows slowed in '66
despite heavy F N M A purchases
B i l l i o n * of D o l l o r *




1967

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

However, the evidence suggests that the
enthusiasm of the home buying public for
such an arrangement is minimal. Efforts by
a few S&L’s last year to involve the fine print
“escalation clause” in their mortgage con­
tracts elicited a sufficiently negative response
on the part of their borrowers to force a
retreat. This of course was a one-way esca­
lation adverse to the borrower; without a
firm contractual system for downward rate
adjustments in periods of easier money, the
desired inducement for sustained mortgage
borrowing during h ig h -in te re st periods is
lacking.
Implicit and explicit subsidies
Closely related to the problem of adminis­
tered rates is the issue of whether rates on
g o v e rn m en t-in su red mortgages should be
lower than those which the market would
provide. The issue essentially boils down to
the d e sirab ility , on economic and social
grounds, of loan programs which involve an
implicit or explicit element of subsidy. Those
who argue in the affirmative, with the weight
of Congressional opinion behind them, point
out that lower-than-market rates on government-backed mortgages are often needed to
encourage homebuying by lower-and-middle
income families, which means that some special-support operation w ith p u b lic fu n d s
becomes necessary. Some critics oppose sub­
sidies per se, while others m aintain that even
if an element of subsidy is desirable, it might
better be extended by direct means, such as
loans or grants directly to the home buyer
to cover part of the interest cost or purchase
price of a home, rather than through often­
times self-defeating efforts to segment the
structure of market yields.
Still, explicit subsidies could create new
problems. The proposal for the Federal Gov­
ernm ent to make direct rental payments to
low-income families has already run into
snags. Treasury Secretary Fowler, viewing
the alternative of direct government loans,

July 1967

M O N TH LY REVIEW

has concluded that these should only supple­
ment, not substitute for, private financing. It
is conceivable, for example, that direct gov­
ernment lending could become so large in
some areas as to preclude private financing,
because of such factors as the increase in unit
overhead costs which private lenders would
face in administering a smaller volume of
loans.
Beyond that, there remains the problem of
establishing eligibility criteria for any such
subsidies — size of income, size of family,
“need,” or whatever. Furtherm ore, an in­
variant application of these criteria conceiv­
ably might accentuate economic fluctuations
at the very time when economic conditions
call for monetary, fiscal and credit policies
of a contra-cyclical nature.
Insulate the mortgage market?
Still another proposal would go even fur­
ther in an attempt to insulate housing from
fluctuations in the nation’s capital market. As
advanced by the Departm ent of Housing and
Urban Development, this insulation would be
achieved through massive Federal Reserve
purchases of FNM A and FH LB debentures,
the proceeds of which would then be used to
finance FN M A mortgage acquisitions and
FH LB advances to member S&L’s. (These
advances would then be used by the S&L’s
to expand their mortgage lending over and
above any increase in their savings flows and
repayment flows.)
By exerting a downward pressure on yields,
Federal Reserve o p e n -m a rk et p u rch ases
could, it is argued, result in the elimination
of discounts. But as last year’s experience
indicated, any such downward pressure on
mortgage yields could cause a shift of pri­
vate funds out of mortgages if other market
yields were rising at the same time. And since
overall credit conditions during a tight-money
period call for open-market sales rather than
purchases of the instruments in which trans­
are made, either the Federal Reserve
actions


