View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

January-February 1966

LY REVIEW

International Monetary Reform • . • . . • page

3

Current Debate on the Term Structure
of Interest Rates • . • • . • . • • page 10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF KANSAS CITY

Subscriptions to the MONTHLY R EVIEW are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City , Kansas City, M issouri 64106. Permission is granted to reproduce any material in
this publication.

Toward an Understanding of the Dialogue on

International Monetary Reform
By Sheldon W. Stahl

T

INTERNATIONAL monetary system is a
majo r ele m nt in our cv ryday life, operating as it does to enhance the commercial and
financial interdependence of the free world's
community of nation .. Increasingly, however,
this payments mechanism has come under criticism from many quarters. In the United States,
and in other major industrial and financial centers of the free world, a great deal of effort
has been devoted to formulating proposals for
reforming the international payments mechanism so that it will do a better job of meeting
the require ment of a growing level of world
commerce a nd e xchange. In view of the interest in this topic, the n, this article exami nes the
international monetary payments system in an
effort to provide the fundamental background
necessary for a meaningful understanding of
the issues involved in any proposed reform of
the system.

Probably one of the more familiar functions
of the international monetary payment mechan ism is that of enabl ing trade and exchange
to take place across national boundaries, in
much the same way as our domestic monetary
system enables us to conduct trade and exchange freely among ourselves in the United
States. While this aspect probably is taken for

grant d by most of us, there arc certain other
requirements which mu st be satisfied by the
international payments mechanism to make it
acceptab le to the community of trading nations.
In addition to facilitating trade and exchange
among nations, an international monetary system must provide for some means of financing
temporary imbalances which may arise between international receipts and expenditures.
This function may be described as providing
international liquidity- a term open to many
interpretations. Finally, the international financial mechanism should operate in harmony
with the goal of total public policy. That is,
the goal of attainment or maintenance of
equ ilibrium in a country's international balance
of payments ought to be regarded as one of
several goals of national policy. Other goals,
such as the optimal utilization of a country's
economic resources or maintaining its national
security, should be afforded priority as well.
The task of an acceptable international payments mechanism, therefore, is to enable these
goals to be pursued simultaneously without
undue strain, or without re orting to an unsatisfactory compromise that sacrifices one or more
of these goa ls in order to attain the others.
Although the manner of financing international transactions is not as simple in actual
operation as the description which follows,
nonetheless this will help the reader to grasp

January-February 1966

3

IIE

FUNCTIONS AND MECHANICS OF
INTERNATIONAL PAYMENTS

Monthly Review

•

International Monetary Reform

the fundamentals involved in the payments
process. The overriding principle rests upon
the fact that, where international trade takes
place, international payments are required. In
the case of domestic trade, th e disch arge of
debts between the trader involves only an exchange of domestic currency, or a check drawn
on the debtor's bank and given to the creditor.
In the case of foreign trade, however, since the
debtor and creditor reside in different countries with different units of exchange, the matter of payment is not as sim ple. Doll ars do not
ordinarily circulate freely abroad, nor does
fo reign exchange generally circulate in the
United States. Thus , in th e case of th e purchasl;
of a foreign good by an Am e rica n, do llars may
not be an accep table means of payment. Conversely, in the case of a foreign purchase of
U.S. merchandise, the foreigner's currency may
not be acceptable to the U.S. creditor. As a
consequence, there must be some device to
enable traders to convert their domestic currencies into foreign currencies.
It may now be asked how the international
monetary payments mechanism operates to
convert domestic money into foreign money .
As an example, let us suppo e that an American purchases a Briti sh good. This necessitates
payment in pounds ste rling to the British exporter. Although there arc various types of
credit instruments used in conducting intern:itional trade, it is not necessary to take account of them here. To secure the needed
foreign exchange, the American importer pays
dollars-writes a check-to his bank. Let us
assume that the bank is located in New York,
one of the major U.S. financial centers. The
New York bank would then pay to the London bank of the British exporter the required
amount in either U. S. dollars or United Kingdom pounds sterling. Finally, the pounds sterling are paid to the British exporter by the
London bank. It is important to note that the
entire process was carried out by the banks
in both countries acting as intermediaries with4

out any doll ars or pounds actually crossing the
ocea n, yet its effect was to increase the amount
of pounds held by England and to reduce the
amou nt of dollars held by the United States.
Just as smaller city banks or country b anks
in the United State have correspondent arrangements with banks in the larger financial
cen te rs, th e major banks of the different countries mainta in a correspondent relationship
with each other by holding accounts in the
banks of the various fin anci al centers. By building up or draw ing down th ese accounts, international fin anci al payments arc transacted.
That is, banks may build up their fore ign bal ances by purchasing such cred it inst ruments
as com merc ial bills of exc han ge from expo rteL;
conve rse ly, th ese foreign balances arc reduced
when banks sell c red it instruments to impo rters.
Thus, imports create a demand for foreign
exchange, while exports create a supply of
foreign exchange .
Although the major part of foreign exchange
transactions stems from the import and export
of goods or merchandise, there are many other
kinds of international transactions involving the
payments mechanism. In the U. S. b alance of
payments, which records th e total amounts of
U.S. international transactio ns, mercha ndise imports and exports are referred to as "visibles"
and are handled for accounting purposes in a
broad gro uping called "current account. " The
current account also records transactions involving " invisibles. " These consist of such items
as income on investments made abroad, tourist
expenditures for services, transportation expenditures on foreign carriers, and certain other
miscellaneous services. Another major group of
accounts in the balance of payments is "unilate ral transfers,'' which record the flow of gifts.
These transfers arc furth er classified as e ither
private remittances or Government grants. The
"capital account' ' involves another major category of international financial transactions.
This major account records the vast lending
and borrowing activities which take place be-

