View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

December

NEBR.

KANS .

1961

-ON!· LY REVIEW

Relationship of Bank Size
and Bank Earnings .

.

Should the Income Tax
Be Overhauled? . .

. . . page 10

Current Statistics

.

.

.

.

. . page

3

. . page 16

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF KANSAS UITY

Suh.s·criJJI ions lo the ~loNTIJLY HEvmw are avail-

able to th e public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the
R esearch D epartment, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Kansas City 6, Missouri. Permission
is granted to reproduce any material in this
pttblication.

r/(elationJ/iip o/

Bank Size and Bank Earnings
ARTICLES in the February,
March, and April 1961 issues of the
Monthly Review dealt with the association between bank size and costs among a sample of
n1cmbcr hanks in the Tenth Federal Reserve
District. The results of the study described in
those articles indicated clearly that ratios of
costs to assets among District banks tend to
decline with increasing size of bank. The lower
cost ratios of larger banks were traced mainly
to substantially lower wage and salary expenses
per dollar of assets.
In the discussion of the size-cost relationship, care was taken to avoid implying that
the cost advantages of large-scale operations
meant that larger banks enjoyed an equivalent
advantage with respect to net income. Such
an inference could be drawn from the association between costs and size among sample
banks only if gross earnings rates of large and
small banks in the District were identical. For
a variety of reasons, this is not the case. Gross
earnings rates of the larger banks tend to be
lower than those of the smaller banks, and
thus the association between bank size and net
income is considerably different from that between size and costs.
The present article investigates the relationship between size and net earnings among District members. A study of this nature requires
not only statistical measurement of the association between size and net income, but also
consideration of the appropriate measure of income and interpretation of the differing relationships between size and net income sug-

A

SERIES OF

Monthly Review •

December 1961

gested by alternative measures of earning rates .
The factual framework for the discussion is
provided by the use of statistical analysis applied to earnings data for a sample of about
270 District member banks the sa me sample
used in the study of size-cost relationships. The
data employed arc figures for the years 195659 averaged together to minimize the influence
of unusual factors that may distort the sizeearnings relationship in a single year.
In the following exposition, technical features of the study that would be of interest only
to a limited readership are discussed in footnotes and in the notes to the charts.
CHARACTERISTICS OF BANK
EARNINGS REPORTS

Since one of the points at issue is the interpretation of various measures of bank earnings,
it may be helpful to note some of the relevant
characteristics of member bank earnings reports from which data are taken for this study .
In calculating its income position for earnings reports, a bank first computes its net cur-•
rent earnings-representing the difference be
tween gross current earnings and current operating expenses. Adjustments to net current
earnings made to arrive at net profits before
income taxes, a figure which as a rule is smaller
than net curre nt earnings, include losses or
recoveries on loans and investments, profits or
losses on securities sold, transfers to and from
valuation reserves for loans and securities, and
other miscellaneous chargeoffs and recoveries.
Income tax liabilities accrued during the period

3

Relationship of Bank Size

( or taxes paid if the bank's accounts are maintained on a cash basis) are then deducted to
arrive at profits after taxes.
When comparing bank income figures, those
familiar with bank accounting statements lean
toward the use of net current earnings as the
most reliable measure of profitability. A major
consideration underlying this choice is that adjustments to net current earnings used in arriving at net profits figures may vary erratically
from one year to the next because banks have
a fairly wide degree of latitude as to the nature
and timing of these adjustments. For example,
a bank might elect to charge off the cost of a
new building against the earnings of a single
year, and its profits before and after taxes in
that year would understate greatly the true
earnings position of the bank . 1 Such an understatement, in fact, might be seriously misleading even in average profits figures for several
years.
This fact suggests that measurement and interpretation of the size-earnings relationship in
banking should depend primarily on the relationship of net current earnings to size of bank.
That measure of income is, in any case, a good
one to use in the initial search for a relationship between bank size and earnings, for it is
likely to record most of the variations in earnings ability that are systematically associated
with size of bank. Differing degrees of efficiency between large and small banks in the performance of routine banking functions, for example, are reflected in total current expenses
and hence in current income. Moreover, differences by size of bank in rates charged for banking services clearly influence the relative magnitudes of current income at large and small
banks.
For this study, net current earnings of the
sample banks were measured both as a per
cent of bank assets and as a per cent of bank
1 This does not mean, of course, that a bank has the
freedom to write off large outlays of this kind in its
statement of income for tax purposes.

4

capital. The present article is concerned with
the relationship between bank size and ratios
of net current earnings to assets. The association between size and net income as a per cent
of capital accounts will be treated in a futurc
issue of the Review.
BANK SIZE AND THE RATIO OF NET
CURRENT EARNINGS TO ASSETS

The bottom panel of Chart 1 shows the
average relationship between ratios of net current earnings to assets and bank size found
among the sample banks for the 4 years 195659. On the average, net current earnings
amount to about 1.25 per cent of assets for
sample hanks with assets of $ I million , and
the ratio increases by .07 percenta ge point..,
for each tenfold increase in asset size of bank.
The rise in net current earnings rates with increasing bank size reflects the combined behavior of gross earnings and total costs ( expressed
as a per cent of assets) as the size of bank increases. Although both gross earnings and
total cost ratios fall rather sharply with increasing bank size, as displayed in the top two
panels of the chart, the decline in the total cost
ratio is somewhat steeper.
The relationships shown in Chart I make
no allowances for differences in the characteristics of asset and liabilities between large
and small banks that influence their revenues
and expenses, and hence are termed "simple"
relationships. For example, large banks usu ally have higher ratios of loans to total assets
than do small banks. This tends to raise both
gross earnings rates and cost ratios of large
banks relative to small banks, but it is not clear
what effect is produced on rates of net current
earnings by size of bank.
The statistical method of multiple regression
analysis was used, thcrcforc, as a means of
measuring the influence of bank size on net
earnings rates after eliminating the effect on
net earnings of a variety of characteri tics of
the sample banks. These characteristics in-

and Bank Earnings

elude the distribution of assets by major types
(Joans, U. S. Government securities, other securities, and cash), the division of Joans by
principal class of borrower (business, consumer, farm, and real estate), the proportion
Chart 1
SIMPLE RELATIONSHIPS OF BANK SIZE AND
RATIOS OF GROSS EARNINGS, TOTAL
COSTS, AND NET CURRENT
EARNINGS TO ASSETS
Sample of Tenth District Member Banks, 1956-59
Per Cent
5.6

