View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

E C O N O M IC R E V IE W

Additional copies of the ECONOMIC REVIEW may
be obtained from the Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, P. O. Box 6387, Cleve­
land, Ohio 44101. Permission is granted to reproduce
any material in this publication providing credit is
given.



TRENDS IN PRODUCTIVITY,
COSTS, AND PRICES
Growth

in aggregate demand has slowed markedly

since the end of 1968 largely in response to restrictive
public policies, while gains in productivity have become
more d iffic u lt to achieve, and prices have continued to
increase at a rapid rate in many sectors of the economy.
With demand

weakening, it seems apparent that the

major sustaining force in the recent inflationary episode
has been the influence of cost-push factors, as distinct
from the earlier problem of excess demand.1 Frequently,
increasing unit

labor cost is cited as the prim ary—

sometimes the exclusive—determinant of upward cost

IN THIS ISSUE

pressures. However, such generalizations neglect the in flu ­
ence of

Trends in Productivity,
Costs, and Prices........... 3

nonlabor costs (or payments to factors of

production other than labor). In some industries, non­
labor costs play a far more important role in the
form ulation of price than labor costs.

Registered Bank Holding
Company A ctivity in
Ohio, 1964-1969 .........15




i

For a discussion of the concepts of cost-push and demand-pull

inflation, see "Inflation: Problems of the 1960'sand Implications
for the 1970's,” Econom ic Review,

Federal

Reserve Bank of

Cleveland, February 1970.

3

ECONOMIC REVIEW

A crucial aspect of the inflationary process that

industry is defined as shipments (or sales) plus the

is receiving greater public attention is the behavior

change in inventories less that industry's purchases

of productivity.2 Increasing recognition is being

of materials, intermediate products, and services.

given to improved productivity performance as the

In manufacturing, fo r example, the dollar value of

major offset to rising labor costs. In popular

shipments in recent years has been more than

discussions of inflation, however, it is not gener­

twice as large as the dollar value of gross product.

ally emphasized that a high productivity growth

Gross private product, or the gross product of

industry with prices rising at rates slower than in

an industry, also can be defined as the summation

low productivity growth industries may also be

of costs incurred in producing the goods and

exerting significant inflationary pressures.
This article examines some long-run trends in

services: employee compensation (wages, salaries,
and all supplements); net interest (interest paid

output, productivity, costs, and prices in a number

less interest received); capital consumption allow­

of major industries in the private sector of the

ances (depreciation and accidental damage to fixed

economy. The discussion emphasizes contrasting

business property); indirect business taxes (items

trends during the 1964-1969 period, using as

such as excise taxes, property taxes, sales taxes,

background developments during 1959-1964, a

and business transfer payments); and profit-type

period generally characterized by relative cost-

income (corporate profits after inventory valu­

price stability.

ation adjustment, proprietors' income, and rental

CONCEPTS OF OUTPUT,
P R O D U C TIV ITY , COST, AND PRICE

p ro fit as conventionally defined. Some profit-type

As used in this article, output is synonymous
with the concept of gross product measured in
constant dollars. The measure of output for the
economy as a whole is Gross National Product,
which is the market value of the goods and services
produced by the nation's economy for final sales
or for addition to inventories. Gross product
originating in the private sector of the economy
(roughly 92 percent of constant dollar GNP)
consists of GNP less compensation of general
government employees.

The gross product of an

o

As evidenced, for example, by the President's recent
creation of the National Commission on Productivity. See
In fla tio n A le rt, Report to The National Commission on
Productivity by the Council of Economic Advisers,
August 7, 1970.
3
The reason for this article's exclusion of gross product
originating in government is that compensation of general

income). The term, profit-type income, is not all
income, such as the income of self-employed
proprietors, is conceptually the same as employee
compensation.
For an individual firm , purchases o f materials,
supplies, and services from other firms are, of
course, true costs of producing a dollar's worth of
shipments or sales. Those costs essentially "wash
o u t" fo r the economy as a whole. Accordingly, the
distribution of total costs by industry division are
value-added costs—not costs of producing a dol­
lar's worth of sales.
There is considerable variation in the major cost
components among industries. For example, shares
of total costs attributable to employee compensa­
tion range from a low of 14 percent fo r agricul­
ture, forestry, and fisheries (due to the large share

government employees is defined as current dollar output.

of self-employed persons in that industry) to a

There is no allowance for productivity gains by govern­

high of 76 percent fo r contract construction, w ith

ment employees, and all increases in wage and salary
scales are automatically treated as equal increases in unit
labor cost and price.

Digitized for 4
FRASER


55 percent the average fo r the entire private
economy (see Table I). In most industries, net

SEPTEMBER 1970

TABLE I
Distribution of Total Costs Per Unit of Output
By Industry Division
1969

Employee
Compensation

Net
Interest

Capital
Consumption
Allowances

Indirect
Business
Taxes

Profit-Type
Income

55.3%
14.0
38.5
76.2
69.4
63.4
73.4
69.1
45.1
33.2
53.9
59.7
22.2
63.9

3.7%
9.4
1.3
0.4
1.1
1.2
1.0
4.0
5.2
11.8
1.5
1.7
12.2
2.0

9.5%
21.7
21.1
5.3
7.7
8.1
7.5
14.8
14.6
20.9
4.3
5.3
14.9
6.9

10.7%
8.4
8.3
2.5
6.9
12.2
3.3
7.3
13.1
11.8
26.2
16.4
18.9
2.4

20.8%
46.5
30.8
15.6
14.9
15.1
14.8
4.8
22.0
22.3
14.1
16.9
31,8
24.8

Private Economy
Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries
Mining
Contract construction
Manufacturing
Nondurable goods
Durable goods
Transportation
Communication
Electric, gas, and sanitary services
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Services
Source: U. S. Department of Commerce

interest accounts fo r a small portion of total costs.

high cost of production in wholesale and retail

For those industries, however, that rely heavily on

trade and in finance, insurance, and real estate.