International Monetary Reform

tween the United States and the rest of the
world and may be classified as either "private"
or " G overnment" in term s of origin, as well
as either "short-term" or "long-term" in terms
of maturity. The final major account in the
balance of payments is the "gold" account
which records the purchase or sale of gold.
The reason for tre ati ng gold separately should
become clearer when the question of international reserves is discussed. Thus, it can be
seen that the payments mechanism plays a
larger role than merely facilitating the movement of real goods between nations .
Turning to a closer consideration of th e
liquidity function of the payments mechani sm ,
it shoulJ be noted that primary concern in thi s
article is directed at th e liquidity po ition of
central banks or governments , rather than the
"private'' liquidity position of parties or firms
engaged in international commerce. Consequently, "official" liquidity may be broadly
defined as all the resources which the monetary authorities of a country may have at their
disposal for settling its international accounts.
Liquidity so defined includes a country's international reserves of foreig n exchange and gold,
as wcl I as its ability to borrow reserves when
the need arises.
It should be recogn ized th at it would be very
difficult to define, unambiguously, what "sufficient'' li4uidity really is, since, as the current
debate on the subject has revealed, the matter
of just how much is sufficie nt is subject to a
wide range of interpretations, depending upon
whether a country is either a net debtor or a
net creditor on its international financial accounts. Nonetheless, o ne generaliza tion may be
advanced. Just as our domestic monetary system regulate s the supply of money and credit
in an attempt to avoid ei th er inflationary or
deflationary di slocations, the international
monetary sys tem must function in such a way
as to allow the world community to operate
at the most optimal levels of resource utilization without erratic gyrations. Similarly, in proMonthly Review

•

January-February 1966

viding this desired level of liquidity to the
world community , the payments mechanism
should operate so as to:
offset increases and decreases in the
des ire of people to hoard liquid assets at
given levels of inte rest rates and should be
able to prevent shifts in the form in which
liquid assets are held from altering the
total amount of the assets .1
That is, th e level of international liquidity
should be independent of the form in which
international reserves a re held by different
co untries:
Just as a domestic monetary syste m
shou ld be able to offset th e effects on
domestic mon ey supply of conversions between currency a nd bank deposits, the
international system should b e able to
offset the effects on international reserves
of conversions between gold and foreign
exchange reserves and among foreign exchange reserves denominated in different
currencies.
2

Having generally spelled out the functions and
mech anics of the internation al monetary payme nts system, we m ay now turn to a closer
look a t the actua l unde rlying arrangements of
the present system. Only by understanding
th ese basic arrangements as they have evolved
since World W a r lI can one grasp the key
role played by the doll ar in the free world's
monetary system, a nd the issues involved in
the continuing di alogue on monetary reform.

THE PRESENT ARRANGEMENTS
The present international monetary system
generally is referred to as a "gold-exchange"
standard. In contrast with the "pure-gold"
sta ndard, which fell into di suse following
1
Wa lt er S. Salant, "Does the International Moneta ry
System Need Reform?" (The Brookings Institution, Reprint 82 [Washington , D. C., 1964]), pp. 5-6.

"Ibid .

5

International Monetary Reform

World War I, the international reserves of
central banks or national monetary authorities
now include liquid claims against certain reserve currency countries as well as holdings of
gold by the monetary authorities. As this system has evolved since World War II, it has
been aided by the growth of such international
financial institutions as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), along with the development
of imaginative innovations and increased cooperation by the leaders of the free world's
financial community.
Tracing these developments in more detail,
one should recall that, at the close of World
War If, the United States, almost alone,
eme rged relatively unscathed in terms of physical damage to its eco nomy. This contra ted
with the war-torn eco nomies of Continental
Europe, England, and the major powers of the
Far East, notably Japan. The immediate task
at hand was to restore these nations to a state
where their material survival could be assured.
Only the United States possessed adequate
physical and financial resources to markedly
accelerate restoration of these economies. During the postwar period, U.S. dollars and goods
flowed abroad to help accompl i h the task, and ,
by the mid-I 950's, an observable change had
taken place. The productive capacity of these
countrie had been largely reestablished; the
normalization of former trade patterns was well
underway; and their increased competitive viability was reflected in their improved balanceof-payments positio n with respect to the United
States. By the end of 1958, currency convertibility had been reestablished in Western Europe. The IMF, which had come into being as
a result of th e Bretton Woods Conference in
1944, had bee n· firmly established as an international lender of short-term reserves to cope
with temporary imbalances which might crop
up between trading nations. In short, by the
end of the 1950's, the world community had
been visibly strengthened and largely was able
to stand on its own.
6

