View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

July - August

The Deficit Dilemma
-Another View . . .

.

The Market for Farm
Mortgage Credit . . .

.

Current Statistics . .

. .

.

.

.

page

1963

3

. . . . page 10
. . . page 16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF KANSAS UITY

Subscriptions to the MONTHLY REVIEW are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Kansas City 6, Missouri. Permission
is granted to reproduce any material in this
publication.

The Deficit Dilemma
he plethora of writing on the U. S. balance of payments has ranged far and wide
over various dimensions of the Nation's international financial straits. Nonetheless, several
reasons seem to justify further efforts on this
question. First, the importance of the issues is
sufficient motive for continued and expanding
exposure before the general public. Second, a
great deal of con fusion and uncertainty sti11
seems to cxi 't with regard to terminology as
well as to the mechanics and interpretation of
the balance-of-payment data. For that reason,
this article wilJ pay particular attention to the
basic fundamentals which underlie the balanceof-payments system of accounting, as well as
the practical meaning of the balance of payments itself. Finally, in order to place current
U. S. payments difficulties in their proper
perspective, they will be viewed in the framework of the "classical" payments deficit to
determine whether a fundamental disequilibrium-or imbalance-exists.

T

WHAT DOES IT ALL MEAN?

The public has become aroused and anxious
over the persistent and sizable deficits on the
U. S. balance of payments. While some anxiety
is certainly justified, any judgments on that
subject should be based upon an understanding
of the factors involved.
Table 1 presents an analysis of official balance-of-payments data for 1961 and 1962.
While the table may appear to be unduly complex at first, the balance of payments actually
is fairly easy to comprehend, both in terms of
its various basic accounts and the accounting
principles governing the entries.
The balance of payments is an accounting
record which lists the dollar totals of the various international economic transactions beMonthly Review •

July-August 1963

-- An other View

tween the United States and the rest of the
world over a given period. It is a record of
the amount of dollars or receipts that the
United States accumulates as a result of foreign
spending, investing, lending, and the remittance of gifts by foreigners, in comparison with
the amount of dollars which the United States
pays out to foreigners because of similar U. S.
activities abroad. As with any typical accounting statement, there are two sides to the balance of payments- one for credit entries and
the other for offsetting debit entries. Credit
entries indicate dollar receipts by the United
States, while debits denote U. S. payments to
foreigners.
Anyone familiar with rudimentary accounting procedures will recognize this as a doubleentry bookkeeping system. This means that for
each transaction recorded, every debit entry
is offset by a credit entry or entries in the same
amount. The practical effect of this is that,
insofar as the over-all balance of payments is
concerned, total debits must necessarily equal
total credits and, therefore, the balance of payments always "balances." This being the case,
any reference to a "deficit" in the balance of
payments implies a somewhat different meaning of the term than is customary.
As commonly understood, the term "deficit"
refers to a shortfall in receipts or income relative to payments or expenditures. Since this
cannot be the case in a double-entry system of
bookkeeping, it may be asked, "What is meant
by a deficit on balance of payments?" Note in
Table 1 that the balance of payments is made
up of a number of different accounts, such as
goods and services, remittances, and private
and government investments. Although it is
true that the algebraic sum of all the debit and
credit entries must be equal to zero, this need

3

The Deficit Dilemma
Table 1

ANALYSIS OF U. S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS,
EXCLUDING MILITARY GRANT AID
Millions of Dollars
DEBITS
U. S. payments recorded*
Imports:
Merchandise
Military expenditures
Other services
Remittances and pensions
Government grants and capital outflows
Transactions involving no immediate
dollar outflow from the United States
Dollar payments to foreign countries
and international institutions
U. S. private capital
Direct investments
Long-term portfolio
Short-term

1961
31,778

1962
33,254

14,497
2,934
5,436
705
4,056

16,145
3,028
5,791
736
4,281

2,940

3,211

1,116
4,150
1,598
1,011
1,541

1,070
3,273
1,557
1,209
507

CREDITS
U. S. receipts recorded*
Exports:
Merchandise
Financed by Government grants
and capital
Military sales
In come on investments, private
Income on investments, Government
Miscellaneous services
Repayments on U. S. Government loans:
Scheduled
Nonscheduled
Foreign capital other than liquid funds :
Private Iiabi Ii ties
Government li abiliti es

Excess of recorded receipts (credits) [ +] or payments (debits) [ - ]
On goods, services, remittances, and pensions
On Government grants and capital assets
On Government nonliquid liabilities
On private direct and long-term portfolio investment
On private short-term investments
Unrecorded transactions (net)*
Total net receipts(+) or payments(-) equals changes in
official monetary assets and in liquid liabilities
(increase in net liquid assets +, decrease -)
Changes in gold and convertible currency holdings of U. S.
monetary authorities and in liquid liabilities
Gold (sales +, purchases -)
Convertibl e currencies (sales +, purchases - )
Liquid liabilities, total (increase + , decrease - )

19 1
- 1,465
+4,739
- 2,782
+ 85
- 2,143
- 1,364
-905

- 1,161
+4,090
- 2,998
+865
- 2,495
- -623
-1,025

-2,370

-2,1 86

+2,370
+857
- 116
+ 1,629

+2,186
+890

1961
30,313

1962
32,093

19,913

20,479

2,237
402
3,464
380
4,152

2,345
660
3,850
472
4,329

606
668

617
666

643
85

1J5
865

19-62_

+ 17

+ 1,279

* Transactions other than changes In official monetary as set s and in liquid liabilities .
SOURCE : U. S. Department of Commerce , Office of Business Economics .

not, and in most instances will not, be the case
insofar as any one particular account or group
of accounts on the balance of payments is concerned. Thus, the volume of foreign goods and
services which U. S. citizens purchase can exceed or fall short of the amount which foreigners buy here. Similarly, capital outflows, gifts,
and gold movements from the United States
need not be equal to the volume of these items
received from abroad. Consequently, a deficit
or a surplus can exist for any accoun t or group
of accounts, a fact easily verified by Table 1.
During 1962, for example, if transactions involving official U . S. monetary assets, convertible currencies, and liquid liabilities of the
4

