View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September-October 1966

The Changing Structure of Rural Banking ••• page 3
Measuring a Deficit or Surplus in the
U. S. Balance of International Payments •• page 11

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF KANSAS CITY

Subscriptions to the Mo THLY REVIEW are available to the public without charge. Additional
ropies of any issue may be obtained from the
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Kansas City, Missouri 64106. Permission is granted to reproduce any material in
this publication.

The Changing Structure
of Rural Banking
By Raymond ]. Doll

within both the commercial
D banking and agricultural
industries during
EVELOPME TS

the past 15 years have had a sharp impact on
rural banks. During and immediately after
World War II, commercial bank investment
portfolios were highly liquid. Loans generally
were relatively low and investments in Government securities were high. Beginning in
the early 1950's, a number of developments
have brought about significant changes in the
financial sector of the economy, including the
Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord, changes in
rates commercial banks were permitted to pay
on time and savings deposits, abandonment of
the ''bills only" policy, and, until recently, use
of a generally stimulative credit policy to encourage a fully employed and stable economy.
In addition to experiencing the developments within the financial sector of the economy, rural banks also felt the impact of sharp
adjustment problems that occurred in rural
areas. The agricultural industry literally
passed through a technological revolutionwith the number of farms declining at an average annual rate of about 3 per cent-during
the period that the financial developments
mentioned above took place. This revolution
is continuing unabatedly. Total capital requirements of the industry have about doubled

Monthly Review

•

September-October 1966

-making capital requirements per farm currently about 3J~ times as large as requirements
15 years ago.
These changes have caused the average
amount of credit used per farmer to increase
roughly 5 times in this period. Demands for
farm credit have increased sharply, and since
rural banks are a major source of this credit,
the impact of these activities has been reflected
in rural bank portfolios. This situation is particularly important since such banks are
heavily dependent on farm income for their
deposits, and farm income increased only at a
modest rate during this period. The result is
that the structure of most enterprising rural
banks is substantially different now as compared with 1950. This article will show some
of the changes that have occurred, evaluate
these changes, and show the wide variability
that prevails from bank to bank for rural banks
in the Tenth Federal Reserve District.
Before proceeding with the analysis, it is
appropriate to define a rural bank and briefly
discuss the relative importance of such banks.
A rural bank is defined as any bank that had
50 per cent or more of its total loan volume in
agricultural loans on both December 31, 1950,
and December 31, 1965-the beginning and
end of the period being evaluated. There were
3

The Changing Structure
231 member and 329 nonmember banks in the
T enth District that met this definition , so 560
banks , or about 30 per cent of all commercial
banks in the Tenth District, were rural banks .
. ot included in the definition of a rural bank
were 227 banks that had .50 per cent or more
of their total loan volume in agricultural loans
in 1950, hut dropped below the figure in 1965,
and 329 hanks that were above this figure in
1965, but were below it in 1950. It is interesting to note that a substantially larger number
of banks had .SO per cent or more of their loan
volume in agricultural loans in 1965 than in
1950.
rn the s11hseq11cnl analysis, the evaluations
"'ill he hascd 11pon changes occurring between
the hc12;i1111inl!; and end of the 1.5-year period.
\lajor reasons for using this comparative
method are: ( 1) ~Jany of the factors responsible for major changes in bank assets and liabilities during the period were discontinuous
in nature. ( 2) In evaluating credit problems,
such as those facing commercial b a nks and
the agricultural industry today, there are good
reasons for using the most recent data rather
than projecting from time series regression
curves. Such estimates are influenced by information from some banks that, for various
reasons, may not be making an effort to pro-

Chart 1
DEPOSIT GROWTH OF MEMBER BANKS
Tenth District
Index (December 1950 = 100)

4

Chart 2
LOAN-TO-DEPOSIT RATIO
OF MEMBER BANKS
Tenth District
Per Cent

60

50

40

30

ZOl.~9~5~1---'---''--7•5~ 5:-'-_L____L__L______l'L6_0L_...J__J__L____L'6_5_.1_~

,·ide for the credi t r quirements of their communities. ( 3) The general trends influencing
capital and credit requirements in agriculture
were persistently in the same direction and occurred at rapid, even though not consistently
stable, rates.
Before proceeding with an analysis of the
1950-65 change for rural banks, it is of interest
to compare year-to-year changes for several
broad c1assifications of data for all member
hanks. Because bank deposits are influenced
by such factors as changes in rates commercial
banks are permitted to pay on time a nd savings deposits, open market operations, and
variability of economic conditions among the
different areas, it is important to have some
idea of year-to-year changes in deposits for
the banking system in the District. Member
bank data only are used, since they are more
readily available, account for a large proportion of all deposits in th e District, and indirectly influence nonm mber bank deposits. It
is of interest to note in Chart 1 that demand
deposits of these banks increased at a persistent, but slow, rate throu ghout most of the
period. Time and savings deposits, on the
other hand, increased rather slowly at first but,
with the increasing demand for credit and the

of Rural Banking
Table 1
STATISTICAL DATA ON RURAL BANKS
Tenth Federal Reserve District
Member Banks
Dec. 31 Dec. 31
Per Cent
Change
1950
1965
(Millions of dollars)
Total Deposits
Demand deposits
Time deposits
Other deposits•:,
Total Loans
Agricultura l loans

Nonmember Banks
Dec. 31 Dec.31
Per Cent
Change
1950
1965
(Millions of dollars)

All Banks
Dec. 31 Dec. 31
1950
1965
(Millions of dollars)

Per Cent
Change

493

840

+70

385

674

+75

878

1,514

+72

388
44
62

445
274
121

+15
+523
+95

313
26
46

386
192
96

+23
+638
+109

701
69
108

831
465
217

+19
+574
+101

162

466

+188

131

355

+17 1

293

821

+180

133

323

+186

92

245

+166

205

568

+ 177

Cash, balances with other
banks, and cash items
in process of collection

143

157

+10

104

116

+11

247

273

+10

U. S. Government securities

199

219

+10

163

218

+34

362

437

+ 21

22

73

+23 2

15

53

+ 253

37

126

+240

Obligations of states and
political subdivisions

,:, Deposit,; of U. S. Government, states and political subdivisions, and of other banks.
NOTE : Member and Nonmember Bank f ig ures may not odd to All Bank fig ure because of rounding.