Beginning with 1958, the recovery clearly
had entered a new phase. The b alance-of-payments deficits of the U nited States ass umed
greater magnitudes than in earlier years, with
the result that dollars began to accumulate in
central banks abroad in the form of increased
reserve balances. The deficits which the United
States had incurred almost continuously since
1950 were beg inning to be regarded with increasing concern-a concern which was manifested by a stepped-up conversion of dollars
into go ld by foreign central banks. The resulting large U.S. go ld ou tfl ows served to raise
se ri ous questio ns abo ut the sta bility of, and
confide nce in , th e dollar. Beca use of the crucial
position of th e U.S. dollar in world monetary
affairs, these development. have resulted in a
critical reexamination of th e international payments mechanism whose recent performance
has, in the view of many observers. become
un satisfactory in terms of its ability to carry
out its va ried functions in a substantially
changed wo rld economic climate.
Under the present system, the United States
is committed to buy gold at $3 5 per ounce and,
upon request, to sell it to central banks of
fore ign nations at that price, plus a small transportation and handling charge. The dollar,
th en, is firmly committed internationally to
gold and the Government is obli ged to honor
all requests for gold from foreign central banks
at the fi xed rate of $3 5 per ounce. For the
most part, the exchange values of other major
currencies are linked to the dolla r by fixing
their values in term s of dollar equivalents. To
support these excha nge rates-which are fixed
within a ve ry narrow range of fluctu ationthe respective countries either sell or purchase
their own c urrencies, as the case m ay b e, if
and when th e demand for th e ir own currencies,
in terms of so me foreign currency, becomes
excessive , o r, conversely, if the demand for
foreign currencies, in term s of their own currency , beco mes excessive. For example, if the
demand by U.S. importers for British pounds

International Monetary Reform

sterling were to rise as a result of increased
British exports to the United States, this would
act to bid up the dollar price of pounds . In
this instance, the British monetary authorities
- in order to prevent the exchange rate from
rising outside its fixed upper limit-would sell
pounds sterling on the exchange market and
thereby would increase the supply of pounds.
This would serve to lower its price. In the case
of an increase in the demand for U.S. dollars
by United Kingdom importers as a result of
increased U.S. exports to Great Britain, the
procedure on the part of British monetary
authorities would be reversed. However, in
order to purchase their own currency for support purposes, countries mu t offer in exchang
some highly acceptable international liquid resource; and, whe n selling their currency, they
will expect payment in this same medium . The
resources which have found such international
acceptance for this purpose include gold and
"key" currencies-notably U.S. dollars and, to
a lesser extent, British pounds sterling.
However, gold and reserve currencies do not
provide the sole basis of international liquidity
to buttress exchange rates or finance a payments imbalance. As mentioned earlier another
significant element in the international liquidity
spectrum-though quantitatively less important
than owned reserves--consists of "borrowed"
reserves and includes the borrowing rights of
the 102 members of the IMF. In addition to
the subscribed quotas of the Fund, the potential
resources of the Fund were expanded in 1961
by a General Borrowing Arrangement executed
between the Fund and 10 major industrial
3
countries.
Under this arrangement, these
countries agreed to lend their currencies to the
Fund for its use in advancing loans to any
of them incurring a deficit, if, based upon
subscribed quota levels, the Fund was unable
3Thes_e countries are referred to as the "Group of Ten,"
and include Belgium, Canada, Germany, France, Italy,
Netherlands, Sweden, United Kingdom, Japan, and the
United States.

Monthly Review

•

January-February 1966

to supply the necessary currency or currencies
required by the deficit member. Superimposed
on this base is the more recent increase in
Fund quotas resulting from the review and
adjustment of the members' quotas which takes
place at 5-year intervals as provided for in the
Fund's Articles of Agreement.
Holdings of convertible currencies have been
increa ed further in the past 4 to 5 years, as
a result of the creation of a network of bilateral currency exchange agreements between
the Federal Reserve System and the central
banks of a number of the more highly industrialized countric of the world. These are the
so-called "swap" agreements which serve to
provide short-term credit up to agreed amounts
to the wap partners for periods of from 3 to
9 months. Under these arra ngements, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is authorized
to conduct transactions for the System Open
Market Account in such foreign currencies and
within certain limits as may be specified by the
Federal Open Market Committee. Still another
element in international liquidity, and a quite
recent innovation, is the issuance of special
U.S. Government securities which are nonmarketable, and of either hort-term or medium-term maturities. These bonds are, for the
most part, denominated in the currency of the
holder a nd may be converted on short notice
by the holder into cash. The incentive to hold
these bonds stems from the fact that not only
do they earn interest but, by being denominated in terms of the currency of the holder,
they insure the holder against the exchange
risk of devaluation. These bonds are commonly known as "Roosa" bonds, since, in his
former capacity as Under Secretary of the
Treasury for Monetary Affairs, Robert V.
Roo sa was credited with their innovation.
A of June 30, 1965, the free world's official monetary reserves were reported to equal
approximately $69 billion. Of this amount, gold
accou nted for $41 billion, while total holdings
of foreign exchange ( assets denominated in
7

