View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY

Suiim M

evieut
IN

THIS

ISSUE

Liquidity and Economic S ta b ility............. 2

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of CLEVELAND

Around the Fourth District........................8
Liquidity in the Agricultural S e cto r........... 9

WaicA t963
S&ix',

V

. .■

In the current
r e c o v e r y period, t h e liq u ii
asset/G.N.P. ratio has deviated
■■> ■
.
fr o m its u s u a l
cy c lica l
for. Despite the
continuation of
th e r e c o v e r y ,
the ratio turned
up in the fourth
quarter of 1961
and c o n t in u e d
on an u n in t e r ­
rupted d i m
through the end
of 1962.




B i l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

R at i o ( percent)

600

.84

p M U (QUID AS SET / ( »NP RA1 10
Scale-»-

55 0

.82

500

.80

450

.78

GRO! ;s NATI ONAL PI 10DUCT
cale

40 0

.76

4 PUBL CLY HEL D LIQUI D ASSET 5
cale

350

.74

1 1 1

1 i I I 111 I

i i i

1956

1957

1959

1958

i

111
1960

!

ilL.I 1
1961

1 '

,

1962

_L. i 1
1963

G N P S e a s o n a l l y A d j u s t e d at A n n u a l Rat es — Publ i cl y H e l d L i qu i d Assets S e a s o n a l l y A d j u s t e d

Liquidity And Economic Stability
amount of liquidity in the economy is
sired levels of liquidity, business firms may
a major determinant o f both the pace and
postpone plans to invest in plant and equip­
direction of business activity. Despite thement and reduce investments in inventories.
absence o f a widely-accepted definition of
Consumers may also postpone plans for pur­
liquidity, economists and financial analysts
chases of durable goods and attempt to re­
agree that liquidity refers to a myriad of fac­
duce their indebtedness. The result of such
tors which determine the extent to which
actions is a gradual dampening of expan­
assets may be converted into money and
sionary forces.
credit may be made available as an alterna­
The Federal Reserve System exercises con­
tive to the ownership of liquid assets.
siderable influence over the level of liquidity
through the conduct of monetary policy. By
The importance of liquidity in economic
either stimulating or restricting the growth
activity relates to its influence on spending
of bank reserves, the Federal Reserve can
and investment decisions in the private sec­
effect changes in the volume, availability, and
tors of the economy. For example, when hold­
cost of bank credit. The resulting variations
ings o f liquid assets are in excess of the
in the level of bank credit, in turn, provide
amounts which they desire to hold, business
the means of making adjustments in the
firms usually restructure their assets by in­
supply of money, the largest single compo­
creasing inventories or by investing in addi­
nent of total liquid assets. Therefore, in exer­
tional plant and equipment. When consumers
cising control over bank reserves, the Federal
have excess liquidity, they may invest in less
Reserve System influences both the level of
liquid, higher-yielding securities, or they may
liquidity and the direction and pace of eco­
use the liquid assets to purchase additional
nomic activity.
goods and services. In these cases, the flow of
spending and lending is increased, which in
Monetary policy is usually conducted in a
turn generates additional demand for exist­
counter-cyclical fashion. That is to say, dur­
ing real assets, current output, and financial
ing periods of recession it is usually directed
assets. I f there is unused capacity in the
toward the creation of more money and hence
economy, such forces would work in expan­
may indirectly provide more liquid assets
sionary fashion, and toward higher levels of
than the public wishes to hold in order to
production and employment. As the economy
stimulate spending. In periods of excessive
approaches full employment, a continuation
demand, the quantity of liquid assets may be
of expansionary pressures may result in price
increased at a slower rate, or even reduced,
increases, which may be accompanied even­
in an attempt to keep the rate of business
tually by an elimination of excess liquidity.
expansion within sustainable limits.
This does not necessarily occur through a re­
An understanding of liquidity and the fac­
duction in the volume of liquid assets, but
tors which influence decisions regarding the
rather through an expansion in the volume
amount and composition of liquid assets is
of transactions and price increases which
thus essential for the formulation, implemen­
necessitates larger holdings of liquid assets
tation, and evaluation of monetary policy. In
by the public.
attempting to evaluate the state of liquidity
in the economy, a number of factors should
When holdings of liquid assets are consid­
be considered. For one thing, the increased
ered by the public to be at or below desired
importance of nonbank financial intermedi­
levels, the reaction is the opposite of that
just described. In an effort to maintain de­
aries and the changing nature of savings path e

