View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SuiiwM et/m/
MONTHLY

IN

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of CLEVELAND—

THIS

ISSUE

Unemployment Insurance As An
Economic Stabilizer......................... .3
Notes on Federal Reserve Publications... .8
Farm Abundance Continues.................. .9

‘Decctnicx t$ 6 t

Annual Index to Monthly Business Review. 15

During the postwar period, the unemployment insurance program has added to
the nation's income stream in recession years. On the other hand, the program
has withdrawn funds in non-recession years, with the exception of 1959, when
unemployment and unemployment insurance payments were at relatively higher
levels than in other non-recession years.




* first s i x m o n t h s o n l y

Additional copies of the MONTHLY BUSINESS
REVIEW may be obtained from the Research De­
partment, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Cleveland 1, Ohio. Permission is granted to reproduce
any material in this publication.




Unemployment Insurance As An
Economic Stabilizer
insurance is rightly con­
sidered to be part o f a national social
security system. Because of its function as a
supplier of income to individuals who are
unemployed, and thus deprived of their cus­
tomary income, unemployment insurance is
usually identified closely with programs such
as public assistance. Unemployment insurance
is, however, really quite different from these
other social security programs both in its
organization and, more importantly, in its
impact on the economy at large.

U

nem ploym ent

As a case in point, unemployment insur­
ance, in reality, consists o f not one program
but fifty-four separate programs. Each state
as well as the District of Columbia has its
own program; in addition there is an inde­
pendent program for railroad employees, and
two separate Federal Government programs
— one for civilian employees and one for exservicemen. Central direction for all of these
programs is imparted by federal legislation
administered by the Department of Labor,
but there is considerable diversity among the
various states with respect to coverage, eli­
gibility, benefit levels, and duration of bene­
fits.(1) Despite this diversity, however, the
several unemployment insurance programs
should be, and usually are, treated as one
program from the standpoint of their com­
bined effect on the economy.
An important difference between unemploy­
ment insurance and the other social security
programs is that the operations o f the un­
employment insurance programs are much
more closely related to or influenced by fluc(i) For a comprehensive discussion of state unemployment
insurance laws, see Comparison of State Unemployment
Insurance Laws as of January 1, I960, BES No. U-141,
U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Employment Security.




tuations in economic activity. Unemployment
insurance (or UI, as referred to hereinafter)
is widely recognized as one of the “ built-in”
or “ automatic” stabilizers in the arsenal of
counter-recessionary weapons. The list of
automatic stabilizers also includes the vari­
ation in corporate and personal income tax
revenues, as such revenues rise and fall in
response to changes over the cycle of eco­
nomic activity. Similarly, the list includes
the variation in benefits paid and taxes col­
lected under the retirement benefit portions
of the social security programs. These char­
acteristics are considered to be automatic or
built-in responses because they begin to oper­
ate without waiting for the discretionary
judgments and actions which are required in
the case of other measures to cope with eco­
nomic fluctuations, such as the speeding up
or slowing down of public works spending,
or changes in tax rates.
UI A lso Stab ilize s In d iv id u als' Incom es

Unemployment insurance can actually be
thought of as a stabilizer in two respects.
First, UI affects the economy as a whole, on
the one hand, through the payments made to
the unemployed, which add to incomes, and,
on the other hand, through the subtraction
from the income stream represented by the
taxes(2) paid to support the program. In this
analysis of UI, it is the impact on the econ­
omy of the net difference between payments
and taxes that is considered to be an auto­
matic stabilizer. The second respect in which
UI can be thought of as a stabilizer is in a
welfare sense. In this case, UI acts as a eon(2) In view of the compulsory nature of these payments,
it seems realistic to use the term “ taxes” in place of the
official designation “ contribution.”

