View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November-December

1962

ON!· LY REVIEW
KANS .

The Changing Shape
of World Trade . . . . .

page

American Agriculture and the
European Common Market

page 10

Current Statistics

page 16

. .

. . .

3

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF KANSAS EITY

S11hscriptio11s to th e IvJo TllLY R1-:vrnw ar available t o the public 1citl10ut charge. Additional
copies of anu issue may be obtained from the
Resea rch Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Kansas City 6, Missouri. Permission
is granted to reproduce any material in this
publication.

THE CHANGING SHAPE
OF WORLD TRADE

T

he passage of the Trade Expansion Act of
1962 has been hailed as a historic step forward in promoting the liberalization of international trade. Th re is littl d ubt that the
new tra<l bill doc rcpr s nt a signilkant departure from the past in term of th wide latitude it confer upon the x utivc branch f
th Government to deal with the initi ation
and/ or modification of international agreements. It i exceedingly important to note as
well, that its passage was, in no small measure,
a response to a metamorphosis in the world
trade structure. It is in connection with these
developmental changes in world trade over the
past few decades that the primary attention of
thi s article is focused.
THE BACKGROUND

Within recent year , a new dimension ha
be n added to the tructure of world trade. Thi
phenom enon- described as economic regionalism- is manifested by the development of di tinctly regional economic trading blocs. A consequence of this is the increased emphasis
which has been focused upon the bloc as the
vehicle through which the trading policies of
the individual countries are harmonized. This
new dimension has been superimposed upon
the clas ic pattern of multilateral trade betwc n individual nation as envisaged by the
Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934, and
th e 194 7 General Agreem nt on Tariffs and
Trade. Table 1 idcntifie the major regional
tradin g entities in order of their e tablishment
and compares their re pective areas and popuMonthly Review •

November-December 1962

lation with those of the United States so that
some idea may be grasped as to their relative
magnitudes.
The best kn wn tradin g blo is th e uropcan
: onomi
ommunity, kn ow n as th e Europ an
Common Markel. 'I he rapid 1 rowth a nd apparent , ucc s · f th ' Common Mark t has had
a prof und cfTect on the re structuring of foreign trade relationships and ha resulted in the
pawning of a number of other regional groupings, such as the European Free Trade Association and the Latin American Free Trade
Association. In addition, the Eastern European
Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, or
Comecon as it is commonly known, is the
Communi t regional counterpart designed to
promote economic coop ration among Soviet
ate llitcs. Thu , the idea of regional trading
Table 1

MAJOR ECONOMIC TRADING UNITS
1959
Population
(In Millions)
European Economic Community*
European
Free Trade Association**
Latin American
Free Trade Associationt
Total
United Statestt

Area
(Thousands
of Sq. Miles)

167.5

457.7

89.0

493.1

158.3
414.8
179.2

10,374.6
11,325.4
3,615.2

* Includes Belgium , France, Italy , Luxembourg , the Netherlands ,
and West Germany ; exclude s European and overseas associated
co untr ies and territories .
** In cludes Au stria , Britain , Denmark, Norway , Portugal , Sweden,
and Switzerland.
tlncludes Argentina , Brazil , Ch i le , Colombia , Ecuador, Mexico ,
Paraguay , Peru , and Uruguay .
tt lncludes Alaska and Hawaii.
SOURCE : European Economic Community , European Free Trade Assoc iat ion, and U. S. figures are from Benoit 's Europe at Sixes and
Sevens ; Latin American Free Trade Association f igures are from

U. N. Statistical Yearbook, 1960.

3

The Changing Shape

groups is peculiar neither to the Free World
nor to Europe alone.
However, while the Latin American Free
Trade Association is a unique cooperative venture for that area, the apparently recent growth
of regionali m in urope may be traced back
to the period shortly after the clo e of World
War 11. Probably the arlic t tep in th e direction of economic cooperation occurr d in 1921
when a cu toms union was formed between
Belgium and Luxembourg.
The groundwork for eventual E uropean economic integration wa laid in mid- 1947 with
the United tat , offer o f Marsha11 Plan aid
to l"'. uropc conditiona l upon the undertakin g o f
a cooperative fTort o n th part of the ◄ uro­
pcan coun tries to es tabli sh an effcctiv re ovcry
program. In July 194 7, I 6 countries of W stern
E urope e tabli shcd a ommittec for European
ooperation, resulting in the establi hment of
the Orga nization for European Economic Cooperation (OEEC) on April 16, 1948. 1 Earlier
in that year an event took place which wa to
portend the shape of thin gs to come in Europe.
This was the expansion of the Belgium-Luxembourg customs union to include the Netherlands
in the formation r Benelux.
wa. in r Since the r rmation f O
spon c to prop d U. . aid in th e r construction of the West urop an conomy, one
of the immediate co ncerns of that organization was the fo rmul ation of plans which would
enable participating countries to utili ze uch
aid and assistance effectively. In addition to
this, attention was directed by that body to
such problems as combating the "dollar shortage" existing at that time, promoting increa ed
intra-European and external trade through the

lt originally included Au tria, Bel giu m , Denmark,
ire . France, reece, lceland , Ital y, Luxembourg, the
etherlands. Norway, Portugal, weden, witzerland ,
Turkey. and the nited Kin gdo m . We t Germany wa
added shortly thereafter a nd in Jul y of 1959, Spain
became a full member.
1