T

2



Composition of the Public's Holdings of Selected Liquid Assets
(Percentage distribution; selected dates)
Type of A sse t

Jan. '57

Jan. '59

Jan. '61

Jan. '63

39.0
15.3
9.2
10.8
15.8
9.9

37.1
17.6
9.3
12.9
13.4
9.7

34.7
18.4
9.3
15.6
11.7
10.3

31.2
21.7
9.1
17.5
10.4
10.1

100.0

100.0

345.4

374.7

100.0
401.9

461.5

Currency and demand deposits
Tim e deposits in commercial banks
Deposits in mutual savings banks1
Savings and loan shares
U. S. savings bonds
Short-term U. S. Government securities2
T otal
T otal (billions of dollars)

100.0

1 Includes deposits in Postal Savings System.
2 Securities maturing within a year.
Source: B oard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

terns require a careful examination of the
composition of liquid assets. In addition, the
adequacy of a given level of liquid assets is
determined largely by the level of output and
the volume of transactions in the economy. It
is also influenced by the existing levels of
short-term debt outstanding in both the busi­
ness and consumer sectors of the economy.
Finally, the availability of short-term credit
may be as important in evaluating the liquid­
ity situation as is the existing stock of liquid
assets, taken by itself.
The remainder of this article is devoted to
a review of the trend of liquidity during the
past few years, with emphasis on the current
expansion period. It also considers those fac­
tors which have served to influence the level
and composition of liquid assets held by the
public.(1)

Composition of Liquid Assets
I f defined narrowly, liquid assets would
include only the conventional money supply,
i.e., currency in circulation and privatelyowned demand deposits. However, a more
widely recognized concept includes, in addi­
tion to the money supply, time deposits in
commercial banks, savings and loan share
accounts, deposits in mutual savings banks,
U. S. savings bonds, and short-term U. S.
Government securities. The above table pro­
(1) Publicly-held liquid assets include those owned by con­
sumers and business firms with the exception of commercial
banks.




vides information concerning both the growth
and composition changes in total liquid assets
between January 1957 and January 1963.
It is noteworthy that total liquid assets in­
creased 34 percent in the six-year period
under review. Furthermore, approximately
one-half of the growth occurred after the
start of the current recovery in business
activity which began in February 1961 — a
span of less than two years. Even more inter­
esting, however, is the changing composition
of these assets. The most striking change has
been the declining proportion of total liquid
assets that is accounted for by currency and
demand deposits (money supply). The money
supply accounted for only 31 percent of total
liquid assets in January 1963, which com­
pares with 39 percent in 1957. Over the same
period, time deposits in commercial banks
and shares in savings and loan associations,
taken together, advanced from 26 percent to
39 percent of the total.
This, of course, demonstrates the important
role played by interest rates in the public’s
choice of liquid assets. For example, in 1962,
following widespread increases in interest
rates on publicly-held time deposits at com­
mercial banks and share accounts at savings
and loan associations, time deposits increased
$15 billion (18 percent), savings and loan
shares advanced $10 billion (13.4 percent),
and privately-owned demand deposits and
currency in circulation increased $2.2 billion
3

(1.5 percent). In contrast, from 1957 through
1961 the average annual increase in time
deposits was approximately $6 billion (9.8
percent) and savings and loan shares moved
up at annual rate of roughly $7 billion (13.8
percent), while the money supply advanced
at an annual rate of nearly $2 billion (1.3
percent).
The changing composition of liquid assets
has provided the basis for some objections to
the use of the conventional money supply as
a measure of liquidity and as a method of
measuring the accomplishments of monetary
policy. It appears that the impact of mone­
tary policy is more nearly reflected in hold­
ings of interest-bearing liquid assets than in
the money supply. For example, in the in­
itial 23 months of the current expansion
period, the money supply advanced $4 billion,
an increase of roughly 3 percent, while other
liquid assets increased $52 billion, or nearly
20 percent.
A number of analysts who continue to use
the conventional money supply to evaluate
monetary policy argue that recent increases
in the rate of turnover of money, a measure
o f the intensity of its use, indicate that the
present supply of money is insufficient to
support an adequate level o f spending and
investment; and that there is a need for addi­
tional liquidity in the economy. The current
level of interest rates on other liquid assets,
however, serves as an inducement for the
public to use demand deposits and currency
more intensively in order to permit larger
proportions of total liquid assets to be held in
an interest-bearing form. As long as these
conditions prevail, it seems reasonable to as­
sume that further increases in liquidity will
in large part take the form of interest-bearing
assets rather than additions to the money
supply.