3

tinuously operating mechanism to furnish an
income to those individuals who have lost
jobs and incomes because of involuntary un­
employment; this also can be called the social
security function, in the sense that UI helps
to provide security for individuals.
In its capacity as a social stabilizer, UI has
several limitations. First of all, benefits are
limited to those covered by the UI programs
— currently about 80 percent of those in
civilian wage and salary employment. Sec­
ond, UI is intended to provide only rela­
tively short-term help — the maximum dura­
tion of benefits is 26 weeks in most states.
Also, in most states, the maximum benefit
levels represent less than half o f the earnings
they are intended to replace, and, for many
claimants, benefits are in practice often less
than the maximum because these claimants
cannot fulfill the requirements which state
laws impose as to earnings and length of
time spent in covered employment.
These current characteristics o f UI are due
in part to the form that the program took at
its inception and in part to the twenty-five
years of change in both the program and the
economic environment in which the program
operates. One of the more important changes,
for example, has been a decline in the ratio
o f unemployment benefits to the wages they
are intended to replace, or what is often
termed the adequacy of benefits. The decline
has occurred over the years because maxi­
mum benefit amounts, which are fixed in
terms of dollars and are changeable only by
legislation, have not been increased propor­
tionately with rising wage levels.
In 1959, to illustrate this point, average
weekly benefits under state UI programs rep­
resented 36 percent of average weekly earn­
ings of recipients in covered employment.(3)
Although it is true that the ratio has in­
creased since the most recent low point of 32
percent in 1955, thus paralleling the rise in
(3) These and the immediately following data were obtained
from the Handbook of Unemployment Insurance Financial
Data BES No. U-73, U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of
Employment Security, Washington, revised April, 1960.

4




the national unemployment rate, the 1959
ratio should also be compared with an aver­
age of about 41 percent in the years 1938,
1939, and 1940, the first three years in which
UI was in operation, and with the 50-percent
ratio that was apparently intended when UI
legislation was adopted in the mid-1930’s.
These ratios, it should be added, under­
state to an unknown degree the offsetting
effects of UI benefits because earnings are
subject to income tax and UI benefits are
not. Despite the increasing spread between
gross income and take-home pay, however, it
is unlikely that this factor was sufficient to
make up a significant part of the decline in
the offset ratio, i.e., to bring the 36 percent
in 1959 up to, say, the 41-percent level in
terms of net, after-tax earnings. A develop­
ment which has tended to reduce the ade­
quacy of benefits has been the steady increase
in the proportion of employees’ compensa­
tion represented by fringe benefits, most of
which cease when the individual loses his
job; UI benefits provide little or no offset to
this loss. In some industries, it should be
added, fringe benefits include Supplemental
Unemployment Benefits, which provide addi­
tional income for laid-off workers. However,
this particular fringe benefit, which is so far
quite limited in its extent, owes its existence
to the inadequacies of UI benefits, particu­
larly for those in high-wage industries.
The ratios of benefits to earnings cited
above may be open to the criticism that they
are too aggregative, in the sense that such
figures, since they are averages, conceal im­
portant differences among benefit recipients.
For that reason, as well as to accumulate
additional information, several state employ­
ment security agencies conducted studies of
the experience of individual beneficiaries dur­
ing periods of unemployment. Such studies
were made in six widely separated geographic
areas for various periods between late 1954
and early 1958. W ith respect to the adequacy
of benefits, the conclusions, in the words of
the report summarizing the studies, were as
follows: “ The surveys clearly indicate that

during their current spell of unemployment,
beneficiaries did not receive benefits which
compensated for as much as fifty percent of
their actual wage loss.” (4) (Wages were de­
fined here as net wages, i.e., after withhold­
ing of Federal income tax.)

UI benefits(•>) as a percent of:

Ohio

Pennsylvania

Total personal income
Wage and salary
income
Transfer payments

1.4%

1.9%

2.0
19.2

2.8
22.2

( 5) State and federal programs only.

