View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

NOVEMB R 1976

Com ercial Bank Loans and
The Money Supply ... ... .... .... . ... pa e 3
The Concept of
Priva e Income ....... . ..... .. ..... page 11

Subscriptions to the Monthly Review are available
to the public without charge. Additional copies of
any issue may be obtained from the Research
Division, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
Kansas City, Missouri 64198. Permission is
granted to reproduce any material in this
publication provided the source is credited.

Commercial Bank Loans and
The Money Supply
Byl. A. Cacy
he lending activity of the nation's
commercial banks has been unusually
sluggish over the past year or two. Total bank
loans in September of 1976 were only
moderately higher than a year ea rlier. The
growth in the narrowly defined money supply,
MI (i.e., publicly held currency plus demand
deposits). also has been on the weak side during
the past year. Ml increased 4.3 per cent in the
year ending September 1976, which is below
the rate that would be expected during a period
of substantial economic growth accompanied
by a sizable, if diminished , inflation rate.
Some observers have argued that the weakness in the growth rate of the narrowly defined
money supply is closely related to the sluggish
behavior of loans at commercial banks. This
article examines the relations hip between bank
loans and M 1. The first section discusses
possible theoretical reasons why the behavior of
the two variables may be closely related. Next,
the actual behavior of bank loans and M 1
during the last 25 years is examined to
determine whether or not the two variables
have behaved in similar ways. Finally, the
article examines the behavior of bank loans,
bank credit, and the broader measures of the
money supply to determine if any of these
variables show common behavior patterns.

T

THEORETICAL RELATIONSHIP
BETWEEN LOANS AND MONEY

Observers who claim that the behavior of the
narrowly defined money supply is closely
Monthly Review • November 1976

related to that of commercial bank loans hold
that M 1 tends to increase when loans are
increasing and to decline when loans are
declining. These observers offer several reasons
for expecting the close relationship to exist.
Some of these reasons are potentially val id,
while the validity of others is questionable.
Certain observers, for example, appear to
argue that Ml and loans are necessarily related
because the public cannot increase its Ml
balances unless banks make loans. It is true, of
course, that commercial bank lending is an
important source of potential increase in Ml.
When banks make loans , the proceeds may be
and frequentl y are used by the public to
augment its M 1 balances.
Bank lending , however, is only one of several
sources of potential increase in the narrowly
defined money supply. Another source is the
investing activity of commercial banks . As in
the case of loans, when banks acquire
investments, such as U.S. Government
securities, the public may use the proceeds to
augment its M 1 balances. A third source of
potential increase in money balances is the
asset-acquiring activities of the Federal Reserve
System. When the Federal Reserve buys U.S.
Government securities, the proceeds potentially
may be used by the public to add to its M 1
balances.
Potential increases or decreases in M 1
balances, therefore, result from changes in the
assets-investments as well as loans-held by
the nation's banking system, i.e. , the Federal
3

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Reserve and commercia l banks. When the
banking system adds to its assets, a potential
increase in M 1 occurs; and when t he banking
system reduces its assets, a potential decline in
MI occurs. Of course, these changes in Ml
may not always materialize because the public
may not add to M 1 balances when the banking
system acquires assets. Instead, the public may
add to its time deposits or to other non -M 1
liabilities of the banking system . 1
The potential change in M 1 that results from
a change in bank loans during a particular time
period can be seen b y examining t he
consolidated balance sheet of the banking
sys tem . The assets of the b a nking syste m
co n s is t of Fed e ral R e erve assets a nd
commercial ba nk credit- that is, loa ns plus
in vest ments. Liab ilities may be broken d own
into M 1 and non -Ml li abi liti es. The poten tia l
increase in M 1 during the year ending in June
1976 was $42.5 billion, as the assets of the
banking system increased by that amount. (See
Table 1.) Of the total increase in assets, only
$9.8 billion was accounted for by an increase in
bank loans. Th e largest single positive
influence on Ml was the $24 .0 billion rise in
b ank investments. 2
Because bank lending is only one of several
sources of potential increase in the mon ey
suppl y, M 1 can increase even though loans do
not. Also, loans m ay increase while M 1 remains

I Changes in MI balances m ay occ ur in the absence of
ch a nges in the loans and investments a nd other assets of
th e banking system. For examp le , wh en business firms
redeem their large CD's , they may place t h e proceeds in
MI balances . In this case. MI in creases even though there
h as been no ri se in earning assets. Of course , the reduction
in large CD' s a nd the in crease in MI bala nces m ay h ave an
indirect impact o n com m ercia l banks. It may. for exam ple ,
increase th e required rese rves of co mm e rc ia l banks and
induce ba nk s to reduce th e ir ea rnin g assets.
2 Tab le I shows that MI did not increase by th e a m ou nt of
th e rise in bankin g system assets because a $30.4 billion
in crease in non- MI li abi li t ies absorbed most of the rise in
assets. Thus. Ml increased o nl y $12. 1 bi llion ($42.5 billion
minu s $30.4 billi on) .

4

unchanged. Thus , the behavior of Ml is not
necessan·ty related to bank lending activity.
Nevertheless, there are several reasons that a
close relationship may exist between loans and
M 1. One reason is that banks typically require
their business loan customers to hold
compensating balances. Such balances may be
related to the size of the customer's loan so that
as loan amounts rise and fall, compensating
demand balances rise and fall. Since these
compensa ting balances are included in the
mo ney supply , their sensitivity to changes in
loa n vol ume may res ult in a correlation between
the mon ey supply and bank loans.
An.ot h e r facto r that would lead to a
cor relation between th e m oney supply a nd bank
loa ns is that th e d ema nd for mo ney balances
may tend to ri se a nd fa ll in line with the
d em a nd for loa ns at banks. For exa mple,
during a n economic upturn, rising consumer
and business spending may be financed in part
by loans from commercial banks. At the same
time, the expanding economy may lead the
public to add to its money balances. Also ,
during an economic downturn, the public may
be inclined to reduce its indebtedness to
commercial banks ; and the low economic
growth rate may reduce the public's need for
money balances. Thu s, the demand for bank
loa ns a nd money balances may rise and fall
together a nd m ay tend to cause a close
correlation between bank loans and the money
supply.
Finall y, the conduct of monetary policy may
tend to produce a correlation between bank
loans and the money supply. Monetary
authorities may tend to accommodate an
expansion of bank loans by increasing reserves
during periods in which bank loans are
expa nding. Increasing bank reserves , in turn ,
may give rise to increas ing money balances . By
th e sa me token, when bank loans are fa llin g
the Federal Reserve may respond by reducing
bank reserves , giving rise to a decline in money
balances. Therefore, to the extent that
Feder.:il Reserve BanK of K:ansas City