International Monetary Reform

convertible currencies) comprised approximately $21 billion. An additional $5 billion
represented the IMF position of various countries. The balance consisted of about $1 billion
of Roo a bonds, and about $700 million in
foreign currencie obtained under swap arrangements. It should be clear, from these
figures, that gold is the single most important
reserve asset and the basic source of international liquidity. Equally apparent is the fact
that currency holdings account for nearly one
third of official monetary reserves, and, therefore , constitute the second mo t important
sou rce of international liquidity. Since the
major share of official monetary reserves is in
the form of either go ld or reserve currenciesprimarily dollars and lesser quantities of pounds
terling-and since these asset are the primary source of international liquidity, one may
ask what determines the total amount of these
official rese rve components as well as the
changes which take place in them.
Newly mined gold and sales by the Soviet
Union to the free world provide the basis for
additions to free world official gold stocks. To
the extent that gold supplied from these sources
exceeds the amount of gold used for industrial
purposes or added to private hoard ,4 the
monet a ry gold stock will grow. From the end
of I 959 through mid-1965, $3.2 billion of gold
was added to the official monetary reserves of
the free world. This accounted for a little more
than one fourth of the total growth of official
monetary reserves during that period .
The magnitude of the other major components of official monetary reserves-the reserve currencies, i.e. , dollars and sterling-is
a function of the amount of these currencies
( or assets denominated in terms of these currencies) held by central banks of countries
' It is unlawful for U. S. citizens to hold gold, although
the existence of free m a rkets for the purchase and sale
of gold is countenanced by a number of countries, with
the result that a considerable portion of the world's gold
stocks finds its way into private hoards.

8

other than the respective reserve currency countries. Thus, it can be seen that this element of
international liquidity can grow only to the extent that the reserve currency countries incur
deficits with the rest of the free world. Conversely, when the re erve currency countries
have surpluses in their balance of payments ,
the volume of international reserves-hence,
international liquidity-declines. Of the approximately $ 11.5 billion increase in official
monetary reserves which took place between
December 31 , 1959, a nd June 30, 1965, $4.5
billion- nearly 40 per cent-of the total expansion was accounted for by increased holdings of foreign exchan ge. The rem a inder of
the increase in monetary reserves during thi s
period-o ther than the 3.2 billion in gold
previously mentioned-was accounted for by
reserve positions in the IMF, currency-swap
arrangements, and Roosa bonds. The sizable
additions to international reserves, in the form
of increased holdings of foreign exchange by
the nonreserve currency countries, was effected
primarily as a consequence of the large and
protracted balance-of-payments deficits of the
United States . During thi s period, the United
States experienced a loss in reserves of more
than 25 per cent, a loss which stemmed directly from its persistent bala nce-of-payments
deficits and subsequent convers ion of dollars
into gold by foreign cent ral ba nks . It should
be pointed out, however, that sizable additions
to the dollar holdings of foreign central banks
during the period served to hold down the
actual gold loss of the United States compared
with what it might have been. One also might
note that the expansive influence of the U. S.
deficit is offset when central banks convert
dollars to go ld . Thus, international reserves
and internation al liquidity are diminished when
reserve currency holder reduce their stocks of
foreign exchange a sets in favor of gold. A
c ritical observation of an international payments system operating largely through vehicle
or key currencies is succinctly made by Salant:

International Monetary Reform

The timing and size of their deficits
have no rational relationship to the needed
expansion in international reserves. Moreover, expansion in these reserves increases
the liquid li abilities of the reserve currency
countries in relation to their liquid assets.
Such increases in liabilities create growi ng
danger-or fear on the part of the holders
-that the reserve currency countries will
be unable to pay off those who wish to
co nvert their holdings into gold or other
currencies, and this, in turn , increases the
lik elih ood that th e holders will actually
want to co nvert. The rese rve currency
countries arc in the position of banks in a
system wit h no central bank; they face a
growth of deposit li abilities payable on
demand and have no mean of increasing
their reserves correspondingly except by
bidding reserve assets away from others .
This situation increases the likelihood that
depos itors will create a run on the bank.
Thus, the holding of re se rves in national
currencies not only fails to provide for a
rati o nal way of increasing this component
of internatio nal reserves, but renders the
system increasingly un stable. 6
SOME FINAL OBSERVATIONS

The record of the prese nt international financi al payments mechanism through the postwar period is mi xe d. Although the more recent
years have revealed certain stresses and strains
present in the system, these should be weighed
against the high degree of international financial cooperation an d inventiveness demon st rated
by the world financial community which permitted the system to function in sp ite of its
shortcomings. Viewed from th e wider per pective of th e entire postwar period, rather than
the last 6 or 7 yea rs, the achievements of the
"Salant. op . cir., pp. 12- 13.

Monthl y Revi ew

•

January-February 1966

international payments mech anism are highly
impress ive. The renai sance of Western Europe
a nd Jap an, the return to curre ncy convertibility,
the tremendou s increase in the volume of world
trade and exchange, and the provision of adequ a te liquidity to accommod ate these developments all attest to the performance of the paymen ts rnechani m .
Thi s impres ive performance, however, must
not detract from th e responsibility of looking
towa rd th e future. The current dialogue revolving about the reform of the inte rnational
payments mecha ni sm is well grounded in tem1
of the implications wh ich mi ght be drawn from
th e record of th e past. The grow th in world
imports in the past 6 years ha far outpaced the
grow th in to tal monetary reserves and the ratio
of monetary reserves to imports has fallen
sharpl y. Recogni zing th e sub stanti al contribution o f the U. S. balance-of-payments deficits
to the over-all increase in fore ign exch ange
holdings and, consequently, to the level of international reserves during the past 6 years, it
can be seen th a t any future success of the
United States in res toring eq uilibrium to its
bal ance of pay ments wi11 erve to curtail the
primary ource of the increase in total moneta ry reserves. The re olve of the Administration to resto re bala nce in th e . S. international
acco unts sho uld provide a continuing and
potent stimul ant to th e search for acceptable
mon etary reforms .
While there is an apparent international consensus a mong th e m ajor industrial nations of
the free world th at there is no shortage of
liquidity at present, their view is less hopeful
a bo ut the adequacy of future liquidity given
ex istin g international financi al arrangements.
Thu , a continuing e ffort toward reform of th e
intern a tional pa yme nts system may be ass ured.
In light of thi s, it is important to have some
fundamental unde rstanding of the issues involved .