Liquid Assets and Gross National Product
Another widely-used indicator of the li­
quidity position of the public is the relation­
ship between total liquid assets (as previously
defined) and GNP. As evidenced by the chart
on the cover, holdings of liquid assets by the
4



nonbank public have increased at roughly the
same pace as GNP over the past six years.
The relationship between these two series is
more clearly demonstrated by expressing
liquid assets as a percentage of GNP, as
shown by the ratio line on the cover chart.
Until the current recovery, the liquid asset/
GNP ratio increased during recessions (as
shown by the shaded areas on the chart) and
subsequently declined during the ensuing
recovery periods. In the 1958-60 expansion
period, the ratio began to decline after the
start of the recovery period in early 1958.
The decline continued until the beginning of
the steel strike in mid-1959. Reflecting the
brief downturn in economic activity which
accompanied the steel strike, the liquid asset/
CrNP ratio began to rise. After settlement of
the strike and a return to higher levels of out­
put, however, the ratio resumed its downward
course until the beginning of the most recent
recession in the spring of 1960.
In the current recovery period, the ratio
has deviated from its usual cyclical behavior.
Despite the continuation of the recovery and
in marked contrast to what usually happens
during an expansion period, the ratio turned
up in the fourth quarter of 1961 and contin­
ued on an uninterrupted climb through the
end of 1962. It is noteworthy that a ratio of
80.9 percent at the close of the fourth quarter
of last year exceeded the previous peak which
occurred at the beginning of the expansion
period in the first quarter of 1961.
The atypical behavior of this ratio in the
current expansion period is attributable
largely to two factors. First, the maintenance
of monetary ease by the Federal Reserve
System throughout the current recovery
period is in marked contrast to the policy
pursued in previous periods. Second, changes
in savings patterns by the public have also
played a major role. The aforementioned in­
creases in interest rates on both time deposits
and savings and loan share accounts at the
beginning of 1962 encouraged individuals to
hold a larger share of their savings in a
liquid form. Moreover, the sharp decline in

Chart 1.
CONSUMER LIQUIDITY RATIO
Ratio

Ratio

7
e n d of Q

1956

1957

1958

1959

I960

1962

1963

Source of da ta : Securities and Exchange Commission, and the
B oard of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

common stock prices in the second quarter of
1962 and the accompanying uncertainty about
the direction of stock prices, have added fur­
ther to the willingness of individuals to place
their funds in savings institutions and com­
mercial banks.

Debt and Liquidity
Just as the amount and composition of
liquid assets held by the public affect total
liquidity, existing short-term debt represents
both an immediate claim against existing
liquid assets and a limiting factor on the
ability to acquire additional credit. Thus, the
repayment of debt with current income serves
to increase potential liquidity since it restores
borrowing ability and reduces potential claims
on liquid assets, while an increase in short­
term debt has the opposite effect.
In analyzing the relationship o f short-term
debt to liquid assets it is helpful to consider
the consumer and business sectors separately.
Each of these sectors behaves differently in
response to changes in the volume of liquid
assets and changes in the relationship of debt
to liquid assets.