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Table 1
CONSOLIDATED BALANCE SHEET
U.S. BANKING SYSTEM (FEDERAL RESERVE AND COMMERCIAL BANKS)
(In Billions of Dollars)
LIABILITIES

ASSETS
Levels as of June 1976
Federal Reserve Assets :
U.S . Govt. securities
Oth er assets
Total
Comm ercia l Bank Credit :
L oans
I nvest rn ents
T ota l

Money Supply (M1)
95.6
26 .8
122.4

Large CD's
Oth er l iabilit ies
Total

511 .7
236 . 1

--

399 .2
69 .2
99.4
567 .8

747 .8
870 .2

T otal A sse ts

Non -M1 Liabiliti es:
T ime deposits other
than large CD 's

302.4

870.2

Total L iab ilities

Ch ang es Dur ing Y ear Ending June 1976
8 .7

Federal R eserve A sse ts :
Commercial Bank Credit :
Loans
Investmen t s
Total

12.1

Non-M1 L iabilities :
9 .8
24 .0

--

T otal A sset s

33 .8

42 .5

mon etary policy accommodates alterations in
bank loans, a correlation between bank loans
and the money su ppl y may result.
In brief. compensa ting balances , demand
factors. and the conduct of monetary policy
may possibly result in a close correlation
between bank loans a nd the money supply.
Wh ether or not such a correlation has resulted
from these or other factors is examined in the
foll ow ing section.

STORICAL RELATIONSHIP
BETWEEN LOANS AND M1
Some broad si mil arities may be observed
betwee n the behavior of bank loans and M 1
Monthly Review• November 1976

Money Supply (M1)

Time deposits other
than large CD 's
Large CD 's
Other I iabil ities

46 .0
- 13 .1
- 2 .5

To tal

30.4

Total L iabilities

42 .5

during the past 25 yea rs. Both M 1 and tot a l
bank loans, as well as business loans. have
increased steadi ly throughout most of the
period from 1952 through the early part of
1976. (See Chart 1.) The increase in loa ns
indicates that commercial bank lending activity
has been an important source of potent ial
increase in M 1. From 1952 through 1975, for
examp le. total loans increased $448 billion and
accounted for about 70 per cent of th e rise in
the assets of the banking system.
Other similarities exist between th e behavior
of bank loans and Ml . For example. the
upward trends of both loans and M 1 are slowed
or in terrupted from time to time. Moreover, m
5

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Chart 1
OMMERCIAL BANK LOAN5 AND THE MONEY SUPPLY
1952-76
Bil lions of Doi lors

p

p

I

500

400

300

200

100

0

1952

1

54

1

56

1

58

1

60

1

62

1

64

1

66

1

68

1

70

1

72

1

74

1

76

NOTE: The shaded areas in Charts 1 , 2, and 3 pertain to recessions , with the p 's and t's at the top of the
charts referring to peaks and t roughs of business cycles. With two exceptions , these reference periods are
designated by the National B ureau of Econom ic Research (N BER ) . The fi rst exception is the early-1967 period ,
which is inc luded here because the behavior of financial variables was quite similar to other recessionary
periods. The second exception is that while the NBER has not yet designated a trough for the current
recession , the trough is s hown here as the first quarter of 1975 .

both cases. these interrupt ions are associated
wit h business cycles, as may be seen in Chart 2,
which shows the growth rates of total loans and
M 1. The growth rates of both of these variables
decline fo r several quarters prior to the onset of
economic recessions. Also, for both loans and
M 1, growth rates tend to accelerate during the
first few quarters of economic recoveries.
Beyond these broad similarities. however. the
behavior of bank loans and M 1 is not closely
correlated. For example. the statist ical
correlation between simultaneous move ments in
the growth rates of these two variables is quite
low. Specifically, for a regression involving the
current growth rates of M 1 and bank loans
6

from the tirst quarter of 1950 through the
second quarter of I 976. the coefficient of
determination , R2 , is only .10. (See Table 2.)
This means that movements in the growth rate
of loans during any quarter explained only
about 10 per cent of the movements in the
growth rate of M 1 during the same quarter.
Regression analysis shows further that M 1 and
business loans are not correlated at all. as the
R2 between the growth rates of the two
va riables is zero. 1
The contrasting behavior of the growth rate s
o f loa ns and MI is illustrated by their
m ove ments during th e 1973 -75 recession a nd
s u bseq u en t period of economic recovery.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Chart 2
GROWTH RATES OF BANK LOANS AND THE MONEY SUPPLY
Quarterly Averages , 1952-76
Per Cent

p I

25

20

15

10

5

0

-5
1952

During the recovery, the money supply grew
more rapidly than during the recession. In
contrast, bank loa ns grew much more slowly
during the recovery than during the recession.
In the recovery period from the first quarter of
1975 through the third quarter of 1976. Ml
3 The R2' s in Table 2 are for single variable regressions in
which a current money supply va riable was regressed on a
current asset variable. For examp le , one regression had Ml
as the dependent variable and loans as the independent
variable. The origina l data were seaso nally adjusted
quarterly data for the period from the first quarter of 1950
t hrough the second quarter of 1976. The observations that
entered the regressions were differences between the actual
and trend grov.1h rates of the variab le s. Trend gro"'1h rates
were determined b y regression analys is . For example, the
trend grov.th rate of MI is defined as:
T
T
A
~ In M1t = In M1t - In M1 t - 1

where In MI A is the natural logarithm of the actual level of
MI a nd In MIT is the predicted value of the regression
equation:
~ In M1 t = a + b In M1 t _

1

+ ut.

This procedure allows th e trend growth ra te to change
through time . In the case of M l. for examp le. the trend

~onthly Rev ew • l\iovernbe~ 1876

grew at an annual rate of 5.3 per cent,
compared with 4.1 per cent in the recessionary
period from the fourth quarter of 1973 through
the first quarter of 1975. The recovery growth
rate of loans was 1. 1 per cent, compared with
the recession growth rate of 9. 1 per cent.
While the growth rates of bank loans and M 1
are not closely related , there is some correlation
between the two variables. An examination of
Chart 2 suggests that a time lag may be
grow th rate increases from 2.0 per cent in the tirst quarter
of 1950 to 6.3 per cent in the second quarter of 1976.
The se ries used in the regressions- th e difference
between ac tual and tre nd growth rates - ha ve zero meam
and have no t re nd . However. the series do contain cycles.
as no atte mpt was made to re m ove se rial corre lation. It
shou ld be noted . a lso. that the resid uals o f th e regressions
in Tabl e 2 a re se riall y corre lated.
In add ition to the regre sio ns in Table 2. reg ressions
were run using growt h rat es ( ~ in) as observations. In
most cases. the growth rate regressions produced hig her
R2's than the reg ressions reported in Tab le 2. However. th e
growth rates do. in most cases. co ntain trends which
contribute to the higher R2· s.