52

Ratio of Gross Earnings to Asse1's

4.8
4 4

110

3 .6
3 .2

of deposits consisting of time accounts, and
the banks' growth rates between 194 7 and
1959 and between 1956 and 1959. The average relationship between size and the ratio of
net current earnings to assets found among
the sample banks, when this method of analysis is employed, is depicted in Chart 2. 2
The relationship shown there differs little
from that portrayed in the bottom panel of
Chart 1. The similarity in the slopes of these
two lines of average relationship means that
the ability of larger banks to earn higher net
rates on their assets does not stem simply from
diff erenccs between large and small banks in
the characte ristics mentioned in the preceding
paragraph. Rather, it results from other fac tors influencing net current earnings rates that
arc so closely associated with bank size as to be
inseparable from it by statistical analysis.

2 .8
3 .8
3.4

Ratio of Total Costs to Assets

3.0
2.6
2.2
1.8
1.4

2 8
2.4

Ratio ot Net Current Earnings to Assets

2 .0
1.6
1. 2
.8
.4

L_1_

0
.5

L ..L

I

l u..ul
5

10

1

.L...J

.l.Ll.J...lL
50

100

_L

.l

500

Assets in Millions of Doi tors
NOTE: The relationships portrayed are based on simple regres~ion
fu nctions fitted to average data for the years 1956-59. The equations
are, (1) X1 3.940 .209 tog X2 ; (2) X, = 2.694 .284 log X2; (3)
X 1 = 1.248 I .072 log X2 ; where X 1 Is the ratio of gross earnin~s
t o assets in equation (1), the ratio of total c9sts lo assets !n
eq uation (2), and the ratio of net current e_a rnIngs to assets I_n
eq uation (3), with these ratios expressed In pe~ cent. X2 Is
assets in millions of dollars . A logarithmic expression for X2 was
ch osen for reasons outlined in an article dealing with size-cost
relationships published in the February 1961 (ssue of th_
e Month!Y
Rev iew. For equation (1), the simple correlation coefficient (r) Is
-.171; for equation (2), r =-.262 ; and for equation (3), r =. 108 .

Monthly Review •

December 1961

2 As the text implies, the group of six independent
variables included in the equation underlying Chart 2
was selected from a larger list of characteristics that
might reasonably be expected to be related to net
earnings rates. Since these characteristics are bound
to be intercorrelated , however, not all of them can be
included in the same regression equation and turn out
statistically significant. Various combinations of these
variables were tested experimentally to obtain the best
fit in terms of maximizing the multiple correlation
cocfficicnl, corrected for degrees of freedom, while
confining the list of independent variables to those
which proved to be statistically significant.
In the experimental process, attention was given to
what effect the omission of a variable might have on
the regression coefficient of the size variable. This is
important because some of the omitted variables may
have been insignificant by reason of intercorrelation
with bank size. The ratio of business to total loans is
a prime example. This raises a question concerning
the interpretation of the size-earnings relationship,
since it is not entirely clear whether larger banks earn
higher rates of return simply because they are larger,
or because they specialize in commercial lending, or
both. The results of the experimentation indicate that
omission of these characteristics does not influence
materially the interpretation of size-earnings relationships. For example, addition of the ratio of business
to total loans to the group of independent variables
employed in the equation alters the regression coefficient of the size variable by only about 10 per
cent of one standard error.

5

Relationship of Bonk Size

The margin of difference in ratios of net
current earnings to assets between large and
small banks is not, to be sure, exceptionally
great. But it is sufficient to confer a meaningful earnings advantage to larger District members. Thus, the line of average relationship
shown in Chart 2 implies that banks with $100
million in assets achieve an average ratio of
net current earnings to assets about 12 per
cent higher than for banks with $1 million in
assets. The increase in net current returns to
scale does not, furthermore, end when the $100
million point in asset size is reached, but contin ucs over the full range of sizes present within the District banking community.a

Chart 2
RELATIONSHIP OF BANK SIZE AND RATIOS
OF NET CURRENT EARNINGS
TO ASSETS
Sample of Tenth District Member Banks, 1956-S9
Per Cent (Rati o of Net Curr e nt

Earn ing s to Total As se t s

2 .8
24
2 .0
16

1.2

I

I

I

Identification of the specific factors that
permit larger banks to earn higher net rates of
return on their assets would go far beyond the
scope of the present investigation. Nevertheless, it is well worthwhile to consider the broad
forces that might account for the earnings advantage accruing to large-scale operations.
Prices of Banking Services

It might be thought, first, that the relatively
greater net earnings rates of larger banks reflect, in part, higher charges to bank customers
for services comparable to those performed by
smaller banks. Interest rates on loans of similar credit quality would be the most important
case in point, since roughly 60 per cent of the
gross earnings of District member banks dur3The statistical basis for the last statement lies in an
examination of the fit of the equation for larger
banks. To inspect more closely this area of the size
range, the equation underlying Chart 2 was fitted to
the data for sample banks with over $25 million in
assets. The regression coefficient of the size variable
in this case proved to be larger than when data for
all sample banks were included (. I 02 as opposed to
.076) . A test for nonlinearity of fit using the DurbinWatson ratio also was employed for the equation describing the size-earnings relation among the larger
banks, and it did not indicate any significant departure from linearity.