U! Sm all in Relation to Total Incom e

When attention is turned to the role of UI
in the economy as a whole, it is apparent
that, on the basis of their contribution to
national income in any one year, UI benefits
have not been large. For example, in 1958,
when a record $4.2 billion in UI benefits
(under all programs) was paid out, the total
represented only:
1.2% of total personal income;
1.3% of disposable personal income;
2 . 5 % o f t otal p a y r o l l s in U l - c o v e r e d
employment; and
16.0% of all transfer payments.
It is thus readily apparent that in 1958,
which was a year of recession and relatively
heavy unemployment, UI benefits were a
small proportion of personal income and
other, less comprehensive measures of income,
with the exception of transfer payments.
Moreover, these proportions were even smaller
in non-recession years.
Additional evidence of the relatively minor
contribution of unemployment benefits to
total income is suggested by the data pertain­
ing to individual states. For example, both
Ohio and Pennsylvania, as heavily industrial­
ized states, were much more severely affected
by the 1957-58 recession than most other
states; u n e m p l o y m e n t was consequently
greater, in proportion, than in most other
states. Even in these two states, however, UI
benefits were relatively unimportant in rela­
tion to personal income, as is shown in the
following table.
(4) U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Employment
Security, Adequacy of Benefits Under Unemployment Insur­
ance, BES No. U-79 (R ), Washington, October, 1958, p. 20.




While it is true that UI benefits have not
in any one year accounted for a substantial
proportion of personal income or its major
components, the effectiveness of UI as an
economic stabilizer is perhaps better meas­
ured by the extent to which it offsets declines
in income during periods of recession, and
correspondingly withdraws purchasing power
during periods of rising economic activity.
Such an approach may be considered to
measure the “ dynamic” aspect of UI, as dis­
tinguished from the “ static” aspect involved
in the previous comparisons. In evaluating
the stabilizing effect of UI operations, con­
sideration is given first to the postwar period
as a whole.

UI Benefits H a v e A d d e d to Incom es in
P o stw a r Period

UI operations are influenced by and have
an impact on the economy, as mentioned
earlier, through the variations in benefits
paid and taxes collected. By finding the dif­
ference between the dollar totals of benefits
paid and unemployment taxes collected, it is
possible to arrive at an approximate measure
of the dollar impact of UI operations on the
economy, i.e., whether such operations add to
or subtract from the income stream. A sur­
plus of benefit payments over taxes collected
during a specified period of time means a net
addition to purchasing power during the
period; conversely, a larger total of taxes
collected than benefits paid indicates a sub­
traction from the income stream. A surplus
of benefit payments over taxes results in a
decline in the reserves of the UI program,
which are subsequently rebuilt during a
5

period when taxes exceed benefits. (The
other, and much less important, source of
income for the UI trust funds is the interest
earned on the federal government obligations
in which the reserves are invested.)
For the period from January 1946 through
June 1961 (the most recent date for which
such data are available) the operations of
the state and railroad UI programs, com­
bined, added nearly $1 billion more to the
spending stream in benefits than was sub­
tracted in taxes. Most of this net addition,
however, took place in recent years. UI oper­
ations for the years 1946-57, taken as a whole,
indicate a subtraction from purchasing power
of about $2.5 billion, whereas in the 1958-61
period UI operations added nearly $3.5 bil­
lion to the income stream.
To keep these figures in proper perspective,
it needs to be remembered that the totals,
while significant in relation to the UI pro­
gram, were small in relation to the changes
actually experienced in national income. In
the 1946-57 period the net effect of UI oper­
ations was clearly insignificant in relation to
the gain o f nearly $190 billion in national
income. UI operations were, however, rela­
tively more important in the 1958-61 period
when national income increased by a little
more than $50 billion.
The different record of UI operations in
the 1958-61 period as compared with the
earlier postwar period was, in turn, due
largely to the higher level of unemployment
in those years, and to the fact that the 196061 recession followed so closely on the 1957-58
business downturn. Thus, while years of rela­
tively low unemployment and high business
activity predominated in the 1946-57 period,
a somewhat dissimilar situation characterized
the 1958-61 period. The unemployment rate,
i.e., the proportion o f those looking for work
to the total o f those persons working and
looking for work, averaged 4.2 percent from
1946 through 1957; in the 1958-61 period
(through June 1961) the rate averaged 6.2
percent.
6