changes in rates commercial banks were permitted to pay on them, these deposits commenced to increase at an accelerating rate in
the late 1950's and were roughly 6 times as
large in 1965 as in 1951.
The average loan-to-deposit ratio of all
member banks in Chart 2 shows that this ratio
has increased rather persistently throughout
the period, indicating that total loans made by
District member banks have trended upward
throughout the period at a more rapid rate
than have deposits. The ratio almost doubled,
increasing from 30 in December 1950 to 57 in
December 1965.
RURAL BANKS
General statistical data for rural banks included in Table 1 show total deposits of these
banks increased 72 per cent during the period
being evaluated. This growth compares with
an increase of 45 per cent in cash receipts
from farm marketings and Government payments to farmers in Tenth District states during the same period. Even though deposits of
these banks grew at a noticeably more rapid
rate than farm income, two observations are
pertinent. ( 1 ) Deposit growth in the rural

Monthly Review

•

banks was not as large as for all member banks
in the Tenth District. ( 2) Changes in rates
banks were permitted to pay on time and savings deposits probably had a substantial impact on deposit growth, since the higher rates
enabled aggressively managed banks to pull
funds in from outside the area and from other
financial institutions. Changes in these rates
did have an impact on deposits of rural banks
as is shown by the impressive 574 per cent increase in time deposits versus the 19 per cent
increase in demand deposits. Without the
change in rates banks were permitted to pay,
these banks might have had a difficult time
maintaining a rate of deposit growth equivalent to that of gross farm income.
There was wide variation in the increase of
total deposits and deposits by type among
banks. In many of the rural banks, time deposits increased from a relatively minor part
of total deposits at the beginning of the period
to where they were more important than demand deposits by the end of the period. At
the other extreme, a significant number of
banks either had no time deposits or suffered
substantial declines in time deposits between
the beginning and end of the period. More

September-Octobe r 1966

5

The Changing Structure

Table 2
CHANGES IN DEPOSITS OF RURAL BANKS FROM 1950-65
CLASSIFI ED BY LOAN/ DEPOSIT RATIO IN 1965
Tenth Federal Reserve District
Loan/
Deposit
Ratios
(Per Cent)

Number
of
Banks

Demand
Time and Savings
Other
Dec.
Dec.
Dec.
Dec.
Dec.
Dec.
31
31
Per Cent
31
31
Per Cent
31
31
Change
1950
1965
1950
1965
Change
1950
1965
(Millions of dollars)
(Millions of dollars)
(Millions of dollars)

Total
Dec.
Dec.
31
Per Cent
31
Change
1965
1950
(Millions of dollars)

Per Cent

Change

All Banks
Up to 40
40-49
50-59
60-69
70 and up

98
117
159
121
65

116
139
209
160
76

133
164
259
184
90

14.6
17.9
23.9
15 .0
18.4

10
14
19
20
7

Total

560

701

831

18.S

69

62
83
143
125
52

520.0
492.8
652 .6
525 .9
642.8

17
22
34
24
11

33
43
68
52
22

94.1
95.4
100.0
116.6
100.0

144
175
261
204
94

229
290
469
362
164

59.0
65.7
79.6
77.4
74.4

465

573.9

108

2 17

100.9

878

1,514

72.4

Member Banks
Up to 40
40-49
50- 59
60-69
70 and up
Total

33
41
75
53
29

59
63
116
104
46

64
73
143
117
49

8.4
15 .8
23 .2
12.S
6.5

7
6
11
14
5

231

388

445

14.6

44

38
39
84
82
31

442.8
550.0
663 .6
485.7
520.0

11
21
15
6

9

17
20
40
34
JI

88.8
81.8
90.4
126.6
83.3

75
80
149
133
56

118
131
149
232
92

57.3
63.7
79.1
74.4
64.2

274

522.7

62

121

95.1

493

840

70.3

8
12
13
9
5

16
23
28
18
10

100.0
91.5
115.3
100.0
100.0

70
95
113
71
37

111
159
202
130
72

58.5
67.3
78.7
83.0
94.5

96

108.6

385

674

75.0

Nonmember Banks
Up to 40
40-49
50-59
60-69
70 and up

65
76
84
68
36

58
76
93
57
30

70
92
116
68
41

20.6
21.0
24.7
19.2
36.6

4
7
7
6
2

25
45
58
43
21

Total

525 .0
542.8
728.5
616 .6
950.0

329
313
386
26
192
638.4
46
23.3
NOTE : Member and Nonmember Bank figures may not add to All Bank figure because of rounding.

than a fourth of the member banks and a fifth
of the nonmember rural banks suffered declines in demand deposits ranging up to 49
per cent. Increases in demand deposits ranged
upward to 147 per cent for member banks and
191 per cent for nonmember banks.
There was considerably more variability in
deposit change from December 1950-65 among
nonmember banks than among member banks.
Five per cent of the nonmember banks lost
deposits during this period and, almost without exception, these banks were small. On the
other hand, 4 per cent of the nonmember banks
more than tripled their deposits during the
period-with one bank increasing total deposits
.5½ times . Only 1 per cent of the member banks
lost deposits, but less than 1 per cent tripled
total deposits during the period; the largest
increase in total deposits of a member bank
was about 3¼ times. Even though a larger proportion of nonmember banks lost deposits, a
6

larger proportion of nonmember banks also
showed greater rates of deposit growth. The
larger average size of member banks, plus the
fact that more member banks had only moderate rates of growth, combined to cause the
rate of growth in total deposits of member
banks to be somewhat lower than for nonmember banks.
Data in Table 2 indicate that there was
substantial variability among rural banks in
their loan-to-deposit ratios. There were more
banks, with a larger dollar volume of deposits,
with ratios oJ up to 40 per cent, than there
were banks with ratios of 70 per cent and up.
The ratios varied from 21 to 83 per cent for
member banks and from 9 to 93 per cent for
nonmem her banks. In checking through the
data by individual banks, it is interesting to
note that, with four exceptions, all member
banks with loan-to-deposit ratios of up to 40
in December 1965 also had ratios of less than