4

liberali zation or elimination of quantitative rctri ctions, achieving method for increasing productivity of Europea n industry, and additionally, formulating procedure for th e eventual
economic unification of We tern E urope.
Althou gh it wa th e hope of th e O E
to
create a free trade area whi ch would encompa ss th e whole of West rn uropc, thi wa
not to be realized. While the O E
did
achieve some degree of uccess in eliminating
quantitativ restrictions on trade, it proved to
be ineffective in combating tariff . For this
and other rea o ns, ome countrie the refore
fcit that a m re far-reachin g a pproach to integration was nc dcd . Th first step in April
195 I , was th e signin g of a treaty establishing
th ' E ur p an
oa t and Steel
mmunity
( CS ) . Known as th
chum an Pl an, it
became ope rational in August 1952. lts membe rs included West Germany, France, Italy,
and the Benelux group . The effect of the plan
was to establish a common market in coal,
iron, and associated products which was totally free of all impediments to free movement
of such products within the market area. It
wa from the initi al success of this cooperative venture that the more ambitious cheme
for a n expanded comm n market a rrange ment
stemmed.
By 1955, the advantag of the European
Coal and Steel ommunity were evident to
its members, and accordingly, they gave serio us consideration to forming a larger customs
union along th e lines of the ECSC. This decision by the six ECSC members to go it alone
prompted an investigation within the OEEC of
the possibilities of a multilateral association
with the proposed common mark t and the regroup. Their findings
mainder of th e O
indicated that uch a relation hip with the
Six wo uld be technically po siblc and economically advantageou . Negotiation among the
Six culmin ated in the acceptance of th a rticle of the Trea ty of Rome on March 25, 1957,
and le s than a y ar later , on January 1, 195 8,

of World Trade

the European Economic Community (EEC)
came into being. In response, some OEEC
countries actively pursued the establishment of
a free trade area which, under the original
plan, would have comprised all OE C countries including those of the Common Market.
By the latter part of 195 8, negotiations along
these lines had ended in disappointment. The
implementation of the Treaty of Rome began on January 1, J 959, with the first tariff
reductions within the European Economic
Community. Within several months, at the invitation of Sweden , six other nations-Austria , D nmark , witze rland , Portuga l, Norway,
and th United Kingdom- met to furth e r the
stablishm ·nt of a free tr~1d area whi ·h it was
h p d would a ·t as a p·1 rallel r rec t the
E
By the close f 1959, the
uropean
Free Trade Association ( FTA) had become
a reality and the new economic regionalism was
represented on the Continent by the Six of
the Common Market and the Seven of the
European Free Trade Association .
It is important at this juncture to distinguish
between the two terms "free trade area" and
"customs union." In essence, a customs union
is an arrangement among the participating
countries whereby all internal barriers to trade
among member arc dispen sed with and a common economi policy with respect to external
trade is c tablished. Benelux was an example
of uch a customs union even before the Common Market was a reality . The European Economic Community is an example of such a
classic customs union with its ultimate external tariff for the most part being an unweighted
arithmetic mean of the former tariffs of the
individual members. However, the founders of
the
aimed at more than a cu tom union ;
they de ired the subordin ation of the individual nation' monetary and fi cal policies, domestic political considerations , and agricu ltu ral
a nd transport policie in favor of an integrated
approach for the entire union. Thus, the Common Market not only involves economic inteMonthly Review •

November-December 1962

gration, but also contemplates a large measure
of political unification.
In contra t with the customs union approach
to the European Economic Community, the
European Free Trade Association pur ued less
extensive goa ls. Within this free trade area,
al l barriers to internal trade were to be remov d , and in this respect there was no differt.:nce between the "customs union " approach
of the Common Market and the "free trade
area" approach. However, several important
differences did distinguish the Jatter from the
form r. The free trade area would not be
characterized by a common ex ternal ta rifT, this
bei ng left to the discretion of each country,
and no extensive attempt would be made to
harmoni ze agricultural, transp rt , fis al , monetary , or any oth r i sue of dome ·tic policy
among the participants. All in all, the objectives of the European Free Trade Association
were quite modest in contrast with those of
the European Economic Community. The aims
of the former were simply to liberalize trade
among the members while a11owing almost
complete autonomy in the conduct of domestic
and international economic affairs. In the
latter case, a more extensive economic and
political integration was sought with the eventual end being some form of supra-national
organization.
rt was this clear-cut di tinction between the
two schools of thought in the economic rebirth of Western Europe which preordained
the outcome of the efforts to establish a free
trade area for the whole of Western Europe.
However, in a short time the success of the
Common Market would cause a reassessment
on the part of Britain, the leader of the EFTA.
On July 31, 1961, scarcely more than a year
after the European Free Trade A oc1at1on
convention had been ratified by the member
nations, Great Britain made public it decision
to apply for full member hip in the European
conomic Community. Although this issue is
not yet resolved, the United Kingdom could

5

The Changing Shape

become the seventh member of the European
Commu nity. The fate of the EFTA in that
event is conjectural; the loss of Great Britain
would undoubtedly diminish its strength. Once
the question of British membership has been
resolved, the answers to this and other questions may be clarified .
WORLD TRADE OVER TIME

In 1938, the volume of world exports was
eq ual to $23.5 billion; by 1948 the level of
exports stood at $57 .3 billion; at the close of
1961 thi s figure exceeded $133 billion. This
wa s a n absol ute increas in excess of $100
billion and a percentage gai n of more th an
450 per cent in less than 25 years . Although
th e trade ligures a rc not meas ured in constant
clo!Jars, the growth of world trade during the
period is substantial , even after allowances
have been made for world-wide price inflation. However, the gains in the volume of
trade have not been distributed equally among
the trading nations and while some have fared
well both in an absolute and a relative sense,
others have not.
Table 2 shows the percentage of world exports accounted for by the developed and the
so-called unde rd eveloped areas for th e period
1938 through 1960. It can be seen that the
developed areas have managed not only to retain their traditional export share over this
period, but have increased this share slightly
- from about 65 per cent in 1938 to 67 per
cent in 1960. As for the underdeveloped areas,
the picture is not quite so bright. Beginning
in 1938 with 25 per cent of world exports,
this group increased its share to nearly 30 per
cent in 1948, but from then to 1960 its share
has steadily declined , reaching little more than
21 pe r cent in 1960. The fact that this downward trend in export shares wa s in ev idence
before the European Economic Community or
the European Free Trade Association had
come into existence indicates that at least
through 1958, these developments ought not to
6

Table 2
WORLD EXPORT SHARES BY BROAD AREA
CLASSIFICATION
(Per Cent of World Trade)

1938
1948
1949 and 1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960

Developed
Areas*
64.7
63.7

Underdeveloped
Areas**
25.1
29.8

63.1
65.1
64.8
64.1
64.5
66.1
67.0
65.7
65.3
66.9

29.3
26.1
25.6
25.9
25.5
24.2
22.9
23.0
22.4
21.4

t

t

--

* United States , Canada, Western Europe, Japan , Australia , New
Zealand , and South Afri ca.
• 'Total of regions other than Developed Area s and Eastern Europe
and China (mainland ).
t Data for 1949 and 1950 are not comparable as they exclude trade
with the Soviet Union and other Communist nat ions .
SOURCE : U. N. Statistical Yearbook, 1961 .