United States are excluded, th remaining
transactions resulted in an excess of payments
over receipts-total net payments-by the
United States of $2,186 million. This was the
magnitude of the deficit for 1962. Notice, however, that this deficit was matched exactly by
the volume of changes in gold and convertible
currency holdings of the U. S. monetary
authorities, and in liquid liabilities, so that the
over-all balance was eq ual to zero.
A better grasp of the existence of a deficit
on balance of payments may be gained , perhaps, if a "stock-flow" approach is used. Assume that at the beginning of the accounting
period, the United States has a given stock of

-Another View

official monetary assets as well as a given level
of international claims against her. As a result of transactions during the period, receipts
generated by U. S. exports, investment income,
etc., flow into the United States from abroad.
Conversely, U. S. imports, dividend payments
to foreigners, Government grants or loans, etc.,
occasion payments which result in an outflow
of funds from the United States. If the two
flows are of equal volume, there is no net accretion to or drawing-down from the U. S.
stock of monetary assets, nor is there any net
change in the international claims positionneither a "surplu " nor a "deficit" exists. But
if, as in th e case of the United States in recent
yea rs, th e stock of monetary asse ts i drawn
down, or the total of intern ational claim
aga in st the United States increases in order to
finance a shortfall in U. S. receipts, a "deficit"
situation exists, measured by the decrease in
U . S. monetary assets and the increase in the
amount of international claims against the
United States.
DISEQUILIBRIA AND THE
"CLASSICAL" DEFICIT

To most people, a balance-of-payments defi cit probably implies a fa ilure on th e part of a
country to export as much as it imports. However, this is only a part of the picture and in
no way determines whether or not some fundamental disequilibrium exists in the deficit country. That is to say, the existence of a deficit
on one or another of the balance-of-payments
accounts is not in itself a sufficient condition
for determining the existence of a fundamental
disequilibrium.
Table 2 views the U. S. balance of payments
somewhat differently than does Table 1. Current Accou nt consists largely of merchandise
exports and imports and , to a lesser extent,
services such as those associated with transportation and tourism ; investment income both
here and abroad; and military outlays made by
the United States as well as those of its allies.
Monthly Review • July-August 1963

The merchandise component of the Current
Account is commonly known as the "balance
of trade," and it is this single element that
many people refer to in discussions which purport to deal with the balance-of-payments deficit in its entirety. If merchandise imports exceed the dollar amount of exports, a "negative"
or "unfavora ble" or "adverse" balance of trade
is said to exist. This would be reflected by
an excess of debi ts over credits for this particular item, a situ ation which does not hold
for the United States in 1962, or for that
matter throughout the entire postwar period.
Table 2

AN ALTERNATIVE VIEW OF U. S. PAYMENTS
POSITION FOR 1962
Millions of Dollars

Debit( - ) Credit(+ )
I. Current Account

Merc hand ise
Services
Investment income
Mil itary outlays
Net on current account, excluding
transfers under military grants
II. Unilateral Transfers
Pr ivate
U. S. Government (except military
grant aid)
Net, excluding military transfers
Ill. Capital Account
U. S. private
Short-term
Long-term
Net
U. S. Government
Long-term
Repayments
Foreign currency holdings and
short-term claims,
net (increase - )
Net
Foreign (increase in U. S.
liabilities +l
Long-term
Short-term and U. S. Government
Increase in foreign holdings of
liquid dollar assets
Net
IV. Gold and Convertible Currencies
Gold (sa les by monetary
authorities
l
Convertible currencies
(purchases - )
Net
V. Errors and Omissions
Net

16,145

20,479

4,796
995

4,329

3,028

4,322
660
4,826

491
2,148
2,639
507
2,766
3,273
2,1 33
1,283
245
1,095

271
749
1,279
2,299

+

890
17
907
1,025

SOURCE : U. S. Department of Commerce, Offi ce of Business Economics.

5

The Deficit Dilemma

During 1962, the United States recorded a
trade surplus of approximately $4. 3 billion,
while income from U. S. investments abroad
exceeded outpayments to foreign investors by
$3.3 billion. These two elements of strength in
the balance of payments were offset somewhat
by net debits of $467 million on services and
approximately $2.4 billion for military outlays.
Nevertheless, the Current Account as a whole
was a positive element in the balance-of-payments picture to the tune of nearly $5 billion.
Unilateral Transfers represent private or
public gifts and, as the debit balance indicates,
they have moved outward from the United
States. This has been the case for the entire
postwar period. In 1962, private remittance
accounted for approximately one fifth of the
net outflow, with Government nonmilitary
grants and payments to pensioners living
abroad accounting for the remainder. Note
that the effect of the debit balance on this account serves to offset, by more than half, the
level of excess receipts on Current Account.
The Capital Account records changes in international claims against the United States,
as well as in the level of claims which the
United States holds against the rest of the
world. It reflects changes in the international
debtor-creditor status of a country and denotes capital inflows by credit entries, and
capital outflows by debits. As Table 2 shows,
these claims may be private or public, and
they may be long- or short-term. The private
short-term claims consist primarily of demand
deposits held abroad by Americans or in the
United States by foreigners. Long-term claims
involve securities such as stocks and bonds"portfolio" investment-while long-term "direct'' investment takes the form of outlays on
actual physical plant and equipment abroad ,
or acquisition of controlling interest in foreign
corporations.
Consider the U . S. private capital account
on Table 2. For 1962, there was net debit
balance of $3,273 million, consisting of long6