of Rural Banking
40 in December 1950. Three of the four exceptions dropped from ratios of slightly above
40 to slightly below 40, and one bank's ratio
dropped from 60 to 39 during the period. The
same general situation prevailed for nonmember banks. Banks with high ratios at the end
of 1965 varied widely in their changes from
December 1950, but generally, banks with
high ratios in December 1965 also had relatively high ratios at the end of 1950. The latter point can be verified by noting that the
banks with loan-to-deposit ratios of 70 and
up in December 1965 had total deposits of
$94 million in December 1950 and total loans
of $42 million, making an aggr gate ratio of
4.5 in 19.50. The banks with ratios of up to 40
at the end of 1965 had total deposits of $144
million at the end of 19.50 and total loans of
$37 million. Thus, their aggregate ratio in
1950 was only 26.
Rural banks with loan-to-deposit ratios of
up to 40 per cent in December 1965 had a
slower rate of growth in total deposits than
did any other group. For nonmember banks,
the rate of growth in total deposits tended to
increase directly with loan-to-deposit ratio,
while for member banks, the rate of deposit
growth was the highest for the group of banks
with loan-to-deposit ratios from 50-59. A comparison of all rural banks shows that total
deposits tended to grow with increase in loanto-deposit grouping until the 50-59 group was
reached and did not change significantly
beyond that point.
Comparing growth rates by loan-to-deposit
ratio grouping by type of deposit, illustrates
the general tendency for the growth rates of
member banks with both relatively low and
high ratios to be below average for demand
deposits, with the greatest rate of growth for
the intermediate-ratio range. Growth rates
for demand deposits for nonmember banks
did not vary significantly with change in ratio
grouping, except for the 70 and up group,
which showed a substantially greater rate of
Monthly Review

•

growth than did the other groupings. Growth
rates in time deposits from December 1950-65
tended to be positively correlated with loanto-deposit ratios at the end of 1965 for nonmember banks, but were erratic for member
banks. For deposits of various types of Government units and interbank deposits, growth
rates were relatively stable for banks in the
different ratio groupings.
Total loans of rural banks increased 180 per
cent and agricultural loans 177 per cent, as
compared with the 72 per cent increase in deposits. Agricultural loans accounted for 69 per
cent of the total loans outstanding at these
banks at the nd of 1965. Despite their relative importance at these banks, farm loans increased at approximately the same rate as total
loans. It also should be pointed out that farm
loan growth at these rural banks did not match
the 204 per cent increase in farm loans held
by all commercial banks in the United States.
This difference indicates that the portion of
the agricultural industry financed by the rural
banks relied increasingly on other banks and
other sources of credit for financing during
this period. Agriculture probably relied heavily on other banks b ecause of the slow rate of
deposit growth in rural banks and current
correspondent banking mechanisms, which
tend to funnel a substantial volume of funds
out of agricultural areas and return part or all
of them through such devices as participation
loans. Correspondent banks probably are returning a larger proportion of country bank
deposits in the form of overlines and purchase
of country bank notes today than 15 years ago.
In the case of both total loans and agricultural loans, there was substantial variability
among banks in the changes that occurred
from December 1950-65. Changes in total
loans varied from a -49 per cent to a + 889
per cent. Nine member and 36 nonmember
banks either had decreases or increases of 50
per cent or less, while 36 member and 37 nonmember banks had increases of 300 per cent

September-October 1966

7

The Changing Structure

Table 3
LOANS OF RURAL BANKS BY PER CENT CHANGE FROM 1950-65
Tenth Federal Reserve District
Member Banks
Dec.
Dec.

Nonmember Banks
Dec.
Dec .

Number

31
1950

31
1965

Per Cent
Change

9
26
51
46
29
34
36

6
23
41
35
17
22
18

7
38
92
97
56
84
92

16.6
65.2
124.3
177 .l
229.4
281.8
41 l. l

36
52
68
54
35
27
57

231

162

466

187.6

329

- - (Millions of dollars)

Num ber

31
1950

All Banks
Dec.
Dec .
Num31
31
Per Cent·
1965
Change
ber
1950
- - ( Millions of dollars)

31
1965

Per Cent
Change

16
24
28
25
13
10
16

20
42
62
67
43
36
83

25.0
75.0
121.4
168.0
230.7
260.0
418.7

45
78
119
100
64
61
93

21
46
68
59
31
32
34

27
80
154
164
99
120
175

28.5
73 .9
126.4
177.9
219.3
275.0
414.7

131

355

170.9

560

293

821

180.2

18.l
75.0
125 .0
178.5
218.1
240.0
408.3

48
100
108
80
70
48
106

18
39
44
33
25
18
28

22
69
99
88
80
66
144

22.2
76.9
125.0
166.6
220.0
266.6
414.2

166.3

560

205

568

177.0

- -(Millions of dollars)
Total

Up to 50

50-99
100-149
150-199
200-249
250-299
300 and up
Totol

Agricultural
Up to 50
50-99
100-149
150- 199
200-2 49
250-299
300 and up
Total

13
34
40
36
31
30
47

7
19
24
18
14
13
17

9
34
54
49
45
49
83

28.5
78.9
125.0
172.2
221.4
276.9
388.2

35
66
68
44
39
18
59

11
20

14
11
5
12

13
35
45
39
.35
17
61

231

113

323

185 .8

329

92

245

20

NOTE: Member and Nonmember Bank figu res may not odd to All Bonk figure because of rounding .