6

I

II

5
Asset s

FORCES INFLUENCING NET EARNINGS RATES
BY SIZE OF BANK

)

3 .2

in

I
10

I

I

I

I

I I II

50

I

100

M1ll1 o n'i of Dollar s

NOTE

The equati on on wh ic h th e chart 1s ha ~e d 1s X I l 265 I
076 log X1 I .0171 X 1
0225 X-1 I 0067 X,,
.01 21 X1, wh ere
X1 is the ratio of net current earnin gs to assets , X 1 i s ass ets
in millions of dollars, X3 1s the ratio of total loan s to total assets, X4 is the ratio of cash to total assets , X,, is the ratio of

x~

consumer to total loans , and
1s the ratio of time to total deposits . All ratios are expressed in per centage terms . The multiple
correlation coefficient for the equation i s .53, and all ind ependent
variables are statistically significant at the 5 per cent l evel. The
chart is obtained by setting variables X 3 through X6 at their
mean values and then graphically portraying the result i ng relation
between X 1 and X2 •

ing the years 1956-59 consisted of interest and
discounts on Joans. An additional 25 per
cent was accounted for by interest income on
investments, on which yields arc established by
market forces generally well beyond the influence of the individual bank.
While data needed for a careful examination of this hypothesis arc scarce, inferences
may be drawn from statistics relating to interest rates on business loans obtained in surveys of business lending at District member
banks. The last survey of this type-taken in
the fall of 1957-disclosed a structure of interest rates by size of bank, size of business
borrower, and maturity of loan as indicated in
Tab]c 1. Loans to quite large businessesthose with assets of more than $5 millionwere not included in the table , because only
the biggest banks in the District have any appreciable amount of loans outstanding to these
larger firms.

and Bank Earnings

Table 1
AVERAGE INTEREST RATES ON BUSINESS LOANS BY SIZE OF BUSINESS
SIZE OF BANK, AND MA TURI TY OF LOAN
'
Sample of Tenth District Member Banks, October 1957

Asset
-----,------~----

$1 to $5

Bank Size
(Deposits
in
Millions
of Dollars)

ShortTerm
Loans

LongTerm
Loans

Over 100
50-100
20-50
10-20
0-10

5.04
5.04
4.92
5.09
5.1 l

4.95
5.22
4.90
5.17
*

Size of Business

$250,000 to
$1 Million

Million

$50,000 to
$250,000

$25,000 to
$50,000

Short- LongShort- LongShortTerm
Term
Term
Term
Term
Loans Loans Loans Loans Loans
Average Interest Rate (Per cent per annum)

l

5.07
5.16
5.24
5.58
5.40

5.07 I 5.40
5.46
5.38
5.38
5.52
5.62
5.88
5.70
6.00

l

5.3815.76
5.90
5.62
5.94
6.27
6.07
7.11
6.40
6.80

Under

$25,000

LongTerm
Loans

ShortTerm
Loans

LongTerm
Loans

6.14
6.96
7.02
7.52
6.74

6.24
6.12
6.47
7.56
7.52

7.35
9.10
7.70
9.06
8.38

*Number of loans too small to permit meaningful calculation of average interest rate .
NOTE , LonP, term loans are defined as loans with an orip,lnal maturity of more than I year. It is not surprising that, In some cases, average rates of Interest are higher on short term loans than on long term
c:rectIts for a given sI1e class of business and si1e class of bank This reflects the fact that the survey
was made In October 1957, when bank loan rates were at cyclical peaks . Long-term loans negotiated considerably earlier thus would tend lo carry lower average rates than would generally have been available on
the survey date .

The assumption underlying the construction
of the table is that loans of a given maturity
to a given size of business are reasonably comparable in terms of risk exposure of the lender.
Thus, rates may be compared among the various bank size groups to gain an impression of
price differences for similar banking services.
The data in the table indicate that interest
rates of a given maturity to a given business
size class arc not directly related to bank size,
but tenc.J to be inversely related to it. That is,
rates generally arc higher the smaller is the size
of bank. Data from a business loan survey at
District member banks in 1955 display a pattern of interest rates by size of bank consistent with that shown in Table 1.
It is to be recognized, of course, that aspects
of loan contracts other than those listed in the
table-such as the type of collateral, the business of borrower, the size of loan, and the existence of compensating balance requirements
-also affect rates of interest on business loans.
The rate differentials shown in Table 1, therefore, reflect not only the size of the lending
bank but other characteristics of the loan also.
Nevertheless, when the effects of these characMonthly Review •

December 1961

teristics are taken into consideration as adequately as possible, given the available data,
differentials in interest rates still exist that appear to be associated with the size of the lending bank.
The tendency for rates of interest on comparable loans to be lower at larger banks may
reflect, in part, the fact that administrative
costs of lending are less at larger banks, even
for loans comparable in size to those made by
small District members. If that is the case,
prices of other banking services may bear a
similar relationship to bank size-tending to
decrease with increasing size of bank-since
the greater efficiency of larger banks which results in lower administrative costs of lending
presumably influences costs of performing
other banking services as well. It should be
noted, however, that cost differences per se
are not an adequate explanation of differential
pricing of services between large and small
banks. The strength of competitive forces in
local markets also is an important consideration. The larger sample banks are concentrated
in the District's metropolitan areas, where
competition among banks may be relatively
7

Relationship of Bank Size

strong. The distribution of medium-size and
smaller banks, on the other hand, is more diverse. Some of them are located in major
cities, but the majority are scattered among
the farm communities and the small- to medium-size cities of the District's seven states,
where competitive forces in local financial markets are less intense.
Since the above data relate only to interest
rates on business loans, they can at best be
merely suggestive of the association between
bank size and the prices of comparable banking services among District member banks.
Nonetheless, they do seem to indicate that the
rise in ratios of net current earnings to assets
with increasing bank size shown in Chart 2
docs not emanate from difTerential pricing of
banking services. If anything, it occurs despite
these price differences.
Differences in Types of Banking Services