and short-term capital movements. That is to
say, there was an export, or an outflow, of
capital from the United States. Ignore for the
moment the funds which left the United States
and focus upon the movement of the claims
instead. In exchange for the funds received,
foreigners gave U. S. citizens international
claims in the form of demand deposits in
foreign banks, short-term notes, or stocks and
bonds. As a result of this capital outflow, U.S.
claims against the rest of the world increased
or, conversely, the rest of the world's claims
against the United States decreased . The fund s
flowed from the United States- they were exported- but the claim flowed into the United
tatcs- they w re imported- and it is by regarding the import of th claim , rath r th an
the export of the fund , that on can a ociate the debit entry with capital outflow . It
should be clear, however, that from the point
of view of the foreign country which receives
the capital funds from the United States, the
entire analysis is reversed. That is, the receipt
of funds results in an "export" of an 1.0.U.
to the United States, and this would be reported as a credit, acknowledging the outmovement of the claim.
This capital accounting procedure may be
illustrated by the example of a U. S. citizen
who buys a foreign bond and pays for it by
writing a check, in dollar , to the seller. Thi s
would be recorded on the U. S. balance of
payments in the following manner: The purchase of the bond increases the amount of U. S.
claims against the rest of the world but results in a capital outflow which is recorded
by a debit on long-term capital. The receipt
of the check by the foreigner, which is subsequently deposited in his bank, increa es foreign
dollar demand deposits, thereby increasing the
rest of the world's claims again t the United
States and is therefore record d as a credit on
short-term capital. Thus, the offsetting capital
entries are consistent with the double-entry
system of accounting.

-Another View

Gold and Convertible Currencies are media
of international payment in addition to dollars,
of course. They are treated in the balance of
payments in the same manner as the Current
Account items, but because of their significance as international media of exchange,
they have been separated from the other items.
As Table 2 shows, in 1962 the United States
sold $890 million worth of gold. This sale was
similar to any other merchandise sale or export in that it generated receipts for the
United States and therefore was recorded by a
credit in the gold account. The sale of convertible currencies similarly generated receipts
for the United States, much as a merchandise
export would, and was therefore recorded as
a credit on convertible currencies.
The final account in Table 2 is Errors and
Omissions. In some balance-of-payments presentations, it is referred to as Unrecorded
Transactions. It is a balancing account and
owes its existence to the fact that balance-ofpayments data originate in many separate
agencies which utilize varying standards and
principles. Thus, it is possible that some transactions may not be accounted for on both sides
of the balance of payments in the same
amounts at the same time. In addition, it is
possible for some types of transactions to go
unrecorded altogether- particularly, according
to some observers, short-term capital movements. In order to provide the missing debits
or credits, so as to make the over-all balance
of payments balance, it becomes necessary to
have an Errors and Omissions or Unrecorded
Transactions account.
Having spent some time on the actual meaning of, and the mechanics involved in, the
balance of payments, the relationship between
deficits and disequilibria may now be considered. As stated earlier, the most commonly
held view of a deficit is one which involves an
unfavorable balance of trade. However, as has
been pointed out, such a deficit need not imply
a fundamental disequilibrium. Because a fundMonthly Review • July-August 1963

amental disequilibrium is characterized by a
distortion in the basic cost-price relationships
between the deficit country and the rest of the
world, its effects are felt mainly on the merchandise component of Current Account. Thus,
an adverse trade balance is a necessary, but
not a sufficient condition for the existence of
such a disequilibrium. In the case of the United
States, not only has a "favorable" balance of
trade been maintained during the entire postwar period, but a surplus has existed for the
entire Current Account. Even if a country
should experience a trade deficit, this is not in
and of itself an unhealthy situation. During
the latter half of the 19th century, the United
States was in this position. This coincided with
the wave of railroad construction which entailed considerable imports from Europe, but
which was financed to a large degree by longterm capital inflows from abroad. Similarly,
England for many years in this century recorded trade deficits which were offset by income from investments made years earlier.
Thus, one cannot view the deficit alone to determine the existence of a fundamental disequilibrium; rather it is the manner in which
the deficit is being offset or financed which
makes this determination.
U. S. DEFICIT - CLASSICAL OR OTHERWISE?

Because so much importance has been attached to U. S. balance-of-payments deficits
in recent years, one might suspect that they
represent a new phenomenon for the United
States; In point of fact, such deficits have occurred annually since 1950, the sole exception
being 1957 when a small surplus was recorded
in connection with increased levels of activity
engendered by the earlier Suez crisis. The U. S.
net position on balance of payments for the
entire postwar period is included in Table 3.
The reasons for the more recent heightened
concern over the deficit problem become
obvious when the pre-1957 figures are contrasted with those for the period since 1958.
7

The Deficit Dilemma
Table 3

NET BALANCE ON MAJOR ACCOUNTS
Net Current Account, excluding
transfers under military grants
Net Unilateral (except military grant aid)
Net Capital
Net Private
Net U. S. Government
Net Foreign (increase in U. S.
liabilities +l
Gold and Convertible Currencies
Gold (sales + l
Convertible Currencies (purchases -l
Errors and Omissions
Net Surplus* (+) or Net Deficit** (-)
Net Current Account, excluding
transfers under military grants
Net Unilateral (except military grant aid)
Net Caiital
Net rivate
Net U. S. Government
Net Foreign (increase in U.S.
liabilities +l
Gold and Convertible Currencies
Gold (sales +l
Convertible Currencies (purchases -)
Errors and Omissions
Net Surplus* (+) or Net Deficit** (-)