real

The shares of profit-type income, which vary

estate; electric, gas, and sanitary services; and

borrowed funds

(finance,

insurance, and

widely among the industries, should not be con­

agriculture, forestry, and fisheries) net interest

sidered indicators of relative p rofitability. For

accounts fo r a relatively large share of total costs.

example, profit-type income ranks very high as a

In every industry, the cost of capital consump­

share of total costs in agriculture, forestry, and

tion allowances is a greater share than net interest.

fisheries largely because proprietors' income is

Among industries that are capital intensive (for

included in this component of costs. To a lesser

example, agriculture, mining, and electric, gas, and

extent, the same is true fo r contract construction,

sanitary services), the shares of capital consump­

where the proprietors' income from many small

tion allowances in total costs are more than double

unincorporated enterprises is a part of profit-type

the average for all industries. In the electric, gas,

income. In finance, insurance, and real estate

and sanitary services industries, the combined

(another industry w ith significantly above average

costs of net interest and capital consumption

profit-type income), rental income is an important

allowances

component of profit-type income.

are roughly

equal

to

outlays for

employee compensation.
For the private economy as a whole, indirect

Several other terms discussed in this article,
specifically productivity

and price, should be

business taxes account fo r a greater share of total

clarified. Productivity is much easier to define

costs than capital consumption allowances (see

than to measure; it means output (commonly

Table I). Indirect business taxes are a relatively

measured in physical terms) per some unit of input




5

ECONOMIC REVIEW

(usually labor input, although other factors of
production such as land and capital—or a combin­

AN O VER VIEW OF P R O D U C TIV ITY ,
COSTS, AND PRICES: 1 9 5 9 -1 9 6 9

ation of all three—also can be used). In order to
compare productivity trends, given the limitations

The annual behavior of the key components of
price change in

the

private economy

during

of data availability, the concept of gross product

1959-1969 is shown in the chart. The fundamental

measured in constant (1958) dollars is used as

relationships are as follows: the change in compen­

output, and the number of full-tim e equivalent

sation per employee minus the change in output

employees is used as input in this article.4 On that

per employee is approximately equal to the change

basis, annual rates of change in productivity were

in unit labor cost; the weighted summation of

computed fo r each major industry division and for

changes in unit labor cost, unit nonlabor cost (net

the entire private economy.
Price trends by industry were based on im plicit
price deflators fo r gross product—that is, prices

interest,

capital

indirect

business taxes), and

consumption

allowances, and
unit

profit-type

income equals the change in price.

paid by an industry fo r purchased materials and

When

the

increase

in

compensation

per

intermediate products were netted out from the

employee exceeds the gain in productivity, unit

industry's selling

In other words, the

labor cost w ill increase. For the economy as a

price deflators for each industry are

whole, and for most industries, the longer the

im plicit

prices.

value-added price indexes, and the weighted sum­

period

mation of those prices is equal to the im plicit price

changes in unit labor cost are associated with

deflator for the private economy (the weights, of

changes in price. In the short run, however, a given

under consideration, the

more closely

course, are each industry's share of constant dollar

increase in unit labor cost does not automatically

private GIMP).5

cause or contribute to a corresponding increase in
price. As a case in point, during the recession year
of 1960, the increase in unit labor cost accelerated

4

(from 1.8 percent in 1959 to 2.6 percent in 1960)
Both constant dollar gross product and the number of

full-time equivalent employees, by industry division, are

and u nit nonlabor cost rose sharply

(by 5.3

estimated by the U. S. Department of Commerce. Data

percent), while the rate of increase in prices in the

are published each year in the July issue of Survey o f

private economy was the same as it had been in

Current Business.

1959—1.4 percent. The reason why the rate of
advance in prices was unchanged in 1960, despite

^Implicit

price

deflators for any particular industry

should not be confused with the more commonly known
Consumer Price Index or Wholesale Price Index. For
example, the implicit price deflator for manufacturing is
not the same as the Wholesale Price Index for manufactur­

accelerated increases in unit labor and unit non­
labor

costs,

is that

unit

profit-type

income

declined by 4 percent in response to weakened
aggregate demand.

ing, and the implicit price deflator for retail trade is not

During 1961-1965, increases in compensation

the same as the Consumer Price Index. Components of

per employee were largely offset by gains in

both the Consumer Price Index and Wholesale Price
Index, together with other price measures, such as trans­
portation and construction cost indexes, are used to con­
struct the implicit price deflators.

6



o

For both the private economy and each industry, the
weights are the shares of total cost listed in Table I.

SEPTEMBER 1970

S E L E C T E D E C O N O M I C IN D IC A T O R S, P R IV A T E E C O N O M Y
(P er cen t C h a n g e From P re v i o u s Y e a r)
P e rc e n t
Percent
10
Z O M P E N S A T IO N PER EMPLOYEE

5

1 ■
1

0

OUTPUT PER EMPLOYEE

5

■

UNIT LA BOR COST

n

0

UNIT N O N L A B O R COS T
-

1 ■

10

Hi

HI

mm

BB

n

it

10

5

m

.
■
■
■

_

10

■ ■ n 0 n n

■

0

n n n T
1 .■ 1

10

5
'

0

UN IT PROFIT-TYPE IN C OME

5

0

n u
■■
_

1959
Last e n try :

'60

n

_

U

U N IT PRICE
—

'61

,

i

'62

—

■

—

'63

1969

,

'64

—

■

'65

'66

_ i_

....... '

'

'

■ ,■ ,I
67

'68

10

5

0

'69

ANNUALLY
U. S. D e p a rtm e n t o f Com m erce , S u r v e y o f C u r r e n t B u sin e ss (J u ly 1970, J u ly 1968, and A p r il 1967) and N a t i o n a l In c o m e

Sources o f d ata :

a n d P r o d u c t A c c o u n t s o f th e U n it e d St a t e s, J 9 2 9 - 1 9 6 5 .