Consumer Liquidity
The ratio of consumer liquid asset holdings
to consumer debt is shown in Chart 1. Con­
sumer holdings of liquid assets are shown as




a multiple of total consumer debt, with the
series plotted quarterly.
The usual behavior of consumer liquidity
over the business cycle is to rise during peri­
ods of recessions and to decline in recovery
periods. In the current recovery, however,
consumer liquidity has remained relatively
stable. A t the end of 1962, consumer liquid
assets exceeded consumer debt 6.1 times, as
compared with 6.0 times at the beginning of
the recovery period.
The lack of a significant decline in con­
sumer liquidity in 1962 is somewhat surpris­
ing in view of the fact that consumer debt
outstanding rose approximately $6 billion, as
compared with an average annual increase
of $3 billion from 1957 through 1961. The
explanation for the continuation of a rela­
tively high level of consumer liquidity during
the past two years lies in the fact that, al­
though consumer debt increased substantially,
holdings of liquid assets expanded at an
equally swift pace, thereby preventing a sig­
nificant decline in consumer liquidity.

Corporate Liquidity
The conventional analysis of corporate
liquidity considers the relationship between
holdings of cash and short-term U. S. Govern­
ment securities (liquid assets) and total cur5

Chart 2.
CORPORATE LIQUIDITY RATIO
R atio (percent)

Ratio (percent)
50%

__I__ 1__

20%
1956

1957

1958

1959

1960

1962

20%

1963

Source of d a ta : Securities and Exchange Commission.

rent liabilities (short-term debt). Chart 2
shows corporate liquid assets expressed as a
percent of total corporate short-term debt.
The behavior o f corporate liquidity has
differed considerably from that of consumer
liquidity in the past few years. As the chart
shows, corporate liquidity has been declining
steadily, with an especially sharp decline
occurring in 1962. Between the beginning of
1957 and the end o f 1961, the ratio of corpo­
rate holdings of liquid assets to corporate
short-term debt declined from 43.9 percent to
35.3 percent, and by the close of 1962 it had
declined further to 33.4 percent. (Not shown
on Chart.)
A significant amount of the apparent loss
of corporate liquidity during this period re­
flects an obvious bias in the method o f meas­
uring liquidity. The ratio of cash and short­
term U. S. Government securities to current
liabilities includes accounts payable as a short­
term debt, but excludes accounts receivables
as a liquid asset. Receivables have grown
rapidly in recent years, as the extension of
trade credit has been used increasingly as a
competitive device, and corporations have
used funds that might otherwise be main­
6



tained as cash balances in order to extend
additional trade credit. As a result of this
bias in the conventional method of measuring
corporate liquidity, it appears to have been
reduced far more than would have been the
case if a more satisfactory measure were
employed.
It is also important to remember that the
expansion of trade credit has increased the
liquidity of those who receive the credit,
namely, consumers and other business firms.
It may also provide for improvements in the
availability of credit. F or example, the ex­
tension of trade credit frequently results in
a transfer of funds from large corporations,
which have access to numerous sources of
credit, to small- and medium-sized firms
which may have only limited access to short­
term credit to finance their working capital
needs. The extension of trade credit thus
provides greater mobility and more intensive
use of existing sources of funds. In addition,
the extension of credit to large segments of
the consumer sector may result in a wider
distribution of liquid assets, and also aid in
maintaining relatively high levels of con­
sumption and investment.

Chart 3.
RATIO OF BANK LOANS TO DEPOSITS
Ratio (percent)

Ratio (percent)
45%

45%
• nd

55%

55%

65%

65%
1956

1957

1958

1959

Source of da ta : The Board of Governors of the Federal Reservi

Liquidity and Credit Availability
Still another indicator of liquidity is the
ability of the economy to supply sufficient
amounts of short-term credit. The ability of
both bank and nonbank financial institutions
to satisfy the demands for credit is origin­
ally determined by the amount o f reserves
made available by the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem, the composition of the assets o f such
institutions, and the nature of their liabilities.
One of the measures most frequently used
in determining the availability of credit in
the commercial banking system is total bank
loans expressed as a percent of total deposits,
i.e., the loan-to-deposit ratio. Chart 3 shows
the behavior of this ratio between the start
of 1957 and the close o f 1962. The chart is
plotted with an inverse scale so that a down­
ward slope of the line indicates an increase
in the ratio of loans to deposits, i.e., a decline
in liquidity.
Due in part to the cyclical nature of the
demands for bank credit and in part to the
usual counter-cyclical fashion of monetary
policy, the availability o f bank credit tends
to increase during recessions and decline dur­
ing recovery periods. In the current recovery,
due in large part to the continuation of
monetary ease, the rise in the loan-deposit