Millions of Dollars
1948
1949

1950

1951

1952

1953

1954

+6,149
-5,627

+1,779
- 4,007

+3,671
-3,492

+2,226
- 2,505

+386
- 2,454

+1,828
-2,262

-906
- 1,024

-553
-652

-1,265
-156

-1,048
- 156

-1,160
-420

- 383
- 218

-1,622
+93

-1,792
-2,850
-2,850

+352
- 1,530
-1,530

+72
-164
-164

+ 1,927
+1,743
+1,743

+601
- 53
-53

+ 1,637
- 379
-379

+1,169
+ 1,161
+ 1,161

+936

+ 1,179

+ 1,492
+298
+298
+ 173

-3,580

-305

1959

1946

__IBL

+7,744
-2,899

+11,529
-2,612

+6,440
-4,511

-413
- 3,019

- 987
- 4,224

- 985
-623
- 623
+195

-

+ 1,261

+4,567

+ 1,005

1955

1956

1957

+775
+175
1958

+2,009
- 2,486

+3,967
- 2,398

+5,729
- 2,318

+2,206
- 2,338

- 1,255
- 310

- 3,071
- 629

- 3,577
- 958

+1,498
+41
+41
t 503

+1,894
-306
-306

+765
-798
-798

+543

+ 1,157

-

,145

-935

+520

-21

+477

t 601

+339

,046

-2,152

1960

1961

1962

+134
- 2,424

+3,769
- 2,336

+5,444
- 2,559

+4,826
- 2,639

- 2,936
- 971

- 2,375
- 353

- 3,892
- 1,105

- 4,150
- 928

- 3,273
- 1,095

+1,276
+2,275
+2,275

+3,875
+731
+731

+2,545
+ 1,702
+ 1,702

+2,357
+741
+857
-116
-905

+2,299
+907
+890
+17
- 1,025

-2,370

-2,186

-

t.488
,529

+412

-3,743

-683

-3,881

-

1,550

(Debits - and Credits +); *Defined as the reduction In U. S. liquid liabiliti es and / or increase in U. S. gold holdings; **Defined as the Increase in U. S. liquid
liabilities and / or reduction In U. S. gold holdings.
SOURCE : U. S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics .

From 1950 through 1957, the United States
experienced a cumulative deficit of some $10.2
billion, including a net outflow of gold of
about $1. 7 billion, with the remainder accounted for by an increase of about $8.5 billion in short-term and liquid liabilities held by
foreigners. From 1958 through 1962, the overall balance-of-payments deficit approximated
$15. 7 billion, while the net gold outflow
reached nearly $6.5 billion. In other words, in
the past 5 years, the size of the cumulative
deficit has increased by almost 50 per cent,
while the outflow of gold has exceeded that of
earlier levels by almost four times.
Merely pointing out the up and downs in
balance-of-payments deficits during the postwar period accomplishe little if anything toward determining whether these figures indicate
either a fundamental weakness in the economy
or an economy which is living"beyond its means."

8

During the entire postwar period, the United
States has experienced continuous and, for the
most part, substantial "favorable" balances on
its trade account--even if one excludes that
portion of the export surplus which is associated with U. S. Government aid or financing,
such as under Public Law 480 or the Mutual
Security Program. 1 This should not imply,
however, that there are grounds for complacency, since any additional improvement in the
trade balance will enable the Nation to more
1 For

the years 1955 through 1962, excluding 1959,
the U. S. trade surplus averaged more than $2.6 billion annually after subtracting P. L. 480 shipment
and M.S.P. nonmilitary aid. The year 1959 hows an
"adver e" trade balance if one subtracts these items
from the over-all surp lus. A noted below, this i
largely explained by a harp increase in imports associated with a cyclical ri e in the level of economic
activity in the United States, rather than with a decline in the level of exports.

- A nother View

easily accommodate the burden on the other
balance-of-payment accounts. The absence of
an " adverse" balance of trade, though , is a key
indication th at the U. S. payments deficit is
not of the "classical" variety.
Without a deficit on balance of trade, it is
difficult to argue th at the United State has
experienced any sort of fundamental di sequilibrium . Table 3 verifies thi point. At no time
durin g the entire postwar period has the
United States incurred a deficit on Current
Acco unt. T he smalle t net surpluses on Current Account were in 1953-when U . S. imports remained relatively unchanged from a
y a r arlier whil e xports fell by nea rly $ I
billion- and in 1959, when exports r main d
constant while imports rose by n ·1rly $2.4
billi n vcr year-earl ier lev Is as a res ult of a
harp upswing in dome ti econom ic a tivity.
A further indication of a lack of the existence of a fundamental disequilibrium may
be noted by observing that, wi th the sole exception of the gold account, the remaining accounts in each instance carry an opposite sign
than that which would imply the presence of
a fundam ental disequilibrium. For exa mple,
on Unilateral T ran fers, the tring of net debit
ba lances indicate that th e United State has
been a net donor, rath r th an a recipient of
gifts. Simil arly, the capital account shows net
capital outflows ( debit ) on both private and
Government accounts for each of the postwar
years, th e sole exception being a small inflow
on Government acco unt in 1954. Thus, the
United States has provided both long-term investment funds and short-term liquid funds to
foreigners rather than the converse.
CONCLUSIONS

appear to be of a rather special variety, stemming
from strength rath er than weakness.2 Such a
view, however, is not inconsi tent with the notion that the U. S. bala nce of payment is not
in equilibrium. The absence of a fundamental
di sequilibrium does not imply that the payments deficit do not have erious implications .
Such an interpretation would be naive in the
extreme. It i important, however, to be fully
aware of the varied dim ensions of the balanceof-p aymen ts problem in taking step s to cure it.
The pre-1 95 8 de ficits were ge nerally regarded as desirable in the se n e th at they provided th e world with badly needed liquidity for
purposes o f co ndu cting th e smooth fl ow o f in terna ti ona l com mer ·e, without undul y threatning th e U. S. international r ·serve position .
H wever, 5 co ns cutive yea rs of sub tanti al
pay ments defici ts entailing signifi ca nt capital
and gold outflows have re ulted in an agonizing reappraisal of not only the strength of the
U. S. international financial position , but the
state of the dom estic economy as well. It may
seem paradoxical to question the competitive
strength of an economy which has shown that
it can generate sizable export surplu ses year in
and yea r out in pite of increasing rivalry from
all over th e globe. Neve rthe less, in the face of
ubstanti al U. S. military and economic commitm ents ove r mu ch of the world, th e ov r-a ll
ca pabilitie of th e economy can no longer be
taken for gra nted or con idered in i olation,
but must be viewed in relation to the demands
being made on it- demands which in many
cases are not predicated upon economic criteria, but rather upon political, humane, or national defense considerations. Seen in this light,
U. S. p ayments deficits, though "noncla ical"
in na ture, non th cles repre cnt a dil mma.