7

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Table 2
R2 FOR REGRESSIONS OF VARIOUS
MONEY SUPPLY MEASURES ON
BANK LOANS, INVESTMENTS, AND
BANK CREDIT
Indep en de nt Varia bl es
Dep en dent
Varia b les

T o t al
Loan s

Bus iness
Loans

Inv es tments

M1
M2
M4

.10
.00
'. 09

.00
.00
.06

.4 2
.3 0

.10

Loans Pl us
Inves tm ents
.29
.45
.63

NOTE: M1 consists of demand deposits of
commercial banks other than domestic interbank
and U .S . Government less cash items in process of
collection and Federal Reserve float ; foreign
demand balances at Federal Reserve Banks ; and
currency outside the Treasury , Federal Reserve
Banks , and vaults of commercial banks . M2
c onsists of M1 plus sa vings deposits , time
deposits open account , and time certificates of
deposit other than negotiable CD 's of $100,000 of
large weekly report ing banks . M4 consists of M2
plus large negotiable CD 's .

involved in the relationship. Note, in
particular, the tendency for a turnaround in the
loan growth rate to lag a turnaround in the
money growth rate. This tendency is especially
evident during periods in which the growth rate
of M 1 is accelerating after having been
declining. Typically, these turning points in the
growth rate of M 1 are near the peaks of
business cycles. During the first part of the
periods of accelerating Ml growth, the growth
rate of bank loans typically either declines or
does not change much. The growth rate of
loans does not begin accelerating until some
time after M 1's growth rate has undergone a
reversal of direction.
The recent behavior of total loans and M 1
illustrates the tendency for the turnaround in
the loan growth rate to lag behind the
turnaround in the money growth rate. As
usual, the growth rate of M 1 began declining
several quarters prior to the onset of the
1973- 75 recession, which began in the last
8

quarter of 1973. M 1's growth rate declined
throughout the recession (surprisingly, since
M 1's growth rate usually begins accelerating
we ll before the end of recessions) and bottomed
out in the first quarter of 1975, the recession 's
final quarter. In the second quarter of 1975,
the growth rate of money accelerated sharply ,
and grew much more rapidly in both the second
quarter and the third quarter of 1975 than in
any quarter during the recession. The loan
growth rate, however, instead of accelerating
during the second quarter of 1975 , continued to
decline, with total loans falling during both the
second and third quarters of 1975.
Statistical ana lys is supports the impression
ga in ed from Chart 2 that a time lag may be
in vo lved in the relati nship between bank loan
and MI . Th e analysi hows that movements in
th e grow th rate of MI duri ng any quarter can
explain about 29 per cent of th e movements in
th e growt h rate of loans two quarters iater. 4
Th is moderately high correlation between
current money supply movements and future
movements in loans may be du e to a tendency
for M 1 movements to lead movements in the
general business cycle and for the cycle to
coincide with or lead movements in bank loans.

RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN
BANK CREDIT AND THE MONEY SUPPLY
As pointed out ea rlier. increases in the
mo ney supply may potentia lly arise when banks
add either to their loans or their investments.
4 The 29 per cent is the R2 from a regressi on invol ving time
lags. The general form is:
t).ln L ~ = t ( t). In M1

~_

2

)

where the superscript D denotes differe nces between a ctual
and trend growth rat es. Simil a r multi va riate regress ions
with up to four lagged MI vari a ble-, in crease the R2 to as
high as 35 per cent. Regre ss ion s with loans instead of MI
lagged -of th e form
t). In M1 t = t (~ In Lt _

2

)

have R2·s of less than . 10 per cent. rcgarclle~s of the
number o f lagged loan variable~ invol ved (up to four lagged
va ria b les).

Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

Chart 3
GROWTH RATES OF BANK CREDIT AND THE MONEY SUPPLY, M4
Quarterly Averages, 1952-76
Per Cent

p t

20

15

10

5

-5

Ll-il..U...1..1..

1952

1

56

1

58

1

60

1

62

Thus . one would ex pect the correlation between
total bank earning assets-i.e., loans plus
in vestments-and M 1 to be closer than the
correlation betwee n any component of earning
assets-such as loans or invest ments-and
money. This expectatio n turns out to be
correct. The R2 between the growth rates of
earning assets during a ny quarter and the
growth rate of M 1 in the same quarter is 29 per
cent. compared with 10 per cent between loans
and M 1. and 10 per cent between investments
and M 1. (See Table 2.)
The correlation between bank credit and M2
also may be expected to be higher than the
correlation between bank credi t and M 1. This
is becau se increases in bank ea rning assets may
pote ntially be used by the public to a ugment its
tim e d eposits as well as its M 1 balances.
Wh e th er Ml balances or tim e deposits (except
la rge CD 's) a re augme nted , M2 will increase
because time deposits ot her than large CD's are
includ ed in M2 along with M 1. Also. because
Monthly Review • November 1976

1

64

1

66

1

68

1

70

1

72

1

74

1

76

funds arising from increases in earning assets
may be placed in large certificates of deposit
rather than M2 balances. and because M4 is
defined as M2 plus large CD's , the correlation
between bank credit and M4 should exceed
that between bank credit and M2. These
expectations are confirmed by statistic a l
ana lysis. Table 2 shows that movements in the
growth rate of bank credit explain 45 per cent
of the movements in M2, while the R2 between
cred it and M4 is 63 per cent. 5 The high
correlation between bank credit and M4 may
be observed in Chart 3, which plots the growth
5 The R2's reported in Table 2 are for current period
regressions. Regressions in volving time lags give somewhat
different results. When M2 or M4 is regressed on past
values of investments or bank credit, the R2' s are lower
than reported in Table 2. Similarly, when investments or
bank credit is regressed on past values of M2 or M4 , th e
R2· s are lower than in Table 2. However , when loans are
regressed on past values of M2 or M4 , the R2 •.,; are
somewhat higher than reported in Table 2. This resu lt is
similar to that reported for loans and Ml in the text.