would sell some FN M A and FH LB obliga­
tions along with the usual Treasury securities
— thus increasing their yields— or the special
Federal Reserve support of mortgages would
necessitate still further sales of other instru­
ments, generating upward pressures on their
yields. Under these circumstances, the m ar­
ket might witness a re-emergence of discounts
on mortgages, a drying-up of private m ort­
gage funds, and an accelerating reliance on
the Federal Reserve to provide the nation’s
mortgage funds.
Rolling back savings rates
Another possible means of easing the pol­
icy impact on the mortgage market would be
a “rollback” in the interest-rate ceilings which
thrift institutions may pay on their time-andsavings deposits. A forced reduction in the
cost of these funds is necessary to the thrift
institutions (so the argument goes) if the
price at which these funds are then made
available to mortgage borrowers is to be re­
duced. The problem, of course, is that an
administered rollback in the rates paid to
depositors might prove to be self-defeating
if the yields on the other instruments which
compete for investors’ funds should rise. The
funds would roll out of the thrift institutions
(and fail to roll in) and the ability of these
institutions to make mortgage loans would
tend to evaporate.
There remains, too, the problem of just
what rate ceilings should be applied to the
various types of thrift institutions. Until re­
cently, for example, S&L’s in certain Western
states were allowed to pay higher rates than
their counterparts elsewhere, the differential
being based on the grounds that these states
are fast-growing capital-deficit areas with a
relatively greater “need” for long-term funds.
Yet no such regional or local differential is
allowed com m ercial banks in these same,
states, notwithstanding the fact that they have
traditionally maintained a much higher ratio
of time-and-savings to total deposits than

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

banks elsewhere in the nation, as well as a
much higher ratio of real-estate to total loans.
Building up liquidity —
Yet another proposal, designed to reduce
the housing industry’s vulnerability to credit
changes by bolstering institutional liquidity,
has been advanced by the Home Loan Bank
Board and endorsed by the Council of Eco­
nomic Advisers, the American Bankers Asso­
ciation, and the Federal Reserve Board of
Governors. This proposal would have thrift
institutions— most notably the S&L’s— build
up a buffer stock of cash and government
securities during periods of general monetary
and credit ease, sufficient to help finance con­
tinued mortgage lending during periods of
credit restraint.
Such a buffer stock of liquidity would not
only reduce the S&L’s vulnerability to reduc­
tions in savings inflows, but would also make
them less dependent upon FH LB borrowings.
Also, by its very nature, it would reduce
lenders’ incentive to make loans of inferior
quality during periods of general credit ease.
A related proposal would have the S&L’s
and mutual savings banks supplement their
normal sources of loanable funds by issuing
a greater variety of longer-term securities. If
issued during periods of credit ease and gen­
erally low interest rates, the securities not
only would provide the institutions with a
greater proportion of funds “locked in” at
lower rates — thus improving their earnings
— but would make them less vulnerable to
savings outflows during periods of credit re­
straint and rising yields.
— and diversified lending
Finally, there remains a somewhat contro­
versial proposal that has been advanced not
so much to help housing as to help the S&L
industry. This is the suggestion that nonbank
depositary institutions specializing in m ort­
gage lending be allowed to diversify their loan

144
and investment portfolios— in effect, making


OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

them more like commercial banks.
Savings-and-loan men argue that such di­
versification would not only result in greater
competition, to the advantage of the public
at large, but would also help to spread the
impact of m o n etary policy actio n s more
evenly throughout the financial system, and
perhaps lessen the need for a system of struc­
tured rate ceilings on the deposits of the vari­
ous types of thrift institutions. By increasing
the flexibility of S&L’s, diversification also
would improve their earnings, and this in turn
would make it easier for them to limit savings
outflows by adjusting rates paid to savers as
yields rise during periods of heavy credit
demands.
Those opposed to a broadening of the
lending powers of heretofore specialized in­
stitutions maintain that any such diversifica­
tion would, by its very nature, divert funds
to uses other than the financing of mortgages.
But there is yet another dimension to the
problem — to what extent can nonbank de­
positary institutions be made more like com­
mercial banks on the lending or asset side
of the ledger, without corresponding adjust­
ments on the capital and liabilities side as
well?
Some such adjustment may be desirable
so as to achieve a more equitable incidence of
taxation, and also to achieve a more effective
“incidence” of monetary policy. The poten­
tial for destabilizing shifts of funds between
various types of in stitu tio n s might be in­
creased if lending powers were more nearly
equalized but reserve and liquidity require­
ments were not — that is, if S&L’s were not
required (as their competitors are) to im­
mobilize a large part of their assets into cash
and relatively low-yielding assets out of def­
erence to reserve and liquidity requirements.
As the foregoing pages indicate, all quar­
ters of the financial world have developed
ideas about what went wrong with the m ort­
gage market in 1966 and what can properly