C a lc u la tio n s w e re m ade by the F ederal Reserve Bank o f C le ve la n d .

productivity. As a result, increases in unit labor

longer being offset by gains in productivity. The

cost were moderate and, in turn, contributed to

upward price pressures stemming from rising unit

the relatively small price increases during that

labor cost were reinforced by large increases in

period. Progressively smaller gains in unit nonlabor

unit nonlabor cost in 1967, 1968, and 1969.

cost reflected

the

spreading of certain fixed

portions of capital consumption allowances, inter­
est, and indirect business taxes over larger gains in

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE
MAJOR INDUSTRIES

output. These small gains in unit nonlabor cost,

Table II shows the behavior of the major

combined w ith moderate changes in unit profit-

factors influencing prices during the two periods,

type income, also helped to keep price increases

1959-1964 and 1964-1969. Several qualifications

relatively small until 1965. In 1965, however, a

of the data should be mentioned. In the contract

strong

income was

construction industry, fo r example, price indexes

associated w ith a moderate step-up in the rate of

are based on costs of labor and materials w ithout

price increase (from 1.1 percent in 1964 to 1.7

full allowance for increased efficiency in produc­

boost

in

unit

profit-type

percent in 1965). During 1966-1969, the rate of

tion. As a result, increases in the im plicit price

inflation continued to advance, partly because

deflator for gross product in the contract construc­

gains in compensation per employee were no

tion industry somewhat overstate both the true




7

ECONOMIC REVIEW

TABLE II
Trends in Major Factors Affecting Price
By Industry Divisions
1959-1964 and 1964-1969
Average Annual

Change, Compounded

Period

Output

Compensation
per
Employee

Private Economy (100.0% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

4.2%
4.6

3.9%
5.4

2.9%
1.3

1.0%
4.0

3.4%
3.6

-

0.6%
0.5

1.1%
3.0

Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries (3.7%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

1.1
1.1

4.1
8.9

3.3
6.1

0.7
2.6

3.5
7.2

-

1.9
3.9

0.2
5.0

Mining (2.5%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

2.4
3.1

3.6
5.8

5.1
3.3

- 1 .5
2.3

- 0 .2
0.6

-

0.6
2.3

- 0 .8
0.3

Contract construction (3.6%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

1.2
0.4

4.3
6.3

-0 - 2 .5

4.3
9.0

4.4
7.1

2.8
5.5

4.0
8.3

Manufacturing (34.1% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

4.6
5.5

3.9
5.0

3.8
2.2

0.1
2.7

2.2
1.1

-0 0.6

0.4
1.9

Nondurable goods (13.5% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

3.9
4.7

3.6
5.1

3.3
2.5

0.2
2.5

2.1
1.4

-0 0.3

0.7
1.9

Durable goods (20.6% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

5.1
6.1

4.0
4.8

4.1
2.0

-0 2.7

2.8
1.3

-

-0 1.1

0.3
1.9

Transportation (5.2%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

3.4
5.7

3.8
5.6

4.2
3.9

- 0 .3
1.6

2.1
3.2

1.6
-1 1 .0

0.5
1.2

Communication (3.1%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

6.8
9.2

5.0
5.0

6.5
4.7

- 1 .4
0.3

2.9
2.4

-

0.5
4.1

0.4
- 0 .1

Electric, gas, and sanitary services (3.0%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

5.7
5.7

4.6
5.2

5.5
3.9

- 1 .1
1.2

- 0 .2
3.5

-

1.7
5.3

0.4
0.3

Wholesale trade (8.3%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

5.2
5.8

3.8
5.3

3.6
2.5

0.2
2.7

0.7
4.8

-

2.8
2.2

- 0 .1
2.5

Retail trade (10.5% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

3.3
4.0

3.6
4.4

1.6
- 0 .1

2.0
4.5

4.1
6.9

-

1.3
1.2

1.6
3.9

Finance, insurance, and real estate (14.5%)

1959-1964
1964-1969

5.0
4.3

4.1
5.6

2.6
0.6

1.5
5.1

5.3
4.0

-

2.7
1.4

1.4
3.3

Services (10.3% )

1959-1964
1964-1969

3.9
4.6

4.4
6.1

0.9
0.3

3.5
5.9

4.9
3.5

1.9
3.0

3.2
4.8

Industry

NO TE: The 1969 shares of gross private product, measured in 1958 dollars, are in
parentheses. Included in the private economy, but not shown separately,
are gross product originating in government enterprises and in the rest of
the world; those industries account for 1.2 percent of gross private
product.
Source: U. S. Department of Commerce

Digitized for 8FRASER


O utput
per
Employe

Unit
Labor
Cost

Unit
Nonlabor
Cost

U nit
Profit-Type
Income

-

Price

SEPTEMBER 1970

rate of price increase and the increase in unit labor

industries could be higher or lower than those

cost, while growth

called for in the guideposts if the industry had

in output and changes in

Similarly, in the services industry, the im plicit

insufficient or excess capacity at full employment
demand, if costs other than labor had risen or

price deflator is widely thought to be biased

fallen, and if excess market power of an industry

upward

resulted in unusually high p ro fit rates.7

productivity

are

because

correspondingly

no

allowance

understated.

is

made

for

improved productivity in certain activities, such as
household services. As a result, growth in output
and productivity is understated, and increases in
unit labor cost and price are overstated.

