View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY

SEPTEMBER 1952
CONTENTS
The National Product Before
and After K o re a....................................... 1

Keview

Farm Short-Term Debt—Top-Heavy?
Announcement

.

7

............................................ 10

The Rare Earths and Their Future . . .

11

FIN AN CE • INDUSTRY • A G R ICU LTU R E • TRADE
FOURTH
Vol. 34—No. 9

FEDERAL

RESERVE

DISTRICT

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

,

Cleveland 1 Ohio

The National Product Before and After Korea
time has now elapsed since the
SUFFICIENT
outbreak of the Korean war to yield a fair per­

spective on the principal ways in which the nation’s
pattern of economic activity has changed. The
period from mid-1950 through the second calendar
quarter of 1952 — the latest for which data on
national product are available at this time—embraces
eight calendar quarters, or the equivalent of two
full years.
Such a “post-Korean” period takes its place as the
second broad phase of the seven-year span since the
end of World War II, including an almost unbroken
continuity of brisk economic activity in the aggre­
gate. For convenience, the first postwar phase is
designated as “pre-Korean” (from 1946 through
the 2nd quarter of 1950) as distinguished from the
second or post-Korean phase (from the 3rd quarter
The GNP Concept. The Gross National Product or
Expenditure is a statistical estimate of the market value of
the total output of goods and services currently produced
in the national economy, before deduction for depreciation
and other allowances for consumption of durable capital
goods.
The main streams of the Gross National Product are
the purchase of goods and services by consumers and by
government (including federal, state, and local), gross pri­
vate domestic investment (including new construction, in­
vestment in producers’ durable equipment, inventory
changes) and net foreign investment.
All dollar figures for GNP or its parts used in this
article, unless otherwise specified, are the official estimates
of the U. S. Department of Commerce, National Income
Division. Interpretations, as well as percentage computa­
tions, are our own.



of 1950 to the present).
To discern similarities as well as differences in the
composition of the national product in the two
periods thus defined is the central aim of the article
which follows. For this purpose examination is made
of the total, as well as the makeup, of the statistical
measure known as the Gross National Product or
Expenditure, or GNP for short.
M ovem ent o f the N atio nal P ro d u c t and Its Parts

The first chart of the series shown on page 4 de­
picts the course of the Gross National Product, as
well as a number of its more important constituents,
from the first quarter of 1946 through the second
quarter of 1952. Looking first at the total, without
reference to the parts, it is clear that: (a) GNP has
risen during the entire period except for the year
1949, during which it sagged moderately, and (b) the
rise in total GNP was accelerated in the early stages
of what is called here the post-Korean period, espe­
cially during the last half of 1950 and the early part
of 1951.
Before proceeding from the total to the parts of
GNP, it should be noted that all figures shown on
the charts are in current dollars, with no correction
for price changes. That is the way in which GNP
is compiled and ordinarily published. The question
springs to mind, however, whether gains in GNP
are illusory, reflecting merely the effects of price
increase. The answer is that gains in GNP have
been partly, but far from entirely, illusory in this
sense. For example, the rise in total GNP in current
dollars from the year 1950 to the year 1951 was

Page 2

Monthly Business Review

about 16 percent; after allowance is made for price
rises in the interval, the gain in GNP (in “constant
dollars” ) is about 8 percent.(1) Furthermore, during
each quarter since June 1950, it appears that GNP
has increased even after allowances for price changes,
although such gains would not be as large as those
shown on the chart.
Six important components of GNP are shown in
the first chart on page 4. Altogether they account
for a large part of GNP, and a consideration of their
magnitudes may help provide a framework for assay­
ing day-to-day problems as the nation moves forward
toward the “plateau of rearmament.” The perspec­
tive which they yield may also be useful in taking
the dimensions of the problems which will be faced
when (or if) the rearmament program is eventually
unwound, —- at least in part.
The remaining three components designated as
“All Other” are shown in detail on the smaller chart
in the lower right comer of the same page.
The heavily shaded area at the base
of the first chart indicates in billions
of dollars, the portion of GNP rep­
resented by federal government purchases of goods
and services, — mainly but not altogether for defense.
Its rise since Korea is obvious. It is equally clear,
however, that the federal government’s share even
after the rise has not been as large as certain other
components of GNP. (More details on proportionate
parts are discussed at a later point.)
Government
Purchases