or more. It also is of interest to note that the
rise in dollar volume of total loans for the
banks having 50 per cent increases or less was
only $6 million, while for the banks with 300
per cent increases or more the growth in dollar
volume of total loans was $141 million.
Some interesting evaluations can be made
if the changing asset structure of rural banks
is observed by loan-to-deposit groupings. By
definition, loans should be relatively low in the
low-ratio grouping, and it also would be expected that loan growth from December
1950-65 would tend to be positively related to
loan-to-deposit groupings at the end of 1965.
This relationship did prevail throughout all
groupings for nonmember banks and for all
groupings of member banks, except for the 70
and up group. Loans in the 70 and up group
of member banks grew more slowly from December 1950-65-than loans in all other member
bank groupings, except the up to 40 group.
This slow growth is explained partly by the
relatively slow rate of growth in deposits at
this group of banks. Starting with a relatively
high loan-to-deposit ratio at the end of 1950
and being confronted with the slower-than-

8

average rate of growth in deposits, these banks
were unable to maintain a rate of growth in
loans comparable to that for most other
groupings.
The second most important asset held by the
rural banks was Government securities. An
inverse relationship with loan - to - deposit
grouping would be anticipated in change in
Government securities investment from 19506.5. This relationship did prevail for all ratio
groupings for both member and nonmember
banks. For all banks, the largest change-an
increase of 60.6 per cent-was in the up to 40
grouping, while the largest decrease-29 per
cent-was in the 70 and up grouping. Changes
in bank investments in Government securities
tend to reflect a difference in the degree of
conservatism and aggressiveness of bank management. Bank investment in Government
securities became routine during the World
War II period. Since the procedure for investing in these securities is well established
and such investments are considered as good
risks-particularly if held until maturity - a
number of banks have more funds invested in
Government securities than in loans.

of Rural Banking
Cash, balances with other banks, and cash
items in process of collection were ranked
third in importance as rural bank assets at the
end of 1965. These asset items are held to
service community needs or to obtain services
from city correspondents, and are largely nonearning assets. Consequently, the growth in
this category of assets would be expected to
be held to a minimum regardless of loan-todeposit ratio . The data in Table 4 indicate
that growth in this category of asset items
was relatively small during the 19.50-65 period
and fluctuated erra tically among ratio groupings for both mcmb r and nonmember banks .
Finally, rural banks had a ubstantial dollar
volume of their invcstm 'nts in obligations of
states and other political subdivisions. Because of changes in rates banks were permitted
to pay on time and savings deposits and tax
considerations, investment in this category of
assets increased rather sharply in recent years.
There did not appear to be any significant

variation in rate of growth in this category of
assets by loan-to-deposit ratio grouping or b y
member and nonmember banks. The average
rate of increase from 1950-65 was 240 per cent
for all banks with an average rate of increase
of 232 per cent for member banks and 253 per
cent for nonmember banks.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The preceding analysis emphasizes that
rural bank structure has changed substantially
during the past 15 years. It also indicates that
there was a high degree of variability in the
kinds and d egree of change from bank to
hank, with some of th rural banks showing
substantial d ecreases in the dollar volum of
assets in loans, while others showed hug increases. The average increase in dollar volume
of loans outstanding for the rural banks in the
Tenth District was 180 per cent.
The fact that total farm debt outstanding
increased 227 per cent from December 1950-

Table 4
MAJOR ASSETS OF RURAL BANKS BY LOAN/DEPOSIT RATIOS IN 1965
Tenth Federal Reserve District
Loan/Deposit
Rat ios
( Per Cent)
Up to 40
40-49
50-59
60-69
70 and up
Total
Up to 40
40-49
50-59
60-69
70 and up
Total
Up to 40
40-49
50-59
60-69
70 and up
Total

Cash, Balances with Other
Banks, and Cash Items
Total Loans
Dec . 3 1 Dec . 31 Per Cent
Dec. 3 1 Dec. 3 1 Per Cent
Change
~ 1965
~ ~ Change
(Millions of dollars)
(Millions of dollars)

Governments
Dec.3 1 Dec. 31 Per Cent
1 9 5 0 ~Change
(Millions of dollars)

States and Political
Subdivisions
Dec. 3 1 Dec. 31 Per Cent
1950 ~ Change
(Millions of dollars)

44
51
71
56
25

49
52
84
60
27

11.3
1.9
18.3
7.1
8.0

37
53
87
75
42

73
131
257
235
124

All Banks
97.2
147.1
195.4
213.3
195.2

66
77
109
79
31

106
101
133
75
22

60.6
31.1
22 .0
-5 .0
-29.0

6
7
12
8
4

19
29
36
30
11

216.6
314.2
200.0
275 .0
175.0

247

273

10.5

293

821

180.2

362

437

20.7

37

126

240.5

33
36
62
53
16

50
41
71

3
3
7
5
3

11
15
22
19
6

266.6
400.0
214.2
280.0
100.0

24
24
41
37
16

25
24
51
41
15

4 .1
0
24.3
10.8
-6.2

18
22
48
47
26

143

157

9.7

162

20
26
30
19
9

24
28
33
19
12

20.0
7 .6
10.0
0
33.3

18
30
39
27
16

104

116

11.5

131

Member Banks
39
116.6
172.7
60
146
204.l
221.2
151
70
169.2
466

187.6

Nonmember Banks
88 .8
34
71
136.6
184 .6
Ill
211.1
84
237.5
54
355

170.9

12

51.5
13.8
14.5
-16.9
-25 .0

199

218

9.5

22

73

231.8

34
41
47
27
15

55
59
62
31
10

61.7
43 .9
31.9
14.8
-33.3

2
3
5
3
1

8
14
14
11
6

300.0
366.6
180.0
266.6
500.0

163

218

33 .7

15

53

253.3

44

NOTE : Member and Nonmember Bank figures may not add to All Bonk figure because of rounding .