A second possible source of the earnings
advantage of large banks is the existence of
differences in the types of banking services offered by large and small banks, some of which
may be more profitable than others. The statistical method employed to derive Chart 2 sought
to allow for many important characteristics of
the sample banks that influence their net earnings rates. However, other characteristics remain which, because they are so intimately related to bank size, could not be dealt with adequately by this method.
Several additional differences in structural
characteristics of large and small banks were
discussed in the study of size-cost relationships
mentioned earlier. These include differences in
the relative size of trust departments at large
and small banks, in the proportion of demand
deposits made up of interbank balances, and
in the average size of demand deposits. 4 Further consideration of these attributes seems un4
The effect of these attributes on bank costs was discussed in the March 1961 issue of the Monthly Review.

8

necessary, for they do not appear to be dominant factors in explaining variations in earnings rates by size of bank. The association between bank size and net current earnings rates
is, however, very importantly influenced by a
fundamental characteristic of asset structure
that is closely related to bank size- namely,
that larger District banks engage in transactions
for individual earning assets in substanti ally
larger dollar amounts than do the smaller District members.
With respect to transactions in open-market
securities, purchases and sales in large dollar
quantities is an unalloyed blessing. Transactions costs arc reduced thereby, and since
yields on these instruments arc set by market
forces, the lower cost reflects itself in higher
net earnings. Added to this is the fact that
management of the portfolio of Treasury securities-the major type of open-market instrument held by banks-is largely a oneman job, and hence the larger is the portfolio,
the cheaper is the cost of its administration.
But quite different principles are involved
in determining the effect of acquiring large
versus small loans on ratios of net current
earnings to assets. For while the granting of
loans in large dollar amounts is highly ignificant in holding down expenses at large banks,
it is also important in reducing gross earnings,
since interest rates are substantially lower on
large than on small loans. The impact on net
current earnings depends on which of the two
is reduced more.
There are two good reasons for believing
that as banks increase in size and gradually
move into the markets for larger and larger
loans, their ratio of net current earnings to
assets is affected adversely. The first reason
is that larger loans typically are made to larger
borrowers, and generally are thought to be
less risky. Consequently, the return to the
lender over and above administrative costs
tends to be considerably less than that for
smaller loans. The second reason is that the

and Bank Earnings

strength of competitive forces is also substanti ally greater for larger loans than fo,r small
loans, since large borrowers have greater access
to alternative sources of credit. At the one
extreme, the small business firm borrowing in
a local loan market may have no more than
one or two alternative sources of credit open
to him. At the other end of the spectrum, the
largest corporations are able to tap the financial resources of the entire Nation.
An inkling as to how important difTerences
in the strength of competitive pressures can be
in determining loan rates is provided by the
data in Table I. It was noted above that for
any business size class and maturity of loan ,
rates tend to be somewhat higher at the smaller
bank. But the margin of difTerence between
rates at large and small banks tends to be
smaller for the larger business size classes.
T hus for the smallest business size class shown
in the table, the average rate on short-term
loans is about 1 ¼ percentage points higher at
b anks with up to $10 million in deposits than
at banks with over $ 100 million in deposits.
For the largest business size class, on the other
hand, the differential is only .07 percentage
points.
Differences in Efficiency
This line of reasoning suggests that, on balance, large banks arc not able to achieve higher
rates of net current earnings to assets either

Monthly Review •

December 1961

because of differences in the prices they charge
for banking services comparable to those supplied by smaller banks, or because they offer
different types of services to banking customers. Their higher net ratios of earnings to assets occur despite price differences and variations in types of banking services. They are
associated, rather, with the fact that dollar
costs of rendering given banking services arc
markedly lower for large banks. This, in turn,
reflects the ability of larger banks to organize
their activities in ways that contribute to lower
costs and hence to higher net current earnings
per dollar of assets.
FURTHER LINES OF INVESTIGATION

The development of the argument in this
article has left open two important avenues
of investigation that deserve further pursuit.
One interesting question is whether bank profits-both before and after taxes-as a per
cent of assets are related to size of bank in
the same way as net current earnings. A second question has to do with the relationship
between bank size and measures of bank income as a per cent of capital accounts-a
relationship which, as noted earlier, differs
considerably from that disclosed by ratios of
net earnings or profits to assets. These questions will be treated in a future issue of the
Monthly Review.

9

Should the Income Tax Be Overhauled?
HE LAST two issues of the Monthly Review
have carried articles dealing with proposed
revision of the Federal tax on individual incomes. The October article outlined the structure and coverage of the income tax, which applies to less than half of the Nation's total
personal income. The November article reviewed several proposals that would add greatly to the amount of income that is taxed.
Proponents of broadening the tax base rest
their case on several grounds. First, they argue
that broader coverage, or fewer "loopholes,"
would make the income Jevy a fairer tax than
1t 1s now. ln addition, it is contended that
broadening the tax base would make it possible to lower significantly the rates at which
individual income is taxed without loss of
revenue to the Treasury. As the October article
pointed out, a lowering of marginal tax rates
with no change in the total tax yield presumably reduces the adverse effect on incentives of an income tax because taxpayers are
allowed to keep a higher share of any additions
to their taxable income. Furthermore, most
analysts agree that income taxes should have
the maximum feasible coverage to avoid creating artificial incentives to channel income into
tax-sheltered categories, thereby interfering
with the working of the market system.
For all these reasons, the proposals outlined
in the November article-which would enlarge
the taxable income base by over 30 per centhave received widespread support among disinterested students of taxation. Nonetheless, many
of the proposals have also encountered strong
opposition-in part from those whose financial status would clearly be harmed by the
suggested changes.
It is sometimes tempting to dismiss such opposition by those adversely affected as mere