The item marked “Producer Durables,” located on the chart just above
the area for government purchases,
refers to private investment in producer? durable
equipment, e.g., machinery and plant equipment of
all kinds. This share, although it has not risen as
spectacularly as government expenditures, has been
important in the period since Korea; its connection
both with the defense effort and with the brisk pace
of economic activity in recent times is a matter of
common knowledge. “Producer Durables” together
with “Construction,” standing for private investment
in new construction, constitute the bulk of the broad
segment of GNP classified by the Department of
Commerce as Gross Private Domestic Investment.
(Inventory changes, shown nearer the top of the
chart, are also part of gross private domestic in­
vestment.)
Private
Investment

(1) Based on Department of Commerce estimates of GNP in “con­
stant dollars.”
The relationships discussed in this article are all in current,
rather than constant, dollar terms, for the reasons that: (a) constant
dollar estimates are not available regularly on a quarterly basis (b)
relationships between parts of GNP, as for example when expressed
as percentages of the total, tend to hold broadly true whether or not
attempt is made to remove the effects of price change all along the
line.



September 1, 1952

The next layer, reading upward on
the chart, is “Consumer Durables,”
or more exactly, personal consump­
tion expenditures for durable goods, e.g., autos,
appliances, furniture, etc. As a part of GNP, this
sector appears in the chart to be somewhat steadier
than might have been expected in view of the wellknown fluctuations in production and sales of such
goods during the postwar period. (The scale of the
chart is small relative to the billions of dollars in­
volved.) The two “post-Korean” scare buying epi­
sodes, however, are reflected in the chart by waves
cresting at the third quarter of 1950 and the first
quarter of 1951.
The sector entitled “Consumer Nondurables” is, as
usual, by far the largest single major component of
GNP. This refers to personal consumption expendi­
tures for nondurable goods, including such vital con­
sumer items as food and clothing. It is obvious from
the chart that consumer expenditures for nondurables
has tended to rise somewhat in dollar volume, but
since Korea has declined as a proportion of GNP.
Personal
Consumption

The dotted area above or below the
upper boundary of the consumer non­
durable segment represents changes in
business inventories. During 1946 and 1948 it was
an appreciable “plus” amount to take account of
net additions to inventories of all kinds. During the
minor recession of 1949, inventory reductions were
a significant “minus” element in the GNP total.
After Korea, inventory building was resumed on a
large scale, due partly to fears of impending short­
ages, and became a large “plus” item by the second
quarter of 1951. Subsequently, inventory building
diminished, finally reaching a point during the first
two quarters of this year where inventories show
little over-all change.
Inventory
Change

The Parts of GNP designated as “All
Other” now require explanation.
Included are personal consumption
expenditures for services, purchases of goods and
services by state and local governments, and net for­
eign investment. Neither consumer services nor statelocal government purchases have shown any sharp
increase in the “post-Korean” period, although the
dollar volumes tend to rise persistently from 1946
to the present.
Net foreign investment, which broadly includes
the excess of exports over imports (other than those
exports financed by grants or gifts) together with re­
lated items, represented an addition to total GNP
during several of the earlier postwar years, and also,
to a less extent, during recent quarters. During 1950
and early 1951, however, the foreign account was a
“minus” item in GNP reflecting in part a sharp in­
crease in imports of raw materials.
Other Parts
of GNP

September 1, 1952

Monthly Business Review

Shares of the Total

The foregoing resume of trends in total GNP and
its major parts, as illustrated by the first two charts,
is intended to show the main movements in national
production before and after Korea, in a general con­
text which exhibits the relative size of the various
parts.
Within wide limits the relation of the parts to
each other is constant. For example, consumer ex­
penditures for nondurable goods by their very nature
(a vast aggregate of many relatively small, but re­
curring, purchases on behalf of 157 million people)
involve a considerably larger dollar total than invest­
ment in new construction, even in times when the
latter is on the rise.
A closer view of recent changes in the composition
of GNP requires a device such as that shown by the
chart at the left side of page 5. Each of certain
selected parts of GNP is expressed as a percentage
of total GNP, and such percentages or “shares” are
charted over the time periods under discussion, in
such a way that the tendencies of change in the
various shares may be compared.
Reading downward on the “share” chart,
and paying special attention to the positions at the right of the red lines (postKorean period) it is clear at a glance
that federal government purchases of goods and
services make up the only major component which
has risen since Korea as a percentage of total GNP.
Investment in producers’ durable equipment has kept
pace in general with the rise of total GNP, as indi­
cated by the relative steadiness of the line which
represents its share. The share of total GNP repre­
sented by investment in new private construction, on
the other hand, fell off somewhat in 1951, and then
rebounded during the first two quarters of this year.
Enlarging
or Steady
Shares