Eviden e presented o fa r leads to the conclu ion th at U. S. payments dcfi its h ave bee n
in no sense "classical" and , furthermore, that
th y are not indicative of a fundamental di sequilibrium. Except for th e gold outflow , which
is associated with cla ical deficits, the deficits

:! A la rge meas ure of th e gold outflow m ay be traced
to th e prac ti ce followed by m a ny foreign central
banks of m ai nta ining a fi xed ratio of go ld rese rve to
dollar holdin g . Specul a tive go ld move me nt , on the
oth er ha nd , have dimini hed considerably in th e rece nt p as t a th e probability of deva lua tion of the
doll a r has lesse ned.

Monthly Review •

July-August 1963

9

The Ma rket for

Farm Mortgage Credit
have not been in general agreement concerning the degree of influence
that interest rates have on the supply and demand for credit. Some say there is virtually
no change in the quantity of credit demanded
or supplied wh n interest rates and other economic forces change. Others say there is considerable response.
The response undoubtedly varies among
different markets for credit-that is, for various industries and for different maturities.
Relatively little research has been done to
estimate the responsiveness of supply and demand in various credit markets. This article
summarizes a study designed to measure responsiveness to interest rates and other factor~
in one credit market - the market for farm
mortgage credit. The research on which the
article is based was sponsored jointly by the
U. S. Department of Agriculture and Purdue
University.
The article will discuss the economic model,
or the theoretical considerations upon which
the study was based. It will then present
statistical estimates of the responsiveness of
suppliers and users of farm mortgage credit
to changes in the various economic factors in
the model. Finally, it will discuss some of the
implications of the estimated relationships.
One of at least three concepts could be used
in studying the market for farm mortgage
credit: ( 1) the stock of debt outstanding at
some point during the year; (2) farm mortgage loans closed during the year, a gross flow
concept; or ( 3) farm mortgage loans closed
less repayments, a net flow concept. The con-

E

10

CONOMISTS

cept used in this study was the annual gross
flow of farm real-estate mortgage loans.
As shown in Chart 1, the volume of farm
mortgage debt outstanding in the United States
has fluctuated over the years, but the annual
volume of farm mortgage loan issued- the
fl ow of credit- has been even more erratic.
hart 2 indicat s that the rate of interest also
has fluctuated, though not so much as yields
on preferred stocks, a nonfarm alternative.
AN ECONOMIC MODEL

The economic model for a study of this type
contains the economic factors that are thought
to influence the demand for and supply of
credit.
Demand fo r Credit. The amount of farm
mortgage credit demanded during a given
p'eriod will tend to be inver ely related to the
Chart 1
OUTSTANDING FARM REAL-ESTATE DEBT ON
JANUARY 1, AND ANNUAL GROSS FLOW
OF FARM REAL-EST ATE CREDIT
Billions of Dollars

Billions of Dollars
4

16

3

12

Debt Outstond i n9
✓

(Ltft Scolt)

8

2

4

Flow of Credit
(Ri9hl Scale)
o._,_._..__.__._.___..__._.__._.__._._._._._,_._~..___._,._._..-L.L.,._._~_..............._~ o

1920

'30

'40

SOURCE: U. S. Department of Agriculture .

'50

'60

Farm Mortgage Credit
Chart 2

AVERAG E RATE OF INTEREST ON CURRENTLY
NEGOTIATED FARM MORTGAGE LOANS
AND YIELDS ON PREFERRED STOCKS
Per Cent
8

Per Cent
8

Farm Mortgage Rate

6

6

//
4

4

Stock Yields
2

0
1920

2

LLJ

c 1 1

LI,
' 0

1 1 l

I

I

I

11

l

I

'40

I

I

I

I

J l I,

l,

'50

1

J

1J

I

J L

0
'60

SOURCE : Purduo University ; USDA; and Standard and Poor's Security Prlco I ndox Record.

average rate of interest on farm mortgage loans
closed during the period. With a higher average rate, a smaller volume of loans would be
closed, other things being equal. The question
is how much smaller. An estimate of this comes
later in the article. The rationale for expecting
a negative relationship rests on the proposition
that with a lower rate of interest farmers will
invest more in their businesses, if other conditions are unchanged.
The amount of internal funds available to
farmers will al o influence the amount of credit
demanded. If the amount of investment in such
farm items as new equipment and buildings is
relatively stable, or largely independent of
short-run changes in farm income, then a
negative relationship should be expected between the supply of internal funds within agriculture and the quantity of credit demanded.
An increase in agriculture's internal funds
brought about, say, by an increase in farm income, would be expected to decrease the demand for er dit. Thi a sumes that farmers do
not us for living expenses all of the increase
in income and that at least part of the saving
is invested in agriculture rather than in nonfarm alternatives.
Monthly Review • July-August 1963

Economic logic suggests two additional variables likely to influence the demand for farm
mortgage credit. First, changes in farm wage
rates probably change the demand for credit.
As farm wage rates rise, other things being
equal, capital equipment will be substituted for
labor and this will probably increase the demand for credit. Second, changes in technology
may change the demand for capital resources
and the derived demand for credit.
Supply of Credit. The supply of long-term
credit to agriculture is postulated to be positively related to the farm mortgage rate of interest, relative to the nonfarm rate. Other
things being equal, increasing quantities of
agricultural cred it per unit of time will be supplied at succ sively higher relative rates of interest, and vice versa.
Operationally, a problem arises as to how to
measure the average nonfarm rate of interest.
The ideal would be a weighted average of the
rates or yields on all alternatives in the economy, but this is not available. The practical
solution is to use the return on an immediate
alternative to farm mortgage loans-such as
Government bond yields, corporate bond yields,
or the yield on corporate equities-to represent the nonfarm rate. Government bonds are
an entirely different category of risk for lenders
than farm mortgage loan . Standard and Poor's
index of yields on preferred stocks was used
in the statistical analysis since, in many respects, preferred stocks represent a degree of
investor risk similar to farm mortgage loans.
The supply of loanable funds in the economy
is partly a function of the rate of saving and
changes in the money supply. The supply of
credit, or loanable funds, to a major industry
of an economy would be influenced by these
same variables, although different industries
may be affected differently. It would be expected that the supply of credit to agriculture
would be increased with an increase in the rate
of national saving and with an increase in the
supply of money.
11