July 1967

M O N TH LY REVIEW

M o r t g a g e market hampered
by last year's slump in savings inflow
B illio n i of D o lla rs

be done to cushion the impact of such an
experience if it should re-occur. The Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
in analyzing this subject, came up with sev­
eral broad guidelines in a report prepared
recently for the Senate Banking and Cur­
rency C o m m itte e . The guidelines are:
— A flexible policy should play a greater
part than it did in 1966 in acting, when
needed, to restrain aggregate economic
activity. Timely reductions in income tax
rates earlier in the 1960’s contributed
greatly to the sustained economic growth
that developed after the 1960-61 reces­
sion. If, with the added economic stimulus
provided by escalation of the Vietnamese
war, an income-tax increase had been en­
acted early in 1966, the burden of restrain­
ing general economic activity would have
fallen less heavily on monetary policy
and hence less severely on the residential
mortgage market and on housing.
— The residential mortgage market— both
primary and secondary— should be inte­
grated closely with the general capital




market, not insulated from it. But at the
same time, certain institutional changes
should be made to enhance the ability of
the residential mortgage market to com­
pete prudently for the limited aggregate
supply of available credit. It should be
recognized that the result would involve
payment of higher rates at certain times
for savings funds and for mortgage credit.
— If special public measures appear war­
ranted to ease the impact of tightening
general credit conditions on the availa­
bility or price of residential mortgage
credit, such actions should be taken with­
out sacrificing the objectives of monetary
restraint. Moreover, the extent of the sub­
sidy element involved should be revealed
clearly, and the substitution of public for
private credit should be minimized.
The Board also suggested (although with­
out endorsing) several specific actions de­
signed to stabilize the housing market:
(1 ) Improve the liquidity of thrift institu­
tions so as to withstand better the pressures
that develop when general credit condi­
tions tighten.
(2 ) Improve the marketability of residen­
tial mortgages so as to make them more
attractive and to permit lenders to adjust
their portfolio positions more readily to
conditions of general credit restraint.
(3 ) Improve the allocation of residential
mortgage funds so as to assure a more
efficient distribution of credit during peri­
ods of general credit restraint.
(4 ) Broaden sources of funds available
for residential mortgage investment, there­
by relying less on depository institutions
that tend to be vulnerable to conditions
accompanying general credit restraint.
— Verle Johnston

145

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

Home Away from Home
and pleasure-seekers spend
roughly $1.5 billion a year at Western
lodging establishments in payment for rooms,
meals, liquor, and other goods and services.
On the basis of these receipts, the region’s
lodging industry employs over 120,000 work­
ers and carries an annual payroll of over
$500 million.
u s in e s s m e n

B

Hotel-motel employment in District states
has increased recently at a 6-percent annual
average rate, rising from 75,000 in 1955 to
121,000 in 1965. Wages are rather low in
the industry, because of the relatively low
level of skills required and because of the
reliance on tips as a supplement to wages,
so the industry— although employing about
1 percent of the total working force — ac­
counts for only 0.8 percent of total wages
in District states and for 0.6 precent of total
wages elsewhere in the nation. In some West­
ern states, however, the industry’s importance
is far above average— it accounts for 10
percent of total wages in Nevada and for

146 for FRASER
Digitized


1 to 2 percent of the total in Hawaii and
Arizona.
Diverse growth trends
The region’s lodging industry is extremely
diverse, including as it does some older—
even decrepit — hotels and trailer camps
along with some of the world’s most palatial
pleasure domes. Moreover, establishments
vary considerably in size, ranging from mas­
sive convention hotels in Los Angeles, San
Francisco, Honolulu and Las Vegas to momand-pop operated motels located in small
rural communities. (O ver one-third of the
motels and one-half of the trailer parks in
District states do not report any payroll.)
And the industry also exhibits a wide range
of growth rates; between the 1954 and 1963
Business Census years, hotel receipts in
Western states grew by two-thirds, to $641
million, while receipts in the automobileoriented lodging places more than tripled,
to $442 million. (California and the Pacific
Northwest actually registered a decline in
hotel-room space over this period.)
Hotels have encountered difficulty in ad­
justing to the auto and jet age. Because they
were originally located near downtown rail­
road stations, they have lost tourist traffic
to freeway-oriented motels and trailer parks,
and have lost considerable business traffic
as businessmen have shortened their out-oftown stays in tune with jet-age plane sched­
ules. Hotels nonetheless have fought back
by catering to jet-age tourist and convention
business and by expanding their downtown
parking facilities. Motels meanwhile have
m atured along with the automobile age; the
newer establishments stand in sharp contrast
to the stage-coach inns of the nineteenth
century and in almost as sharp contrast to