Monthly Review

•

September-October 1966

9

The Changing Structure of Rural Banking

65, while rural banks with loan-to-deposit
ratios of up to 40 per cent-more than one
sixth of the banks-increased their loans only
97 per cent may indicate either conservative
management or a relative lack of loan demand
for these banks. If the rural banks are plotted
by loan-to-deposit ratio by geographical area,
no particular pattern is detected. Rural banks
with high ratios and low ratios tend to be
mixed and frequently one or more of each are
found in the same town or rural community.
Since the low ratio banks tend to have relatively high investments in Government securities, the analysis suggests that a significant
number of rural bankers, for one reason or
another, prefer to retain a large investment in
Government securities. It also should be emphasized that large numbers of rural bankers
are making an intensive effort to adapt to the

10

changing structure both in the banking and
agricultural industries. These rural banks are
finding it increasingly difficult to adapt to the
dynamic economic situation that prevails and
are finding it necessary to innovate in their
efforts to serve their communities. To be able
to innovate within the prevailing institutional
environment frequently requires a high degree
of managerial ability and aggressiveness. To
maintain this type of managerial ability in a
large number of isolated, rural banks is a difficult bank-management task Many rural
banks have been able to meet the challenge
reasonably well, as indicated by the changes
that have just been evaluated. However, it appears that some rural banks are in need of additional managerial assistance if they are to do
the most effective job of adapting to prevailing
economic developments.

Measuring a Deficit or Surplus in the
U.S. Balance of International Payments
By Thomas E. Davis

THE

QUESTION of the best way to measure a
d ficit or surplus in the U. S. balance of
payments has been the object of considerable
discussion during recent years. Interest in this
question has been due to the importance attached to the concept of a deficit or surplus as
an indicator of our international economic position, and to the significant influence that the
large U. S. balance of payments deficits have
had on economic policy decisions since 1958.
Last year, after careful review and study,1 the
U. S. Government decided to place primary
emphasis on two measures of our balance of
payments performance-the "liquidity" balance and the balance on "official reserve
transactions." In view of this decision, it is
important when speaking of a deficit or surplus in the U. S. balance of payments to have
a clear understanding of the meaning, as well
as the limitations, of the particular concept
being used. To aid in this understanding, this
article examines some of the problems associated with measuring a deficit or surplus in
the balance of payments, and attempts to explain and compare the two concepts now

1 Review Committee for Balance of Payments Statistics,
The Balance of Payments Statistics of the United States
-A Review and Appraisal (Washington: U. S. Government P~inting O!fice, 1965), and U. S., Congress, Joint
Economic Committee, The Balance of Payments Statistics,
89th Cong ., 1st Sess., 1965.

Monthly Review

•

being used to measure the U. S. international
payments position.
PROBLEMS IN MEASURING
A DEFICIT OR SURPLUS

A major source of difficulty in measuring a
deficit or surplus in a country's balance of payments is that the balance of payments statement as a whole shows neither a deficit nor a
surplus. The method of double entry accounting used in compiling the balance of payments
statement implies-by definition-that total
debit, or payment, entries must equal total
credit, or receipt, entries. Therefore, to obtain
a deficit or surplus it is necessary to strike a
balance on certain selected transactions within
the accounts. In other words, all the transactions in a country's balance of payments
must be divided into two groups, with those
transactions believed to give rise to a deficit
or surplus placed in one group or "above the
line," and the remaining transactions thought
to be balancing, or settlement, items placed in
the second group or "below the line." With
all the transactions grouped in this manner, a deficit or surplus in the balance of payments is presumed to exist when the sum of
the items above the line shows either a negative or positive balance and, in turn, is presumed to be balanced or settled by the sum
of the transactions below the line.

September-October 1966

11

Measuring a Deficit or Surplus in the

Since a deficit or surplus in a country's balance of payments is determined on the basis of
selected transactions only, the crucial problem
is deciding which transactions should be selected. Quite clearly, the transfer of one category of transactions from a position above the
line to a position below the line, or vice versa,
could significantly alter the size and possibly
the nature of a deficit or surplus, even though
the underlying data in the accounts remain
the same. Unfortunately, this selection cannot
be made simply on the basis of the data alone
because the fi gures themselves never indicate
whether a particu1ar type of transaction
sho uld b e entered ahove or below the line.
Rather, the se1ection must depend upon an
analytical interpretation of the data and upon
an analysis of the relationships b etween the
transactions. Any such analysis, however, is
likely to vary with changing circumstances
and with the particular problem being analyzed. Therefore, to better understand why
certain transactions are selected to measure a
deficit or surplus it is necessary to know the
purpose for constructing such a measure.
Ideally, the purpose of determining a deficit or surplus in the balance of payments is to
meas ure the extent of any real disequilibrium
in a country's international economic position.
And yet, there is general agreement that no
measure of the balance of payments, however defined, can be relied upon for this purpose. Numerous adjustments of a qualitative
and quantitative nature would have to be
made to any such measure to take account of
the economic conditions and policies in that
country and abroad. For example, the relation between a country's level of employment
and the level of its imports and exports wou]d
need to be considered. A country may be importing less and exporting more, but at a cost
of experiencing a less-than-desired level of emp]oyment and economic growth. Consideration also would have to be given any special
controls or restraints imposed on a country's

12

international transactions tending to make
them appear more favorable, or possibly more
unfavorable, than they might otherwise be.
Also, any random or special short-run fluctuations that have occurred in the accounts which
do not of themselves reflect a lasting cha~ge
in the country's external position would have
to be sorted out. Only in this way can the international economic position of a country be
determined satisfactorily.
The difficulty in constructing such a measure has forced analysts to fall back on secondbest solutions, and thus it is not surprising
that differences have occurred in the selection
of transactions to b e inc1udcd as a measure of
a d eficit or surplus. Th most general approach to the problem, however, has been to
consider all international transactions as
either "autonomous" or "compensatory." Autonomous transactions are regarded as those
occurring independently of balance of payments considerations and are placed above the
line, while compensating transactions are regarded as those undertaken to finance, or settle, the sum of the autonomous transactions
and are placed below the line. Years ago,
und er the strict gold standard, it was a simple
matter to distinguish b etween autonomous and
compensatory transactions. All transactions
except gold movements were considered autonomous, and so a deficit or surplus was
measured by changes in a country's gold stock.
Today, the distinction between the two is less
precise because it is recognized that not only
are some international transactions settled by
capital flows as well as by gold flows, but that
some capital flows are autonomous while
others are compensatory. But deciding which
capital flows should be considered as compensatory, or balancing, transactions has presented a problem.
One approach to the problem has been to
focus on those transactions which respond to
long-run economic forces. This measure,
known as a balance on "basic" transactions,