Another factor which operated to produce
an excess of benefit payments over tax collec­
tions in the more recent period, although
admittedly it was much less important than
the higher level of unemployment, were the
revisions of UI legislation in several states to
permit lower tax rates on employers than
those previously in effect. At the time these
changes were implemented, reserves available
for the payment of UI benefits were still ris­
ing, despite the fact that the country had
experienced two recessions in the postwar
period, and drains on reserves of the magni­
tude of those which took place in 1958 were
not foreseen.
In summarizing the record of UI oper­
ations in the postwar period, it may be sug­
gested that, although the over-all dollar
impact of UI was small in relation to changes
in national income, UI operations tended to
function in a desirable direction. In the period
1946-58, when purchasing power was expand­
ing rapidly and utilization of manpower and
other resources was generally at high levels,
UI operations on balance withdrew purchas­
ing power. In the period since 1958, when
inflationary pressures were substantially re­
duced, UI operations added to the income
stream. The excess of spending over receipts
in the latter period has resulted in large
reductions in UI reserves, in fact in some
states to dangerously low levels. This problem
of reserve adequacy, though important, is a
separate subject, however, and is not dis­
cussed here.
UI O p e ra tio n s O ffse t Business C y c le

A perhaps more conclusive demonstration
of the effectiveness of UI as a stabilizer than
the record during the two sub-periods of the
postwar period discussed above, is provided
by an examination of UI operations in the
four postwar recessions. For this purpose UI
operations are analyzed on an annual basis.
As can be seen in the cover chart, UI oper­
ations added to the income stream in all the
recession years — 1948, 1954, 1958, and 1960.

Until 1959, UI also ran surpluses, i.e., sub­
tracted from the income stream, in non­
recession years.

such as had occurred following the earlier
postwar cycles.

In terms of year-to-year changes, the
swings in the impact of UI operations were
also fairly significant in relation to the
changes in economic activity in the first three
postwar recessions, but not in the latest and
mildest of the postwar recessions, that of
19G0-61.

Federal P ro gra m s

Net change in
UI operations
( -f- = addition to incomes
between two years)
(in billions o f dollars)

Change in Gross
National Product

1948-1949
1953-1954
1957-1958
1959-1960

+
+

1.4
2.3
1.8
21.7

+
+
+
-

1.1
1.4
2.3
0.1

To some extent the differences between the
pattern of change in GNP and in UI opera­
tions in successive cycles is due to differences
in the timing of the business cycle which are
concealed by a comparison of changes be­
tween calendar years. On the basis of these
comparisons, nevertheless, it appears that in
the 1960-61 period, the impact of UI was
sharply reduced from what it had been in
earlier postwar recessions.
UI operations were less stimulative in 1960
than in 1959 (see cover ch art); benefits in­
creased little from the already high level of
1959, whereas taxes paid by employers rose
considerably more. The high level of benefits
in 1959 in turn reflected the carryover of
considerable unemployment from the 1957-58
recession and the secondary effects, i.e., on
employment in related industries, of the 1959
steel strike. On the other side, the substantial
increase in taxes was due partly to the in­
crease which usually occurs following a reces­
sion, and partly to special efforts which were
made by some states to rebuild their reserves
following the 1957-58 recession. Unfortu­
nately, the downturn of 1960 came too soon
to allow the rebuilding of reserves to take
place in a year of rising business activity,