On the consumption side, as represented by the three segments at the
bottom half of the chart, the central
tendency has been a decline of the respective com­
ponents when measured as percentages of total GNP.
In the case of personal consumption expenditures for
durable goods, the post-Korean period opens with
expenditures on such goods (autos, appliances, fur­
niture, etc.,) at an alltime peak not only in dollars,
but also as a proportion of GNP. This was the re­
sult of the scare buying immediately following the
Korean outbreak. (It is interesting to note that con­
currently, government expenditures as a percentage
of GNP were at a temporary trough, prior to their
renewed climb. See top section of chart.) The re­
action to the scare buying of consumer durables,
coupled with competing demands on materials en­
tailed by the rearmament effort, resulted in a marked
drop in consumer durables as a share of GNP dur­

Diminishing
Shares




Page 3

ing late 1950 and parts of 1951. During the past
four quarters, however, this segment of GNP has
tended to hold its own with the total.
In the case of the share of GNP represented by
personal consumption expenditures for nondurable
goods, the tendency to decline has been rather per­
sistent during the period since 1947. (This is the
other side of the coin from the emphasis on invest­
ment, durable goods, and defense that has character­
ized the postwar period in general.) Thus, from a
high in the third quarter in 1947 when consumer
nondurables represented 41.4 percent of GNP, this
important component dropped to a low during the
second quarter of 1951, when it was 33.8 percent
of GNP. During the most recent four quarters, the
ratio has recovered slightly, and has been running
somewhat above 34 percent.
Personal consumption expenditures for services as
a proportion of GNP, depicted in the final strip of
the “share” chart, reached its highest point of the
postwar period in 1949, when the dollar volume of
expenditures for such services was sustained at the
same time that the most volatile components of
GNP were declining. Since Korea, the ratio declined
for a time, but during the past year or more it has
leveled off at a position about the same as in 1947
and 1948.(2)
The small chart in the lower right corner of page 5
summarizes the changes in the various components
of GNP expressed as percentage shares of the total.
For each share, the average for the peacetime years
of 1935-39 is portrayed as a benchmark for com­
parison with averages for the pre-Korean and postKorean phases of the postwar period.
Viewed against the background of the late 1930s,
it is clear that federal government purchases, pro­
ducer durables and new construction show a broadly
comparable pattern. In all three cases, the postwar
shares of total GNP are substantially larger than the
1935-39 percentages, and in all three cases the postKorean share is larger than the pre-Korean share.
In the case of federal government purchases, the
post-Korean share is more than twice the 1935-39
share, expressed as a percentage of total GNP.
The role of consumer durables is somewhat differ­
ent. Here the post-Korean share of total GNP is
smaller than the pre-Korean share, although larger
than the 1935-39 share.
Consumption expenditures for nondurable goods
and for services, both of which are large components
of GNP, have behaved at the opposite extreme of
federal government purchases as a share of GNP.
(Contrast extreme right of the bar chart with the
extreme left.) In the case of these consumption
items, the pre-Korean phase of the postwar period
(2) The elements of GNP which are not shown in the “share”
chart are state-local government expenditures, inventory change and
net foreign investment.

Monthly Business Review

Page 4

September 1, 1952

COMPOSITION OF GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
Quarterly 1946-1952
(Seasonally Adjusted, Annual Rates)
B ILL IO N S
OF D O LLARS

B ILLIO N S
OF DO LLARS

$360

$360

270

270

80

90

1947

. . . the gross national product has risen in each quarter of the entire postwar
span, except during 1949; purchases of goods and services by the federal govern­
ment have been an important element in the rise since the outbreak of the
Korean War; inventory building was significant in late ’50 and the first half of
’51; personal consumption expenditures for nondurable goods (the largest single
component of GNP) has tended to rise in dollar volume but to decline somewhat
as a proportionate part of GNP.
COMPOSITION OF “ALL OTHER”
Components of GNP Not Shown in Detail in Previous
Chart
(Seasonally Adjusted, Annual Rates)
B IL L IO N S

BILL IO N S

—

. . . largest of the remaining parts of the gross national
product (not itemized on the previous chart) are personal
consumption expenditures for services, and the total of
state-and-local governments’ expenditures for goods and
services; these have shown no acceleration since Korea.




OF D OLLARS

—(SI20

Monthly Business Review

September 1, 1952

Page 5

SELECTED COMPONENTS OF GROSS NATIONAL
PRODUCT
Expressed as Percentage of Total
(Quarterly 1947-1952; red marks date of Korean outbreak)
PERCENT
OF GNP

PERC ENT
OF G N P

'F E D . GO ^ ’ T.

PUR CHASES

✓

. . . purchases of goods and services by the federal gov­
ernment have accounted for an increasing share of the
total GNP since Korea, but the rate of rise has been slow­
ing in recent quarters.