T

10

selfishness, but the fact is that changes in the
income tax, even those designed to perfect it,
can themselves create inequities. A person who
makes economic decisions under one set of tax
rules may experience great hardships if the
rules are changed. Even if a11 concerned agree
that the new rules make more sense than the
old ones, the change itself may have repercu sions that would be hard to justify as equitable.
Fear of potential adverse r p rcussions lie~ be
hind much of the opposition to some of th e pro
posals for enlarging the taxable income base
outlined in the November Montltly Review .
In addition, some of the proposed changes
might raise difficult, perhaps insurmountable,
problems of administration or taxpayer compliance, or both. At least one, the proposal for
treating capital gains as ordinary income, clearly involves substituting one imperfect device
for another.
Thus, income tax revision cannot be taken
lightly, and there is room for honest debate
over the advisability of making practically any
important change. This final article on the
individual income tax deals primarily with
arguments for and against some of the proposed changes in the coverage of the income tax
outlined last month. Attention is centered on
proposals that have invoked the most opposition. The purpose here is not to settle the debates, but to clarify the nature of the conflict
and, in some cases, to show how disagreements
can be resolved, or at least lessened, by careful planning of changes in the coverage of the
tax.
TAXING STATE AND LOCAL INTEREST

A clear-cut example of the economic effects
of favored tax status is found in the market for
state and local securities. Because interest paid

Should the Income Tax Be Overhauled?

on these securities is exempt from the Federal
income tax, investors arc willing to buy state
and local bonds at lower yields than those
available on other securities.
The precise advantage of holding tax-exempt
securities depend s on the investor's marginal
rate of tax. A person in the 90 per cent tax
bracket would gain as much income after tax
from a state or local bond yielding 0.4 per cent
as he would from a corporate issue carrying a
yield of 4.0 per cent (0.4 per cent after tax).
The advantage diminishes as the taxpayer's
marginal rate declines a taxpayer in the first
( 20 per cent) bracket would require a taxexempt yidd of J. 20 per cent to equal the
aflcrtax yield on a corporate bond yielding
4 .0 per cent.
The preference of investors for lax-exe mpt
bonds has made it possible for state and local
governments to borrow at rates substantially
below rates paid by other borrowers. However, as state and local government borrowing
has mushroomed over the postwar period, the
demand of high bracket taxpayers for tax-exempt securities has tended to become satiated.
rt has thus become increasingly necessary for
nontaxable bonds to carry yields that make
them appealing to investors in lower tax
brackets . In consequence, the rate advantage
for state and local issues has diminished considerably in recent years, while the advantage
of investing in tax-exempt issues has been enhanced for people in higher tax brackets.
In 1946, tax-exempt issues rated Aaa sold
at yields less than one half as high as those on
corporate securities of comparable quality. The
subsequent heavy volume of municipal offerings has progressively reduced this differential.
Last year, for example, Aaa-rated state and
local issues sold at rates nearly three fourths
as high as those on comparable corporate issues. ft was thus possible for investors in the
highest brackets to find substantial shelter from
tax progression. A taxpayer in the highest (91
per cent) bracket could realize a tax-free reMonthly Review •

December 1961

turn of $32,600 per year on a $1 million investment in Aaa-rated state and local bonds at
the average rate available in 1960. He could
earn, after tax, only about $4,000 annually
from an equal investment in Aaa-rated corporate issues at the average rate for 1960.
Not only does this state of affairs provide
an unwarranted haven from tax progression, it
is often argued, but it also encourages investment in rather safe securities by those who are
in the best position to finance riskier private
undertakings, the income from which is taxable.
Tax exemption of state and local interest
payments has often been defended on the
ground that it subsidizes <lesirablc spending
programs hy reducing the borrowing costs of
lower levels of government. 1 However, the
postwar decline of the differential between taxexempt bonds and taxable issues has called
into serious question the efficiency of the tax
exemption feature as a subsidy for state and
local borrowing. Taxpayers in high brackets
save in taxes (and the Federal Government
thereby loses in revenue) an amount far in
excess of the saving of interest costs to lower
levels of government. Many analysts who do
favor Federal subsidies to state and local governments have urged that financial aid be given
directly. Such assistance might take the form of
Federal subsidies based on the volume of state
and local interest costs. In that case, interest
savings to the states and municipalities would
precisely equal the cost to the Treasury, and
would thus be less expensive for the Federal
Government than the present system. An
alternative plan would grant to lower levels of
government subsidies which were not necessarily tied to indebtedness, so as to avoid encouraging deficit finance and discriminating in
favor of states and municipalities which borrow
heavily.
1 Some people also contend that Federal taxation of
state and local interest payments would be unconstitutional. Others express a contrary view; in the absence
of a Supreme Court test this remains a moot question.

11

Should the Income Tax

Although those who propose removal of the
tax-exempt status of state and local issues feel
they have a strong case, the plan has received
much opposition. It is often pointed out that a
simple elimination of the tax exemption feature
itself would cause important inequities. Present
holders of tax-exempt securities would suffer
substantial capital losses since, with repeal of
tax exemption, market values of outstanding
state and local issues would necessarily fall to
the point where their pretax yields were competitive with available pretax yields on alternative investments.
To get around this difficulty, it is sometimes proposed that only the interest on new
state and local issues should be taxable- presently outstanding issues would retain their taxexempt status. Such a provision would prevent
arbitrary capital losses to people who held
state and local bonds at the time of the change,
but would have the effect of removing the
exemption gradually as tax-exempt issues were
retired.
Even if this plan were followed, there might
be hardships created for some people. Municipal bond dealers might encounter major and
expensive problems in ferreting out new
sources of demand for state and local issues.
Quite possibly some marginal firms would go
out of business. People connected with these
firms might find it difficult to take comfort
from the notion that the tax system had been
made more efficient, and it would be hard to
persuade them that the change was equitable.
TAXA Tl ON OF IMPUTED RENT