The discussion of the impact of UI opera­
tions thus far has been confined to the state
and railroad UI programs, because of the
impossibility of determining the impact of
the federal UI programs in the same manner
as the state and railroad programs. Although
data on benefit payments under federal UI
programs are shown separately so that their
contribution to income can be measured, the
measurement of withdrawals from purchas­
ing power cannot be made because the costs
of the programs are paid from general gov­
ernment revenues, and not by separately
identified employer taxes.
Furthermore, the federal programs, which
now cover two groups — federal government
civilian employees and ex-servicemen — do
not operate with trust funds, as do the state
and railroad programs. The elastic element
which is indicated in the privately-financed
programs by the increase or decrease in the
trust funds has its counterpart in the swings
of the federal administrative and cash budg­
ets between surplus and deficit. (The opera­
tions of the state and railroad programs are
included in the federal government cash
budget but not in the administrative budget.)
Nevertheless, as judged by swings in the
volume of benefit payments, the federal UI
programs do push the federal government’s
budget toward deficit in a business downturn
(when benefit payments increase) and toward
surplus as the economy improves (and bene­
fit payments decline). The federal programs
have operated generally in a counter-cyclical
fashion since 1953; benefit payments in­
creased markedly in each of the recession
years 1954, 1958, and 1960. This counter­
cyclical behavior is mainly the result of the
fact that the largest part of federal UI bene­
fits has gone to ex-servicemen under the
special programs set up for recently dis­
charged ex-servicemen. The level of un­
employment among this group is apparently
7

determined primarily by the general employ­
ment-unemployment picture.
As might be expected, however, benefit
payments to civilians previously employed by
the Federal Government have not corre­
sponded so closely to business cycle changes,
on a year-to-year basis, during the relatively
brief history of that program. (Benefits under
that program were first paid in January,
1955.) Benefit payments increased sharply in
1958, but moved up only slightly in 1960.

Ul O p e ra tio n s in Ohio and P ennsylvania
The relatively more severe impact of the
1957-58 recession on Ohio and Pennsylvania
has already been mentioned. That differential
effect, combined with the apparently rela­
tively greater incidence of long-term or
structural unemployment in both states, par­
ticularly in Pennsylvania, has resulted in
both states’ UI programs being in deficit for
most of the years since 1953. Benefits under
the Ohio program have exceeded taxes in
each year since 1953; in Pennsylvania a mod­

NOTES O N

est surplus of taxes over benefits was attained
in 1956, but that surplus was the only one
since 1951. UI operations in Ohio and Penn­
sylvania in recent years have been counter­
cyclical in the sense that the deficits resulting
from UI operations generally were larger in
recession than in non-recession years, al­
though in Pennsylvania that was not the case
in 1959-60.
A steady decline has taken place in recent
years in the UI reserves of both Ohio and
Pennsylvania, particularly in the ease of the
latter. In Pennsylvania, the low level of re­
serves has necessitated emergency borrowing
from the federal government to maintain
benefit payments, and, as a longer-run meas­
ure, the enactment of legislation providing
for sharply increased employer tax rates. As
a result of this and previously-enacted legis­
lation, state UI operations in Pennsylvania
resulted in a much smaller addition to in­
comes in 1960 than in 1959, following the
national pattern. In contrast, in Ohio, where
reserves are considerably more adequate, UI
operations acted to increase purchasing power
in 1960.

F E D E R A L R E SE R V E P U B L IC A T IO N S

Among the articles recently published in the monthly business reviews of
other Federal Reserve banks are:
“ Recent Developments in Bank Liquidity” , Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, November 1961.
“ W hat’s Behind the Discount Rumpus in R etailing!” , Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, November 1961.
(Copies may be obtamed, w ithout charge by writing
to the Federal Reserve Bank named in each case.)