-

. . . private investment in producers’ durable equipment,
expressed as a share of GNP, has been maintained fairly
steadily since Korea at a rate slightly higher than during
1947 to mid-’50.

-

— i—

A yvU -i

I9 48

i i i

I1 9 ,' 0 1

1 1 1 — i_ M * v V

° -P R O D U C ER DURAf3LES

-

-

-

--

w vV J— l

i

i

i

i

i

t

i

i

i

i

i

i

—1— 1—'WV*

- CONSTRlJCTION
-

—

i v u —l— 1

194 8
I I I

C O N SUM ER

t

i

i

D U R ABLES




i

195 0

i

i

i

i

. . . the share of GNP represented by private investment
in new construction showed some falling tendency during
1951, but rebounded in early 1952.
. . . personal consumption expenditures for durable goods
has accounted for a decreasing percentage of GNP since
the scare-buying peak of the 3rd quarter of ’50, but the
ratio has tended to level off during recent quarters.
. . . from early 1947 through mid-’51, personal consump­
tion expenditures for nondurable goods tended to decline
as a proportionate part of GNP; the last four quarters
have seen a slight recovery in this ratio.

-- 1--- 1—tyvi’

. . . personal consumption expenditures for services, ex­
pressed as a share of GNP, have returned about to the
1947-48 position, after a rise to a peak in late 1949.
AVERAGES FOR POST-KOREAN PERIOD,
COMPARED W ITH IMMEDIATE PRE-KOREAN
PERIOD, AND W ITH 1935-39
(For Selected Components of GNP, Expressed as % of Total)

of total GNP than during 1947 to mid-’50, and for about
twice as large a share as the average for the prewar years
of 1935-39; at the opposite extreme, consumer expendi­
tures for services have recently represented a smaller share
of GNP than in prewar times, and a smaller share after
Korea than just before Korea.

Monthly Business Review

Page 6

witnessed a decline of the percentage shares from
the 1935-39 average, and the decline was continued
further in the post-Korean phase.
Interrelations of the Parts

When one or more components of GNP rise as a
percentage of the total, it is arithmetically inevitable
that one or more of the other components will fall
as a proportion of the total. Does it follow from this
that the marked rise in federal government expendi­
tures during the post-Korean rearmament has been
at the expense of the other shares in the final reckon­
ing? Arithmetic does not answer this question. It
could be so, to the extent that demands are press­
ing on scarce materials and manpower, and actual
“physical diversion” takes place. The other possi­
bility is that the stimulating effects of government
expenditures (and the associated rise in private in­
vestment in equipment, etc.) make for a larger total
of real GNP than otherwise would be the case,
assuming the existence of the necessary industrial
capacity. Which way the balance falls in the period
under review is a very important question, but it will
not be tackled here; at best, the question is “iffy.”
Two additional facts, related to the showing made
by the charts, may serve to amplify the relation of
government expenditures to other parts of GNP.
(1) Although, as already noted, “federal govern­
ment expenditures” as a percentage share of GNP
is the only major component to have risen since
Korea, it is not the only component to register sig­
nificant increases in dollar volume during the postKorean period. Of the eight calendar quarters of
this period, five show rises in government purchases
which were substantially less than total gains in
GNP. (See Table 1, especially third and fifth col­
umns.) So far this year, however, gains in govern­
ment purchases have been about equal to the gains
in total GNP, which means stability in the dollar
totals of all other components together.
(2) The “share” chart reveals that major shifts
in the percentage makeup of GNP after Korea have
so far been confined to the first year, i.e., from mid’50 to mid-’51. By contrast, the four quarters from
mid-551 to mid-’52 show a greater stability of rela­
tions. (Concurrently, inflationary tensions were
easing.) This suggests the possibility, but not a
guarantee, of a smooth passage through the peak
period of rearmament lying ahead, and up to the
period of slackening of defense expenditures/35
(3) . A steadiness of relations among the parts of GNP is by defini­
tion an avoidance of certain types of strains and distortions. In it­
self, however, it is no guarantee against inflation. It is possible to
have a sharply inflationary situation when all major parts of GNP
are moving upward (in dollar terms) in an approximate unison.



September 1, 1952

Table 1
DOLLAR RISES IN FEDERAL GOV’T PURCHASES
COMPARED W ITH DOLLAR RISES IN GNP
(Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rates)
Federal Change from
Government Previous
Purchases
Quarter
1950—2Q
20.8
—3Q* 20.5
— .3
—4Q* 25.5
+ 5.0
1951—IQ* 30.8
+ 5.3
+ 7.5
—2Q* 38.3
—3Q
45.5
+7.2
—4Q* 48.9
+3.4
1952—IQ
51.2
+ 2.3
—2Q
54.9
+ 3.7

GNP

Change from
Previous
Quarter

277.8
291.3
304.2
319.6
329.3
330.9
337.1
339.4
343.0

+ 13.5
+12.9
+ 15.4
+ 9.7
+ 1.6
+ 6.2
+ 2.3
+ 3.6

* Quarters in which rises in federal government purchases were less
than total gain in GNP.