9

Commercial Bank Loans and the Money Supply

rates of the two variables for the 1952-76
period.
Somewhat surprisingly, a fairly close
relationship was found between commercial
bank investments and M2. (See Table 2.)
Movements in the growth rate of investments
account for about 40 per cent of the movements
in M2. Since the R2 is relatively high between
investments and M2, and low between
investments and Ml , investments and the time
deposit component of M2 must be highly
correlated. And. when the time deposit
component of M2 is regressed on investments,
an R2 of 45 per cent is produced. Evidently ,
during periods when banks are aggressively
adding to their inve tment portfolios, the funds
provided to the public are more likely to be
used to add to tim e deposits rather than to M J
balances. An alternative interpretation of the
stat ist ical results is that banks are more likely
to acquire investm ents when their time deposits
increase than when their demand deposits
increase.
SUMMA RY
Many observers of financial developments
argue that the behavior of the narrowly defined
money supply, M 1, i closely related to the
behavior of commercial bank loans. According
to this argument, MI tends to increase when
loa ns are increasing and to decline when loans
are declining. Some observers appear to argue
further that MI and loans are necessarily
related because the public cannot increase its
MI balances unless banks make loans.
This article points out that while increases in
bank loans may be and frequently are used by
the public to augment Ml balances, bank
lending activity is only one of several sources of
potential increase in Ml. For example , when
banks increase their investments, a potential
increase in M 1 occurs because the increase in

10

investments provides the public with funds that
may be used to add to money balances. For this
reason, Ml may increase even though bank
loans do not , and Ml may remain unchanged
while loans increase. Thus, the behavior of M 1
is not necessarily related to bank lending
activity. Nevertheless, several factors may
produce a close correlation between the two
variables. These factors include compensating
balance requirement , demand factors affecting
both loans and MI , and the conduct of
monetary policy.
An examination of th e historical relationship
between loans a nd M 1 ove r the past 25 years
uncovered some broad simil a rities between the
behavior of the two variables. Both variables
have tre nded upward durin g the J952- 76 period
and comme rcia l bank lending activity ha s been
an important so urce of potential increase in
Ml. Furthermore, the upward trends for both
MI and loans have been interrupted from time
to time and in both cases these interruptions
have bee n associated with the business cycle.
Beyond these broad similarities, however, the
behavior of bank loans and Mt has not been
closel y correlated during the 1952-76 period.
The statistical correlation is quite low between
movements in the growth rate of MI during any
period and movements in the growth rate of
loan s in that sa me peri od . The correlation is
so mewhat high er when th e exis tence of a lagged
re lati ons hip is r ecog ni zed. Even so, the
correlation is only mod erately high.
Furthermore, statistical analysis shows that
the correlation is also quite low between growth
rates of bank loans and the broader measures
of the money supply, such as M2 and M4. As
would be expected, on the other hand, a
somewhat higher correlation was found
between bank credit, which includes both loans
and investments , and various measures of the
money supply. The correlation between bank
credit and M4 is quite high .

Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

The Concept of Private Income
By Robert D. Auerbach and Jack L. Rutner

T here are a number of frequently used
measures of aggregate income or output
for the U.S. economy. One of these is gross
national product (GNP), which is the one most
co mmonly cited. Other less frequently cited
aggregates are net national product (NNP) and
national income (NI). None of these concepts of
income, however, measure the income of the
private sector alone since they also include the
income of the government sector.
There are occasions, though, when a
definition of income is needed that excludes the
government sector. Such instances arise when
one wishes to measure, and perhaps forecast,
the demand for goods and services by the
private sector , such as money balances, durable
goods, vacations, etc. 1 Indeed, the appropriateness of a definition of income that excludes
the government sector was originally suggested
by Milton Friedman and David Meiselman in
connection with the estimation of the demand
for money by individuals in the private sector. 2
For estimating such a demand function, it may

1 Of course , for items where a composite demand by the
private ector and the government exists, account must also
be taken of the government sector.
2 Friedman and Meiselman . "Reply to Ando and
Modigliani and to Prano and Mayer," American Economic
Review, September 1965 . Set also Robert D. Auerbach ,
"The In come Effects of the Government Deficit ,"
unpubli shed Ph.D. dissertat ion , University of Chicago,
1969 .

Monthly Review • November 1976

be appropriate to have a measure of income of
only the private sector.
The purpose of this article is to describe and
develop a concept of income of the private
sector. The concept of private income outlined
here is the total income of individual s including
trans fers and net of taxes plus undistributed
corporate profits. The first section of the article
indicates how this concept can be derived from
the GNP accounts. The second section provides
an analysis of how private income has behaved
in the post-World War II period relative to
other commonly used measures of aggregate
income.
GNP AND ITS RELATION
TO PRIVATE INCOME
The GNP Accounts
To describe the concept of private income, it
is useful to begin with an examination of the
GNP accounts. For reference, Table 1 presents
a summary of the U.S. national income and
product accounts for 1975 as published recently
by the U.S. Department of Commerce in the
Survey of Current Business.
The basic purpose of the GNP accounts is to
provide a continuing measure of the gross
expenditures on final goods and services of the
U.S. economy. The underlying rationale of the
accounts is embedded in an accounting
relationship in which payments equal either
receipts or income from the sale of final goods
and services. Reflecting this accounting
equality, GNP can be computed in one of two
11

The Concept of Pr ivate Income

Table 1
SUMMARY NATIONAL INCOME AND PRODUCT ACCOUNTS, 1975
(In Billions of Dollars)
Co mp ensa t ion of employees
W ages and salaries
D isbursem en ts
Wage accr u als less d is bu r sem ents
Suppl em en ts to wag es an d sa la r ies
Emp loy er con tr ibu tions tor soci al i nsurance
Oth er labor income

928.8
806 .7
806 .7
.0
122. 1
59 .7
62 .5

Pr op riet ors' income w ith inventory val uat ion and
ca pit al cons umpt ion ad j ustm ents

90 .2

Rental inco m e of p ersons with ca pital cons umpt i on
adjustm en t

22.4

Personal consumption ex p en ditures

973. 2

Du ra b le goods
Nondu ra b le goods
Se rvices

131. 7
409 .-1
432.4
183 .7

Gross p riva t e do m estic invest m ent

198.3
147 .1
52 .0
95 .1
51 .2

F ixed in vestment
N onre si d enti al
St r uctures
Pro du ce rs ' durabl e equipment
R esidential

14 .6

Change i 11 bu sin ess invento ri es
Co rp ora t e profit s w i th in ventory va luation an d
capit al consumption adju st m nt s
Profi t s before tax
Profit s t ax liabili ty
Pro f i t s a ft er tax
D ivi d en d s
Undi str ibut ed p rofits
I nventory valuation adjust m ent
Capita l cons u m p tion adju st m ent
Net interest
NATIONAL INCOME