8




Farm Abundance Continues
abundance that has characterized the
Although aggregate crop volume this year
nation’s agricultural activity over the
is down 3 percent from the all-time high of
years has continued in 1961. One indication1960, the area of cropland used declined even
is the fact that farm marketings have been
more, dropping 5 percent to the smallest area
of record proportions this year. (Since total
utilized in nearly 50 years (see table below).
farm output this year will be the same as in
Not since 1912 have fewer acres of cropland
been used. As indicated by the output and
1960, marketings will probably continue at
acreage figures, an increase in farm produc­
advanced levels through the early part of
next year.) Another indication of farm abun­
tivity in 1961 partially offset the reduction
dance in 1961 is that net farm income is
in acreage. In fact, the composite rate of pro­
expected to be up about $1 billion from 1960,
duction in 1961 for the 28 leading crops is
due to larger marketings, higher support
reported to have surpassed all previous rec­
ords. In the cases of sugar beets and soybeans,
prices for some major crops, and larger gov­
however, marked increases in acreages were
ernment payments.(1) And this is so, despite
responsible for the significant increases indi­
the fact that prices of farm products for 1961
as a whole may on average be no higher than
cated in the output of sugar crops and oil
crops.
in 1960. In the pages that follow we discuss
some of the details o f the developments which
have helped to perpetuate farm abundance
O u tp u t of M a jo r C r o p s
in 1961.

T

h e

1 947 - 4 9 - 1 0 0
C r o p Volum e Dow n Less Than A c re a g e

Crop output in 1961, while on a par with
the second highest level in history, is ex­
pected to be down 3 percent from last year,
reflecting mainly a reduction in the outturn
of grains. The latter reduction, in turn, has
resulted from (1) a 16-percent curtailment
o f plantings by participants in the Feed
Grain Program and (2) a decline in the out­
put of food grains caused by a drought that
cut spring wheat production by more than
one-third. The volume of hay and forage
crops in 1961 is also expected to be down
from that of 1960. On the other hand, pro­
duction of most of the other major crops has
been equal to, or well in excess of, that o f the
previous year.
( i ) All data and forecasts used herein are from publications
of the U. S. Departm ent of A griculture.




1961

Percent
change
from 1960

127

-1 1 %

100

- 9
— 5
—
2

Feed Grains
Food Grains
Hay and Forage Crops
Cotton
Tobacco
Vegetables
Sugar Crops
Oil Crops

201

- 3
— 5
-1 3
-1 8

All Crops

117

-

3

89

-

5

131

+

2

Cropland Used
Crop Production
Per Acre

113
102

99
112

147

9

Looking at 1961 as a whole, crop progress
was retarded somewhat by a late and uneven
start in the spring, and relatively cool
weather during the early part o f the grow­
ing season. Beginning in August, however,
favorable weather brought a sharp rise in
crop prospects. Nearly all crops registered
gains during that month, and the expected
outturns o f corn, sorghum grains, and soy­
beans advanced by more than ten percent.
Although some further improvement in crops
occurred in September, the favorable weather
that prevailed generally through October and
early November was of more significance in
permitting complete maturity and harvest of
an annual volume of crops that has been ex­
ceeded only once — in 1960.
Livestock Volume a t New H igh

The abundant outturn of crops in 1961 was
complemented by a 4-percent rise in the out­
put o f livestock and products. As the table
shows, all major livestock groups registered
gains in output, reflecting both a moderate
increase in units of breeding stock and a sig­
nificant increase in production per unit. The
gains registered by the three livestock groups
combined to push the total output of live­
stock and products to an all-time high.
Poultry products registered the greatest
gain over year-earlier levels. With broiler
production up at least 12 percent from the
1.8 billion birds of 1960 and the number of
turkeys raised up 26 percent, the total vol­
ume of poultry products easily surpassed
that of the previous year. A t the same time,
the volume of poultry products established an
all-time high, despite virtually no increase in
the volume of eggs produced.
The 4-percent expansion indicated above
for meat animal output includes a 3-percent
increase in the expected output of beef to a
record 15 billion pounds, and a 10-percent
increase in the slaughter of lamb and mutton.
Although not of major magnitude in the
total output of meat animals, sheep and lamb
slaughter this year is expected to be the
largest in any year since 1948. These gains in