TRENDS: 1 9 5 9 -1 9 6 4
The actual performances of key variables in the
major

Despite these limitations, the data in Table II

industries can

be analyzed against the

background of the concepts underlying the guide-

contribute to an understanding of the various

posts.

industries' contributions to

in

annual increases in compensation per employee in

output arid to changes in productivity, costs, and

the private economy exceeded annual gains in

overall

growth

During the

1959-1964

period, average

prices. The data also reveal instances where the

productivity, on average, by only 1 percent per

actual behavior of key variables during the periods

year. In view of the possible overstatement of unit

under review ran counter to what economic theory

labor cost and price in certain industries, the

might have suggested. Reference points fo r the

moderate average annual increases in unit labor

suggested behavior of the variables are the theoret­

cost and price (1.0 percent and 1.1 percent,

ical underpinnings of the wage-price guideposts
that were promoted by the President's Council of

respectively) were tolerable rates of change.
Among the individual industries, productivity

Economic Advisers in the early 1960's.

gains varied widely—from no measured change in

These guideposts for noninflationary wage and

contract construction to a 6.5 percent annual rate

price behavior call fo r annual increases in wages

of increase in the communication industry. Aver­

and all fringe

benefits per manhour in each

age annual gains in compensation per employee,

industry to be equal to the trend rate of increase

on the other hand, fell w ithin a relatively narrow

in productivity in the private economy (the trend

range—from 3.6 percent in mining, nondurable

was meant to include a period of three or more

goods

years). Industries with above average productivity

percent in communication (see Table II). With

gains were expected to reduce prices, while indus­

respect to output patterns, increases in compensa­

tries w ith below average productivity gains would

tion per employee in eight out of the 12 industries

be justified in raising prices; average productivity

were in accordance w ith what might have been

manufacturing, and retail trade to 5.0

gains called fo r stable prices. As exceptions to the
rule, it was recognized that the faster growing
industries might be required to grant above average
wage increases to

attract the labor resources

needed for expansion ^or if wage levels were
exceptionally low, larger wage increases might be
necessary). In addition, price trends in certain



Although the guideposts have not been promoted in
recent years, their underlying concepts are mentioned
here as a backdrop for evaluating economic developments
in the major industries. See Econom ic R eport o f the
President, together with the A n n u a l Report o f the
Council o f Econom ic Advisers, 1962, 1963, 1964, 1965,
and 1966.

9

ECONOMIC REVIEW

expected (considering nondurable goods manufac­
turing and durable goods manufacturing as two

TRENDS: 1 9 6 4 -1 9 6 9
During the

1964-1969

period, productivity

separate industries). In other words, four industries

performance deteriorated in all industries, except

that experienced below average growth in output

agriculture (see Table II). A t the same time, the

also had below average gains in compensation per

rate of increase in compensation per employee

employee, while four industries w ith above average

accelerated in all industries except communica­

growth in output had above average gains in

tion. In contrast to the narrow spread of increases

compensation per employee.8

between 1959 and 1964, average annual gains in

From 1959 to 1964, the performance of unit

compensation per employee during 1964-1969

nonlabor cost was more adverse than unit labor

ranged from 4.4 percent in retail trade to 8.9

cost in every industry. That is, unit nonlabor cost

percent in agriculture.

either rose at a faster rate than unit labor cost or
declined at a slower rate. In transportation and

Unlike the 1959-1964 period, the relationships

communication, declines in unit labor cost were

between growth rates in output and compensation

more than offset by gains in unit nonlabor cost.

per employee generally were not as might be

Manufacturing and wholesale trade experienced

expected.

moderate increases in unit labor cost that were of

association was negative rather than positive. Four

similar proportions; however, prices moved in

industries w ith below average growth in output

different directions in these two industries largely

had above average growth in compensation per

because of dissimilar changes in unit nonlabor

employee, and five industries w ith above average

cost.

growth in output had below average increases in

A fter the 1957-1958 recession, unit profits in

In nine out o f

12 industries, the

compensation per employee.

industries, except agriculture, mining, and

In every industry, gains in compensation per

contract construction recovered sharply in 1959.

employee far exceeded the sharply reduced rate of

Average annual rates of change in unit profit-type

growth in productivity in the private economy as a

all

income generally were moderate between 1959

whole. Only the very rapidly growing communica­

and 1964.
Perhaps the most significant set of relationships

tion

during the 1959-1964 period is that all eight

increases in compensation per employee w ithin

industries w ith above average increases in produc­

reasonable

tiv ity had below average price increases (or price

improvement. Between the 1959-1964 period and

declines in the case of mining and wholesale

the

trade). The four industries w ith below average

accelerated

productivity performance, as might be expected,

instances, downward trends in unit labor cost

industry—telephone

and

telegraph,

radio

broadcasting, and television—managed to keep
bounds

1964-1969

of

its

own

productivity

period, each industry had an

rise in

unit

labor cost;

in

some

had above average price increases. In contract

during the earlier period were displaced by upward

construction and services, the rate of price increase

trends in the later period. The recent behavior of

was three to four times above average.

unit labor cost was particularly poor in four

o

industries: contract construction; services; finance,

These developments, together with others to be cited,

are summarized in Table III.


10


insurance, and real estate; and retail trade.

SEPTEMBER 1970

Most industries also incurred larger increases (or
less favorable changes)

in unit nonlabor cost

pronounced upswing in unit cost of net interest
and capital consumption allowances.

between 1964 and 1969. As exceptions to the

In the

private economy

as a whole, unit

general pattern, the manufacturing; communica­

profit-type income improved on balance between

tion; and finance, insurance, and real estate indus­

1964 and 1969 (despite declines in 1967 and

tries improved their unit nonlabor cost perfor­

1969).

mance relative to the earlier five-year period. The

however, was the unit p ro fit performance in six

Running counter to the general trend,

industries sustaining the greatest acceleration in

industries that collectively account for almost half

unit nonlabor cost increases were agriculture;

of gross private product (mining, durable goods

contract construction; electric, gas, and sanitary

manufacturing,

services; and wholesale and retail trade.

and wholesale and retail trade). Although the

transportation,

communication,

growth rate of output in those industries increased
In agriculture, the stepped up increase in unit

between the two periods, unit profit-type income

nonlabor cost during the 1964-1969 period was

failed to improve or actually worsened. Only two

due prim arily to a surge in unit cost of capital

industries, nondurable goods manufacturing and

consumption allowances and, to a lesser extent,

services, managed to improve both their growth

higher unit cost of indirect business taxes. In

rates in output and their unit p ro fit performances

contract construction, all of the accelerated rise in

between the two periods. The remaining industries

unit nonlabor cost was due to a substantial

(agriculture; contract construction; electric, gas,

increase in the unit cost of capital consumption

and sanitary services; and finance, insurance, and

allowances (from an average annual gain of 1.7

real

percent between 1959 and 1964 to an average

declines in their growth rates in output, but

estate)

experienced

no

improvement

or

annual gain of 8.5 percent during the most recent

nevertheless improved their unit p ro fit perfor­

five years). In trade, particularly wholesale trade, a

mance.