be blamed for the poor performance of the
underdeveloped areas. Rather, a combination
of factors such as changes in the demand pattern for products of these areas, and an increase in the avenues of supply for these items,
which have resulted in a secular decline in
their market prices, might more logically be
held respon sible for the group's relative decline.
Both the Latin American Republics and the
newly merging African states, as well as others, are includ d among the underdeveloped
areas. However, an interesting pattern has
emerged in th e respective trading structures of
the two groups of nations in response to structural changes elsewhere. A large number of
the African states are presently "overseas associates" of the European Economic Community and thus will receive preferential treatment on their exports to that market. Consequently there has been Jess motivation for development of a regional trading bloc on that
continent, although some regional groupings
are emerging, or are in prospect. On the other
hand , negotiations among the Latin American
R epublics led to the formation of the Latin
American Free Trade Association early in

of World Trade

1960. This move logically can be interpreted
as an attempt to achieve a more rational pattern of industrial development by providing
access to a wider but stiJI protected market,
as well as an attempt to set up a countervailing force in future negotiations with the European Economic Community. Whether it will
serve to improve their position remains to be
seen.
If the distribution of world export shares in
Table 2 is broken down, as in Table 3, to show
the percentage of world exports accounted for
by the major trading nation or regions, several
intere ting a pects of the changing trade patterns may be seen . Although the total volume
of world trade ha s in reased nsid rably ince
1938, int r stingly nough the percentage di tribution of world export shares in 1961 showed
that only the two major trading nations,
the United States and Canada, and the countries of the EEC, have managed to record
gains in their respective positions during this
period. However, for both the United States
and Canada the high-water mark in export
shares was reached a number of years ago.
While both countries exceeded their prewar

shares in 1961, they have been experiencing
a decline in their respective positions for almost a decade. At the close of 1961, the Latin
American Republics, Japan, and the AustraliaNew Zealand-South Africa group still had not
regained their prewar share of world exports.
As a matter of fact, the trend of export hares
for the period is decidedly downward for all
of the group except Japan, which alone show
promise of regaining its former share of the
world market if the upward trend for Japanese exports continues. Great Britain's decision
to apply for membership in the European Economic ommunity implies an end to the pref rr d treatment for Au tralian and N w Zealand xports, a d velopment which can only
erve to accelerate the downward trend in their
world export shares.
Referring again to Table 3, an interesting
feature becomes apparent with respect to the
relative export shares positions of the EEC and
EFT A groups. Although Western Europe had
slightly increased its share of world exports in
1%1 relative to 1938, the distribution of the
trade gains among the countries constituting
the present EEC and EFT A blocs was far from

Table 3

Gains in World Exports Have Not Been Shared Equally By the Maior Traders
World Trade Exports In MIiiion s of Dollars f . o. b. (Bold Face Type)
Respective Shares of World Trade in Per Cent (Light Face Type )
1938
World*
United States
of America
Canada

1948

;23,500 57,300
3,064 12,545
13.0
21.9
3,109
865
3.7
5.4
European Economic
4,360
6,500
Community
18.6
11.3
European Free
4,150
9,560
Trade Association
17.7
16.7
Latin American
1,710
6,520
Republics
7.3
11.4
Japan
1, 109*
258
4.7
0.5
Australia, New Zealand,
890
2,650
South Africat
3.8
4.6
Western Europe
9,240 17,780
39 .3
31.0

1951

1952

1953

1954

1955

1956

1957

1958

1959

1960

1961

82,400
14,888
18.1
3,750
4.6
13,790
16.7
12,230
14.8
7,790
9.5
1,355
1.6
3,470
4.2
28,230
34 .3

80,000
15,054
18.8
4,434
5.5
13,770
17.2
12,010
15.0
7,050
8.8
1,273
1.6
3,030
3.8
28,800
35.0

82,000
15,661
19.1
4,220
5.2
14,090
17.2
12,000
14.6
7,620
9.3
1,275
1.6
3,360
4.1
28,210
34 .4

85,500
14,986
17 .5
4,034
4.7
15,780
18.5
12,640
14.8
7,880
9.2
1,629
1.9
3,160
3.7
30,660
35 .9

93 ,1 00
15,430
16.6
4,386
4.7
18,370
19.7
13,760
14.8
7,960
8.6
2,011
2.2
3,400
3.7
34,470
37 .0

103,100
18,947
18.4
4,916
4.8
20,070
19.5
15,220
14.8
8,640
8.4
2,501
2.4
3,690
3.6
37,680
36 .6

111,100
20,682
18.6
5,094
4.6
22,470
20.2
16,1 90
14.6
8,650
7.8
2,858
2.6
4,090
3.7
41,340
37 .2

107,300

115,100
17,448
15.2
5,536
4.8
25,230
21.9
16,680
14.5
8,310
7.2
3,456
3.0
3,910
3.4
44,700
38 .8

127,500
20,325
15.9
5,563
4.4
29,730
23 .3
18,210
14.3
8,590
6.7
4,055
3.2
3,910
3.1
51,230
40 .2

113,040
20,670
15.5
5,790
4 .4
32,330
24.3
19,090
14.4
8,550
6.4
4,320
3.3
4,240
3.2
54,880
41.3

17,732
16.5
5,045
4.7
22,770
21.2
15,760
14.7
8,190
7.6
2,877
2.7
3,340
3.1
41,130
38 .3

*Excluding trade of China (Mainland ), Mongolia, North Korea , and North Vietnam with each other.
**Although Korea and China (Taiwan) were part of Japan's customs area in 1938, the figures here shown have been adjusted to include the
intertrade among the three areas .
t Flgures for all periods have been adjusted to approximate trade of present customs area.
NOTE: EEC treaty effective January 1, 1958; EFTA convention ratified in 1960.
SOURCE: 1961 figures from U. N. Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, June 1962; all others from U. N. Statistical Yearbook , 1961.