When the rearmament program is
over the crest two or three years
hence (according to the latest ver­
sion of the outlook) how will GNP be affected? This
question is already a subject of some public discus­
sion, in spite of the fact that little is now known
concerning the timing or the magnitude of possible
cutbacks in defense expenditures. A few broad ob­
servations and some illustrative questions may be
offered at this point.
In the first place numerous considerations point
to the likelihood that accompanying the defense cut­
back, private investment in producers’ durable equip­
ment and in new construction may be subject to
influences making for reductions in dollar volume.
Any such reduction in this combination of GNP
segments could be appreciable, although the pro­
portion of total GNP involved should not approach
the dimensions of the 1945-46 shift.
Partially or totally offsetting such a development,
however, there should be a stimulus to consumption
and to some types of investment, particularly as tax
reductions (both in personal and corporate taxes)
would be permitted by the reduction of defense out­
lays, thus providing a climate favorable both to con­
sumption and investment.
Will a rise in state-local government expenditures
also help to take up slack during the period when
defense outlays are reduced from peak levels? A
backlog of needs for highways and community facili­
ties is certainly suggestive here. No doubt problems
of local finances and taxation will be relevant.
How about that part of GNP called “net foreign
investment”? This item has not recently been a very
large part of GNP, nor has much reference to it been
included in the discussion above. However, the
whole question of the relation of this country to the

PostMobilization

(C O N T IN U E D O N P A G E 10)

Monthly Business Review

September 1, 1952

Page 7

Farm Short-Term Debt— Top-Heavy?
absolute dollar volume, the short-term debt of
I NAmerican
farmers today is the largest on record.

For each $1000 owed in 1939, farmers are now obli­
gated to the amount of $3100, in the form of short­
term debt.
On the other hand, in relation to the value and
volume of the instruments of production currently in
use in American agriculture, and the dollar value of
farm output, the present short-term debt of farmers
seems to be unusually small.
Between these two extremes there is another valid
comparison, namely, the ratio of short-term debt to
net income. By this third yardstick, short-term debt
is neither light nor heavy — at prevailing prices.
The real status and possible significance of the
“record” short-term debt of farmers can be appraised
only by surveying the situation from several different
angles, not one of which will provide a conclusive
answer by and of itself.
In Relation to
Credit is an almost universal
"Working Assets" prerequisite of rapid growth in
business. Any growing industry
requires a steady increase of investment not only in
Note: Short-term farm debt as used herein is to institutional lend­
ers only. These include all banks and federally sponsored agencies
and account currently for over one-half of thq total short-term debt.
Dealers, merchants, individuals, etc., are excluded. The discussion is
confined to outstandings on January 1 and does not attempt to
appraise turnover within the year. Comparisons represent national
averages and thus do not necessarily apply to all specific localities;
however, conditions within the Fourth District probably average at
least as good as the national average. Some debts secured by farm
mortgages are used to provide operating capital to purchase equip­
ment and livestock. Such debts are not considered in this discussion.

SHORT-TERM FARM DEBT*
B IL L IO N S
OF D O LL A R S

B IL L IO N S
OF O O LLA R S

plant but in the production implements therein. To
the farmer growth has meant more tractors, ma­
chinery, and livestock. These “tools” for production
have boosted farm output at unprecedented rates.
Yet the amount of short-term debt currently out­
standing is near the lowest in history in relation to
the investment in these “working assets.”
Farm short-term debt dropped to less than twelve
percent of the value of equipment and livestock
within a year after our entry into World War II. It
has remained at this low level throughout the seven
postwar years.
This contrasts sharply with the period following
World War I. By 1921, short-term debt had also
risen to a record dollar high which stood until this
year, but this debt was then equal to 40 percent of
the value of these non-real-estate assets. This un­
favorable relationship was followed by many years
of painful readjustment. The ratio was reduced to
25 percent by the early 1930’s, but was still in ex­
cess of 18 percent as recently as 1940 and 1941.
The current more favorable relationship between
debt and assets implies a greater security both for
lenders and for farm operators. A period of declin­
ing farm prices could reduce the valuation placed
upon these assets. The rate of loss, however, would
now have to be unprecedented in magnitude to pre­
cipitate a relationship as unfavorable as that which
existed during the most unfavorable periods of the
past four decades.
From 1930 to 1932 the value of farmers’ invest­
ment in equipment and livestock was reduced by 35
SHORT TERM DEBT PER $1,000 OF LIVESTOCK
AND EQUIPMENT ON FARMS
450
4 00
350
300
250

2 00

150

100
50

1910

. . . the short-term debt of farmers now exceeds $4 billion,
having recently broken through the former peak reached
21 years ago.
* As stated in the text, the data for this and all ensuing charts refer
to institutional debt only.
Source: Bureau of Agricultural Economics.