10



O u tp u t of M a jo r Livestock P ro d u cts

1947- 49=100
1961

Percent
change
from 1960

Poultry and eggs
Meat animals
Dairy products

163
130
112

+ 8%
Hr 4
+ 2

All livestock

131

+ 4

Animal units of
breeding stock
Livestock production
per breeding unit

98
134

+

1

+ 3

output, however, have been partially offset
by a decline of about 1 percent in the ex­
pected volume of pork production.
A moderate gain in the output of dairy
products this year reflects an upturn in milk
production that began in 1960 and is ex­
pected to continue into 1962. An anticipated
increase this year of about 2 billion pounds
will boost total output to nearly 125 billion
pounds, or about on a par with the record
high of 1956. The current recovery in output
of dairy products stems mostly from a level­
ing off in the long-term downward trend in
number of milk cows. The 1-percent decline
indicated for this year compares with 5 per­
cent in 1958 and 4 percent in 1959, when
beef cattle prices were advancing and herd
owners were culling herds closely. Beef cattle
prices have been below 1959 levels the past
two years and two increases have been made
in the level at which milk and butterfat
prices are supported. These factors appar­
ently have slowed the decline in cow num­
bers, thereby contributing to an expansion in
the output of milk because of the upward
trend in rate of production per cow.
The upturn in milk production this year
has been accompanied by an increase in offer­
ings to the Commodity Credit Corporation
for price support. Government purchases this

year are expected to account for about 6 per­
cent of all milkfat produced and 9 percent of
the solid-not-fat, compared with 3 percent
and 8 percent, respectively, in 1960.
T otal O u tp u t Equal to 1960

Putting together the foregoing facts and
figures, it is found that the record volume of
livestock and products offset the decline in
crop volume, with the result that total farm
output in 1961 is expected to be equal to the
record level of last year. The most recent
estimates place total farm output for 1961 at
127 percent of the 1947-49 average, the same

as in 1960. The upward trend in rates of pro­
duction of crops was a significant factor in
partially offsetting the effect of a 5-percent
reduction in the area of cropland used. Like­
wise, a further significant increase in the rate
of production per unit of livestock added to
the total outturn.
C onsum ption M a y Exceed O u tp u t

On the basis of preliminary indications, it
is expected that, this year, consumption plus
exports of all farm products will about equal
production plus imports, representing the
first time since 1957, as shown in the chart.

la rs

Domestic consumption plus
exports of farm products
will a p p a r e n t l y balance
production plus imports in
1961 for the first time
since 1957

.

o
30

STO CKS o

FARM PRODU

With production and use
expected to be virtually
in balance, no change in
c a r r y o v e r sto ck s from
year-earlier levels is antic­
ipated as of January 1,
7962

20

.

10

o

46

'4 8

e E st im a te d




11

that production and consumption were vir­
tually in balance.(2) The only other time in
recent years that a similar situation prevailed
was in 1950. Consumption has exceeded pro­
duction in only five o f the past fifteen years;
in all other years consumption of all farm
products has fallen short of annual produc­
tion, thereby fostering a gradual build-up in
available stocks.
The total annual consumption of all farm
products represents the combined total of
domestic consumption plus exports to foreign
countries, as shown in the accompanying
chart. Domestic production and stocks plus
imports from foreign countries provide the
supply of agricultural products from which
domestic and foreign requirements are met.
When the total of consumption and exports
is less than that of production plus imports,
as has been true frequently during the post­
war years, a build-up in carryover stocks
occurs, as shown in the lower panel of the
chart. Conversely, if consumption and exports
exceed production plus imports, carryover
stocks decline, as occurred in 1946, 1947, 1951,
and 1957. On the basis of preliminary infor­
mation, total carryover stocks as of January
1, 1962, are expected to be the same as on the
year-earlier date.
Surplu s Lim ited to Few C om m o ditie s