U. S. Balance of International Payments
places above the line all transactions on goods,
services, transfer payments, and long-term
capital movements. All other transactions, including short-term capital movements and
changes in official holdings of international reserves, are placed below the line. The rationale
for this approach is that it provides a measure
of the underlying competitive economic relationships which a country must seek to balance
over time if it wishes to maintain equilibrium
in its external position. In spite of its apparent
simplicity, the analytical usefulness of the basic
balance has been questioned on the- grounds
that it is difficult to clearly distinguish transactions on the hasis of their sensitivity to
short-run or long-nm economic forces. For example, capital movements nominally classified
as long-term may, in fact, be of the short-term
variety, while capital movements classified as
short-term may be repeatedly renewed. Also,
certain types of short-term capital movements
are closely related to merchandise transactions
which they finance, so it cannot be said that
the two respond to different sets of economic
forces. Hence, it is felt that while the basic
balance concept might be a helpful partial
measure in the context of a broad analysis of
the balance of payments, it does not always
serve as a reliable summary indicator of a
country's current external position.
Another approach to the problem of how to
treat capital flows has been to place b elow
the line those transactions specifically undertaken by national monetary authorities to settle all other transactions arising in the balance
of payments. This approach, which was employed by the International Monetary Fund in
the early postwar years, is identified with the
balance on "official compensatory finance."
According to this approach, official financing
includes changes in a country's gold and official foreign exchange position, its net position
with the International Monetary Fund, and
government grants or loans made for balance
of payments reasons . In addition, changes in

Monthly Review

•

the foreign exchange holdings of a country's
commercial banks are included to the extent
that the authorities exercise control over these
holdings. The problem with this approach is
that when the principle of official compensatory financing is extended to various types of
capital flows , it involves the impossible task of
detecting the motive for capital flows from
the data alone. As a result, the practical application of this approach has met with great
difficulty.
The problems involved in treating capital
flows have been further complicated b y the
close association of deficit and surplus determination with economic policy considerations.
This association has increased in importance as
governments have adopted policies to protect
their domestic economies from fluctuations in
international economic activity, and have
agreed to maintain the external value of their
currencies at relatively fixed rates of exchange.
Consequently, governments have become
vitally interested in having a measure of their
countries' international transactions that can
serve as a guideline for their economic policies.
Such a measure, it is believed, should concentrate on the country's means of making international payments and, more specifically, on
the government's ability to maintain the external value of its currency. In constructing
such a measure, the problem is determining
which funds should be considered available for
this purpose. For most countries, however,
this does not present a particularly difficult
problem. Their official means of making international payments readily include their official holdings of gold and foreign exchange
and their net position with the International
Monetary Fund. In addition, to the extent
that the foreign exchange holdings of their
commercial banks are controlled by the government, any changes in these holdings also
are included.
For the United States, which is a reserve
currency country, special problems exist in de-

September-October 1966

13

Measuring a Deficit or Surplus in the

Table I
U. S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS, 1965
( In Millions of Dollars)
T ransoctions

Balance of
Payments
Receipts

Exports of goods and services-Total
Imports of goods and services--Total
Remittances and pensions

Payments

Type of Balance
Liquidity
Official Reserve
Basis
Transaction Basis
Balancing
Net
Balancing
Net
Balance
Items
Balance
Items

32,036
994

38,993
-32,036
-994

38,993
-32,036
-994

U.S. Government grants and capitol flow, net

3,375

-3,375

-3,375

U.S. private capitol flow, net:
Direct investment
Foreign securities
Other long-term claims
Short-term claims

3,371
758
322

-3,371
-758
-322
761

-3,371
-758
-322
761

429

-429

-429

443

71
-443

71
-443

97
451

451

38,993

761

Errors and unrecorded transactions
Foreibir;~~it~~:~f~e~t:
U. S. corporate securities
Other U. S. nonliquid liabilities:
~ ~~l~~e~fficial agencies
Liquid U. S. liabilities to all foreigners:
To foreign commercial banks
To other private foreigners
To fore ign official agencies

f

U. S. official reserve assets; increase ( - )
Totol

71
97
451

17

116
34
-17

41,745

1,222
1,355

116
34
1,222
41,745

97

-1,355

116
34

-1,302

-17
1,222
1,302

SOURCE: U. S. Department of Commerce.

termining a measure which can serve as a
guideline for its economic policies. As an international reserve currency, the U. S. dollar
is used widely throughout the world in settling transactions, not only between the United
States and the rest of the world but also between third-party countries. As a result, foreign official agencies hold U. S. dollars as part
of their international reserves and foreign private parties have accumulated a substantial
amount of U.S. dollars as a means of payment
in world trade. Moreover, as part of its obligation to the International Monetary Fund to
maintain the exchange rate of the dollar, the
United States stands ready to convert dollars
held by foreign official holders into gold for
legitimate monetary purposes. Therefore, it is
felt that in determining its international payments position the United States should not
only consider its holdings of gold and other
official international reserves but also should
14

take into account the large volume of outstanding foreign dollar claims that may be exercised
against these reserves. Which of these foreign
dollar claims, or U. S. dollar liabilities, should
be included as an offset to U. S. official reserves has been a matter of dispute. In recognition of the opposing views in this dispute,
the United States recently adopted two measures of its international payments positionthe "liquidity" balance, and the balance on
"official reserve transactions."