1915

1920

1925

1930

1935

1940

1945

0

1955

. . . for every $1,000 of livestock and equipment on the
farm the average farmer owes less than $120 in short-term
debt, as against $400 in 1922.
E Estimated.
Source: Derived from Bureau of Agricultural Economics data.

Monthly Business Review

Page 8

percent. It would now take a drop in excess of 50
percent to create a similar debt-asset ratio in spite
of the current record-high dollar debt. Similarly,
from 1920 to 1922 these assets were reduced in value
by 31 percent but the present value would have to
be cut by over two-thirds to create a ratio of com­
parable unfavorableness. Actually the rate of shrink­
age would likely have to be even greater because at
the same time the debt itself would tend to decline,
thus prolonging the period within which the relation­
ship would reach historical lows.
Never before have farmers been
able to repay a given quantity of
debt with so small a physical vol­
ume of farm output. Except for the brief interrup­
tion just prior to the Korean War, rising prices for
farm produce have reduced the amount of output
required to pay each $1000 of debt during every
year since 1939. The current favorable relationship
surpasses even that of the booming years of World
War I and ranges from one-half to less than onefourth that of all other years prior to 1940.
This relationship has been improved even more
by the fact that the physical volume of farm output
available for paying each unit of debt has also risen
to record heights. The greater output at rising prices
has boosted cash farm income at a rate and to a
level without parallel in the history of American
agriculture.
On the other hand, as has already been pointed
out, the short-term debt of farmers has by no means
remained fixed or constant during this period of ris­
ing income. Debt more than tripled during the past
thirteen years. The consequent ratio between actual
In Relation to
Cash Income

September 1, 1952

debt and actual cash farm income shows a some­
what different situation than the comparison of a
fixed debt with prices alone.
Gash farm income is expected to set another
record in 1952, the ninth in eleven years. The pro­
portion of this income, however, that will be needed
to pay the January 1 debt may be the largest since
1941 and about equal to the 1935-37 average. An
estimated 13 percent of the 1952 receipts will be
required if the carry-over of debt from last year is
paid in full. This would represent the fifth consecu­
tive year of increase from the all-time low of six
percent. It is still better, however, than in most
years previous to the last decade, particularly in
comparison with the 48 percent and 38 percent
reached in the extremely unfavorable years of 1921
and 1932.
^ anY warning sign is evident conRctio
ceming the general short-term debt
position of agriculture it would per­
haps be in the relationship it bears to net income.
Gross earnings have shown a marked change of
distribution in recent years with a much larger share
going to cover production costs. Net cash income
now amounts to roughly 45 percent of gross cash
income, whereas it was in excess of 57 percent for
many years prior to 1948. This change is significant
in that it is largely the remaining net income which
must be drawn upon to pay outstanding debt unless
assets are liquidated or the debt is refinanced with a
long-term real estate mortgage.
At the prevailing ratio of net to gross cash income,
the current short-term debt could become distinctly
and widely burdensome if the gross were reduced
Net Income

PHYSICAL VOLUME OF FARM OUTPUT NEEDED
TO PAY A $1,000 DEBT

PORTION OF GROSS CASH INCOME EQUIVALENT
TO SHORT-TERM DEBT

IN D EX

PERCENT

IN D EX

. . . in paying off a given short-term debt today, a farmer
needs only 36 bushels, pounds, or bales, as against over
160 in the extremely adverse year of 1932.
F Forecast.
Source: Derived from Bureau of Agricultural Economics data.




PERCENT

. . . to pay off existing short-term debt would require only
about 12 percent of gross income, as against nearly 50
percent in 1921. The percentage has been rising, how­
ever, since 1947.
F Forecast.
Source: Derived from Bureau of Agricultural Economics data.

Monthly Business Review

September 1, 1952

CASH FARM INCOME AND PRODUCTION
EXPENSES

SHORT-TERM DEBT AS A PERCENT OF NET
FARM INCOME
PERCENT

1935

1940

Page 9

PERCENT

1945

. . . a relatively small reduction in gross cash income to
early postwar levels could greatly handicap farmers’ debt
repaying ability, because production costs have also in­
creased sharply.