9 1.6
114 .5
49 .2
65 .3
32 .1
33 .2
- 11.4
- 11.5
74 .6

N t export s of good s and servi ces

20 .5

Export s
Imp ort s

148.1
127.6
339.0

Gov ern m ent p urc h ases of goods and serv ic es
F ed eral
Natio nal d e f ense
Nondefense
State an d local

124.4
84 .3
40 .1
214 .5

1,207 .6
Add endum :

Bus ine ss transfer paym ents
Ind irect bus iness t ax and non t ax l iab ilit y
Less : Subs id ies less cur rent su rp lu s of govern m ent
enterpris es
Statistical discr ep ancy
CHARGES AGAINST NET NATIONAL PRODUCT
Cap i t a l cons umpti on allowances w i th capit al
cons umpt ion adju stm ent
CHARGES AGAINST GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT

6 .3
138 .7
2. 0
4.4

20.5
11 .9
0.9
7.6

1,355.0
16 1.4
1,516 .3

ways: by summing the values of expenditures
of all final products sold , as illustrated on the
right side of Table 1; or by summing the
receipts or gross income from these sales , as
illustrated on the left side of Table 1.
As illustrated by Table 1, national income is
a narrower measure than GNP. The difference
arises because GNP as derived on the right side
of the accounts is essentially a consolidated
sales figure of all final goods and services sold,
12

Net ex port s of good s an d services
N et foreign inv est m ent
Perso nal transfers t o for eign ers
Interes t and transfer s p ai d b y f oreigners
less ca pita l grant s recei ved by U .S.

G ROSS NATIONAL PR O DU CT

1,5 16 .3

while NI equals only the value of final goods
and services produced in the current period .
This difference between the value of goods sold
and goods produced , which is shown in Table 1
as adjustments to NI , does not represent
income earned by factors of production for
producing the current period's output. One
such adjustment , for example, is called
depreciation and shown in Table 1 as capital
consumption allowances and represents the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

The Concept of Private Income
3

using up of output from a previous period. In
order to avoid double counting output from two
different periods, depreciation is subtracted
from GNP to obtain NI.
When this adjustment and others 4 are made
to NI on the left side of the accounts, the total
exactly balances with the product side of the
acco unts. In other words, total charges against
GN P-including factor costs and other
costs-exactly equal GNP derived via the right
side of the accounts. The concept of net
national product is obtained by subtracting one
of these items of adjustment, i.e ., depreci ation
cha rges, fro m GNP.
The Derivation of Private Income

As indicated earlier, the concept of private
income d sc ribed here is the income of persons
incl udin g transfers a nd net of taxes plus
undistributed
corporate in come.
Income
acc ru ing to the government sector , both federal
and state and local governments, is explicitly
excluded in deriving private income. Since the
totals of the income and product sides of the
GNP accou nts are exactly equal after making
certain adjustments, private income can be
obtained by subtracting government income
from either side of the accou nts.
Table 2 shows the relationship of private
income to GNP in 1975, together with th e
various categories that comprise private
income. Many of the categories are identical to
those in Table 1. They have simply been
rearranged to reflect the se paration of the

3 Output from a previous period which is not consumed in
that period is an additio n to the stock of wealth .
4 Other adjustments a re made for indi rect business taxes,
business transfer payments, current surpl us of govern ment
enterprises less subsidies, a nd fo r an item called statistica l
di screpa ncy . Th e prese nce of the statisti cal discrepancy
a ri ses beca use of th e different meth od s of accounting used
to arrive a t the right and le ft si des of the national income
and prod uct acco unt s. It is use d as a balancing item to
reconcile both sides. As a technical ;natter , NNP (GNP less
deprecia tio n ) is la rger than national income because it
includes indirect business taxes (sales and pro perty taxes) .

Monthly Review• November 1976

accounts into personal, corporate , and
government income. Other categories , however ,
as well as the values for certain categories. do
not appear in the summary accounts of Table
1. Rather , they are contained in supplemental
sector accounts, which are published in
considerable detail along with the GNP
accounts by the U.S. Department of
Commerce.
Private income derived from the left side of
the GNP accounts consists of disposable
personal income plus corporate retained
income. 5 As shown in Table 2, d is posable
personal income amm:~ts to personal income
minus personal tax and nontax payments.
Persona l income includes most of the item
show n previously in Table 1, such as
compensation of employees,
proprietors'
income, rental income , dividends , and net
interest. 6 Also included are transfer payments
from government and businesses , which are
considered income received by persons even
though they are not related to the sale of goods
and services. Contributions to social insurance
are also deducted under the assumption they
are government income and not savings to the
private sector. Finally, personal taxes and
nontax payments are deducted to arrive at
disposable income. Tax payments are deducted
because they represent income accruing to the
government sector.
Corporate retained income consists of
retained corporate profits whether in the form
of cash or invested in inventory or equipment.
Corporate dividends, as indicated above , are
5 The statistical discrepancy must be added or subtracted
from one side of the accounts in order that both bal a nce , so
that private income could also arbitrarily include the
statistical discrepancy. Without some additional evidence
as to th e so urce of the discrepancy. there is no basis for
making a deci sion as to which side of the accounts the
discrepancy is to be assigned.
6 The value of net interest received by person s shown in
Table 2 is different from the net interest received by all
factors of production , which as shown in Table I is
corrected for inter-sector transfers.

13

The Concept of Private Income

Table 2
RELATION OF PRIVATE INCOME TO GNP, 1975
(In Billions of Dollars)
1,0 58 .1

D isposable p erso na l 111come
Personal 111come
Compensation of employees
Proprietor s· rncome
R ental income
Dividends
Ne t interest received by p ersons
Tr ansfers to p ersons
B y b usiness
6.3
B y government
168.9
L ess empl oyee and employer
con tr ibutions to social insurance
L ess wuge accruals plu s d1sbu1sements

1,226 .9
928 .8
90 .2
22.4
32 .1
87.9
185.2

168.8
10.3
33.2
11 .4
- 11 .5

0.9
64.4

PRIVATE I NCOME

339.0

7.6
282 .2
1,072.8

Government n t incom e

282 2

Capital consumption allowances

161.4

1,0 72 .8
282 .2

Government n et i ncome

168 .8
49.2
138.7
109.7
0.0
168 .9
13.3
2.0
1,355 .0

Cap i t al consumption allowances

161.4

G R O SS NA T IONA L PR ODUC T

1,516 .3

shown as part · of personal income. Corporate
tax payments are not treated as part of
corporate income because they represent
income received by the government sector.
Thus, adding the value of disposable personal
14

12 0

4.4

PRIVA T E INCOME

NET NA TIO NAL PRO DUCT

N et foreign investment

Government purchases of goods
and services
Interest and transfers paid by
gove1 nment to for eigners less
ca µ1t ul giant s rPce1ved by U .S.
L es s g vP1nmPnt rw1 income