One of the most far-reaching proposals for
broadening the tax base involves taxation of
imputed net rent on owner-occupied houses.
As the article in the November Monthly Review explained, the present deductibility of interest payments on mortgage loans and property taxes, combined with the fact that none
of the rental value of owner-occupied homes
is reportable income for tax purposes, results

12

in favored treatment of homeowners as opposed to renters.
Many students of income taxation argue that
this unequal treatment should be corrected by
making the rental value of owner-occupied
houses reportable in the owners' adjusted gross
income for tax purposes . The homeown er
would then be permitted to deduct all expenses
of producing this imputed rental income, including currently allowed deductions for interest payments on mortgage loans and property
taxes, and additional allowances for depreciation and maintenance expenses connected with
the home.
Such a plan would involve certain administrative difficulties and pt.:rhaps would raise
serious problems of taxpayer compliance
some people have objected to the proposal on
these grounds. To be administratively feasible ,
estimation of rental values for the millions of
owner-occupied houses in this country probabl y
would require the use of arbitrary formula s.
For example, a system of estimating rental
values from property tax evaluations might be
set up, although the extreme unevenness of assessment practices throughout the country
would greatly complicate such a procedure.
Depreciation and maintenance deductions also
would involve serious problems of administration and taxpayer compliance. Again, it mi ght
be necessary to impose arbitrary rules, such as
the use of a uniform percentage of estimated
property or rental values for depreciation and
maintenance allowances.
If such arbitrary formulas were used, inequities no doubt would arise among homeowning
taxpayers who encountered divergent circumstances not recognized by the rules. But proponents of taxation of imputed net rent contend that these inequities would be much less
serious than the ones presently arising out of
preferential treatment of homeowners as compared with renters.
Jt is argued by some that since taxpayers do
not ordinarily think of the rental value of their

Be Overhauled?

homes as income, they might strenuously object to its inclusion in adjusted gross income.
Even if reporting of rental values could be
strictly enforced, it might nonetheless engender
a serious over-all deterioration of taxpayer
morale if it did not make sense to the average
citizen. A successful income tax depends importantly on public willingness to comply, and
experience in other countries has shown that
widespread antipathy to a tax tends to promote
evasion, defeating the purpose of raising
revenues in an equitable and efficient manner.
Too much quest for logical purity in a tax
thu~ may actually make matters worse if it docs
not meet with general acceptance.
The kind of compliance and administrative
problems envisaged by opponents of taxing im
puled rent would be largely avoided under an
alternative plan of simply disallowing the present deductions for interest and property tax
expenses on owner-occupied houses. This
change would be less likely to perplex taxpayers, and it would not require estimation of
rental values and depreciation and maintenance
costs. However, as the November article
pointed out, this plan would only partly meet
the criticism leveled at the present law, because
it would not bring the rental value of the homeowner's equity into the tax base. People who
own their homes outright would lose only the
property tax deduction, and would continue to
enjoy considerable tax advantages over renters
and, in addition, over people with mortgaged
homes.
Economic Impact of Taxing Imputed Rent

Beyond these more obvious problems of devising a fair and feasible method of eliminating discrimination in favor of homeowners lie
issues concerned with the economic impact of
such a change.
As the relative advantage of owning a home
was reduced or eliminated by changes in the
tax Jaw, some people presumably would decide
to rent rather than buy. Furthermore, the higher tax bills faced by homeowners would reduce
Monthly Review •

December 1961

their disposable income and their ability to
borrow from mortgage lenders. These developments presumably would tend to reduce the
demand of consumers for houses to own;
prices of existing homes would come under
pressure, while building of new homes would
be retarded. Those who believe that homeownership should be encouraged by tax policy
thus argue that either taxation of imputed net
rent or elimination of the deductibility of interest and property tax expenses would tend
to retard the growth of homeownership.
In addition, to the extent that the change
tended to reduce the demand for houses, present homeowners and people connected with
industries related to housing and home finance
would suffer. Thus, in removing one source of
inequity, the change in the tax law might bring
with it another. No scientific rules exist which
would make it possible to say whether the
"short-run" setbacks suffered by homeowners
and people connected with the housing industry
would be sufficiently serious to offset the "longrun" gain in equity deriving from more equal
treatment of renters and homeowners. Just as
in the case of removal of tax exemption of state
and local interest payments, the taxation of
rental values of owner-occupied houses does
not guarantee complete equity. One regrettable
feature of imperfect tax provisions is that, once
established, their removal may itself work hardships because of its economic impact.
TREATMENT OF CAPITAL GAINS
AND LOSSES

Probably the most controversial of all proposals discussed in the November Monthly Review is the one which calls for taxation of
capital gains in full as ordinary income. Present
law provides for the taxation of any excess of
net long-term capital gains ( on assets held
more than 6 months) over net short-term capital losses at rates of only one half the marginal
rate applicable to ordinary income, or 25 per
cent, whichever is lower. Thus, for example, a