Monthly Review •

November-December 1962

7

The Changing Shape

equal. While the EEC countries were increasing their share of the expo rt trade from 18.6
per cent in 1938 to more than 24 per cent in
1961, those co untries in the EFTA saw their
share of world exports decline from less than
18 per cent in 1938 to little more than 14
per cent at the close of 1961. Furthermore,
while the figu res in Table 3 indicate vigorous
growth for th e EEC n ations, a lmost the e ntire
decade of the I 950's is characterized by a
relative decline in the world markets for the
EFTA group.
A further example of the dynamism of the
EEC in contrast with the EFTA nations i in
terms of the abso lu te difference in their respective shares f world ex ports for th e p riod .
In 193 8, the I E ' group of co untri es recorded
$2 10 million more in world exp rts th an did
their FT A cou nterparts; in 1948, however,
the sca les had shifted in favor of the EFTA
group by more than $3 billion. The shift was
temporary, however, and could be attributed
to the wartime destruction of the physical plant
on the Continent as well as the attendant political turmoil. This was clearly evidenced by
the figures for th e period 1951 through 1961.
For example, in 1951, EEC countries recorded
$ 1,560 million more in the volume of exports than did the EFTA. This marked the
beginning of an unbroke n trend of eve r-widening absolute margins between the two groups,
climaxed in 1961 by an excess of EEC exports
of more th an $13 billion over EFT A shipments. A large portion of this increased EEC
trade undoubtedly represents a stepping up of
intra-EEC trade at the expense of traditional
external markets as a result of the lowering
of internal trade barriers.
While these " trade diversion" effects of the
Common M arket should not be overlooked,
it shou ld also be poin ted out that the freeing
of trade within th e Common M arket area must
have also resulted in a considerable amount
of " trade creation." For example, stati stics
published by the United Nations show that the

8

U. S. share of exports going to the EEC increased from 13.5 per cent in 1959 to nearly
17 per cent in 1960, and again rose to more
than 17 per cent in 196 l. :! However, it should
also be noted th at during this same period
Western E urope was undergoing a strong cyclical expansion which resulted in an increased
demand fo r U.S. exports of capital goods.
While it is generally recognized th at a shrinking share of world exports is con sidered undesirable, th e seriousness of such a situation
varies with respect to th e relative importance
which foreign trade assum es in the process of
incom e creation for a ny particul ar co untry . An
approximate meas ure of c hanges in th e relati ve
impo rtance o f fo reign trade as a nati o nal in·omc-producing activ ity is th e per cnta 1 c which
exports a rc o f gross na tional product ove r tim e
for each coun try. Table 4 provid s this info rmati on for selected co untries, including all
th ose within the EEC.
For most of th e last decade, exports were
from 10 per cent to more than 35 per cent
of the GNP of the variou s countries comprising the Co mmon Market. Furthermore, in
most instances for these same countries, exports a re an increasing proportion of the total
nation al income over tim e. In th e case of
Japan, ex po rts as a perce ntage of GNP have
been ri sing almost tead ily since 1953 and were
equ al to more th an IO per cent of total income
from J 956 throu gh 1960. In the case of the
United Kin gdom , Canada, and the United
States , however, the role of exports as an income producer has diminished over the past
decade. Since the ratio of exports to GNP for
both the United Kingdom and Canada is more
than three times as great as that of the United
States, their declining role in world markets
has a greate r impact on th eir respective economics than is the case for th e United States.
However, the fact that ex ports are little more
:!See Uni ted Natio ns S tatistical Y earbook, 1961 ; see
also U . N . Monthly Bulletin of S tatistics. June 1962.

of World Trade

Table 4

EXPORTS AS A PER CENT OF GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
1948
4.9
20.6
22.0

United States
Canada
Belgium-Luxembourg
France
Germany (Federal
Republic)
Italy
Netherlands
United Kingdom
Japan

n.a.
n.a.

7.7
17.9
13.8
n.a.

1951
4.5
18.7
31.6
11.6

1952
4.4
17.9
27.4
9.3

1953
4.3
16.5
24.9
8.8

1954
4.1
15.8
24.2
9.2

1955
3.9
16.0
27.7
10.1

1956
4.5
15.7
29.2
8.4

1957
4.7
15.3
27.7
8.9

1958
4.0
14.8
26.6
9.0

1959
3.6
14.8
27.7
10.7

1960
4.0
15.5
29.7
11.8

1961
4.0

12.3
10.1
34.1
18.4
9.6

12.4
8.0
35.2
17.2
7.8

12.7
8.0
33.7
15.7
6.7

14.1
8.1
33 .9
15.3
8.0

14.5
8.4
33.7
15.6
8.9

15.7
9.0
33.4
15.8
10.0

16.9
10.0
33.3
15.6
10.2

16.1
9.4
34.0
14.5
10.4

16.5
9.9
35.5
14.5
10.4

17.2
11.4
35.9
14.1
10.4

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

n.a. not available
SOURCE : GNP f i gures f ro m U. N. Yearbook of National Account Stat istics, 1961 ; export fi gures fr om U. N. Yearbook of International Trade
Statistics, 1959, Vol. 1.

tha n 4 per cent of U . S. income does not mean
th at th e impli ca ti ons o f a shrinking Ame ri ca n
sha re o f wo rld ma rk ets arc not serious. T hese
implicati o ns fo r th e domestic eco nomy dese rve furth r investi gation, b ut it is suffic ient
to no te here th at th e passage of the T rade E xpansion Act o f 19 62 was predicated, to a substantial degree, upon an immedi ate and serious concern over America's declining relative
position in world trade.
CONCLUSIONS

The economic justification for trade and
exch ange among ind ividu als rests upon the
opportunities which such trade afford s those
pa rti es wh o volun ta ril y engage in trading activiti e to inc rease th eir level o f sati fac ti on or
utility. Thi s applies qu ally well to trade between regions or states within a single country,
or to trade between diffe rent nations. Therefore , the fewer the impediments to trade and
exchange, the more easily individuals or nations may enjoy the gains attendant to these
activities.
The development of the various regional
trading blocs di scussed in this article was

Monthly Review •

November-December 1962

characte ri zed by one ex tremely desirable effect.
In eve ry instance, th e estab li shment of these
r gio nal tra din g units res ulted in th gradu a l
eliminati on o r redu cti on o f th e ba rri e rs to t rade
within th eir bo und a ri es, the reby fac ilita ting
trade among th e peopl es within that bloc.
However , th e possibility does ex ist th at these
same groups, which h ave on the one h and freed
trade intern ally, may restrict trade with external markets in an effort to expand their domestic industries and insul ate them from the
forces of worldwide competition. If thi s should
happen, then some o f th e tangible gains from
trad e m ay be largely vitiated and th e result
will be a Jess th an opti mal allocation of th e
wo rld 's economi c reso urces. A lthough the
da nger whi ch is inhe rent in such " trade diversion" is a rea l one, th e re is equ al justi fica ti on
for assumin g th at th e new structure o f world
trade will , in th e Jong run , result in increased
trade among economically stronger , well-defined region al trading blocs, thus affording to
those individuals and nations the gains resulting
from increased interregional as well as international trade. Only th e future can indicate
which of these possibilities will m aterialize.