THE LIQUIDITY BALANCE
The liquidity balance measures a deficit or
surplus in the U. S. balance of payments by
any changes in U. S. official reserve assets and
in liquid U. S. liabilities to all foreigners
( Table I). U. S. official reserve assets are defined to include U. S. official holdings of gold
and convertible foreign exchange, plus the
U. S. net position with the International Mone-

U. S. Balance of International Payments
tary Fund. 2 Liquid U. S. liabilities include all
short-term liabilities to foreigners and international nonmonetary institutions reported by
U. S. banks, and all foreign holdings of marketable, and nonmarketable but convertible,
U. S. Government securities. All other trans-actions recorded in the U. S. balance of payments are entered above the line and presumed
to give rise to a change in the U. S. international liquidity position. Thus, according to the
liquidity balance, a deficit in the U. S. balance
of payments is measured by any decrease in
U. S. official reserve assets plus any increase
in U. S. liquid liabilities to foreigners. a
The rationale for the liquidity balance is that
it serves the needs of policymakers who have
the final responsibility for maintaining the exchange rate of the U. S. dollar. It does so, it is
felt, by focusing on the liquid resources available to the authorities to defend the dollar, as
measured by changes in U. S. official reserve
assets, and by spotlighting the liquid claims
which may be exercised against these reserves,
as measured by changes in U. S. liquid liabilities to all foreigners. Such a measure, it is
believed, provides the authorities with an indicator of their ability to maintain the external
value of the dollar and to determine whether
a given pattern of international transactions
can be sustained over the long run.
While it is generally agreed that the external liquidity of the United States is important in assessing the U. S. payments position, the liquidity measure has not been free
from criticism. A major objection to the

2

The U. S. net position with the International Monetary
Fund is measured by the U. S. "gold tranche" position.
This position represents virtually automatic U. S. drawing
rights from the Fund to the extent that the Fund's holdings of U. S. dollars are less than the U. S. quota.
3 A variant of the liquidity balance, called the balance
on "regular" transactions, appeared in official U. S. publications prior to 1965. This variant included below the
line those items presently carried by the liquidity balance,
plus any receipts from "special government transactions"
undertaken mainly to finance a deficit, such as advance
repayments on U. S. Government loans.

Monthly Review

•

September-October 1966

liquidity measure is its asymmetric treabnent
of short-term private capital flows. According to this measure, changes in U. S. liquid liabilities to private foreigners are placed below
the line, while changes in private U. S. capital
claims on foreigners are placed above the line.
This treatment is criticized because any inflow
of short-term private foreign capital tends to
worsen the U. S. liquidity position, but any inflow of short-term private U. S. capital does
not. The justification given for this treatment
is that U. S. liquid liabilities to private foreigners are considered a potential threat to the
U. S. gold stock because they are readily transferable to foreign official holders to whom the
United Statcs is obligated to sell gold upon demand. Private U. S. capital claims on foreigners, on the other hand, are placed above the
line because they are not considered readily
available to the U. S. authorities for use in defending the U. S. dollar in foreign exchange
markets. Only U. S. official reserves are regarded as available for this purpose. The
asymmetric treatment of private short-term
capital flows also is said to be justified because
it corresponds to the asymmetries of the real
world. Since the U. S. dollar serves as an international reserve currency throughout the
world, unlike currencies of most other countries, the United States is felt to have a special
obligation as banker to the world to weigh its
official reserve assets against all its liquid liabilities, both official and private.
The view of the liquidity concept that foreign private dollar claims should be put on the
same basis as foreign official claims has met
with further criticism. This view, it is argued,
gives inadequate recognition to the positive
motives causing private foreigners to acquire
dollar claims, and so underrates the advantages
and attractiveness of the U. S. money market
as a place for foreigners to invest liquid reserves and to hold working balances. It also is
thought that a sizable portion of private foreign claims are linked closely to liabilities
15

M easuring a Deficit or Surplus in the

that foreigners have incurred to U. S. residents,
and thus are essentially "locked into" dollars
and not likely to be withdrawn. A common
instance is when a U. S. bank lends money to
a private foreigner and requires that the foreigner place on deposit at the bank certain
compensatory balances-which in practice are
foreign private dollar claims not subject to
liquidation or withdrawal. Another instance
is when a U. S. resident places funds in a foreign bank, say a Canadian bank, and these
funds are then invested by the bank in liquid
assets in the United States. These liquid dollar
assets are not likely to be converted into
for ign currencies in view of the foreign
hank's outstanding liability to the U. S. r sidcnt. Hence, it is believed that the effect of
treating foreign private capital flows as different from U. S. private capital flows, or as
similar to foreign official capital flows, tends to
exaggerate the threat to the U. S. gold stock
and the deficit in the U. S. balance of payments.
Another objection to the liquidity approach
is that it lacks precision because liquidity is
a relative term. As such, any classification of
foreign held dollar assets based on their degree of liquidity is susceptible to change, depending upon changing circumstances and
changing points of view. In a larger sense,
moreover, all U. S. dollar assets held either by
foreigners or by U. S. residents, are in some
degree liquid to the extent they are freely
exchangeable into foreign currencies. In this
sense the liquidity approach may underestimate the potential drain on U. S. official reserves and so provide a misleading picture of
the ability of U. S. monetary authorities to
maintain the valt1e of the dollar.
THE BALANCE ON
OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS

According to the balance on official reserve
transactions, a deficit or surplus in the U. S.
balance of payments is measured by any
16

changes in U. S. official reserve assets and in
liquid and certain nonliquid U. S. liabilities
to foreign official agencies ( Table I). This
measure differs primarily from the liquidity
balance by excluding U. S. liquid liabilities to
foreign private holders and nonmonetary international organizations. A second difference, of
less importance, is that changes in certain nonliquid U. S. liabilities to foreign official
agencies are included in the official reserve
transactions balance, but not in the liquidity
balance. These nonliquid liabilities primarily
consist of nonmarketable, nonconvertible U. S.
Government securities held by foreign official
monetary institutions.
The hypothesis underlying this approach is
that the need for a summary indicator of the
balance of payments arises from the nature of
the present international monetary system in
which the final responsibility for maintaining
stable foreign exchange rates rests with national monetary authorities, i.e., central banks
and treasuries. In carrying out this responsibility, monetary authorities act to settle the
net deficits and surpluses that arise on all
other international transactions by gaining or
losing international reserve assets and by increasing or decreasing their liabilities to foreign monetary authorities. Therefore, the size
of a monetary authority's transactions in international reserves is thought to provide the
most useful measure of the market intervention necessary to maintain the exchange rate,
and, hence, of any balance of payments disequilibrium.
A comparison of this approach with the
liquidity approach , for the 6-year period 19606.5, shows that by either measure the United
States has incurred balance of payments "deficits" in every year ( Chart I). According to
the liquidity approach, however, the annual
deficit during these 6 years averaged $2,550
million, $490 million higher than the deficit
measured on the basis of official reserve transactions. The primary reason for this differ-