Farm Mortgage Credit

The supply of credit offered to agriculture is
postulated to be a function of lenders' expectations concerning the ability of farmers to rep ay . It is not known how lenders formulate
expectations. Perhaps they consider "real"
prices of farm products as an indicator. The
hypothesis is tested using the ratio of the index
of prices received by farmers for all farm products to th e index of prices p aid for items used
in production as a meas ure of rea l farm prices.
It was also hypothesized that lenders consider th e value of agriculture's assets in deciding how much credit to extend to the industry.
T he value of total farm assets is included as a
variable in th supply relation.
The influ nee of eac h o f th variab les on
the supp ly and demand for farm mortgage
ere lit was estim ated in a m odel which permits
estimating th e separa te influence of each variable, taking into account the simultaneous influence of all the other variables being considered. Estimates were computed by using
annual data for the period 1921 to 1959.
ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF THE
STATISTICAL RESULTS

Statistical studies of credit m arkets generate
useful knowledge about important causal factors and their direction of influence, as well as
estimates of the degree of responsiveness of
both suppl iers and use rs of credit to changes
in different economic forces. Such knowledge
has implications for policy formulation.
Estimates of the degree of responsiveness of
suppliers and users are called elasticities. In
the study being reported, the estimated elasticities of the variables, together with the observed
fluctuations or changes in the variables over
time, provide a basis for unde r tanding shifts
in th e upply and dema nd for fa rm mortgage
credit. This gives insight into the important
economic forces at work, and shows the manner in which the farm mortgage m arket is related to both the agricultural sector and the
nonfarm sectors of the economy.
12

The estimated elasticities of the economic
variables in the model are presented in Table
1. The elasticity of demand with respect to
the interest rate, minus 2.29, indicates that if
all other variables are constant a 1 per cent
change in the interest rate would cause an
opposite change of 2.29 per cent in the quantity of farm mortgage credit demanded. More
specifically, a 5 per cent dec rease in the farm
mortgage interest rate, say from 5.00 to 4.75
per cent, would be associated with an 11 per
cent increase in the volume of credit demanded.
The same interpretation is applied to changes
in th e other vari ables. For instance, a 1 per
c nt increase in the farm wage rate would be
as ·o ·iatcd with a I .49 per cent increase in th e
demand ror farm mortgage cred it.
he stati sti cal results suggest that short-run
flu ctu ations in the volume of farm mortgage
credit stem more from dem and forces than
from changes in supply. This is in contrast to
Klaman's finding in the residential mortgage
market. H e shows rather convincingly that supply rather than demand has determined volume and price of residential mortgage credit. 1
Two fac tors are probably important in explaining thi s difference. F irst, capital form ation in ag ri cul ture is la rgely financed internally
from gro s fa rm income, with les dependence
on ex ternal capital or cred it. Second, th e role
of the intern al fund s variable is important in
understanding why flu ctu atio ns in the farm
mortgage credit market are largely initiated by
demand. The results indicate that the demand
for farm mortgage credit is relatively responsive to changes in internal funds. (An elasticity
larger than one lmplies th at ch anges in internal
funds prompt a greater th an proportional
chan ge in th e volume of credit demanded.) ln
addition , int rn al fund are th e m ost volatile of
th e demand hifters in th e short-run, with 7 .5
1 S.

B. Kl a m a n, The Postwar Residential M ort[!,age
Market , Princeton University Press , Princeton , New

Jersey, 1961.

Farm Mortgage Credit
Table 1
ELASTICITIES AND FLUCTUATIONS OF
DEMAND AND SUPPLY VARIABLES
Average
Annu al
Short-Run
Perce ntage
Variable
Elasticity
Fluctuation
Demand
Interest rate
- 2.29
+2 .2
Internal funds
- 1.37
+7.5
Technology
- 1.96
+5.4
Farm wage rate
+1.49
+ 5.9
Supply
Interest rate
+1.51
+1.8
Yield differential
+0.14
+10.0
National saving
+0.20
+19.4
Change in the money su pply
23.0*
+0.16
Farm pri ces
+0.22
+5.5
Farm assets
I 0.23
-! 5.6
'1111 Is an averag • of Ilic pcrccnlag, of 1he s co ne! dill rcnce,
sin e' the varIalllc I~ thr first d1ffc rcn c (change) of the mon y
supply .
NOT : Demand elasticities and flul tuatIon s wer• estimated with
data from 1921 to 1959 , upply, from 1935 to 1959. Te chnology
wa s measured by an unpublished revIsIon of the index published
in graphi c form tn T. T. Stout and V. W. Ruttan, "Regio nal Pattern s of Technologi ca l Change in American Agriculture," Journal
of Farm Economics , May 1958.

per cent average annual fluctuation. Coupled
with the high elasticity, this suggests that fluctu ations in internal funds are a main cau e of
fluctuation in the quantity of mortgage credit
sought by farmers.
The concJu ion th a t short-run fluctuations in
internal fund s arc negatively related to the
quantity of credit suggests th at with a decrease
in int rnal fund gross inv strncnt tend to be
maintained by using more credit. The volatility of farm income and the relative shortrun stability of investment then explain much
of th e fluctu atio n in the market for far m mortgage credit.
These relationships also go a long way in explaining the prevalance of "internal credit rationing" among farm people, or the tendency
for many farmers to use les credit than i available to th em . 1f gross invc tmcnt and con umpti n by farmer tend to be relatively stable in
the hort run , and farm income tends to be
comparatively volatile, th en credit demand of
farmer tend to be a residual source of fund s
that fluctuate in the opposite direction from
Monthly Review •