9

American Agriculture and the
European Common Market

I

AN INDUSTRY as dynamic as American
agriculture, longer-run developments frequently are important in evaluating the current
situation. The adjustment problem confronting
farmers in this Nation is primarily the result of
technological advancement that has cau ed produ ctivity of resources to increa e more rapidly
than demand for farm products. Under these
conditions, it is necessa ry to have consid rablc
mobility of reso urces in the domestic economy
or to in rease demand for farm product if
serious adjustment problems are to be avoided.
Even though much research and educational
work has been done on the problem of shifting resources within the economy, they have
not shifted rapidly enough to prevent serious
difficulties. At the same time, efforts have been
made to expand the demand for farm products.
Two approaches which have been taken include: ( 1) attempts to expand domestic demand for farm products by finding new u es
for them and by ex panding per capita consumption, and (2) efforts to expand export demand
for farm products. There are limitations to the
achievements that can be attained by either of
these approaches. This article will discuss agricultural exports briefly, evaluate some implications of the development of the European
Common Market on the potential export demand for farm products produced in the United
States, and point out th e major provisions contain ed in the Trade Expansion Act of 1962.
N

AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS

During the past 2 years , approximately 15
per cent of all cash receipts from farm marketin gs in the United States has come from ex-

10

ports. Although a con iderable proportion of
these exports was old for dollars, a sub tantial quantity was moved under Public Law 480
and by other special Government program .
Measured in physical terms, movement during
the p ast 2 year ha been at record-high levels.
ince there i a fo d shortage in most areas of
th e world , it is sugges ted frequently that th e
outlook for a continued growth in export d mand for Am rican farm products is unu ualIy favorable. Such foreca ts often ignor both
potenti al and actual difficulties .
Although many underdeveloped nations have
a great need for food and fiber, they frequently lack purchasing power to obtain farm products for dollars. The United States has attempted to overcome this difficulty through programs
in which effective prices are reduced by export
payments and in which surplus food and fiber
are moved into foreign markets for local currcncie , by gift, and by barter. Although such
programs can serve a u eful purpose both for
the United States and for recipient nations,
certain difficulties must be recognized. First,
unless uch programs are handled with extreme
care, they are likely to be viewed by other
countries as "dumping." Second, they are costly and, therefore, dependent on the continued
appropriation of relatively large sums of money.
Only to the extent that such programs are carefully planned for long-range development in
which future economic demand is created can
they be viewed as providing permanent markets.
1n the fiscal year July 1, 1961-June 30,
1962, the United States exported $5 .1 billion
worth of agricultural products . Major markets

American Agriculture and the European Common Market

EXPORTS TAKE BIG PART OF U.S. FARM OUTPUT
Export Share of Total
Production
Fiscal Year

Exports
Fiscal Year

1954-60
Commodity

Unit

Wheat*
Dried edible peas
Rice (milled basis)
Hops
Tallow
Nonfat dry milk
Cotton
Soybeans**
Dried prunes
Tobacco (farm sales weight)
Raisins
Rye, grain
Barley, grain
Cottonseedt
Grain sorghums
Dried whole milk
Lard
Corn
Dry edible beans
Flaxseed

*

1954-60

Average
Millions

391.6
1.2
15.2
14.9
1,229.6
521.3
4.6
139.9
91.1
548.6
93.6
5.4
73.4
1.4
54.4
39.2
522.9
149.4
2.6
6.7

bu
cwt
cwt
lb
lb
lb
bale
bu
lb
lb
lb
bu
bu
ton
bu
lb
lb
bu
cwt
bu

1960-61

1961-62

Millions

Millions

660.9
1.8
21.5
17.2
1,465.7
633.8
7.0
228.7
72.7
569.5
123.5
7.7
83.0
1.2
86.4
19.0
490.1
260.7
2.3
7.0

**

716.5
2.0
20.4
18.3
1,631.5
809.2
4.8
236.6
85.8
584.5
127.9
7.5
81.7

Includes grain equivalent of flour.
Includes bean equivalent of oil.
SOURCE: U. S. Department of Agriculture .

were Japan, the United Kingdom, Canada, West
Germany, the Netherlands, India, Italy, United
Arab Republic-Egypt, Belgium-Luxembourg,
and Spain. Of the total exports, $3.5 billion
were commerci al sales for dollars and $1.6
billion were moved under Public Law 480 and
other Government program .
Of the $5. I billion of farm products exported in fiscal year 1962, $1 .2 billion , or about
23 per cent, went to the six European Common Market countries. Exports to the Common
Market countries accounted for about a third
of the $3 .5 billion of products sold for dollars.
Because of the current significance of the European Common Market and the fact that it is
likely to become a substantially more important factor, the U. S. agricultural industry needs
to be well informed on developments in the
Market.
TH E EUROPEAN COMMON MARKET

The European Economic Community- commonly referred to as the European Common
Monthly Review •

November-December 1962

1.1

85.8
14.3
432.9
388.8
1.7
1.5

t

Average
Per Cent

36
36
43
34
40
35
34
32
30
28
23
21
19
25
15
37
20
4
15
18

1960-61

1961-62

Per Cent

Per Cent

49
56
56
37
38
33
49
41
26
29
32
23
19
20
14
21
21
8

58
57
54
52
44
39
34
34
31
29
28
27
21
19
18
17
17

13

8
7

23

11

Includes seed equivalent of oil.