marked increase in unit cost of indirect business
taxes largely contributed to the accelerated rises in
unit nonlabor cost. Special mention should be
made regarding wholesale trade, where the annual

INDUSTRY CO NTRIBUTIONS TO
RECENT IN FLA TIO N
Price increases accelerated in practically all

rate of increase in unit cost of indirect business

industries during the recent five-year period; only

taxes more than quadrupled between the two

communication and electric, gas, and sanitary

periods under review (from 1.0 percent between

services registered an improvement relative to the

1959 and 1964 to 4.4 percent between 1964 and

earlier five-year period. As might be expected,

1969). As a result, by 1969, indirect business taxes

industries w ith above average productivity gains

accounted fo r more than one-fourth of the total

had

cost of gross product in wholesale trade. In the

agriculture), and all industries w ith below average

capital intensive electric, gas, and sanitary services

productivity performance had above average price

below average price performance (except

industry, which had declining unit nonlabor cost

increases (see Table III). One particular problem

between 1959 and 1964, the relatively steep rise in

area stems from the agricultural industry, where

unit nonlabor cost during 1964-1969 reflected a

prices rose only about one-sixth as much as in the




11

ECONOMIC REVIEW

TABLE III
Ranking of Industrial Trends in Output, Compensation
Per Employee, Productivity, and Price
(With Respect to Average Changes in Private Economy)
1959-1964 and 1964-1969
Compensation
per Employee

Output

Industry
Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries
Mining
Contract construction
Manufacturing
Nondurable goods
Durable goods
Transportation
Communication
Electric, gas, and sanitary services
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Services

19591964

19641969

—

—

—
+
—
+
+
+
+
+
—

—
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
—
A

Output
per Employee

19591964

19641969

19591964

19641969

+
+
A
—
+
+
+
—
+
+

+
+
+
—
—
+
—
—
+
+

+
+
—
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
—
—

+
+
—
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
—

Price
19591964
—

+
—
—
—
—
—
+
+
+

19641969
+
+
—
—
—
—
—
+
+
+

NOTE: Plus signs indicate above-average changes; minus signs indicate belowaverage changes; and A signifies average change.
Source: U. S. Department of Commerce

private economy between 1959 and 1964, but

increase in manufacturing, fo r example, more than

then rose two-thirds faster during the following

quadrupled

five years (reflecting the fact that the industry's

responsible was the durable goods industry, which

selling prices—determined in the short run much

sustained a greater cutback in productivity growth

more

between the two periods.

Largely

than

and a more severe increase in unit labor cost than

demand—rose faster than its buying prices).
The other four problem industries w ith above

the nondurable goods industry. Moderate price

average rates of price increase (contract construc­

ted to the low rate of price increase during the

by

conditions

of

supply

rather

declines in the wholesale trade industry contribu­

tion; services; retail trade; and finance, insurance,

1959-1964 period, but the situation was reversed

and real estate) all have been consistently charac­

during the following five years, when wholesale

terized by low productivity growth, and their

trade incurred relatively large price increases. A

impact on the overall rate of inflation in the

less pronounced price reversal also occurred in the

private economy is clearly evident from an inspec­

mining industry.

tion of the data in Table II. Other industries w ith
below average rates of price increase, however,
also

contributed

CONCLUDING COMMENTS

to the nearly trebled rate of

It is impossible to distinguish between cause

inflation in the private economy between the two

and effect in examining aggregative sets of indus­

five-year periods under review. The rate of price

try data relating to price. The blame for the

Digitized for12
FRASER


S E PT E M B E R 1970
Trends in Wages and Salaries Per Employee and
Supplements Per Employee,
1959-1969
Average Annual Percent Change,
1969

Compounded
Wages and Salaries
Per Employee
196419591964
1969
Private economy
Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries
Mining
Contract construction
Manufacturing
Nondurable goods
Durable goods
Transportation
Communication
Electric, gas, and sanitary services
Wholesale and retail trade
Finance, insurance, and real estate
Services

3.6%
3.8
3.4
4.0
3.5
3.3
3.6
3.6
4.6
4.2
3.4
3.7
4.2

5.1%
8.6
5.7
6.4
4.6
4.8
4.4
5.3
4.5
5.0
4.4
5.4
5.9

Supplements
Per Employee
196419591964
1969
7.5%
14.3
5.2
8.5
7.6
6.6
8.1
6.0
8.8
7.2
7.8
8.5
9.9

7.8%
15.6
7.2
5.4
7.5
7.5
7.3
8.1
8.6
6.4
8.3
7.7
10.9

Wages and Salaries
Per Employee

Supplements
As a Percent
of Total
Compensation

$7,074
2,894
8,587
8,628
7,768
6,977
8,319
9,293
8,032
9,016
6,523
7,596
5,495

10.0%
6.0
11.0
8.0
12.4
11.7
12.8
10.7
13.4
13.5
7.5
11.9
6.1

Source: U. S. Department of Commerce

accelerated pace of inflation in recent years should

cited for certain industries d o 'n o t cause inflation,

not fall on any particular industry, although it

but instead are the effect of a more rapid rate of

does seem clear that inflationary pressures have

advance in prices. A t any rate, it is hoped that this

stemmed more forcefully from some industries

article has contributed to a better understanding

than others. By the same token, caution should be

of the relationships between growth in output,

exercised before pinning the burden of inflation

employee compensation, and productivity, and the

on any particular type of cost. As a case in point,

interaction of changes in the major components of

the recent increases in unit interest cost that were

unit costs in the determination of price.