1960

1961

1962

1963

System.

ratio has not been as wide as in previous
expansion periods. For example, in the initial
24 months of the 1958-60 recovery period the
loan-to-deposit ratio rose from 48.5 percent to
56.8 percent, as compared with an increase
from 55.5 percent to 56.9 percent during the
initial two years of the current expansion
phase.
It is noteworthy, however, that the level of
the ratio at the beginning of the current re­
covery was much higher than in the initial
stages of the 1958-60 recovery period. In
evaluating the liquidity of commercial banks,
it should be borne in mind that the loan-todeposit ratio fails to reveal (1) the composi­
tion of deposit liabilities, (2) the characteris­
tics of earning assets or (3) the interrelation­
ships between these two variables. In this
connection, the recent shift from demand de­
posits to time deposits has permitted larger
proportions of total deposits to be used to sat­
isfy credit demands, due to lower primary and
secondary reserve requirements associated
with time deposits. As a result, the familiar
guidelines concerning the availability of
credit associated with given levels of the
loan-to-deposit ratio may no longer be useful
as a means of evaluating bank liquidity. For
example, bankers have demonstrated in­
creased willingness to accept higher loan-to7

deposit ratios and to extend additional credit
so long as they believe that time deposits will
remain stable and the public will not treat
time deposits merely as interest-bearing
demand deposits.

appear to be adequate to meet the public’s
demand for funds.
It is widely recognized that public policies
should be designed to encourage a fuller
utilization of capacity in this economy. It
should also be recognized, however, that
monetary policy must avoid excesses of liquid­
ity that would result in further untoward
pressures on the U. S. balance of payments
position and the monetary gold stock. More­
over, a course of action which resulted in ex­
cesses of liquidity might seriously blunt the
effectiveness of future monetary policy.

Some Concluding Comments
The foregoing analysis provides support
for the argument that there is sufficient liquid­
ity in the economy to support a continuation
of business expansion, and that monetary
policy has contributed significantly to the
maintenance of this liquidity. The amount of
liquid assets and the availability of credit

A to u u td the tyounth Jb U & iict—
Kentucky was the only state in the Fourth District which
recorded a gain in total net income per farm in 1962. The gain
apparently was registered in the form of additions to inventory
since cash receipts in the state declined.
*

*

*

In February, the volume of bank debits at 35 Fourth District
centers advanced moderately. The month-to-month increase meas­
ured 1.5 percent, seasonally adjusted.
*

*

*

Cumulative sales at Fourth District department stores for the
period from January 1 to March 23 trailed year-ago volume by
1 percent. In contrast, total department store sales in the nation
showed a 4 percent year-to-year increase for the same period.
#

8



*

*

Liquidity in The Agricultural Sector
W orld W ar II, the amount of debt
owed by farmers in the U. S. has increased
steadily. By the end of 1962, total farm debt
amounted to $29.3 billion, which compared
with a figure of $8.0 billion at year-end
1945.(1) In comparison with trends in other
private sectors of the economy, farm debt has
increased at about the same rate as that of
corporate debt, but at a slower pace than
that of both consumer credit and nonfarm
mortgage debt.
in c e

S

Beyond this point, however, the compari­
son is not quite so favorable. While the abil­
ity of these other sectors to service and repay
debts has also grown substantially in the
postwar period, gross farm income has ad­
vanced only at a modest pace. Moreover, net
farm income, which is perhaps a better meas­
ure of ability to repay debt, trended down­
ward throughout the 1950’s. (See Chart 1.)
Thus, we find that a sharp rise in farm debt
along with a downtrend in net farm income
raises some questions concerning the degree
of liquidity in the agricultural sector of the
economy.

measuring liquidity in this way are discussed
later in the article.
As can be noted in Chart 2 on page 10,
liquidity in agriculture has declined substan­
tially from the high level that prevailed at
the end of W orld War II. This decline has
resulted from the consistent increase in nonreal-estate liabilities. In contrast, the amount
of liquid assets held by farmers remained
fairly stable from 1947 through 1959, and
then declined somewhat. Nevertheless, the
liquid assets held by U. S. farmers still exceed
the non-real-estate liabilities, with the liquid­
ity ratio amounting to 1.08 on January 1,
1963.(3) Although this figure may seem high
in comparison with, say, the corporate liquid-