Market-was officially established by a treaty
signed by six countries in March 1957. The six
countries signing the treaty were France, West
Germany, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, and
Luxembourg. Greece became an associate
member this November. The treaty recogn izes
the interests of certain over eas countrie and
t rritories that have pecial links with the ommon Market countries and provides for ex pansion. Other countries seeking either full or associate membership include the United Kingdom , Ireland, Denmark, Turkey, Austria, Sweden, Norway, Switzerland, and Spain. The
eventual objective is to conduct commerce
freely within the area. There are to be no tariffs among individual member countries and no
restrictions on movement of good , capital ,
ervices, or worker . It is anticipated, however
that the Common Market, as a unit, will have
a single policy on imports from "outside" countries .
Important steps toward implementing the
program already have been taken . Tariffs
11

American Agriculture and the

among member nations have been reduced significantly and quota restrictions on industrial
goods have been abolished. Some basic decisions also have been taken in formulating a
common agricultural policy.
Economic cooperation can be effective in
restricting and eventually eliminating some
of the intense nationalistic rivalries that have
ex isted hi storically in Western Europe and
have been responsible for much dissension.
Furthermore, it is an effort to remove artificial barriers which have throttled business,
impeded advancement, and caused suspicions among these nation . The effecti.veness
of such coope ration at th e eco nomic Jevcl
has been dcmonstrat d. Trad among member
na ti ons has incrcas d substanti ally more than
has trade with "outside" nations. The rate of
economic growth, although starting from a
lower base, has been greater in Common Market countries than in the United States. The
attainment of the ultimate objective of harmony
in all aspects of social and economic life will be
a noteworthy achievement.
On the other hand , it should be recognized
that a major undertaking such as the Common
Market usually cannot be attained without creating diffi cult problems. Some of these problems arc of particular significance to the agricultural industry in the United States. As was
pointed out previously, the Common Market
co untri es, along with those that may become
associated with them , have been an important
dollar m arket for United States farm products.
Since many agricultural commodities can be
produced more efficiently in this Nation than
in Europe, there is potential for a considerable
expansion of exports to Europe. On the other
hand, it mu st be recognized that a number of
difficult obstacles must be overcome before
this potential can be realized.
Historically , European nations have made
inten sive efforts to become self-sufficient in th e
production of many agricultural products. Beca use the Common Market countries have en12

couraged expansion of farm production, they
now are insistent on protecting their agricultural industry from imports from "outside"
countries. An analysis of the agricultural industry in these countries will be helpful in understanding why these nations are insistent upon
maintaining and implementing protective devices.
There are approximately 9 million farms in
the six Common Market countries. More th an
5 million of these farms are 12 acres or less in
size and frequently are composed of several
scattered strips of land. Location and des ign
of farm buildings often hamper mech anized
hand ling of li vestock. U nd cr th sc circum stances , it is often diffi ·ult to us th e most
fnci nt techniqu s.
The Jarge number of sma ll farm , on which
labor requirements are high, ha s resulted in
farmers accounting for more than a fourth of
the labor force . Furthermore, there has been
a siza ble gap between farm and nonfarm income. The large proportion of farmers and the
disparity in income have caused these countries to support prices of their farm products
at high levels. In recent years, many new techniques have been introduced into European
agri culture. By u in g these techniques, E uropea n farmers have bee n abJc to expa nd output
rapidly. With price protection, th e e farmers
now see an opportunity to improve th eir incomes. Without price protection and import
controls, foreign producers would becom e a
threat to their industry. Since a substantial proportion of their labor force is engaged in agriculture, the pressure for protection against imports from "outside" countries is great.
Because of these developments, the export
market for U. S. farm products is threatened,
even thou gh the indu stry is more efficient in
this Nation than in E urope. The threa t is
largely an outgrowth of the immobility of labor
resources between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors of the economies. The
problem in Common Market countries is more

European Common Market

difficult than that in the United States, since
they have substantially more surplus labor resources in agriculture in terms of use of the
most efficient techniques. Thus, they need to
devote more effort to solving the structural
underemploym ent problem in agriculture and
getting a better balance between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors of their economy than doe the United State . Until problem of this type can be solved and the desire
for self-sufficiency in agriculture can be minimized, there will be considerable pressure on
the Common Market governments to continue
protectioni t policies . In fact , th e pressure for a
continuation f such policies c urrently i grca tr in . . uropcan agricultur than it is in th
United Sta tes. If certain of the policies urrcntly b in g prop scd arc implem ntcd , it will
soon become more difficult to sell certain U. S.
farm products such as wheat, poultry , feed
grains, rice, tobacco , animal products, fats and
oils, and certain fruits to the Common Market
nations.
Devices proposed by Common Market countries to protect their agriculture include variable import duties , fixed tariffs, and buying
preferences. The purpose of variable import
dutic is to protect farmer in the Common
Mark et countries by offsetting the difference
between the world price and the desired internal price through use of these levies . For
example, if it is desired that the internal price
of wheat should be $2.50 per bushel and it can
be imported for $1.75 , the duty would be set
at 75 cents per bushel. The duty can be changed
from time to time as the spread between the
desired price and world price varies. Variable
duties make it particularly difficult to se11 in
such markets, since they can be adju ted so as
to prevent competition. Such duties, combined
with the u e of fixed tariffs and buying preferences, make it virtually impossible to trade on
an economic basis except to the extent desired
by Common Market countries.
Despite regulations promulgated by the ComMonthly Review •

November-December 1962

mon Market, the United States has continued
efforts to maintain grain exports to this important market. The ultimate success of these
efforts is expected to depend on the level at
which target prices finally are set. Bilateral discussion have led to an understanding with respect to trade in grains, which should help at
least partly to maintain United States grain
exports to Europe while the Common Market
agricultura l policy is being implemented . Furthermore, the Common Market has agreed, upon adoption of a common agricultural policy,
to enter into n ew negoti ations with the United
States.
According to th present schedule, external
tarifTs on liv stoc k and meat produ ts arc to
become fully -ITc live in the ommon Market
by 1970. Similarly, by that tim , int rnal tariffs
a rc to have be n aboli shed . xcept for variety
meats, ta1low, hog grease, lard, and fatbackwhich are major U. S. livestock exports-duties
have not been increased significantly for the
bulk of livestock product exports from the
United States. However, if current average livestock prices are maintained in the Common
Market, production of livestock products likely
will increase substantially. Such an increase in
production could tend to reduce over-all import
requirements. It should be pointed out also that
in pcction and sanitary controls on many livetock products may continue to limit import
into the Common Market area. The situation
currently is quite fluid and, if variable levies
are used to support prices at high levels within
the Market, trade in livestock products between the United States and the Market could
be hampered.
There is some encouragement, however, in
th e longer-run outlook for livestock product
trade with the ommon Market. As wa pointed out prev iou ly, genera] economic conditions
in Weste rn urope have been improving rapidly a nd are expected to continue to do so. Under
these circumstance , per capita consumption
of many livestock products is likely to increase .