APPENDIX
The previous discussion of trends in compensa­

during the past decade (see Appendix table). By

tion per employee made no attempt to distinguish

1969, supplements accounted fo r 10 percent of

between wages and salaries per employee and

total employee compensation in the private econ­

supplements per employee. From the standpoint

omy, and fo r more than 13 percent in several

of an employer, and fo r the economy as a whole, a

industries.

dollar "paid” to an employee for supplements is
just as much a part of total cost as is a dollar paid
for wages and salaries.
In

It is noteworthy that in the agriculture, fo r­
estry, and fisheries industry

both wages and

salaries

supplements

per

employee

and

per

most industries, supplements grew at a

employee grew at the fastest rates among all

consistently faster rate that wages and salaries

industries in recent years; nevertheless, both the




13

ECONOMIC REVIEW

average

wage

level

per

full-tim e

equivalent

wages and salaries rather than in supplements. (In

employee and supplements as a percent of total

the contract construction industry, supplements

compensation were still considerably below aver­

accounted

age in 1969. The services industry is also character­

employee compensation between 1959 and 1964,

ized by a low wage level and low supplements,

but only 7.3 percent of the gain during the

despite growth rates consistently above average in

following five years.) Unlike contract construc­

both wages and supplements.

tion, the other four industries experiencing an

fo r

13.1

percent

of the gain

in

easing in the rate of increase in supplements during
Some industries experienced slower rates of

the recent five-year period (durable goods manu­

increase in supplements per employee between the

facturing; communication; electric, gas, and sani­

two periods, 1959 to 1964 and 1964 to 1969. The

tary services; and finance, insurance, and real

largest reduction occurred in the contract con­

estate) each continued to have supplements grow­

struction industry. In recent years, construction

ing at a faster rate than wages and salaries, and in

workers apparently have elected to receive a larger

1969 each had above average shares of supple­

share of their gains in compensation in the form of

ments in employee compensation.

Digitized for 14
FRASER


SEPTEMBER 1970

REGISTERED BANK HOLDING COMPANY
ACTIVITY IN OHIO, 1964-1969
Before 1964, there were only two registered

not include governmental corporations, partner­

bank holding companies in Ohio. One of the

ships, and individuals. Bank holding companies

registered bank holding companies was formed in

may not acquire nonbanking companies except in

1929 and held 22 banks concentrated in the

certain limited circumstances where the activities

counties

of the company to be acquired are closely related

surrounding

Columbus.

The

other

registered bank holding company was formed in
Clark

County

in the late 1950's to broaden

to the business of banking.
To date, most registered bank holding com­

banking services fo r a mutual savings bank. Since

panies in Ohio were formed by large banks located

1964, six registered bank holding companies have

in metropolitan areas that wish to expand their

been formed in Ohio and their affiliated banks are

operations. The bank that initiates the form ation

located in most areas in the state.1 The holding

of the bank holding company is customarily

company headquartered in Clark County discon­

referred to as the “ lead bank." In most cases,

tinued

management o f the lead bank forms a corporation

its operations in

1965, and all o f its

affiliates, which were located in Clark County,

and offers a proposal to the bank's stockholders

were merged into one commercial bank. There­

whereby they may exchange the shares they hold

fore, this registered bank holding company was

of the bank fo r shares in the new corporation.

removed from the data for the years after 1964.
The term

registered bank holding company

Once this exchange is consummated, management
of the newly formed corporation seeks to acquire

refers to any company that directly or indirectly

the stock of an additional bank or banks. A fter an

owns, controls, or holds w ith power to vote 25

agreement is reached w ith the bank to be acquired,

percent or more of the voting shares of two or
o
more banks.
Such a company may be any

the lead bank submits an application to the Board

corporation, business trust or association, but does

of Governors of the Federal Reserve System for
prior approval to complete the transaction. In
other cases, the corporation is formed, but no

1One of the six new holding companies was formed in
1970 and is excluded from data used in this article.

2

action is taken to acquire shares of the lead bank
until an agreement is reached w ith another bank to

This bank was subsequently acquired by another bank
holding company in 1967.

join the initiating bank in forming a registered

3

cation is submitted to the Board of Governors for

In general, shares held or controlled in a fiduciary
capacity by a bank are excluded.




bank holding company. In such a case, an appli­
prior approval for the corporation to acquire both
15

ECONOMIC REVIEW

simultaneously. According to the Bank Holding

company refers only to registered bank holding

Company Act, the Board of Governors has sole

companies.

authority for approving or disapproving requests
for

Growth of Holding Company Influence in

the formation of registered bank holding

Ohio. As mentioned earlier, there were two regis­

companies and subsequent acquisitions. Banks that

tered bank holding companies operating in Ohio at

are owned by bank holding companies are ordi­

yearend 1964. Together these two holding com­

narily referred to as bank holding company a ffil­

panies controlled 24 commercial banks and oper­

iates.

ated 51 branch offices. These 75 banking offices

Although the Board of Governors applies the

accounted for 5.3 percent of the banking offices in

provisions of The Bank Holding Company Act of

Ohio at yearend 1964. Between 1964 and 1969,

1956 in approving the proposed transaction, the

five

Department of Justice has 30 days in which to

formed.6 During the period under review, only

registered

bank

holding companies were

bring suit to prevent the acquisition or formation

three of the newly formed bank holding com­

should antitrust laws appear to be violated.4 The

panies proceeded to acquire one or more commer­

holding company may not proceed to acquire the

cial banking affiliates. There were 18 additional

bank during this 30-day period.
Recently, the phrase one-bank holding com­

banks that became holding company affiliates in
the

1964-1969 period as a result of holding

pany has become more prominent. Any company

company acquisitions and formations, compared

that owns or controls only one bank is referred to

w ith 24 banks in the 35-year period from 1929 to

as a one-bank holding company. One-bank holding

1964 (see table).7

companies are not subject to the control or

The increase in the number of banking offices

regulation of present bank holding company legis­

operated by affiliates of bank holding companies

lation or the Board o f Governors.5 Therefore,

was much greater than the gain in the number of

their acquisition opportunities and operations are

banks during the period. To a large extent, the

not limited to only bank related functions, and

sizable increase in banking offices controlled by

they may enter into activities that are not open to

bank holding companies was due to the fact that

registered bank holding companies or independent

the lead bank generally had a large number of

banks. The banking affiliate of a one-bank holding

branch offices. The number o f banking offices

company is, however, subject to the same banking

under the control of bank holding companies rose

legislation and regulation as any other commercial

from 75 offices in 1964 to 216 at yearend 1969.

bank.