Statistical d iscre pan cy

Personal tax and nontax paym ents
Corporat e t ax pa yments
Indirect business taxes
Contributions to social 111surance
Wage accruals less disbursem ent
L ess governm ent tran sf ers
L ess interest p aid
L ess subsidie s plus su rplu s of
enter p rises

22.3

Deficit of government

R ta1n d cor p o1ate 1ncom
Undistribut ed corpo ra te profit s
Inventory valuation adj ustment
Ca pita l consumption adjustment

N et private domestic tnvestment

Personal transfers to foreigners

109.7
0 .0

Less p e1so nal tdx and nontax p aymen t s

973 .2

Personal consumpt ion expe nd itures

GROSS NAT IONA L PRODU CT

1,516 .3

income to corporate retained income (plus a
minor statistical discrepancy item) yields the
concept of private income.
Government net income , which consists of
tax receipts less transfers , is shown on the left
Federal Reserve Bank of Kdnsas C1•y

The Concept of Private Inc me

side of Table 2. The components of government
income also are shown. 7 When government net
income is added to private income , the total
equals net national product; and when capital
consumption allowances (depreciation) are
ad ded to NNP, the total equals GNP.
The concept of private income can also be
derived from the right side of the GNP
accounts . Conceptually, the methodology is the
same , i.e., to subtract from the accounts all
incom e accruing to the government sector.
Accordingly , private income includes personal
consumption expenditures, net private domestic and foreign investments, personal transfers
to foreigne rs , and the deficit of the government
sec tor. The d eficit of the governme nt is
ob tained by s ubtrac tin g government net income
from gove rnm ent expe nditures. 8 The resu lting
va lu e of private income on the expend iture side
of the acco unts is exactly equal to the same
concept on the income side . By the same token,
when government net income and capital
consumption allowances (de preciation) 9 are
added to private income, the total equals GNP.
It shou ld be mentioned that the computation
of private income from the right side of Table 2
treats the gove rnm ent sector in a manner

7 Spcci ti ca ll y. a ll perso nal. co rpora te. a nd indirect tax
rece ipt~ a re li sted as part o r govern me nt in co me a lo ng with
government rece ipt s a ris in g from co n tributi o ns to social
in surance . De ducted fr o m these rece ipt s are governm ent
domest ic transfe r pay me nts and int e res t p a id b y the
governme nt. In terest paid b y th e government e xcludes
intere st paid to fo reigners. th e latter being tre a ted ex plicitly
o n the expe nditure side of the acco unts. Finally. th e net
in come figure for govern m e nt is actually d o mestic net
in c:o me since it e xcludes ca pital g rant s received b y the
nit ed States .
8 Government ex penditures include expen di t ures for goods
and serv ices a nd net govern ment outlays to th e foreig n
sectors . The va lu e o r s u ch o utl ays to foreig ners whe n added
to net fore ign in ves tmen t a nd perso na l transfers to
foreigners equa ls the net e xport o f goods a nd se rvices
sh own in Table I.
9 Since capi ta l cons umpti o n all owances are exc luded from
pri,·at e in co m e. th e item net pri va te domestic inves tment is
used in Table 2 rathe r than gross pri vate domestic
in ves tm e nt as sh o wn in Tab le I .

Monthly Rev ev, • NovefTlber 1975

analogous to the foreign sector. That is , just as
imports
are
subtracted
from
exports,
government receipts are subtracted from
government expenditures. Viewing the government sector this way reveals why deficit
spending by government is treated as a
stimulant to private income during recessionary
periods. In such periods, there is an attempt to
stimulate income by increasing exports or by
restricting the importation of goods produced
abroad. Similarly, there is an attempt to
increase sales to the government or reduce
government receipts-namely , taxes. 10
A further point is that the concept of private
income derived here, because it excl udes the
government sector, is not a measure of the tota l
ex penditures on final goods and service in th e
economy. Indeed , the value of private income
in 1975, which is estimated at $1,072.8 billion,
wo uld understate total expenditures on final
goods and services as measured by NNP and
GNP, which are valued at $1,355.0 billion and
$1,516.3 billion, respectively. Private income
also falls short of national income, valued at
$1,207.6 billion in 1975. These aggregate
measures, however, often have been used to
help measure the demand for goods and
services by the private sector. The following
section , therefore,
examines how these
aggregate measures have behaved relative to
private income.
THE BEHAVIOR OF PRIVATE INCOME

To examine the behavior of private income ,
va lues for the concept were calculated for the
post-World War II period 1946- 75. Table 3
contains these values calculated on an annual
basis along with values for the major

10 One ca nn o t conc lude. h owever . the precise m ag nitude
or sign changes the govern m en t deficit or net ex po rt s will
h3\·e o n privat e inco me by looking only at these simpl e
acco unting id en titie s. inasmuch as some other compon ents
of the accounting identity must also change. and this may
ha ve o ffsetting effects.

15

The Concept of Private Income

Table 3
PRIVATE INCOME, ANNUALLY 1946-75
(In Billions of Dollars)
Sources of Income

Year

D isposable
Personal
Income
(Ad j usted )