13

Should the Income Tax
taxpayer in the 91 per cent bracket who records
net long-term capital gains of $10,000 and no
short-term losses pays a tax of only $2,500 on
the gains. His aftertax gain is 75 per cent of the
total, or more than eight times as great as he
would retain from an equal amount of ordinary
income. Moreover, gains on assets held at the
time of death are never subject to the income tax.
Needless to say, investors in high tax brackets
find it profitable to channel income into the
form of long-term gains, and many investment
decisions revolve around this consideration .
In contrast to the tax advantage of longterm capital gains is the limitation imposed on
deduction of losses on the sale of capital assets. Taxpayers arc allowed to offset losses
against gains, but if losses exceed gains in any
tax year, no more than $1,000 of net losses
can be offset against ordinary income. "Unused" losses may be carried forward to offset
capital gains and up to $1,000 of ordinary income in each of as many as 5 future years.
However, the taxpayer who suffers severe capital losses may very well find that only a small
portion of his total loss can be offset under
these provisions.
The limited offset of capital losses is justified
as an offset to the favorable treatment of capital gains. But a serious equity problem arises
under these provisions si nce those who suffer
capital losses which cannot be offset against
capital gains or other income arc not those
benefitting from the favored tax treatment of
capital gains.
The capital gain and loss provisions have
come under considerable criticism, both because they distort investment decisions and because they considerably reduce the progressiveness of the income tax in practice. The proposal that all capital gains be taxed in full is
generally coupled with a recommendation that
limitations on Joss offsets be removed. If
adopted, these changes would no doubt have a
profound infJucnce on the distribution of tax
burdens and on investment decisions as well.

14

Their controversial nature can perhaps best be
pointed up by noting that there is also a current movement afoot to reduce the severity of the
capital gains tax. To understand the nature of
the conflict, it is necessary to look rather closely
at the features of capital gains which first led
Congress to accord them special treatment.
Capital Gains vs. Ordinary lnc:ome

One of the chief reasons advanced for special
tax treatment of capital gains and losses arises
out of what is essentially a problem in the
timing of income receipts. For administrative
reasons, gains and losses enter into the computation of taxable income only when they arc
"realized" by sale or exchange of the a-;scts in
question . Thus, for example, a person who
bought I 00 sh~tres of common stock lrn
$ I 0,000 in 1940 and sold them for $ I I 0,000
in 1960 realized the entire $ I 00,000 gain in
1960, no matter when the actual rise in market
value took place.
Under progressive income taxation, full taxation of the $100,000 realized gains in 1960
might have put the taxpayer into a much higher rate bracket than would seem justified. Suppose that he had $6,000 ordinary income after
exemptions and deductions in each of the years
1941-1960. His average income for the 20
years would then be $1 1,000 per year. Ir he
were married and filed jointly with his wife,
his tax per year on $ I 1,000 taxable income
would be $2,460, using present rates, and his
total tax over the 20-year period would be
$49,200. But if the entire $100,000 were
allocated to his 1960 income, he would pay
$1,240 on his $6,000 taxable income in each
of the first 19 years, and $58,140 on his 1960
income of $106,000. His total tax bill over the
20-year period would then be $81,700, or
$32,500 more than in the case where the same
income is spread equally over the 20 years.
As long as the realization method of accounting for capital gains is used, taxing longterm gains in full discriminates against them
because their "lumpy" character tends to put

Be Overhauled?

the taxpayer in excessively high marginal rate
brackets in years of realization. Thjs fact,
more than any other, provides the rationale
for special tax treatment of long-term gains.
But it is evident that, while the preferential
tax treatment of long-term capital gains may
prevent or reduce inequities in some cases, it
also gives rise to considerable favoritism in
others. Furthermore, the use of the realization
criterion makes it possible for investors to
avoid the capital gains levy by not selling or
exchanging assets whose value has risen. If
they are held until death, the gain in their
value is never subjected to income tax. The
current drive for reduced taxes on capital gains
is based largely on the argument that at present tax rates investors arc loath to sell assets
whose value has risen. It is asserted that this
seriously impedes the mobility of investment
funds and makes it more difficult to raise capital for new ventures.
While it is clear that the present law may
strongly favor taxpayers who are able to channel their incomes into the form of capital gains,
the fact remains that taxation of long-term
gains in full as ordinary income on a realization basis would also create inequities because
of the lumpiness which often characterizes these
gains. The problem arises out of the computation of taxes on an annual basis, and the most
promising solution-administrative problems
aside-lies in averaging income for tax purposes without any special treatment for capital gains.
Under an averaging scheme, taxpayers
would be allowed to spread their incomes
evenly over a number of years, so that unusually high incomes in particular years would
not be taxed at unjustly high rates. This device
is now available, on a limited basis, to artists
and inventors. Under certain circumstances,
they are permitted to spread the income from
creative works over as many as 3-5 years.
However, averaging schemes are thought to
entail important limitations because they add
Monthly Review •

December 1961

considerably to the complexity of taxes, both
from the viewpoint of the taxpayer and from
that of the tax administrators. 2 In the absence
of averaging, it will always be possible for one
group of critics to contend that taxation of
capital gains in full is too seyere while another
group can point out that anything short of full
taxation of these gains as ordinary income may
allow the progressiveness of the income tax to
be eroded for people whose income takes the
form of long-term capital gains. Logic wiB support both cases and any compromise solution
will be imperfect.
OTHER CONTROVERSIAL PROPOSALS

There is also opposition to some of the other
proposals for broadening the tax base that were
discussed in last month's article. However, it is
not possible to discuss each case in detail here.
Suffice it to say that proposals for inclusion of
social insurance benefits, veterans benefits, certain military payments, and unemployment and
workmen's compensation payments are not
unanimously endorsed. Nor is the suggestion
that taxes on interest and dividend income be
withheld at the source by corporations and
thrift institutions without strong opposition.
In aB of these cases, the changes envisaged
by those who back them arc thought to be for
the better. The appeal of broadening the tax
ba e is strong, both because it would seem
equitable to close off loopholes and because the
reduction in tax rates that would be made possible by enlarging the tax base might greatly enhance economic incentives.
But opposition to change is not necessarily a
manifestation of the self-interest of conniving
tax dodgers. In many cases, people who have
made economic deci ions and investment com2 However, one ingenious and logically impeccable
averaging scheme has been proposed which would
entail, according to its author, very few administrative or compliance difficulties. See William Vickrey,
Agenda for Progressive Taxation, New York: Ronald
Press, 194 7, pp. 172-95.