13

American Agriculture and the

To illustrate, per capita red meat consumption
in Common Market countries currently is
somewhat less than two thirds of that in the
United States. With the increasing incomes of
recent years, meat consumption has been increasing sharply and is likely to continue to do
so. H demand for meat and packinghouse
products expands rapidly enough, demand for
meat imports from outside countries could increase, even with increased production within
the original market and the entrance of meatexporting countries such as Denmark. Demand
for feed grains also could increase under these
condition .
T he ex port situ ation for many other farm
products is quite simil ar to that for the grain s
and meats. If prop r agreement can b work d
out, th e demand for agricu ltural xpo rts from the
United States could po sibly expand substantially in the future. If such agreements cannot be worked out, there is reason for anxiety
concerning the future of much of the export
market for farm products from the United
States. This is why it is important to keep informed on the continued efforts being made to
work out trade agreements with the Common
Market.
Prior to the time th at the Trade Expansion
Act of 1962 was passed , it was ex trem ely difficult even to attempt effective tariff negoti ations
with the ommon M arket, si nce it nego ti ates
tariffs on an across-the-board basis. Under
previous legislation, the authority of the U . S.
Government to conduct negoti ations was limited to concessions which could be granted in
exchange for reciprocal agreements and to selective items. Authority was needed to negotiate
on a comprehensive basis.
TRADE EXPANSION ACT OF 1962

T he purpose of th e Trade Expa nsio n Act
of 1962, as stated in Title I, are " ... through
trade agreements affo rding mutual trade benefit - ( 1) to sti mul ate the economic growth of
the United States and maintai n and enlarge
14

foreign markets for the products of United
States agriculture, industry, mining and commerce; (2) to strengthen economic relations
with foreign countnes through the development
of open and nondiscriminatory trading in the
free world; and ( 3) to prevent Communist
economic penetration." Title II provides the
authority for the President to enter into trade
agreements and revise any existing duties or
other import restrictions. Provision for tariff
adjustment and other adjustment assistance is
made in Title Ill, while Title IV contains a
number of general provisions.
Briefly, the Act gives the President authority
to enter into trade agreements with foreign
co untri es during the period from July I, 1962,
to July 1, 1967, if he determine th at any xi ting duti s or other import restrictions are
unduly burdening the foreign trade of the
United States. To accomplish the objectives of
the Act, the President, within limits, may modify or continue existing duty or other import restrictions as he determines to be appropriate
to carry out proposed trade agreements. Except as otherwise specifically provided for in
Title II, the President is limited to a 50 per
cent reduction in any rate of duty from the
levels prevailing on July 1, 1962 . One general
exception is made for low-rate articles which
a rc defi ned as those for which the rate of duty
on July 1, 1962, was not more than 5 per cent
ad valorem. Another general exception pertains to articles that are of special importance
in trade between the United States and the European Economic Community. The President
also is permitted to increase any duty to a rate
not more than 50 per cent above the rate existing on July 1, 1934.
Title II, Chapter 2 of the Act, contains the
special provi ion concerning the European
Eco nomic Community. Section 2'11 in this
chapter gives the President authority to reduce
rates by more than 50 p r cent in any trade
agreement with the European Economic Community providing " . . . the United States and

European Common Market

all countries of the European Economic Community together accounted for 80 per cent or
more of the aggregated world export value of
all articles in such category." To determine
which articles fall into this classification, the
President is requested to select a system of
comprehensive classification of articles by category and the Tariff Commi sion is to determine
the articl s falling within each category of such
system. Both the President's system of classification and the Tariff Commission's determinations are to be made public. Methods to be
used for making a determination with respect
to any catego ry of article arc stated in conside rable detail. Provi ion al o is made f r
ce rtain ex lu sion s, requirements cone rning
n go tiations, national security, administrative
I roe dur s, and other it m of a gen rat nature. The Act provide considerable flexibility
for negotiating with the Common Market countries on a comprehensive basis.
Title I U of the Act provides for tariff adjustment and other adjustment assistance for
workers and industries harmed by imports when
industry-wide relief possible under the old law
is not feasible. Chapter 1 of this Title specifies
the procedures to be used in determining eligibility for assistance. Afte r eligibility has been
determined , variou types of assistance arc provided for on an industry , firm, or worker basis .
If the Tariff ommis ion determine that, as
a result of concessions granted under trade
agreements, an article is being imported into
the United States in such increased quantities
as to threaten serious injury to the domestic
industry producing a competitive article, the
President may: ( 1) provide tariff adjustment
for such industry, (2) provide that its firms
may request certification of eligibility for adjustment assistance, ( 3) provide that its workers may require certification of eligibility to
apply for adjustment benefits. Assi tance available for firm includes Government loans, technical aid, and tax relief. Assistance to workers
includes a weekly payment which can equal 65
Monthly Review •

November-December 1962

per cent of the average weekly wage, training,
and relocation allowances.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
Trade is necessary for any economy to
achieve the advantages of geographical specialization. In recent years, the economy of the
United States has been the largest in the world
within which goods and services have been permitted to flow more or Jess freely. Thus, the advantages of geographical specialization have
been available within the Nation. Many commodities can be produced more efficiently outside this Nation 's boundaries, while others can
be produced more efficiently in th e United
States than in most other nations. Many farm
products fall in the latter category.
To the ext nt that each nation produces
tho c items it can produce most efficiently and
trades with other nations for th e products that
they can produce most efficiently, the economic
welfare of all nations is enhanced. It is for this
and other reasons that the European Common
Market was created. There is little doubt that
the Common Market will be advantageous to
those countries within the Market. It also can
be advantageous for "outsid e" nations if the
force s that dictate geographical specialization
arc allowed to operate and the various nation
arc p rmittcd to trade.
Factors such as immobility of resource , customs, political considerations, and mi sunderstandings frequently cause nations to use devices designed to protect certain categories of
their citizens. To accomplish such protection,
various types of trade-restriction devices are
used . Because of these devices, it is necessary
for nations to enter into trade agreements with
each other and make a mutual effort to minimize these devices if increased trade is to be
encouraged. The Trade Expans ion Act of 1962
wa pa sed in order to give the President adequate authority to enter into trade agreements
with other nations-particularly the European
Common Market.