M O NTH LY REVIEW

July 1967

Receipts rise at hotels, but even more rapidly at auto-oriented lodgings
. . . W estern establishments obtain growing share of total receipts
M illio n s of D o lla r)

D istrict Share of U.S. R eceip t* (P e rce n t)

600

0

5

10

M illio n s of D o lla rs

15

T ra ile r
P a rk )

M o te ls

H otels

1954

the cold-water shacks of the 1930’s.
The lodging industry has gone through
drastic changes in the postwar period. The
increased number of travelers, the longer
vacations, the sharp rise in auto traffic— all
have spurred an especially heavy demand
for wayside accommodations which could
not be met by the traditional commercial
hotels and the older motels and trailer parks.
The result is the “grand motel”— an estab­
lishment with a hotel-style range of services
but motel-style conveniences and parking
facilities. Located as they are near airports,
in major shopping centers, and even in
downtown areas, the new-style elegant mo­
tels have become a characteristic feature of
the postwar landscape.
Strong income trends
Despite the faster growth of motels, West­
ern hotels have been able to expand their
average receipts at the same rate as their
competitors. Annual receipts per room in­
creased by about two-thirds in both types
of establishments over the 1954-63 period,
to $2,900 for hotels and $2,100 for motels.
Average receipts for hotels in the West were
Digitized forabout
FRASERone-fifth above the average hotel in­


1956

1963

come in other regions, while receipts for mo­
tels were roughly in line with the average
elsewhere.
Higher average receipts for hotels reflected
both a higher level of room rates and a
wider range of income-producing services.
In 1963, less than half of hotel receipts in
Western hotels came from room rentals —
much of the rest was generated by restaurant
and bar facilities — while three-quarters of
motel receipts came from room rentals.
Rising hotel income was accomplished
despite the increasing age of the industry’s
physical stock; two-thirds of the region’s
hotels, as against one-third of its motels,
commenced operations before 1949. Rising
income was achieved also in the face of a
decline in occupancy rates; occupancy, which
had exceeded 90 percent during and imme­
diately after World W ar II, declined from
72 to 62 percent between 1955 and 1965.
Motel occupancy rates have been maintained
above 70 percent during the past decade, as
the aggregate demand for motel space has
grown at the expense of traditional hotels.
But the hotel industry’s problems have
centered around the older, smaller hotels

that are both short of modern conveniences
and are located in the smaller population
centers which have been bypassed by the
major airlines and freeways. The magnificent
new establishments which cater to the tourist
and convention trade have generally pros­
pered. In the 1963 Business Census year,
occupancy rates in large hotels in California,
Nevada, and Hawaii ranged between 69 and
77 percent, in contrast to a national (largehotel) average of 63 percent.
Even in the larger convention centers,
however, a downtrend in hotel space oc­
curred between 1954 and 1963. In the latter
year, New York maintained 122,000 hotel
rooms, as against 70,000 in Chicago, 40,000
in Los Angeles, 35,000 in Miami, and 33,000
in San Francisco— which means a drop in
room space of one-tenth or more in almost
every area. But Hawaii was an exception
to this downtrend; hotel-room space in that
rapidly growing vacation center tripled over
the decade, and recently has grown even
more.
Travelers' impact on construction
Meeting the transient population’s demand
for housing has been a major stimulus to the