9

CURRENT DEBATE ON THE
TERM STRUCTURE Of INTEREST RATES
By Frederick M. Strnble
TllE MONETARY authorities-the Federal Reserve System and the U.S . Treasury-alter the relationship among maturity
yields on Government securities by changing
the maturity composition of Government securitie outstanding? For many years, two different
theories-the expectations theory and the segmented markets theory-have been used as a
basis for answering this question.
The expectations theory contends that a
change in relative supplies of securities with
different maturities will not affect maturity
yield relationships unless, in the process, it
brings about a change in market expectations
of future intere t rates. On the other hand, the
segmented markets theory argues that maturity
yield differentials are caused by an imbalance
between the maturity composition of debt demanded by lenders and supplied by borrowers.
From this it follows that a shift in the maturity
composition of supply will affect relative yields.
The segmented markets theory acknowledges
that market expectations of future interest rates
may be changed as relative supplies in the
various maturity sectors are altered, thus augmenting the change in yield differentials
brought about by this operation. In general,
however, most discussions of the segmented
markets theory have emphasized the direct effects that changes in relative supplies will have
on relative yields apart from any possible
changes which might occur in expectations of

C

10

AN

future interest rates. Discussions of the expecwtions theory similarly have played down the
possible effects that changes in the maturity
composition or debt might have on interest
rate expectations. As a result, the theoretical
controversy has been clearly defined.
Although each of these theoretical positions
has a long history, it seems a safe judgment
that the segmented markets theory has been
and continues to be the theory most generally
accepted by market analysts. However, the
degree of consensus on this question has been
reduced considerably as a result of recent research. Older statements of the expectations
theory have been reinterpreted incorporating
more plau iblc behavioral assumptions and the
more rigorous modern formulations have added
clarity to the meaning of the expectations hypothesis. On an empirical plane, several of the
more sophisticated tests have provided strong
support for the expectations theory.
This article reviews the current state of this
controversy. To simplify the discussion, references to specific studies have been avoided.
The reader interested in pursuing the topic
further is referred to the brief bibliography
of the major works on this question at the end
of this article.

THE SEGMENTED MARKETS THEORY
Although the term, segmented markets, is
used here to identify one theory of the term

Current Debate on the Term Structure of Interest Rates

tructu re of intere t rate , in other discussions
this theory has been identified by several other
terms, includ ing institutional, imperfect substitutes, and hedging. Each refers to a type of
balance sheet deci ionmaking complicated by
legal restrictions and traditional practices such
a the matching of the maturity structure of
one's a ·sets with the maturity structure of one's
liabilitie -pre umably in order to avoid ri k.
It is argued that because major groups of
borrowers and lenders prefer to match assets
and liabilities in thi way, the market for
credit in. trument is partly compartmentalized,
or segmented. according to the maturity of
debt in . truments. As a result, loan with different maturities arc imperfect ub titutes in
the .1ggregatc a. well a. for individual inve tor
and borrower group in the ense that different rates of return arc required to hold securities with different maturities, and also, the
size of the difference in rates of return varies
with changes in the maturity composition of
as et portfolio . Thi means that maturity yield
differentials are determined by an imbalance
between the maturity structure of debt demanded by inve tors and the maturity structure
of debt supplied by borrower .
Since the alternative theoretical position to
be di . cussed in the next section of this article
:tres. es the importance of interest rate expectations, it i. worthwhile to note that di cus. ions of the segmented markets theory generally have limited the influence of interest
rate expectation
to possible effects that
changes in expectation of future interest rates
can have on current interest rate relationships.
This is quite different from the primary role
as igned to expectations in the expectations
theory . For, briefly, the expectation theory
a. :crt that current difference in the maturity
yields exist because the market expects interest
rates to change over future periods of time .
Moreover, it contends that it is possible to
determine from a given yield relation hip the
pattern of future intere t rates predicted by
Monthly Review • January - February 1966