Net
Corporate
Re taine d
Earnings

Final Sales

Sta tist ical
D iscrepanc y

Co nsumpt ion

Tota l Private Income

Net
Dom est ic
Investments

Net
Fo re ign
Investments

Defici t of
Government

Cu rrent
Do llars

As a
Per Cent
of NNP

In 1972
Pr ices

1946
1947
1948
1949
1950

157 .2
166.6
185.3
184.8
202 .8

1.9
4.6
9.7
9.6
6.9

0. 7
1.8
- 1.2
1.0
2.0

143 .8
161 .7
174.7
178.1
192.0

16.9
16.8
25 .6
13 .3
29.9

4.6
9.0
2.0
0 .6
- 2.1

- 5.4
- 14.4
- 8.4
3.4
- 8 .0

159 .8
173.0
193 .8
195.4
211.7

81 .7
80 .3
81.2
82 .8
80 .7

334 .8
327 .6
347 .3
351 .0
372.8

1951
1952
1953
1954
1955

221 .9
233 .1
246 .7
251 .4
268 .6

7.0
7.5
6 .4
7.9
12.3

4 .0
2. 7
3.3
3.0
2.5

207 .1
217 .1
229.7
235 .8
253 .7

31 .6
22.5
21 .7
19.6
33 .1

0.3
- 0 .2
- 1.9
- 0.3
0.3

-

6 .1
3 .8
6 .9
7. 1
3.1

232 .9
24 3 .3
256.4
262 .3
283.4

77.0
76 .6
76 .7
78 .7
77 .9

385 .2
393 .3
406 .6
412 .4
441 .0

1956
1957
1958
1959
1960

285 . 7
301 .0
311 .2
329.6
342 .0

9.8
9.2
7.1
12.4
11 .0

- 0 .8
- 0 .2
1. 7
- 0 .2
- 0.7

266 .0
280.4
289.5
310.8
324 .9

32 .1
27 .2
17.8
31 .5
28 .7

1.8
3 .6
0.1
- 2.0
1.7

-

5.2
0 .9
12.6
1.6
- 3.1

294 .7
310.4
320 .0
341.8
352.3

77 .2
77.4
79 .1
77 .6
76 .8

449 .7
458.5
462.9
485 .1
491 .2

1961
1962
1963
1964
1965

355 .2
375 .6
393.4
426 .5
460.5

10.8
16.5
17.9
21 . 7
27.1

1.6
4 .0
3.7
2.2
0.9

335 .0
355.2
374 .6
400.4
430 .2

25.2
34 .7
38 .0
42.0
54 .5

3.0
2.4
3 .2
5.7
4.3

4.3
3.8
0. 7
2.3
0 .5

367.6
396 .1
415.0
450.4
488 .5

77 .5
77.2
76 .5
77 .5
77.5

506 .8
538.1
555 .3
595 .0
633 .2

1966
1967
1968
1969
1970

497 .8
531 .3
574 .0
614 .8
669.4

29.4
26.7
24 .5
19 .2
10 .5

3.2
1. 7
- 0.6
- 3.3
- 2.1

446 .8
490.4
535 .9
579 .7
618 .8

62.8
53.8
57 . 7
63 .7
50 .0

1.6
1.2
- 1.4
- 2.0
0 .5

1.3
14 .2
5.5
- 10.7
8 .5

530.4
559 .7
597.9
630 .7
677 .8

76.7
76.7
75.2
73.9
76 .0

668 .3
688.3
706 .7
712.6
732 .7

1971
1972
1973
1974
1975

725 .5
782.4
880 .2
959 .7
1,057.2

16.9
25 .9
22.6
1. 7
10.3

1.3
1. 7
2.6
6 .6
4.4

668 .2
733 .0
809 .9
887.5
973 .2

61 .2
82.9
102.4
77.3
22.3

- 3 .2
- 9.0
- 0.6
- 3.0
12 .0

17 .6
3 .1
- 6 .3
6 .3
64 .4

743 . 7
8 10.0
905.4
968.0
1,071 .9

77.1
76 .0
76. 1
76 .0
79 .5

769.4
81 0.0
861.0
829.8
846 .8

-

-

NOTE: Components may not sum to total due to rounding . Also , disposable personal income (adjusted) is
adjusted to exc lu de interest paid by consumers and personal transfers to foreigners .

components of private income. 11 As is apparent
from Table 3, private income has risen
11 The values of private income in Table 3 exclu de
personal transfers to foreigners . Hence, the value of private
income shown for 1975 ($1 ,071.9 billion) is $0.9 billion less
than the va lu e shown in Table 2. This treatment was
suggested in Friedman a nd Meiselman , "Reply to Ando
and Modiglia ni and to Pran o and Mayer. "

16

throughout the period although it has a
somewhat different pattern of growth than
other measures of income. Prior to the Korean
war private income averaged a bout 81 per cent
of NNP. Since that time, however , reflecting
the growth of the government sector, private
income has averaged only about 77 per cent of
NNP, although in 1975 private income jumped
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

The Concept of Private l'lcome

Chart 1
REAL AND NOMINAL PRIVATE INCOME
(Quarterly, 1947-75)
Bil li ons of Doi lars

1150

950

750

550

350

I50

1--....1....---1.._1...-...1.........i...----1_.1....-_.____,,__L-..J..-....L...---1._..._...1....---L----JL--..J..----'----'-,--..___--'-__.__':---_.__---':-___,__':---...........

1947

1

49

1

51

1

'53

55

1

57

1

59

1

61

1

63

1

65

1

67

1

69

1

71

1

73

1

75

SOURCE: See text .

to 79 per cent of NNP. For the entire postwar
period, private income has varied from a high
of 83 per cent to a low of 73 per cent of NNP.
The rising va lu es of several meas ures of
aggregate expen ditures on final goods and
services in recent yea rs have partly reflected
inflationary facto rs. The impact of rising prices
on these variables has led increasingly to the
use of "real" values, i.e. , values deflated to
account for an increase in prices. The last
column in Table 3, therefore , also provides
a nnu a l values for private income calculated in
constant do ll ars. 12

12 The met hodo logy e mpl oye d to ar r ive at the rea l va lu es is
described in the appendix .

\'1onthly P v ew • Nover1ber

0

16

The distorting effect that changes in the
price level have had on private income may be
seen in Chart 1. The level of private income is
expressed in both current and real terms and is
displayed on a quarterly basis for the 1947-75
period. As is clearly shown, the rapid price
increases since the late 1960's have led to a
sharp rise in private income expressed in
current dollars. In contrast, gains in real
private income have been relatively more
moderate. Since price changes have tended to
obscure the underlying behavior of real
private income , real values are subsequently
employed in comparing private income with
other income measures.
Chart 2 shows the behavior of real private
income relative to three other measures of real
17

The Concept of Private Income

Chart 2
FOUR MEASURES OF REAL INCOME
(Quarterly, 1947-75)

Gross Notional Product

\

1100

900

700

500

300
1947

1

49

1

51

1

53

1

55

1

57

1

59

1

61

1

63

1

65

1

67

1

69

1

71

1

73

1

75

SOURCE: Real GNP, NNP, and NI : Survey of Current Business, U .S . Department of Commerce , Washington ,
D.C ., January and July 1976 ; Real Private Income : see text.
NOTE: The shaded areas in this chart pertain to recessions , with the p 's and t 's at the top of the chart
referring to peaks and troughs of business cycles .

aggregate income: GNP, NNP , and NI. As is
readily apparent, there is a similar upward
trend in each of the four measures during the
entire 1947-75 period. Closer inspection,
however, indicates some dissimilarities between
real private income and the other series.
During recessions, real private income often
tends to remain more stable , or to fall by less,
than the other three measures. In the 1953-54
recession , for instance, real GNP, NNP, and NI
all declined until the second quarter of 1954,
whereas private income reached its low in the
last quarter of 1953. Moreover, the decline in
18

private income was much less than in the other
three measures. In the 1957-58 recession,
private income again declined moderately,
while the declines in the other measures were
much larger. In the 1960-61 recession and in
the 1969-70 recession , private income actually
rose somewhat compared to declines in the
other measures. Only in the most recent and
ve ry severe 1974-75 recession did private
income decline sharply along with the other
three measures of income.
There were two other periods when real
private income behaved atypically relative to
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