As a result of the gain o f 141 offices,the share of

In this article, the term bank holding

4

The Sherman Act and The Clayton Act are normally
cited in cases brought by the Justice Department.

banking offices in the state under the control of
bank holding companies increased from 5.3 per­
cent in 1964 to 12.5 percent in 1969. With the

^The U. S. Congress is presently considering legislation
which would bring one-bank holding companies under
some form of Federal regulation. For a discussion of this
proposed legislation, see "Pending Federal Legislation
Concerning One-Bank Holding Companies," Econom ic
Com mentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, August
31, 1970.

Digitized for 16
FRASER


A net addition of only four after allowing for elimi­
nation of one of the prior existing holding companies via
merger of affiliates in 1965.
^Includes three banks acquired by holding companies in
January 1970 that were approved for acquisition in 1969.

SEPTEMBER 1970
Total Banking Offices, Deposits and Loans of Registered Bank Holding
Companies in Ohio
1964-1969
1964
Number of Companies

1966

1965*

1968t

1967

1969$

2

2

2

3

4

24
51
75
5.3%

25
74
99
6.6%

26
80
106
6.9%

29
107
136
8.5%

31
136
167
10.1%

39
177
216
12.5%

791.5
5.7%

$ 1,413.6
9.3%

$ 1,531.5
9.5%

$ 2,181.4
12.2%

$ 2,807.7
14.5%

$ 3,439.8
17.5%

6

Banking Offices
Banks
Branches
Total
Total as percent of State total
Total Deposits!
Held by bank holding companies
(thous. of $)
Percent of State total

$

Gross Loans §
Held by bank holding companies
(thous. of $)
Percent of State total

$

405.4
5.2%

$

811.3
9.5%

$

955.7
10.2%

$ 1,237.8
1 2.6%

$ 1,619.9
14.6%

$ 2,153.6
1 7.6%

532
1,069
1,601
$17,865.6
$ 9,860.5

526
1,130
1,656
$19,371.6
$11,069.9

522
1,211
1,733
$19,699.4
$12,220.6

State Totals
Banks
Branches
Banking Offices
Deposits (thous. of $)
Loans § (thous. of $)

549
873
1,422
$13,820.5
$ 7,750.8

543
948
1,491
$15,136.5
$ 8,564.5

538
1,009
1,547
$16,126.1
$ 9,408.9

* One holding company went out of existence, but a new one was formed,
t One affiliated bank merged with another affiliated bank.
t Included in 1969 data are three banks acquired by existing registered bank
holding companies which were approved in 1969 but were not actually acquired
until January 1970.
§ Excludes hypothecated deposits.

Sources: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation; Federal Reserve Bulletin-, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

exception o f 1966, the annual increase in the

volume of loans outstanding at bank holding

number of banking offices under the control of

companies (see table). These gains in deposits and

bank holding companies exceeded that of the

loans principally reflect the large size of the lead

previous year (see table).

banks in the holding companies formed during this

The volume of deposits and loans accounted for

period. In general, the lead banks of bank holding

by bank holding companies increased even more

companies were among the state's largest banks in

rapidly than the number of banking offices. From

terms of deposits and loans.

yearend 1964 to yearend 1969, deposits of bank

Geographic Location o f Holding Companies. In

holding companies grew fro m .$791.5 m illion to

general, in Ohio, a commercial bank may branch

$3,439.8 m illion, increasing from 5.7 percent to

only throughout the county in which it is head­

17.5 percent of deposits held by all banks in the
state. Similarly, there was a marked increase in the

quartered. A bank holding company, however, can




acquire affiliates anywhere in Ohio.
17

ECONOMIC REVIEW


18


SEPTEMBER 1970

A t yearend 1964, there were affiliates of bank

Affiliated banks in nine counties accounted for

holding companies in 20 of Ohio's 88 counties. By

between 25 percent and 50 percent of the deposits

yearend 1969, affiliated banks were located in 31
counties, w ith six of these counties added in 1969

in their county. Of the eight counties where bank
holding company affiliates held more than 50

alone (see Map 1).

percent of the deposits, affiliates held up to 75

Twelve of the 39 banks affiliated w ith bank

percent of the deposits in five counties; in one

holding companies at yearend 1969 were the

county holding company affiliates accounted for

largest banks in

75 percent to 90 percent o f the deposits; and in

their respective home office

counties in terms o f deposits, and 14 were the

two counties, affiliates held more than 90 percent.

largest in terms o f loans. A t yearend 1964, nine

The concentration in loans held by bank holding

affiliated banks were the largest banks in their

company affiliates was essentailly the same as that

respective home office counties in terms of de­

in deposits (see Map 3).

posits, and 10 were the largest in terms o f loans.
However, the lead bank of the five new bank

Since there were 39 banks affiliated w ith bank

holding companies formed since 1964 was not the

holding companies in 31 counties, some counties

largest bank in its home office county in terms of

had more than one bank affiliated w ith a bank

loans or deposits when the holding company was

holding company. Five counties had more than

formed. Thus, the increase in the number of

one affiliated bank and included the three in

affiliates that are the largest bank in the county

which 75 percent or more o f deposits are under

represents acquisitions of banks that were the

the control of holding companies (see Map 4). In

largest bank in their county rather than the size of

each of these five counties, the largest bank in

the lead bank. A fter excluding the five lead banks,

both deposits and loans is a holding company

five of the 13 banks that have become affiliates

affiliate.

since 1964 were the largest banks in terms of both

Four of Ohio's six registered bank holding

deposits and loans in their counties at the time of

companies are headquartered in Columbus, Ohio

acquisition. In 1969 alone, three o f the eight

(Franklin County). However, one does not have an

banks that were acquired were the largest banks in

affiliate in Franklin County, while one other has

their counties in terms of both deposits and loans.

two affiliated banks in Columbus. This is the only

One affiliated bank became the largest bank in

area in the state where a single holding company

its county in terms of deposits, and three became

has more than one bank in a single county. As a

the largest banks in terms of loans. Two affiliated

result, Franklin County has four banks affiliated

banks that had been the largest in their counties in

w ith bank holding companies, the most for any

terms of deposits and three affiliated banks that

county in the state.

had been the largest in terms of loans fell from
that position during the 1964-1969 period.