the market. Di cussions of the segmented markets theory have either ignored this issue or
have asserted that a current yield structure is
not affected by interest rate expectations in
this manner.
Several fact appear to provide strong support for the segmented markets theory. In
particular, the behavior of many institutional
lenders accord with the a sumption about
investor behavior made by this theory. For
example, commercial bank portfolios are heavily weighted with as ets of short maturity while
as. ets held in the portfolio of in urance companies and . avings and loan in titution are
predominantly long term. Many example of
borrower behavior al. o may be cited which
conform to the a .. umption underlying the
egmented market theory. Con umers usually
finance purcha es of houses with long-term
mortgages and purchases of less durable consumer goods with shorter-term debt agreements. In a . imilar manner, busines firms
generally attempt to match the maturity of
their liabilities with the durability of their assets
-inventories are financed by short-term loans
while plant and equipment inve tments are
financed by longer-term loan . The e examples
clearly arc far from exhaustive. Presumably,
it is the perva ivene s of such practices that
makes the egmented markets theory o compelling to many analyst , particularly tho e
involved in the day-to-day operation of credit
markets.
Against thi evidence supporting the segmented markets theory, the results of recent
empirical studies have been surprising. One
study after another designed to measure the
effects of the maturity composition of debt on
maturity yi Id differentials wa unable to discern a ubstantial relationship between these
variable . Con. equently, these findings have
cast doubt on the segmented market theory.
These empirical studies have not been entirely convincing, however. In attempting to
estimate the implications of changing supply
11

Current Debate on the

conditions, all but one study ignored the possible consequences of simultaneous shifts in demand. Most studies assumed that the demand
for loans with different maturities remains
relatively stable over time. If this is the case,
then changes in maturity yield differentials can
be attributed to changes in relative supply. If,
however, conditions of demand change concurrently with changes in relative supplies, this
would reduce the correlation between relative
supplies and relative yields. The failure of most
studies to consider this problem reduces their
significance. The fact that the one study which
did consider this problem came to essentially
the sa me conclu ion s as the others, however,
suggests that failure to consider this contingency may not have been an important deficiency. In addition, on an a priori basis, it
see ms unlikely that changes in demand would
vary inversely with changes in supply so consistently that an actual relationship between
relative supplies and relative yields would be
entirely obscured.
THE EXPECTATIONS THEORY

The consistent findings that changes in relative supplies of securities with different maturities have only small effects on maturity
yield differentials not only cast doubt on the
seg mented markets theory, they also provide
indirect support for an alternative theoretical
explanation of the term structure of interest
rates. Both the pure expectations theory and
the version of this theory which contends that
liquidity preference is partly responsible for
the establishment of maturity yield differentials,
agree on one vital point: that the maturity
structure of outstanding deb t does not affect
the maturity structure of yields.
The basic assertion of the pure expectations
theo ry is that loans with different maturities ,
that are similar in all other respects , are perfect substitutes to investors in the aggregate.
This means that the relationship among current prices a nd yields on securities with differ12

ing maturities are adjusted so that the rates of
return on this debt-calculated to include capital gains and losses where applicable-are expected to be equal for any given period of time ;
and that th e maturity composition of outstanding debt does not affect maturity yield differentials. From these assertions it follows that maturity yield differential s exist because the market is expecting interest rates to change over
the future-to change in such a way that appa rent differences in return which might be
inferred from yield differentials are wiped out
in the process- rather than because it expects
the rates of return on loan s with different
maturities to differ. Moreover, any proccs.
which alters the maturity compo. ition of investor portfolios, but docs not change expectation s of future interest rates, will not affect
the existing structure of yields on loans with
different maturities .
It should be emphasized that loans with
different maturities may be perfect substitutes
in the aggregate even though not every investor views them as such. Credit markets may
be dominated by a relatively small but wellfinanced gro up of traders who treat loans of
different maturities as perfect substitutes. If
this i the case, the investors , whose actions
are offset by these traders , would have no
influence on security prices and yields. Security
prices and yields would be established by
traders willing to adjust their holdings of securities with different maturities until they expect
the realized rates of return on the securities to
be equal over any given period.
Still another possibility exists for rationalizing that certain securities in the aggregate are
perfect substitutes. The preferences of different
investor groups may overlap so that all securities within one maturity range may be perfect
substitutes for one investor group, while securities in another maturity range may be perfect substitutes for another investor group. For
example, banks may consider debt instruments
over a certain range of short-term securi ties to

Term Structure of Interest Rates

be perfect substitute while savings and loan
associations, insurance companies, and other
investors m ay view longer maturity dates as
perfect substitutes. If the maturity ranges of
differe nt investor group overlap sufficiently,
the tructure of yield would be adjusted as if
each inve tor beli ved all securities to be perfect sub titutes.
However one views the process which leads
to loans with differing maturities being perfect
substitutes in the aggregate, the essential point
is that the yields and prices are determined by
investors who expec t th e rates of return on
these sccurit ie to be th e amc over any given
period of time. It is necessa ry to qualify thi
statement moderate! , si nce most pre cntations
of the expectatio ns th eo ry do r cognizc that
such factors as marke t impediments and tran actions costs may r es ult in some inequality in
expected rates of return and may cause some
distortion between actually established yield
structures and tho e which would be established
if these factors did not exi t. In general analysis,
however, it seems a valid practice to ignore
these factors, for yield differentials change
rather ubstantially over time, and it is highly
unlikely that thi behavior could be attributed
in any significa nt way to changes in transaction costs or othe r market impediment .
There arc two co mpatible ways to look at the
eq uality o f expected rates of return. An existing
lon g-term ra te can be considered equal, roughly
speaking, to an ave rage of a current shortterm rate and the short-term rates which are
expected to be es tabli shed over time until the
long-term loan matures. On the other hand, a
current long-term rate can be viewed as standing in a specific relation hip to a current shortterm rate such th a t its price is expected to
change just sufficie ntl y o that its rate of r turn
will equ al the short-term rate over the period
req uired for th e sho rt-term loan to mature.
In either case, any yield differential represent a market prediction that interest rates
will change over th future. For example, conMonthly Review • January - February 1966