nation’s construction industry over the post­
war period. Between 1949 and 1963, the
industry produced 5,000 new hotels (alm ost
1,000 of them in the W est) plus 17,000 new
motels (m ore than 3,000 of them in this
region).
Motel construction benefits from relatively
low building costs. A new 2-to-3 story motel
requires only one-half to four-fifths of the
cost per room of the average new hotel, and
typically it contains less than half the number
of rooms of the average hotel. Using massproduction techniques which perm it substan­
tial cost savings — and consequently, low
room rates— “instant motels” have been es­
tablished by large national motel chains to
take advantage of the high-density traffic
generated by major freeways. Financing of
such facilities is usually done through lifeinsurance firms, commercial banks, and even
oil companies, which frequently guarantee
mortgages in addition to operating motel
service stations.
In the future, the rapidly growing number
of business, tourist, and conventioneering
travelers promises to generate a growing
amount of business for W estern hotels, m o

Demand shifts cause sharp expansion in motel (but not hotel) room space
. . . hotel space concentrated in New York and other convention cities
Hotel Rooms (Thousands)




Number of Hotels

Number of Holt! Room s (Thousands)

Rooms (Thousands)

120 75
100
400

50

80
25

300

60
15
40

10
20

New York

Chicago

Los Angeles

M iam i

San Froncitco

0

5

1954

1958

1963

July 1967

MO NTHLY REVIEW

tels, and tourist parks. With more people on
the highways, and more coming on the sky­
ways with the advent of jumbo jets, a grow­
ing influx of visitors can be expected to tax
present lodging capacity and thereby create
a need for increased construction of motels
and hotels— or at least of those establish­
ments which will offer a wide range of mod­
ern facilities in convenient locations. But as
the following sample indicates, the Western
lodging industry already is preparing for
the growing tide of visitors.
In California, construction in recent years
has included three large motels, each with
250 to 400 rooms, near San Francisco air­
port, plus a 1,200-room hotel in downtown
San Francisco and a 800-room facility in
Beverly Hills. In the planning stage are two
large hotels in San Diego, two in Los Ange­
les, one in Oakland, and one in Anaheim,
with room sizes ranging from 400 to 1,000
rooms, plus two more large hotels in the
700-800 room category in San Francisco.
One of the latter will contain the largest
ballroom-banquet facilities in the West.
In Nevada, convention facilities and gam­
ing tables have attracted a sharp rise in
tourism and a consequent boom in construc­
tion. Room capacity reached 24,000 in 1963,
for a one-fifth increase in four year’s time,

W estern establishments hold edge
in average room receipts
R c c tlp ti Ptr Room (D o llo r tl

0__________ 1000
W EST

—V-

2000

3000

1954
1963

0 t h « r U .S .

Motel#

and it is now sharply higher. Las Vegas in
recent years has built a 680-room and a
1,000-room hotel, and major new hotelconvention facilities are now planned for
Reno and Henderson (near Las Vegas).
In Hawaii, a substantial construction boom
has gone hand-in-hand with its tourist boom.
Hotel room space more than tripled in the
1955-65 period, to 15,000, and a 50-percent
expansion of this capacity will probably be
completed within the next several years. The
industry recently added two new hotels of
880-room and 1,060 room capacity, respec­
tively, and in the planning stage are two more
large hotels at Waikiki as well as several
smaller establishments on the islands of
Kauai and Hawaii.
— Paul Ma

Publication Staff: R. Mansfield, Chartist; Phoebe Fisher, Editorial Assistant.
Single and group subscriptions to the Monthly Review are available on request from the Admin­
istrative Service Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 400 Sansome Street,
San Francisco, California 94120




149

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

Growth and Muni Bonds
with other financial markets, the
market for state-local governm ent
bonds (m unicipal bonds) felt the pressure
of restrictive monetary policy in 1966. Yet,
despite a sharp drop in muni-bond sales
during the summer period’s tight-money
peak, total state-local sales reached $11.05
billion for the year as a whole. This was ex­
ceeded only by the previous year’s record
sales of $11.14 billion.