Ross County has three banks affiliated w ith
registered bank holding companies, although these

A t yearend 1969, bank holding company a ffil­

three banks as a group control less than 75 percent

iates accounted for less than 25 percent of the

of deposits and loans at banks in the county.

deposits at banks in 14 of the 31 counties in which

Coshocton County has only tw o commercial banks

bank holding companies own banks (see Map 2).

and both are owned by holding companies. Clark




19

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Map 2.

SHARE of DEPOSITS ACCOUNTED for by REGISTERED BANK HOLDING C O M P A N Y
AFFILIATES by COUNTY as of JUNE 30, 1 9 6 9 *

ASHTA
BULA
LU C AS

FU LT O N

W IL L IA M s l

GEAUGA

OTTAW A
CUYAHOGA

W OOD
SANDUSKY

PO R T A G E
IR ON
P A U L D IN G
PUTNAM

M A H O N IN G
HANCOCK
ASH _ |
CR AW

V A N W ER T

[W Y A N D O T FO R D

A LLE N

R IC H ­

[l a n d

W AYNE

C O L U M B IA N A

LA N D

H A R D IN
H O LM ES

A U G L A IZ E

M OR
ROW

TUSCARAW AS

C AR R O LL

KNOX

iSH ELBY j
D ELA W A RE
C H A M P A IG N

L IC K IN G

B E LM O N T

;r a n k i
C LA RK -

M U S K IN G U M '
N O BLE

MONT ~
G O M ER Y

M A D IS O N

P ICK AW AY

W A S H IN G T O N

FAYETTE.
BU TLE R

W ARREN

M O N RO E

[M O R G A N

H O C K IN G '
C L IN T O N

ATHENS
V iN T O N

H A M IL T O N

(C L E R ­
MONT

'B RO W N

ADAM S

SC IO TO

Less than 25%
.LAW R E N C E

25% - 49.9%

50% - 74.9%

m

75% - 89.9%

□

90% - 100%

*Less
So u rce :

h y p o th e c a te d d eposits.
F e d e ra l R e s e rv e B an k o f C le v e la n d

Digitized for20
FRASER


□
□

SEPTEMBER 1970

M ap 3.

SHARE of LOANS ACCOUNTED for by REGISTERED BANK HOLDING C O M P A N Y
AFFILIATES by COUNTY as of JUNE 30, 1969 *

ASHTA
BU LA
FULTO N

W IL L IA M S

OTTAW A:

TR UM BU LL

CUYAHOGA

W OOD
SANDUSKY
LO R A II

SUM

HURON
PUTNAM

M A H O N IN G

HANCOCK
ASH _ |
[l a n d

CR AW
V A N W ER T

W AYNE

C O L U M B IA N A

IY A N D O T FO R D

A LLE N
H A R D IN

M A R IO N

H O LM ES
MOR
ROW

LO G AN

TUSCARAW AS

KN O X

IS H E LB Y
CO SH O C TO N
DARKE

D ELA W A RE
C H A M P A IG N

BE LM O N T
R A N K L IN
M U S K IN G U M
NOBLE

MONT “
GOMER'

M A D IS O N

PICK AW AY

MONROE

Im o r g a n
W A S H IN G T O N

W ARREN

H O C KIN G ;
C L IN T O N

ATHENS
V IN T O N

HAM I L t d I
ig h l a n d

JAC KS O N
BROW N

GA LLI
ADAM S

Less than 25%
-AW RENC E

25% - 49.9%

50% - 74.9%

75% - 89.9%

90% - 100%

*Less

h yp o th e cated deposits.

So u rce :

F e d e r a l R e se rve




Bank

of C le v e la n d

21

ECONOMIC REVIEW


22
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

SEPTEMBER 1970

and Fayette Counties also have two banks a ffil­
iated w ith bank holding companies.

acquisitions are approved, holding companies w ill
have the authority to operate banking offices in 16
additional counties. This would bring the number

Registered Bank Holding Company Activity in

of counties in which holding company affiliates

1970. The Board o f Governors has approved the

are permitted to have offices to 47, or more than

form ation of a seventh registered bank holding

half of the counties in Ohio.

company in Ohio. In addition, another large bank
in the state has announced its intention to become

CONCLUDING COMMENTS

the lead bank of a proposed eighth bank holding

Registered bank holding company formations

company in the state. Furthermore, as of August

and acquisitions have increased sharply, especially

1970,

since 1966. In a period of approximately three

existing

bank

holding companies have

received approval to acquire ten banks in the state,

years, from mid-1967 to August 1970, the number

have applications pending to acquire two banks,

of registered bank holding companies rose from

and have announced intentions to acquire five

two to seven, w ith intentions already announced

additional banks. These holding company forma­

to form an eighth. During this three-year period,

tions and acquisitions could increase the number

the potential net gain in holding company a ffil­

of bank holding companies in the state to eight

iates amounts to

34

banks.

Registered bank

and the number of holding company bank a ffil­

holding companies control more than 10 percent

iates to 60.

of the banks in Ohio and more than 20 percent of

Thus far in 1970, seven of the 21 actual or

the loans and deposits at banks in the state.

proposed bank acquisitions are the largest banks in

Nevertheless, the bank holding company move­

their home office county. If all of the proposed

ment in Ohio is still in the early stages.




23