Chart 1.
TOTAL NET FARM INCO M E
Bi l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

As suggested in the first article in this re­
view, it is difficult to arrive at agreement
concerning a working definition of liquidity.
Insofar as we are concerned here, liquidity in
the agricultural sector is measured by the
ratio of farmer holdings of liquid assets,
which includes demand deposits, time depos­
its, currency, and U. S. savings bonds, to the
amount of non-real-estate debt owed by farm­
ers.(2) Some o f the problems involved in
( ! ) A ll data used herein, unless otherwise specified, are
from publications of the U .S . Department of Agriculture.
(2) The non-real-estate debt total used excludes obligations
to the Commodity Credit Corporation.




(3) This ratio would be expected to vary during the year.

9

ity ratio, it is necessary to keep in mind that
hazards of the weather and the wider fluctu­
ations in agricultural prices, along with the
high proportion of fixed costs in farming,
demand relatively more liquidity in the agri­
cultural sector.

Higher Production Expenses
A number of factors are responsible for the
growth in non-real-estate liabilities of farm­
ers. These include mainly increases in farm
working capital needs, as well as a consider­
able expansion in investment by farmers in
equipment, livestock, and crops.
Farm working capital needs have increased
along with the rise in farm production ex­

penses, as shown in Chart 3 on page 11.
Higher farm costs, in turn, reflect the general
expansion in farm production. We can thus
attribute some of the increased costs to in­
creased output, i.e., farmers are experiencing
larger expenses now relative to earlier years
because they are buying more feed, more live­
stock, more fertilizer, and other items neces­
sary to expand production. As is shown in
Chart 3, since 1951 advances in farm output
have in general out-distanced the rise in farm
expenses, with the exception of the past two
years. In 1961 and 1962, farm programs were
successful in curtailing grain production, and
this was a significant factor in reducing the
rate of advance in total farm output. At the

Chart 2.
N on-real-estate debt of farm ers has grow n steadily since W orld W ar II. In contrast, liquid
assets rem ained stable until 1959, but have since declined. Liquidity in the agricultural
sector is now slightly less than in 1940.

B i l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

Ratio




Bi l l i ons o f d o l l a r s

Ratio

same time, however, farm costs of such pro­
ducers did not turn down correspondingly, in
part due to the large amounts o f fixed costs
involved as well as to the tendency to apply
more fertilizer per acre on a smaller planted
acreage.
In addition to increased outlays associated
with larger farm output, other trends in
agriculture also play an important role in
increased costs. Farmers today are buying
a great deal more of inputs than they did in
earlier years. This is true in the case of
both farm-produced inputs as well as non­
farm inputs. The trend toward specialization
in farming is one cause of these higher out­
lays. Looking first at farm-produced inputs,
purchases of feed have moved up more than
any other farm expense in recent years.(4)
Larger feed costs stem in part from an ex­
panded volume of livestock production by
U. S. farmers. A t the same time, specialized
livestock operations often result in larger
feed purchases than those experienced with
a ‘ ‘ general farm operation, ’ ’ which was more
characteristic of farming in earlier years.
Likewise, specialization is also a factor in the
larger livestock outlays. For example, it is
common practice for dairymen to purchase,
rather than to raise, their herd replacements.
Farm mechanization has played a very
fundamental role in increased farm produc­
tion costs. The replacement of animal power
with “ tractor power,” and subsequent fur­
ther increases in mechanization, have brought
about a steady rise in depreciation charges,
fuel and other power expenses, and repair
costs. In addition, adoption of new technol­
ogy has resulted in farmers purchasing many
items which were not on the market several
years ago, e.g., new pesticides and feed addi­
tives. Outlays for hired labor, another impor­
tant nonfarm purchased input, have also
moved up moderately; this rise is due to
higher farm wage rates as farmers are em­
ploying less hired labor. Taxes on farm prop­
erty are another farm expense which has
moved up substantially. In addition, the
( 4) See “ 1 9 6 2 : A T ear of Stability in Agriculture,” Monthly
B u siness R eview , Federal Reserve B ank of Cleveland, D e­
cember 1 962 .