. . . the record short-term debt is not far from 30 percent
of net income (long time average)—the residual out of
which debts are paid.

F Forecast.
Source: Derived from Bureau of Agricultural Economics data.

F Forecast.
Source: Derived from Bureau of Agricultural Economics data.

merely to levels which prevailed during the early
postwar years. This assumes that prices paid by
farmers for production goods will largely maintain
their “sticky” tradition.
Both net income and short-term debt have fluctu­
ated widely over the past 42 years. An average of
all these years will show that about one-third of the
net income would be required if the debt carried
over from the previous year were to be paid in full.
This has ranged from a low of 11 percent in 1947
to a high point back in 1921 when the entire annual
net income would not have retired the debt.
The record dollar debt outstanding on last Janu­
ary 1 was not far from that average in relation to
prospective net income for the year of 1952. The
relationship was about as favorable during World
War I, and was more favorable in all but a few
years since the early 1930’s.
Net dollars remaining after subtraction of out­
standing debt may be greater in actual numbers now
than in other favorable periods previous to 1946.
Their buying power, however, has been greatly re­
duced and any substantial loss of them would cut
farm living standards and hinder agriculture’s ability
to mechanize and apply other improved practices

for high efficient production. Even the liquidation
of some existing production facilities would seem
probable should they fail to yield a satisfactory
return.
In the final analysis it appears that agriculture in
general is not in an immediate precarious position
even though dollar debt is the largest on record. In
some respects most farmers are in excellent condi­
tion. It must be conceded, however, that their
ability to repay the growing short-term debt out of
current income has become slowly but progressively
less favorable through most of the postwar years.
With the present debt load, a distinct and widespread
problem could emerge if gross cash receipts were
reduced even to World War II levels. This would
result in a considerable amount of asset liquidation
and refinancing of short-term loans. A temporary
weakening in domestic and foreign farm produce
demand of a smaller degree than has occurred in
many past periods could bring about such a situation.
The financial condition of many farmers would
undoubtedly carry them through a rather short-run
period of stress, but those who are heavily indebted
would be severely affected by a relatively small de­
cline in income.




Page 10

Monthly Business Review

NATIONAL PRODUCT
(C O N T IN U E D F R O M P A G E 6)

less developed parts of the world is bound to be of
continuing importance. A relatively substantial ex­
port of capital, both on private and public account,
is one of the possibilities for replacing the fractions
of GNP slated for reduction.
The above notions are merely indicative of dozens
of different permutations or combinations within the
structure of GNP which may occur if and when the
rearmament burden is lightened.
The possibility cannot be excluded that two less
enticing alternatives may be faced: (a) an economic




September 1, 1952

rescue mission, or pump-priming series of operations,
by the federal government in order to “fill the gap”
(structurally, this would maintain the federal gov­
ernment’s share of GNP at a high level, but by
means of activities quite different in important re­
spects from the present ones) or, (b) a business
recession. (The latter would imply a lowering of
the GNP total both in physical terms and in prices,
accompanied probably by unemployment and cumu­
lative decline in business indicators.) In view of the
resiliency under shock and strain which has been
demonstrated by the economy of the United States
in recent years, he would be rash indeed who would
forecast that a recession is bound to be the outcome.

A n n o u n ce m e n t

The Farmers and Merchants Bank, Fairborn, Ohio,
became a member of the Federal Reserve System on
August 7, 1952.
The new member bank is located in a town with
a population of about 10,000, a few miles northeast
of Dayton, Ohio.
Incorporation of the bank took place October 31,
1951. At the present time, combined capital and
surplus total $200,000. Officers of the new member
bank are:
A. E. Chenoweth............................................ President
D. W. H oak......................................... Vice President
................Cashier
Arthur J. Gneuhs ....
Assistant Cashier
Miss Marjorie Wones

Monthly Business Review

September 1, 1952

Page 11

The Rare Earths and Their Future
by CLYDE WILLIAMS, Director, Battelle Memorial Institute