15

Should the Income Tax Be Overhauled?

mitments under one set of rules may find that a
change in the rules has highly unfavorable economic repercussions for them. Any such hardships ought to be considered when tax changes
are discussed. This is not to say that changes
in the tax system should never be made simply
because they may create some inequities.
Rather, the potential gains of a change must be
weighed against whatever disadvantage may
be entailed before a decision is made.
One factor to be considered is that as time
passes and personal incomes continue their upward trend, people will no doubt become increasingly tax-conscious, and effo rts to channel
incom into tax-sheltered areas probably will
intensify . As the eco nom y becomes increasingly sensitive to th e income tax, chan ges in th tax
will become potentially more di srup tive than
they would be now.
FURTHER PROBLEMS OF TAX REVISION

Although the focus of recent criticism of the
individual income tax has been on its fractional

coverage of total personal incomes, other features of the tax also have come under fire.
Among these are the tax treatment of retirement income, dividends, and income of personal trusts .. There is also considerable controversy regarding the proper ize of personal
exemptions, and the granting of extra exemption to the aged and the blind.
Furthermore, if the tax ba e is to be broadened so that a- downward revision of rates is
possible, the whole que tion of the proper
structure of rates is reopened. Should income
splitting of married couples be disallowed?
Should the income tax be mad less progressive
as a spur to economic incentives?
These and many other quest ions of tax 1-c
vision arc beyond th scop' of thi s series of
articles. One thing, however, is clear. Very few
proposal for tax revi ion arc entirely free from
difficulties, and differences of opinion over their
advisability are bound to exist even among disinterested observers.
PRICE INDEXES, UNITED STATES

BANKING IN THE TENTH DISTRICT
Deposits

loans
Reserve

District

Index

Reserve

City

Country

City

Country

Member

Member

Member

Member

Banks

and

Banks

Banks

Banks

October 1961 Percentage Change From

States

Oct.
1961

Sept.
1961

Oct.
1960

Consumer Price Index

(1947-49

100)

128.4

128 .3

127.3

Wholesale Price Index

(1947 - 49

100)

118.7

118.E

119 ..5

Prices Rec'd by Farmers ( 1910- 14

100)

240

242

241 r

Prices Paid by Farmers

100)

301

301

296 r

(1910-14

r Revised .

TENTH DISTRICT BUSINESS INDICATORS
Sept.
1961

Oct. Sept.
1960 1961

Oct. Sept. Oct. Sept. Oct .
1960 1961 1960 1961 1960

District
and Principal
Metropolitan

+1

+ s

t

+7

+2

+6

+2

+s

Colorado

- 1

+s

+ 2

+9

t

+9

+3

+9

Kansas

+ 2

+ s

+1

Missouri *

+ 2

+ 7

+ 1

Tenth F.R.Dist.

Nebraska
New Mexico *
Oklahoma *
Wyoming

+ 1

+ 8

+ 3

+ 7

+ 6

+ 14

+ 2

+6

+ 6

+9

+3

+8

**

**

- 2

+ 3

**

**

+ 2

+9

- 1

+6

**

**

* Tenth Dis trict portion only.
t Less than 0.5 per cent.

16

-I 5 + 2 +3
+4 +4 +5

- 2 +11
-

1

** No

+8

t

+ 7

t

+10

**

**

+4

+7

reserve cities in this state.

Value of
Check
Payments

Percentage change- 1961 from 1960

Areas
Oct.
Tenth F. R. District

Value of
Department
Store Sales

I

Year
to date

Oct.

Year
to date

-l 3

13

1-7

4

Denver

-/ 12

13

2

+ 6

Wichita

-/ 12

+5
+5
+4

- 11

- 2

Kan sa s City

+14

Omaha

+ 11

Oklahoma City

+25
+9

Tulsa

- 1

+ 1

- 8

+ 14

+ 11

- 12

- 10

+4

- 2

- 2

JnJex o/

MONTHLY REVIEW olrticleJ /or 1961
ARTICLE

ISSUE

ARTICLE

ISSUE

Agricultural Outlook for 1961
(7 pages) ........................................ January

Is the Cattle Cycle Changing?
(7 pages) ........................................... April

Consumer Food DollarsWhere Do They Go? ( 6 pages) .... September

Patterns of Change in District
Business Loans (5 pages) .....................May

District Bank Liquidity in Recession
and Recovery ( 6 pages) ··················-·······July

Profits on Commercial Bank
Time Deposits (7 pages) .............. September

Economic Aspects of the
New Farm Program (7 pages) ······-·October
Economic Problems of the
Early Sixties ( 6 pages) ·······--··--·····-·January
Federal Receipts and ExpendituresAlternative Measures (7 pages) ........ August
Financial Responses to
Monetary Policy (8 pages) ....................May
Free Reserves and Bank Reserve
Management (7 pages) ................ November

Proposals for Broadening the
Income Tax Base (7 pages) .......... November
Relationship of Bank Size
and Bank Costs (7 pages) ..............February
Relationship of Bank Size
and Bank Earnings (7 pages) ........ December
The Relative Status of Farm
Prices (7 pages) .................................... July
Savings Bond Anniversary ( 1 page) ..........May
Should the Income Tax Be
Overhauled? (7 pages) ................ December

Implications of the U. S. Balance
of Payments Problem (8 pages) .. ..........June

Structural Change and
Unemployment (7 pages) ............... .August

Importance of Size and Other Factors
Affecting Bank Costs (7 pages) ... .........April

What's Happening on Tenth District
Farms? (6 pages) .......................... February

Individual Income Tax-Structure
and Coverage ( 6 pages) ···-·-·-··········October

What Is the Future for Dairying?
( 6 pages) .............................................. June

Interpretation of Size-Cost Relationships
in Banking (7 pages) .......................... March

Wheat Utilization- Trends and
Prospects (7 pages) .......................... March