A

lo n g

Over the 1962-66 period, municipal-bond
sales exhibited a 6-percent average annual
rate of growth. This upsurge in borrowing
accompanied a sharp rise in state-local gov­
ernment spending, which over the postwar
period has increased far more steeply than
federal spending. By late 1964, in fact, statelocal expenditures on goods and services
actually exceeded those of the Federal gov­
ernment, and continued to do so through
the middle of last year, when sharply in­
creased expenditures for Vietnam reversed
the balance once again.
Interest rates on municipal bonds have

Muni-bond sales slacken
during tight-money period
Millio** of Dollor*

Ptrcont
—

DISTRICT SHARE OF U.S.

20

10
150

1962

1963




1964

I96S

1966

1967

fluctuated with overall monetary conditions.
In the last several years, little variation in
spread has developed between muni-bond
yields, on the one hand, and corporate and
Treasury bond yields, on the other. In 1962,
the average yield on A aa municipal bonds
was 3.03 percent; by 1965, it was 3.16 per­
cent; and for 1966 it was 3.90 percent with
a peak of 4.18 percent being reached in
September. Lower-rated bonds followed a
roughly similar path, but there was one new
development: the spread between A aa and
Baa bonds tended to narrow somewhat over
time. In 1962 the spread varied between 57
and 80 basis points, while in 1966 the spread
was from 39 to 60 basis points.
W est outpaces nation
Governmental units in Twelfth District
states increased their borrowing as well as
their spending at a faster-than-national pace
during the 1962-66 period. Total new issues
rose from $1.38 billion in 1962 to $2.30
billion in 1965, before declining to $2.02
billion in 1966. Thus, the W est’s share of
total bond sales rose from 16 to 18 percent
over the period, and actually exceeded 20
percent in 1964 and 1965.
The average volume of borrowing has
tended to vary directly with the various states’
population and income. While there are, of
course, other forces influencing decisions to
borrow, the high degree of correlation of
these two factors with bond sales is quite
clear, and the relationship undoubtedly is
mutual. Income and population growth, in
other words, have been m ajor factors in­
ducing and supporting the growth of W estern
state-local borrowing over this timespan, and
the consequent rise in state-local spending
has added to income and attracted potential
migrants.
California governmental units naturally

July 1967

M O N TH LY REVIEW

were the largest borrowers over this period;
their issues were never less than half the Dis­
trict total of funds raised, and in 1966 Cali­
fornia issues ($1,642 million) made up
almost four-fifths of the regional total. Fur­
thermore, in every year since 1962, they
accounted for the largest dollar volume of
issues of any state in the union. The totals
were bolstered during the past three years
by five State of California issues of $100
million or more.
Washington came next in regional imporportance, being second to California in every
year of this period except 1966. Washing­
ton’s peak was reached in 1963, when its
$722 million in new flotations— mostly as­
sociated with the financing of the Columbia
River power project— gave it fourth place
in national rankings. That state also floated
a $ 3 14-million offering in 1964— the fifth
largest single issue sold in the nation up to
that time.
Physical and human resources
A breakdown of last year’s total flotations
permits an analysis of the purposes for which
Western governmental units borrow so heavi­
ly. The largest category last year, making
up one-third of the District total (as against
one-sixth nationally) was public utilities and
conservation. California’s program dominat­
ed both District and national borrowing in
the category of water-resource and recreation
development. Six issues, ranging from $20
million to $160 million in size, helped push
the state-wide total to $638 million.

Next in importance was education, which
took more than one-quarter of total funds
raised in the District last year. Higher edu­
cation in District states accounted for almost
6 percent of total borrowing, as opposed to
a 3-percent share nationally. The District
also outpaced the nation in borrowing for
elementary and secondary education. Over
the 1962-66 period as a whole, California
governmental units led all others in borrow­
ing for this purpose, as the state in some
years devoted almost 30 percent of its bond
receipts to elementary and secondary schools.
Social-welfare activities, such as public
housing, veterans, and recreation, amounted
to 14 percent of District borrowing last year.
Almost one-third of the total was concen­
trated in a single State of California issue,
which divided $100 million equally between
recreation and veterans programs. Oregon
also raised $30 million in two issues for
veterans.
Transportation issues took under 9 percent
of District borrowing, concentrated mostly
in two large bond issues— $50 million for
the San Francisco Bay Area Rapid Transit
District and $48 million for the California
Toll Bridge Authority. Transportation issues,
by the way, have been declining in impor­
tance over the past decade, since the Federal
highway program has relieved much of the
financial burden on states and local govern­
ments.
The District failed to participate in the
upsurge of industrial-aid financing, which