ider two loans with 1 and 2 years to maturity
that are selling to yield 2 per cent and 3 per
cent, respectively . According to the pure expectations theory , this interest rate relationship
indicates a m arke t prediction that the price of
th e 2-year loan will fall by roughly 1 per cent
over the year. Or, it indicates that the market
i expecting the yield on a I-year loan to be
roughly 4 per cent 1 year in the future. This
prediction i implied because the average of the
current 1-year yield of 2 per cent and the expected 1-yea r yield of 4 per cent is roughly
equ al to the current 2-year maturity yield of
3 per ce nt. In short, the expectati o n theory
co ntend s that diffcrenccs in yi Ids o n loa ns
with different maturities arc c tabli hcd not beca use the market expects to receive a higher
return on one ecurity than on anoth er, but instead, because th e m arket expects the rates of
return on the two securities to be the same
over an equal period of time.
To view this conception from a broader perspective, consider the relationship among a
whole range of yields on loans with differing
m aturities . This relationship is usually depicted
by a yi eld curve, a curve which provide a
general picture of the relationship among all
maturity yield on a particul ar date. Three prevalent types of y ield curves have been established during thi century. The first i an upslopi ng curve with yields ri sing as maturity
lengthens and then generally becoming flat in
the range of longe t maturity date . The second
is a downsloping curve with yields declining
as maturity lengthens and then generally becoming flat in the range of longest maturity
dates . The third is a flat yield curve with all
maturity yields equ al.
According to the expectations theory, the
up sloping curve indicates that the market is
expecting all yield to rise over future periods
of time , with the greatest increases expected
among short-term yields. The downsloping
curve reflects ma rket expectations that all yields
will fall over future periods of time, with the
13

Current Debate on the

greatest declines expected in shorter-term
yields. The flat curve reflects market expectation s that all yields will remain unchanged.
As might be expected, yield curves tend to
vary over the business cycle and the types
assoc iated with the various phases of the business cycle lend plau sibility to the expectations
theory. For exa mple, upsloping yield curves
are usually observed during recessions and
throughout the early part of a bu siness ex pansio n. It seems quite plausible that borrowers
and lender would be expecting intere t rates
to increa e at such times. Conversely, downslopi ng yield curves ge nerally have been e tabIi hed at or near th e peak. of bu in css expa nsion. With interest rates ge nera lly hi gh historically, it is at least plausible that investors
would be ex pecting to see yields decline in the
future.
THE LIQUIDITY PREFERENCE VERSION
OF THE EXPECTATIONS THEORY

Several discussions of the expectations theory
have concluded that expected changes in yield
relationships provide only part of the explanation for the exi stence of yield differenti als.
They have argued th at lenders generally prefer
to hold hart-term loans as as et because the
price of these a et tends to vary minimally .
Thi s preference is reflected in the willingness
of investors to forego some expected return in
order to hold short-term assets . As a result,
longer-term assets generally provide a liquidity
premium and their expected rate of return tends
to be higher. To put this another way, it is
asserted that the level of longer-term yields is
always higher than it would be if the structure
of yields was _determined solely by market
expectations. The fact that yield curves have
sloped upward considerably more often than
they have sloped downward since World War
II often is cited as evidence of the existence of
a liquidity premium on longer-term securities.
It should be noted, however, that the predominance of upsloping yield curves is not
14

necessarily inconsistent with the pure expectations theory. If the market generally had expected yields to rise over this period-and
yields did rise-the larger proportion of yield
curves would have had an upward slope. It
will be remembered that at the outset of the
postwar period interest rates were at historically
low levels .
Although the liquidity preference variant of
the expectations theory contends that rates of
return on loans with different maturities are
expected to differ, it does not view credit market as being segmented. Instead, the size of
the pres umed liquidity premium is held to be
unrelated, or c sentiall y unrelated, to th e
maturity co mpo ition of out tanding debt.
Thus, the position of the liquidity preference
approach i the same as th e pure expectation
approach on this vital point. In addition, the
liquidity preference theory asserts that, in
general, changes in yield differentials imply
that the market has changed its expectations
about the future course of interest rates. Here,
again, the liquidity preference approach is in
accord with the pure expectations approach
and in conflict with the segmented markets
approach. For these reasons, it is po ible to
consider thi s po ition as a vari ant of the expectations theory.
IMPLICATIONS OF EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

The expectations theory has never been
widely accepted outside of academic circles .
Until recently, one reason was the inability of
analysts to develop a test which supported this
theory. In fact , early studies which purported
to test this theory concluded that it had no
empirical validity. This conclusion was based
upon the demonstration that yield predictions
derived from a structure of yields in accordance with logic of the expectations theory
were usually wrong. Recent presentations of
thi theory have made it clear, however, that
this is not a valid test. A test of the market's
ab ility to form accu rate forecas ts of future