The Concept of Private Income

Table 4
RATES OF CHANGE AND VARIABILITY OF
FOUR MEASURES OF REAL INCOME, 1947-75
Annual

Quarterly

Standard

Standard

Inco me Measures

Mean

Dev iation

Mean

Dev iation

Gross Nati onal Product
N et Nati onal Product

3 .38
3 .29
3 .35
3.44

3.20
3.50
3.94
3.16

3 .36
3 .26
3 .27
3.43

4 .58
5 .02
5.46
5.82

Nationa l Income
Pr iva t e In come

CORRELATION OF RATES OF CHANGE OF
FOUR MEASURES OF REAL INCOME, 1947-75
Annu al

N et Nati ona l Prod uc t
ational Income
Pri vate Income

GNP

NNP

.999
.982
.842

.981
.845

Quart er ly
NI

GNP

NNP

NI

.844

.996
.956
.680

.967
.681

.623

the other measures of real income . The first
was during the Korean war (1951-52) and the
second was in the midst of the Vietnam conflict
(1 968-69). During both of these periods, private
income declined while the other measures of
income increased. The decline of private
income in these periods clearly reflected the
inc rease in the government's share of income.
In a sense, the increase in the government's
sha re of income during these periods of military
conflict could be viewed as if the private sector
had purc hased more government services in the
form of defense.
Further evidence on the behavior of real
private income relative to the other three
income measures is contained in Table 4. As
shown in the top portion of the table, the
ave rage rates of change of all four measures
were very sim ilar during the 1947- 75 period,
whether using annual or quarterly data. On the
other hand, dissimilarities occur in the
Monthly Review • November 1976

variability of the four income series as shown by
their respective standard deviations. Using
annual data, for example, private income is
found to be the least variable; i.e., it only
varied within ±3.16 percentage points of its
average rate of change. Using quarterly data,
though, private income is found to be the most
variable of the four income series.
The degree of correlation between the rates
of changes in each of the four income measures
is also shown in Table 4 . On an annual basis,
the correlation between private income and the
other measures is quite high, although not as
high as between each of the other three
measures. On a quarterly basis, the differences
are quite pronounced. GNP, NNP , and NI are
all highly correlated with each other on a
quarter ly basis as they are on an annual basis.
Private income, though, is much less correlated
with GNP, NNP, and NI using quarterly data .
These correlations suggest that for quarterly
data at least 32 per cent of the deviation in real
income is uncorrelated with deviations in the
other measures of income; and, hence. these
other measures may be inappropriate proxies
for private income.
SUM M AR Y

This article has described a concept of
private income and its accounting as well as
statistical re lat ionships to other meas ures of
income. Essentially, the concept includes
income of individuals wit h transfers net of taxes
plus corporate retained earnings. Income of the
government sector, both federal and state and
local governments, is explicitly excluded from
private income. Compared to the other
measures of income , real private income in
most recessions tended to be more stable, or to
fall by less. than the other three measures of
real income. Moreover. during the entire
1947-75 period, the rates of change of real
private income. although similar in average
magnitude to the other measures of income.
were found to be more variable when using
19

~.,e Cnnr..m• of Private Income

quarterly data than the other income measures .
In addition, the correlation between real
private income and each of the other three
meas ures was also not particularly high.
Based on the national income accounts, it
a ppears that the concept of private income
desc ribed here is a more precise measure of the
in come of the private sector than GNP , NNP,
or NI . In addition, private income is not as
highly correlated with these other measures of
income a nd a ppears to follow a somewhat
different cyclical pattern than they do . Hence ,
researchers interested in using a concept of
income to analyze the behavior of the private
sector may well find the concept of private
in co me described here superior to these other
meas ures of income .
APP NDIX

The Computati on of Real Val ues
of Private Income
The computation of private income in constant
purchasing power wa s performed by applying price
deflators to the different components of private
income . This approach posed som ewhat of a
problem because not all of the appropriate price
deflators for the components of private income
exist . In those instances , the choice of the
component deflators was m·ade on a basis that was
deemed to be the most appropriate and reasonable .
The following list is a summary of the methods
used to compute the deflators for the major
components of private income . The source of all
data used is the Survey of Current Business
published by the U.S . Department of Commerce.
Components of Real
Private Incom e

Method s of
Computation

1. Real consumption
expenditures . . . ...... . From published data
2. Real net domestic
investment . ... .. . ... . Real gross domestic
investment
less
real
capital
consumption
allowance
3 . Real net foreign
investment . .. . . .. .. . . Nominal
net
foreign
investment/ implicit deflater of imports

20

4. Real deficit .. ..... ... . (1) + (2) + (3)
(5) - (6) - (7)
5. Real disposable
personal income
(adjusted) . . . . . . . ... . . Nominal
disposab le
personal income (adjusted)/ implicit deflater
of disposable persona l
income
6 . Real ret ained corporate
earnings . . ..... . . . .. . Nominal retained corporate earnings/ implicit
deflator of
business
output
7. Real res id ual . . .. . . . . . Fro m published data
The f irst fou r items pertain to the components of
real private income ap pearing on t he expend iture
side of the accounts and the latter three items
pertain to the income s ide . The price deflators for
some items are taken d irectly from publ ished data
an d for others the methods of computation are
rather stra ightforward . In Item 3, for instan ce ,
no m inal net foreign investment was divided by the
impl icit deflator of imports . A deflator for exports
was also tried but it gave about the same results as
the import deflator. In Item 5, the deflator on
disposable personal
income appeared
most
reasonable inasmuch as disposable personal
income (adjusted) differs only slightly from total
disposable personal income.
The computation that presented the most
diff iculty was for the government deficit , Item 4.
An attempt was orig inally made to deflate the
defic it by the price at which the government
purchases goods and services . This attempt
resulted in some large statistical errors so an
alternative method was chosen . The alternative
method measures the deficit as the difference
between the components taken from the income
side , Items 5, 6 , and 7 , and the componentsexcluding the deficit-taken from the expenditure
side , Items 1, 2 , and 3. Among the components
from the income side is a residual , Item 7, which is
analogous to the statistical discrepancy item . It
should be pointed out that this ind irect method of
computing the real deficit, rather than some
alternate direct method , will tend to cause any
methodological errors present in other parts of
private income to be contained in the real deficit.
The deflater for private income , as it turns out , is
nearly identical to the deflator on consumption
because private income is dominated by the
consumpt ion component .

Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City