P U R P O S E S O F S O R R O W IN G , BY STATE, 1966
($ millions)
Elem.-Secondary
Education
A lask a
Arizona
C alifo rn ia
H aw aii
Idaho
N evada
Oregon
Utah
W ashington
Total

Higher
Education

__

-----

14
346

28
60
—

5
10
33
8
21
437


Source: Investment Bankers Association


1
—

17
1
7
114

Transportation
5
131
1
1
19
11
_

8
176

Utilities,
Conservation
5
16
638
____
____

13
18
3
27
720

Social Welfare

__
7
219
3
3
3
49
1
6
291

Other

Total

6
23
190
20
1
6
13
2
16
277

11
93
1,584
24
11
51
141
15
85
2,015

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

on the national scene was perhaps the most
noticeable development in the field of statelocal finance last year. This type of financing,
which uses the tax-free feature of municipal
bonds to provide facilities at a lower cost
than private corporations can obtain, is de­
signed to attract new industry to develop
particular areas. Nationally, industrial-aid
issues doubled in 1966, to $504 million, or
roughly 5 percent of total state-local borrow­
ing, but none of these bonds were issued by
Twelfth District states. Actually, only four
District states permit the issuance of such
bonds, which have come to be widely crit­
icized as a doubtful fiscal practice.
States expand their borrowing
In the West as in the rest of the nation,
borrowing by state governments has in­
creased relative to that by cities and counties.
Borrowing by special districts and similar
public bodies meanwhile has risen substan­
tially, because of the capabilities of such or­
ganizations for accomplishing area-wide proje c ts o r b e c a u s e o f th e d e s ire to av o id
limitations on borrowing imposed by state
constitutions.
School-district financing has tended to lag,
but since educational expenditures have re­
mained high, this simply represents a shift to
state-government borrowing. The State of
California, to cite the most obvious case,
borrowed over $600 million between 1962
and 1966 to provide credits for local school construction programs.
The dollar volume of bonds raised by
special districts more than doubled in the
1962-65 period alone, thereby financing such
heterogeneous activities as toll bridges, elec­
tric companies, water works, and irrigation
projects. These public bodies have been set
up to handle projects not easily operated by
ordinary government organizations or to un­
dertake joint functions for several govern­
ments.

In the West, where public power and
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
152
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

OF

SAN

FRANCISCO

State-governm ent borrowing
more important here than elsewhere
Poretnt

100 |-

Othor U.S.

W EST

WEST

O ttitrU S .

- Sp tcial O iit ric t i-

80

60

School D ist r ic t *-

I

40

- C it it t - C o u n t ie s '

20
■S t a t u -

1962

1965

water projects have been historically impor­
tant, the special district has continued to
play a major role. The Columbia River proj­
ect was largely financed by public-utility
districts in Washington, while California’s
water-development program has stimulated
local water and irrigation districts to increase
their activities. California meanwhile has wit­
nessed the development of a new form of
public agency— a special authority which
constructs some project, usually a civic build­
ing or stadium, and then leases it back to
the city or county concerned. Recent issues
under this kind of arrangement include the
$27-million San Diego Stadium and the $26million Oakland-Alameda Stadium.
Like public bodies everywhere, District
governmental units have expanded their bor­
rowing in order to finance their growing
expenditures. A temporary setback occurred
during 1966’s period of monetary restraint,
but the basic uptrend has now reasserted
itself; in the first half of 1967, muni-bond
sales in the nation as a whole were about
30 percent higher than in the like period of
a year ago. Indeed, the strong growth trend
in municipal borrowing seems certain to
continue in line with the upward trend in
state-local expenditures.
— Robert Johnston