July-August 1963

internal funds. 1n other words, farmers do not
borrow as much at a given point in time as
would seem to be economically rational so that
they may have borrowing power to draw on
when incomes temporarily decline. In this way,
they can maintain investment and con umption
pattern s bas d on longer-run considerations.
The stimated ela ticitic for both the farm
wage rate and tcchn logy provide in ight into
the substitution process within th e agricultural
industry. The demand for farm mortgage credit
is relatively responsive to ch anges in the farm
wage ra te, and it i rel ated po itively. This sugges ts that capital equipm ent, with a derived demand for credit , t nds t be substituted for
labor with rise s in wag rates, and vice versa.
Fluct ua tion s in th e rea l farm wage rate hav
been co nsidcrabl , with sizab le dec rea ses during th e depres ion and increa s during World
War 11. lf efforts to increase the rate of economic
growth a re successful, and if wage rates rise
with growth, the elasticity suggests additional
substitution of capital for labor and, in turn, an
increase in the demand for credit to finance it.
Changes in technology have also been a contributing factor to changes in the quantity of
credit demanded. The output-increa sing effects
of technical change are such that increases in
tec hnology in agriculture lead to decreases in
the agg r ga te demand for long-term credit. The
estimated ela ticity refl ects th general need to
tra nsfer re ourccs out of agriculture as the level
of technology increases. It suggests that technology is substituted for capital as well as for
labor; that is, that technology in agriculture has
tended to be both capital-saving and laborsaving.
A classic example of an increase in technology in agriculture is the development of
hyb rid corn , which ha s made pos ible significant increases in output per unit of input. Jt
now takes le s land , labor, and capital to produce a given quantity of corn . This concept of
technology differs from the less precise but perhaps more widely held idea that Jinks increased

13

Farm Mortgage Credit

mechanization with increased technology. In
the framework of this study, increased mechanization is considered either an addition to
capital equipment or a substitution of capital
for labor, not an increase in technology as
such. This difference in definition must be
understood in interpreting the elasticity for
technology, because it i the former concept of
technology that the index used in this study
purports to measure.
The statistical results suggest that the demand for long-term farm credit is interest elastic, or very responsive to changes in the interest rate. However, average annual fluctuation
in the farm mortgag rate f interest have be n
small historically, even th ugh f r m y ar
the hang wa ub tantial. In g neral , then ,
fluctuations in the quantity of credit demanded
have stemmed largely from causes other than
changes in the rate of interest.
In interpreting the elasticity of demand with
respect to the rate of interest, it is necessary
to keep in mind that the quantity variable is
the gross volume of farm mortgage loans issued, including loans to refinance existing debt.
During periods when interest rates were lower
than they had been previously, some farmers
may have refinanced at the new lower rates.
This would tend to increa e the volume of farm
mortgage loans closed during the period without changing the volume of outstanding debt.
The result is that the elasticity implied from
using the gross flow as a measure of the volume of credit could be expected to be larger
than an elasticity obtained from using net
changes in the stock of outstanding debt.
In addition, the "price" of farm mortgage
credit manifests itself in more than one dimension. Besides the rate of interest, factors such
as the term of the loan and size of downpayment are subject to market determination. In
this study, the rate of interest was the only price
factor considered. To the extent that the various price factors move together, the rate of interest may serve as an indicator for all of them.
14

The analysis, however, probably overstates the
true price effect of the interest rate on both
credit demand and supply.
The statistical results suggest that supplies
of farm mortgage money are also relatively responsive to changes in the farm mortgage rate
of interest. However, they indicate a much
smaller re ponse to nonfarm interest rates, as
mea ured by differences in the yield between
farm mortgage loans and preferred stocks.
Nevertheless, the average annual percentage
fluctuation of the differential- 10 per cent-is
sufficiently large that shifts in the quantity of
mortgage money supplied in respon e to changing r lativ intere t rat s d occur, v n though
th lasti ity may be low. Analysis of thi s variabl is limit d by l w tati tical signifi ance f r
its coefficient, however, and inferences hould
be drawn with caution.
The impact that national saving and changes
in the stock of money have on the supply of
farm mortgage credit is of interest to policymakers . While national saving is not directly
subject to willful control, a certain amount of
control does exist over the economy's money
supply. The statistical results indicate that the
supply of farm mortgage credit is not very responsive with respect to both national saving
and chang s in the money supply. The relatively large average annual percentage fluctuations in these variables, however, indicate that
noticeable hift in supply conditions do result
from these factors.
CONCLUDING COMMENTS

Persons concerned with supplies of credit
may be interested in estimated future amounts
of farm mortgage loans closed per year and
estimated interest rates. Are significant changes
likely over the n xt several year ? The elasticities, or degrees of respon ivene to economic
forces , indicated by this study may be used to
estimate the effects of projected changes in the
economy. For instance, if farm wage rates continue to increase at an average annual rate

farm Mortgage Credit

about as they have during the recent past,
what effect will this have on the annual vomme
of loans closed and on farm mortgage interest
rates?
In addition to wage rates, agricultural technology and the rate of national saving would
each be expected to increase over time with
normal growth of the economy. However, little,
if any, logical reason exists for expecting either
pronounced increase or decreases over a long
period for the rest of the economic forces considered in this study.
One basis for estimating the effects might be
to assume th at farm wage rate , agricultural
technology, and the rate of national saving will
ca h continue to increase, on the average, at
the am annual rate that they did during a
recent period. The other factors will be assumed to be constant for estimating purposes.
While they will certainly continue to fluctuate
from year to year, and therefore will cause
fluctuations in the annual volume of credit and
interest rates, these other factors, taken separately, will probably average out over several
years without creating a trend in volume or interest rates.
During the 1950's, the real farm wage rate
increased an average of 2.5 per cent per year,
agricultural technology by 1. 7 per cent, and
real national saving by 2.25 per cent per year.
Estimates of future farm mortgage credit requirements and interest rates are made by pro-