Chart 3.
TOTAL FARM OUTPUT AND
FARM PRODUCTION EXPENSES
INDEX 1 9 5 7 -5 9= 1 00

sharp increase in farm debt referred to
earlier has meant a corresponding increase in
interest charges paid by farmers.
Higher prices paid for production items
have also played a part in the increase in
farm costs. Prices of motor supplies, motor
vehicles, farm machinery, building and fenc­
ing materials, and other farm supplies have
moved up in nearly every year since 1940.

Larger Investment
Along with the need for additional work­
ing capital, a steady rise in farm investment
has also played a primary role in the en­
larged demand for non-real-estate credit by
farmers. Mechanization, once again, has been
an important factor here as the tremendous
growth throughout the postwar period in the
number of tractors and field machines on
farms, along with substantial increases in
investment in “ barn” equipment in recent
years, have brought a considerable expansion
in investment in machinery and equipment.
Larger investment also reflects the impact of
11

increased production, i.e., the “ inventory” of
crops and livestock on farms tends to increase
as output increases.

desirable to exclude intermediate-term credit
outstanding in measuring liquidity in agri­
culture, such data are not available.

In addition to the increase in total capital
needs, the reduction in the number of farms
has also had a notable impact on farm credit
demand. In 1962, the number o f farms in the
U. S. was estimated at 3.7 million, or 29 per­
cent less than in 1952 and 38 percent less
than in 1946. This downtrend in farm num­
bers coupled with the increase in total farm
investment, as previously discussed, has
brought about a sharp rise in investment per
farm. On January 1 of this year, investment
in livestock per farm totaled $4,426, approxi­
mately twice that of the $2,283 total in 1950.
Over the same period, the amount of invest­
ment per farm in machinery and motor ve­
hicles more than doubled, rising from $1,756
to $4,310. This concentration of investment in
fewer farms has no doubt been an important
factor in the enlarged use of credit, since
many of the operators leaving farming would
tend to take equity funds out o f agriculture.
Thus, the farmer who acquires the livestock,
machinery, or other assets o f the seller would
need to use additional credit in enlarging his
farm operation.(5)

It is quite clear that farmers hold liquid
assets in addition to those identified earlier
in this article. For example, a portion of
farm crop and livestock assets could be con­
verted into cash at a reasonable price. It is
impossible, however, to determine just how
much. Another farm asset which no doubt
provides some additional liquidity are the
investments by farmers in cooperatives. Such
investments were estimated to have totaled
$4.7 billion on January 1, 1963, or approxi­
mately the same in amount as holdings of
U. S. savings bonds by farmers. Farmer in­
vestments in various marketing, purchasing,
electric, credit, and other cooperatives have
risen steadily since 1940. Inclusion (or exclu­
sion) of the items mentioned here, i.e., farm
crop and livestock assets, investments in co­
operatives, intermediate-term credit, would
tend to raise the liquidity ratio of the agricul­
tural sector, if accurate measures of total
farm liquid assets and short-term debt were
available.

Several considerations are significant in
measuring liquidity in agriculture. First, all
non-real-estate liabilities are not short-term
liabilities that should be compared with liquid
assets. For example, farmer borrowings for
the purchase of new machinery or other assets
that are financed on an intermediate-term
basis without farm mortgage security are
included in non-real-estate liabilities. (Some
lenders do finance these types of purchases
on a short-term basis.) Thus, while it would be

Another aspect of liquidity in agriculture
that is significant, but is difficult to measure,
concerns the concentration of farm debt rela­
tive to holdings of liquid assets. A recent
study by the Bureau of the Census showed
that farm operator debt in this country is
concentrated in the hands of relatively few
farmers. The study indicated that, in 1960,
25 percent of the nation’s farm operators
had 69 percent of the non-real-estate and
related debt outstanding.(6) Whether these
same operators hold a corresponding propor­
tion of total liquid assets would seem to have
serious implications for the liquidity position
of the agricultural sector of the economy.

(5)
The concentration of farm land among fewer farmers
would have a similar impact on farm real estate debt.

( 6) See “ A N ew Look at the Farm Debt Picture,” Federal
R eserve Bulletin, December 1 9 6 2 .

Problems in Measurement

12