Term Structure of Interest Rates

interest rates does not constitute a test of
whether an existing yield structure depends upon market expectations of future interest rates.
All that is asserted by the expectations theory
i that yield differentials exist because the
market expects interest rates to change. It is
not claimed that the prediction of the market
necc arily will be accurate. In addition to thi
clarification, recent tudie have generated new
evidence in support of the expectations approach. And, although these findings taken
individually are not overwhelmingly compelling,
a, a group they do erve to increase the degree of acceptance of the expectations theory.
lt is impossible in the short space available to describe these tests in detail, but their
general approach may be outlined. First,
hypotheses about how intere t rate expectations
are formulated at one point in time or how they
are altered with the pa sage of time are developed. Maturity yield relationships establi hed at variou point in time and the subsequent changes in these relationships with the
pas age of time are then compared with this
independent evidence of market expectations.
A high degree of correlation has been found
between these variable .
Another approach has been to draw inference about the validity of the expectation
approach by comparing actual interest rates
established over a certain period of time with
forecasted interest rates as implied by yield
structures established in the past. The criterion
u ed for judging the results was not whether
market predictions always turned out to be
correct, however, as it was in earlier tests of
this kind. Rather, it was one of determining
whether actual rates turned out on the average
to be above or below foreca ted rates. The presumption has been that if, on the average,
actual rates were equal to forecasted rates, this
suggested that the pure expectations theory
wa correct. The findings in several studies that
forecasted rates generally exceeded actual rates
has been the principal source of support for
Monthly Review • January - February 1966

the assertion that a liquidity premium on longterm debt mu t be recognized as a factor in
determining maturity yield relationships.
Although mo t recent empirical studies of
the expectations theory have proceeded along
the lines de cribed above, it hould be noted
that some inve tigations have approached the
problem from a different perspective and have
found evidence which casts doubt on this
theory. One piece of evidence of this kind has
been the inability to identify a group of balance
sheet units that behave like the hypothetical
speculator as urned in ome pre entations of
the expectation theory. Moreover, objection
have been raised as to the po ibility of the
type of speculative activity a cribed to tradeL
because of technical defici ncie, in the market
with regard to short- elling. Additional evidence, which would appear to be particularly
damaging to the overlapping markets version
of this theory, was the finding in one recent
study that interest rate expectations were not
uniform among different market observers.
This conflicts with one of the assumptions
usually made in pre enting the expectations
theory which is that interest rate expectations
of all investors tend to be uniform.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

The problem of explaining maturity yield
relation hips remains unresolved. The implications of recent empirical findings , although far
from being one-sided, have shifted opinion
away from the segmented markets theory and
toward either the pure expectations theory or
this theory modified to include the existence of
a liquidity premium on long-term debt. Perhaps
the most compelling evidence produced by
these tudie wa the consi tent finding that
changes in the maturity compo ition of debt
have little, if any, effect on the maturity structure of yields. This, of course, constitutes not
only a direct challenge to the segmented markets approach but, in addition, provides indirect
upport for the alternative theory. Other direct
15

Current Debate on the Term Structure of Interest Rates

tests of the expectations hypothesis have added
further support for this theory. In fact, on the
basis of the results of these two groups of
tests, a strong argument ha s been made for rejecting the segmented markets theory and accepting the expectations theory. However, all
the evidence does not point in one direction.
The generally acknowledged fact that major
groups of borrowers and lenders are constrained either by legal res trictions or personal
preferences from viewing securities with different maturities as perfect sub titutes, the inability to identify eco nomic units performing
as speculators, and th e ev idence of diverse inte res t rate expec tation s all serve to temp r any
inclination to di sca rd the segmented market
ap proach and acce pt the ex pectations theory .
Perhaps the best appraisal at thi time is that,
as a result of recent research , the expectations
approach has won an important skirmish, but
the outcome of the war remains in doubt.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
CONARD, JOSEPH W . An Introdu ction to the
Th eory of Int erest. Berkeley and Los Angeles:
University of California Press , 1959.
CooTNER, PAUL H . "S peculation in the Government Securities Market," Fiscal and Debt Managem ent Policies, a series of research studies pre-

16

pared for the Commission on Money and Credit.
Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963, 267-

310.
CULBERTSON, J. M. "The Term Structure of Interest Rates," Quarterly Journal of Economics,
LXXI (November 1957) , 485-517.
DE LEEUW, FRANK. "A Model of Financial Behavior," The Brookings Quarterly Econometric
Model of the United States, ed. J. S. Duesenberry
et al. Chicago: Rand McNally & Company, 1965,
465-530.
KESSEL, REUBEN A. Th e Cyclical Behavior of the
Term Structure of Interest Rates. (Occasional
Pa per 91 , National Bureau of Economic Research.) N ew York:
olumbia Univ rsily Pres,
1965.
MALKI L, BURTON G . "The Term Structure of Interest Rates," American E a nomic R eview, LIV
(May 1964) , 532-543 .
MEISELMAN, DAVID. The Term Structure of Interest Rates. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.: PrenticeHall , 1962.
OKUN, ARTHUR M. "Mo netary Policy, Debt Management and Interest Rates: A Quantitative Appraisal," Stabilization Policies, a series of research
studies prepared for the Commission on Money
and Credit. Englewood Cliffs, N. J . : Prentice-Hall ,
1963, 331-380.
SCOTT, ROB ERT H. " Liquidity and the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXXIX (February 1965), 135-145.