A relatively unused group of
metals, only partially explored by
the scientist and seldom heard of
by most people, is today assuming
greater importance to industry.
Commonly known as the “rare
earths,” the fourteen metals in the
group have been classified in the
Periodic Table by the following
tongue-twisting names: cerium, pro­
methium, praesodymium, neody­
mium, samarium, europium, gado­
linium, terbium, dysprosium, holmium, erbium, thulium, ytterbium, and lutecium. Four
others, lanthanum, yttrium, scandium, and thorium, are
frequently attached to the rare-earth group because of their
close relationship in the Periodic Table, in some minerals,
and in some production properties.
The rising importance of the rare-earth metals stems
from several developments. First, recent discoveries of
large domestic resources of these raw materials will sup­
port a great expansion in their use for years to come.
They will not be produced in tonnage quantities com­
parable to such common metals as steel, copper, and
aluminum. They will, however, be used more to do a
job better than some other material is now doing, or to
do a job that some other material is unable to do. Second,
improved technological practice will provide scientists with
greater quantities of the individual rare earths and en­
able them to study industrial applications more completely.
Third, sizeable new markets for use of the rare earths may
develop in steelmaking, as well as in the aviation, elec­
tronics, and atomic energy industries.
Metallurgists have found that small amounts of the
rare earths can improve the quality of end products made
from such metals as steel, aluminum, and magnesium.
The rare earths, added to some primary metals, can im­
prove resistance to oxidation and corrosion at high tem­
peratures, impart strength, cut down impurities, and make
them easier to work into desired shapes.
Heretofore, it has been extremely difficult to isolate
the individual rare earths because they occur together
and are very much alike chemically. As many as 40,000
operations have been required to get some of the rarer
rare earths really pure. Present commercial usage, con­
sequently, has been largely confined to “misch metal,” a
mixed form of the rare-earth metals usually consisting of
50 per cent cerium, 30 per cent lanthanum, and a 20 per
cent combination of the other rare-earth metals with a
trace of iron.
The principal uses for the rare earths are as misch
metal, to make “sparking” flints for cigarette lighters, and
as oxide and fluoride compounds in the cores of arcing
carbons for moving-picture projectors and searchlights,
where they produce light of sun-like brilliance. Other
uses are as oxide or carbonate compounds in the glass
Editor’s Note — While the views expressed on this page are not nec­
essarily those of this bank, the Monthly Business Review is pleased to
make this space available for the discussion of significant develop­
ments in industrial research.




industry for coloring, polishing, and special optical effects,
and in the electronics industry for making capacitors. For
these and other highly specialized uses, the total consump­
tion of monazite sand, from which misch metal and the
rare-earth compounds have been derived in the past,
amounted to about 3,000 to 4,000 tons in the United
States in 1951.
Monazite sand has customarily been imported from
India and Brazil. India, in 1949, and Brazil, in 1951, im­
posed embargoes on the exports of die mineral. This was
done apparently to set up rare-earth processing operations
for sale of more profitable finished products, and to cur­
tail recovery of thorium for atomic energy uses by other
countries. The price of monazite soared from $60 to $300
per ton in the United States. Old domestic sources that
previously had been unprofitable to work were then re­
opened. An intensive search for rare-earth deposits also
followed in an attempt to make our country independent
in supply of the metals.
The recent search has brought forth startling discover­
ies of large deposits of rare earths in several western
states, including California, New Mexico, and Idaho. The
most promising discovery is contained in a huge “baritecarbonate rock” deposit, rich in bastnasite, found in
southern California. The mineral bastnasite is a com­
pound of cerium, lanthanum, and other rare-earth metals.
Reports have been made recently, based on drillings to
50 feet, showing that this deposit may contain a very
high potential of tonnage of the rare-earth metals.
Wider industrial usage of the rare earths has been
brought closer also by the work of the Atomic Energy
Commission in developing a more rapid, efficient method
of separating the individual metals. The AEC has a stake
in the rare earths because they occur as by-products of the
atomic energy pile. Furthermore, the mineral thorium,
usually found associated with the rare earths, is under
study as a possible raw material for atomic energy gen­
erators.
The AEC’s improved method for separating the indi­
vidual rare-earth metals is based on “ion exchange.” It
is expected that the ion-exchange method will be used
most extensively to isolate the more closely bound rare
earths, such as neodymium and praesodymium. The more
common rare earths, cerium and lanthanum, will probably
still be separated by the conventional method known as
fractional crystallization. A number of commercial firms
are reported to be producing the rare earths by both
methods.
There has not been much demand for the individual
rare earths because so little is known about their indi­
vidual properties, and such small quantities of isolated
metals have been available at reasonably low cost. The
tendency in the future, however, will be to separate the
individual metals into pure form. A frequent result of
purification is to give an entirely new field of usefulness
not realized from the impure metal of the past. Speedier
progress towards new uses is now possible, thanks to more
efficient methods for recovering the pure rare earths and
to a great improvement in the domestic supply of the raw
materials.




c iev eia n |>

TOLEDO
AKRON •

PA

• Jy o u n g s t o ^

CANTON •

4

. *
/PITTSBURGH

OHIO
DAYTON

• COLUMBUS

\ CINCINNATI

LEXINGTON

W h e e l in g

W. VA.

Fourth Federal
Reserve District
■ MAIN OFFICE
★ BRANCH OFFICES