15

BANKING IN THE TENTH DISTRICT
Deposits

Loans
Reserve
City
Member
Banks

District
and

October
States

Country
Member
Banks

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

Country
Member
Banks

1962 Percentage Change From

Sept. Oct. Sept. Oct. Sept. Oct. Sept. Oct.

Loans

Deposits

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

Country
Member
Banks

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

September

1962 Perce ntage Change From

Country
Member
Banks

Au g. Sept. Aug. Sept. Aug. Sept. Aug. Sept.

1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961 1962 1961
Tenth F. R. Dist.
Colorado
Missouri*
N braska
New Mex ico *
Oki homa*
Wyoming

+9 +2 + 13 - 1 +5
t +8
+9 + 1 +17
. ....
. ..,.
+ 2 +11 ** **
- 1 + 5 + 2 +11 - 2 + 1
1
4 + 10 +4 + 14
t
,:c,:c
,11,fc
**
I
18
16
**
2 1+1 1 - 2 + 8
t I 14
:;,1::
** - 1 1
+12 ** **
,

Kansas

-* T enth District

--

t
t

,

+ 2 + 8 + 2 + 10
+ 1 + 11 + 2 + 8
..,.
:!::::
+1 +7
1
7
2 +8
12
3
!5 !8
>!i,:c
**
+ 4 17
1 r- 8 !3 I 13
*,::
+4 +6
-.,

:;:i;:

t +11
+ 1 + 18
- 1 + 10
t + 10
+2 + 11
1 -I 10
2 -j 6
- 1 12

+3 +7 + 1 + 8
+2 + 7 +2 +13
t +7
+ 4 + 6 +2 +9
7
7
+4
t
,:,::c
>!c>:c
·1·
+5
1 10
3
9
,:, ::c
::c:;,
-j 4
6
::::::

,i::::

portion only . ** No rese rve cities in this state . tLess than 0.5 per cent .
NOTE: Due to the reclassification of certain Topeka and Wichita banks on Au gust 23, 1962, and Kansas City, Kansas,
banks on Septembe r 6, 1962, from reserve city to country bank status , data for September 1961 and Octobe r
1961 have been adjusted to produce comparability with current figures .

PRICE INDEXES, UNITED STATES
Index

Oct.

Sept.

Aug.

Oct.

Sept.

1962

1962

1962

1961

1961

Con sumer Price Index (1957-59 = l00L ---- ----- ·--·
Wholesale Price Index (1957-59 ::- 100). .... -......__
Prices Received by Farmers (1910-14 = 100).__ _
Prices Paid by Farmers (1910-14 = lO0L----·- -- -·-

106.0
100.7
245
307

106.1
101.2
250
307
.__

105.5
100.5
244
305

104.6
100.0
240
301

104.6
100.0
242
301

--

TENTH DISTRICT BUSINESS INDICATORS
Value of
Department
Store Sales

Value of
Check
Payments

District
and Principal

Percentage change from previous year
Metropolitan
Areas

Tenth Federal Reserve District. ......
Denver __ ·-·--· ··· -- ---·-- -· ----··-- -- ---·----·
Wichita _·---··-······--··-·--·----···-----·-···
Kansas City.-·---· -- ··- --------------··--··Omaha ·---------···---· ·--·--··--·-·····--·-· ·
Oklahoma CitY---- --···------ -·-·---------Tulsa .·-- -·-- ----- ·---- ---· ·---·-· -···-·-· -·----

16

Oct.

Sept.

1962

1962
0
- 2
- 8
+3
+7
+11
- 10

+8
+ 11
+2
+6
+ 12
+4
+6

Ten
Months

Oct.

Sept.

Ten
Months

1962

1962

1962

1962

+7
+7
+4
+6
9
+ 11
+4

+4
2
+3
+8
+8
+5
+2

- 2
- 8
- 3
+6
- 4
0
+2

+3
0
+1
+7
+1
+5
+3

JnJex o/

MONTHLY REVIEW
ARTICLE

olrticle~ /or 1962
ISSUE

Agricultural Outlook for 1962
( 6 pages) ......... .............................. .January
American Agriculture and the
European Common Market
(6 pages) ....... ............. November-December
Average Labor Productivity As a Guide
to Wage Adjustments
(7 pages) .................................. March-April
Business Credit Demands-Problems of
Interpretation ( 6 pages) ............ July-August

ARTICLE

ISSUE

Our Unemployment Yardsticks:
Concepts and Measurement
( 7 pages) ................. ..... September-October
Postwar Changes in the Pork
Industry ( 6 pages) .................... July-August
Postwar Growth and Di stribution of
District Bank Deposits ( 6 pages) .. May-June
Postwar Trends in District Bank
Earnings ( 6 pages) ........ September-October

Changing Shape of World Trade
(7 pages) .................... November-December

Relationship of Bank Size and Bank
Earnings-Some Further Considerations
( 8 pages) ...................................... February

Economic Recovery and Expansion
( 7 pages) ............................... .... ..... January

Seasonal Patterns of Cattle Prices
( 6 pages) ........... ....................... ....May-June

Meat Consumption and Livestock Price
Trends (5 pages) ....... ............. March-April

Soybean - An Alternative rop?
( 5 pages) ............................ .......... February

Special J3ookletJ on J3anking ...
The Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City recently issued
two booklets on banking which are available to the public without charge. The first,
"Essays on Commercial Banking," contains nine independent studies which were originally printed in the Monthly Review and have now been published in book form for
the convenience of teachers, students, and others. The second is "A Study of Scale
Economies in Banking" and is based on a series of Review articles. Copies of either or
both may be obtained on request to the Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Kansas City 6, Missouri.