Table 2

ESTIMATED AVERAGE ANNUAL CHANGE IN
FUTURE VOLUME OF FARM MORTGAGE
LOANS CLOSED AND AVERAGE FARM
MORTGAGE RATE OF INTEREST
Total
Annual
Change

Annual Change
Resulting from Increases in:
Tech- National
Wage
nology Saving

olume (in millions
of 1954 dollars)
Interest rate
(per cent)

+9.7 +37.o
0 + 0.07

Monthly Review •

July-August 1963

- 32.B
-0.06

+s.s
-0.01

jecting into the future these same average annual rates of change and by using the estimated elasticities ot this study. A 2.5 per cent
increase in farm wage rates would be associated
with a $37 million increase in the annual volume of farm mortgage loans closed and with
an increase of 7 basis points (. 07 per cent) in
the average farm mortgage rate of interest. At
the same time, an increase of 1. 7 per cent in
technology would be associated with a $32.8
million decrease in loans closed, and so on.
The cumulative effects of the indicated
changes in wage, technology, and saving would
be an estimated annual increase of $9.7 million
in farm mortgage loans clo cd and no change
in the farm mortgage rate of interest. The c timat d avcrag annual in r ment in loans clo ed
- $9.7 million- i about one half of 1 per cent
of the average annual volume of the 1950's,
which was $1,871 million in terms of 1954
dollars. Recognizing that credit and capital are
not synonymous, this estimate is at least compatible with Tostlebe's prediction that, although the ratios of capital to labor and capital
per farm will rise, growth of farm capital in
the aggregate will occur " ... at an average rate
that is likely to be substantially less than 1
per cent per annum. " 2
The assumption that technology will continue to increase at the same rate it did during
the 1950's may not be realistic. That decade
was one of exceptionally rapid increases in
technology in agriculture. With a slower rate
9f technological change, the increase in the
volume of farm mortgage credit would be
greater.
The estimates are in terms of a constant
price level. To the extent that inflation or deflation is anticipated the estimates should be
adjusted.
2 Alvin S. Tostlebe, Capital in Agriculture: Its Formatidn and Financing Since 1870, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Princeton University Press,
Princeton, New Jersey, 1957, p. 19.

15

BANKING IN THE TENTH DISTRICT

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

District
and

Country
Member
Banks

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

Country
Mem ber
Ban ks

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

Reserve
City
Member
Banks

Country
Member
Banks
-May 1963 Percentage Change From

June 1963 Percentage Change From
States

Deposits

Loans

Deposits

Loans

Country
Member
Banks

May June May June May June May June Apr. May Apr. May Apr. May Apr. May
1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962 1963 1962

Tenth F. R. Dist.
Colorado
Kansas
Missouri *
N bras ka
New Mex ico *
Ok la homa *
Wyoming

+ 3 +9 +2
+4 +12 +3
** + 3
**
2 - 1
+2
H13
t
+ 1
**
** + 3
+ 4 + 10 + 2
**
** + 1

* Tenth District portion only .

+13 +5
+16 + 3
**
+12
+9 +7
+ 14 + 3
**
-J 13
6
+ 13
**
+12

+6
+8
**
+2
+2
**
11
**

+3 + 8
+3 + 13
+4 +6
6
+1
t -5
-j 2
8
- 5 + 11
t +6

** No reserve citi es in this state .

t
+2
**
- 1
+ 1
**
- 1
**

+9
+9
**
2
+ 12
**
+14
**

+1
+2
- 1
+1
-1- 2
13
+2
+3

+13
+16
+ 13
+ 12
H 13
I 15
+ 13
H- 12

- 2
- 1
**
- 2
1
**
- 2
**

+4
+5
**
+ 1
-j 1
**
8
**

--

-

1 +6
1 +10
2 +5
1 +6
4
3
- 1
12
1
8

t

tL ess than 0.5 per cent.

+5

--

PRICE INDEXES, UNITED STATES
Index

June
1963

May
1963

Apr.
1963

June
1962

May
1962

Consumer Price Index (1957-59 = 100). ___ ___ ____ _
Wholesale Price Index (1957-59 = 100). ___ ________
Prices Received by Farmers (1910-14 = 100) ....
Prices Paid by Farmers (1910-14 = 100). ________

106.6
100.3
241
311

106.2
100.0r
240
311

106.2
99.7
242
311

105.3
100.0
239
306r

105.2
100.2
241r
307r

r R vi sed .

--

--

TENTH DISTRICT BUSINESS INDICATORS
Value of
Check
Payments

District

Percentage change from prev ious year
Metropolitan
Areas

June
1963

Tenth Federal Reserve District__ _____ _
Denver ___________ ___ _________ __________________
Wichita ____ ____ ___ ________________________ _____
Kansas City ______ _________ __ _______ ______ ____
Omaha ______ _________ _______ ____ _______________

- 2
0
- 5
0
- 6
- 1
- 9

Oklahoma City ___________ ___ ____________ __ _

16

--Valu e of
Department
Store Sales

and Principal

Tulsa -- --- -- --- - -- ---- - - -. -- -- - -- ------ --- --- -- -

-

May
1963
+4
+7
- 3
+4
+5
+11
- 2

Six
Months
1963
+2
+3
- 3
+3
+4
+7
- 5

June
1963

May
1963

Six
Months
1963

+5
+2
+7
+12
+5
+3
+5

+2
+6
- 5
+5
- 3
+2
+2

+4
+4
0
+7
+2
+4
+6

--

--

--