U. S. Balance of International Payments

Chart I
ALTERNATIVE MEASURES OF THE
U. S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS DEFICIT
( In Billions of Dollars)

Bi 11 ions of Doi Iors
5

Liquidity Basis
4

/

Official Reserve
/ Transactions Basis

3

1960

1961

1962

1963

1964

1965

ence is that the liquidity measure considers
any rise in U. S. liquid liabilities to private
foreigners, including foreign commercial
banks, as adding to the deficit. During this
period, U. S. liquid liabilities to foreign commercial banks alone averaged an increase of
$440 million and accounted for nearly all of
the average difference between the two measures. Thus, much of the debate between the
advocates of these two measures has been on
how to treat liquid liabilities to private
foreigners.
The rationale for not including U. S. liquid
liabilities to private foreigners in the official
transactions measure is that these liabilities
usually represent ordinary capital movements
and so should be treated like private U. S.
capital claims. This treatment, it is felt, recognizes the key distinction between transactions
of monetary authorities and private parties,
and also is consistent with the concept of a

Monthly Review

•

zero payments deficit since it takes into account the continued need for and the growth
of U. S. dollar claims by private foreigners.
Under the liquidity approach, however, which
considers an increase in liquid U. S. liabilities
to private foreigners as adding to the deficit,
the concept of a zero deficit is not consistent
with a rise in these liabilities unless simultaneously offset by a drop in U. S. official
reserves.
A fundamental criticism of the official transactions measure is that changes in foreign private dollar claims are related closely to central
bank policies and therefore should be treated
like reserve-type transactions. This especially
is true when a foreign c ntral hank either owns
the commercial banks in its country or is able
to control the commercial banks' holdings of
dollar claims through directives or exchange
controls. It also is true when private foreigners have been induced by official exchange
operations to alter the size of their dollar holdings. Such operations, mainly in the forward
exchange market, frequently are conducted
today by official agencies as part of the techniques of international financial cooperation,
and, additionally, as part of th e domestic monetary policies of foreign monetary authorities.
For instance, a foreign central bank may induce its commercial banks to hold liquid dollar assets by agreeing to exchange local currency for dollars at some future date and at a
more favorable rate than is available in the
market. Since the effect of these operations is
to shift dollar balances from foreign monetary institutions to foreign commercial banks,
or vice versa, they tend to blur the distinction
between these foreign dollar claims. Thus,
it is argued that when these operations cause
large short-run variations in foreign official
and private dollar claims it is possible to misinterpret the U. S. payments position viewed
according to tne official transactions measure.
The liquidity measure, it is pointed out, is not
similarly affected by such variations because

September-October 1966

17

Measuring a Deficit or Surplus in the U. S. Balance of International Payments

it places changes in all liquid foreign dollar
claims below the line.
Advocates of the official transactions measure readily acknowledge that short-run
changes in foreign private dollar claims often
are related closely to policy actions taken by
national monetary authorities. However, they
maintain that these changes, whether induced
by official exchange operations or by changing credit conditions, serve to underscore the
market responsiveness of what is essentially
private capital. Moreover, they believe that
these short-run changes in foreign dollar claims
are not dominant enough to justify placing
them below th line, even though occasional
distortions in the data may require special
analysis and explanation. They further maintain that even though national monetary authorities may influence foreign private dollar
claims in the short run, they cannot do so in
the long run. In support of this view, they cite
the large buildup of foreign private dollar
claims over the past 7 years, which is presumed to represent a genuine inflow of private
capital related to the investment or financing
needs of foreigners. For these reasons, the balance on official reserve transactions is thought
by some observers to provide the most useful
measure of the long-run market forces affecting the U. S. international payments position.

pending upon the problem being analyzed
and upon the interpretation given to the underlying data. Also, as indicated earlier, a useful
analysis of a country's international position
rarely is possible on the basis of balance of
payments data alone; domestic economic conditions and policy objectives both in the
country and abroad have to be taken into account. For the United States, the problem is
particularly difficult because of the key currency status of the U. S. dollar in international
trade and finance, and the diversity of U. S.
transactions with the rest of the world. Indeed, it was du largely to these difficulties
that the United States decided to adopt two
measures of its balance of payments performance. Neither of these measures, however, can
be said to be unequivocally superior to the
other in revealing whether the United States
is experiencing a fundamental disequilibrium
in its international payments position. The
value in having two measures, therefore, is that
they may further public understanding of the
complex nature of the balance of payments,
and also encourage people not to evaluate the
U. S. payments position on the basis of a single
concept-a deficit or surplus.

'FOREIGN TRADE AND
AMERICAN AGRICULTURE"

WHICH IS THE BEST MEASURE?
In view of the variety of concepts employed
to measure a country's balance of payments,
and the various arguments presented regarding the two current measures of the U. S. balance of payments, the inevitable question
arises as to which measure is best. The answer
is simply that there is no one best measure to
describe a country's international payments
position, any more than there is one best measure to describe the financial position of a government, bank, or corporation. Any one
measure may be misleading or revealing de-

18

A special booklet, "Foreign Trade and
American Agriculture," has been issued recently by the Research Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. The
booklet provides a historical perspective of
international agricultural trade, reviews the
current status of this trade, and discusses the
agricultural implications of current international trade negotiations. Copies may be obtained on request to the Research Deparhnent,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas
City, Missouri 64106.