An abundance of agricultural commodities
is common to American agriculture, as evi­
denced in the fact that available supply
exceeded consumption twenty-five times in
the 37-year period from 1924 through 1960.
The period from 1943 through 1947 repre­
sents the longest span of time, for which fig­
ures are available, that consumption exceeded
supply. The excess of production plus im­
ports over consumption plus exports in the
postwar period has been relatively small in
each year, ranging from 2 to 3 percent, with
the exception of 1948, when the excess was
(2) The total figures in the chart were taken from M easur­
ing The Supply and Utilization of Farm Commodities, A g ri­
cultural H andbook No. 91, U. S. Departm ent of A griculture,
1957 and 1960. Figures fo r 1961 have been estimated by
the Federal Reserve B ank o f Cleveland.

12




nearly 7 percent. While aggregate measures
of production and consumption indicate the
extent to which production has exceeded use,
such measures conceal the fact that substan­
tial surpluses have accumulated for only a
relatively few commodities. A review of the
investment of the Commodity Credit Corpo­
ration in price-supported commodities sug­
gests the size of the surplus of some of the
principal commodities.
The value of commodities held by the Com­
modity Credit Corporation in inventory and
under loan agreements totaled $7.2 billion on
September 30, 1961. Of that amount, over $6.0
billion, or more than four-fifths of the total,
was accounted for by three commodities—
wheat, corn, and sorghum grains. In terms
of annual production, such holdings were
equivalent to 112 percent of annual produc­
tion for wheat, 66 percent for sorghum grains,
and 47 percent for corn. Holdings of no
other commodity in surplus approached those
levels.
Reduced plantings in conjunction with the
Feed Grain Program brought reductions of 9
percent and 21 percent, respectively, in the
outturns of corn and sorghum grains this
year. Moreover, the quantity of wheat har­
vested was off about 10 percent from the
previous year due to the adverse effect of
drought on the spring wheat crop.
These reductions in the output of feed
grains and food grains, while helpful in
shrinking surplus stocks, were not sufficient
to pull down stocks of these commodities to
levels that are considered to be reasonable
reserves in relation to annual use.
Exports Top P revious Record

Exports of agricultural products have
taken a relatively large share of the annual
output of a number of farm products. This
has been so particularly during the past five
years when foreign shipments have been
above the average of the entire postwar
period, as shown in the chart. In the year
ended June 30, 1961, the latest period for

SELECTED INDICATORS OF
AGRICULTURAL ACTIVITY

which data are available, agricultural exports
reached a new high in both value and volume.
The value of agricultural exports at $4.9
billion was 9 percent above the previous fiscal
year and 4 percent above the record of 1957;
export volume topped the record level of 1960
by 7 percent.
During the year ended June 30, 1961, as
measured in relation to total annual sales,
shipments to foreign countries were equal to
about one-half o f the annual sales of rice,
wheat, and cotton, one-third o f those of
tobacco and barley, one-fourth o f that of soy­
beans, and one-sixth of corn and sorghum
grains. Looking at it another way, total ex­
ports of agricultural products now take the
equivalent o f the output of one acre out of
every six in cultivation.
In the year ended June 30, wheat and
cotton accounted for most of the gain in
total export shipments from the previous
year. In fact, the 660 million bushels of wheat
and flour in wheat equivalent which were
exported represented an all-time high. Cotton
exports of 7 million bales were the second
highest in more than a quarter-century. Some
of the other commodities which registered new
highs in foreign shipments were soybeans,
corn, hides and skins, and poultry meat.

Exports of agricultural products advanced to a
new high In 1 9 H , representing the fifth co nsecu­
tive year in which such exports have exceeded the
average of the p o stw a r period.

Price s H e ld Y e a r-E a rlie r Levels

Prices received for 1961 as a whole are
expected to average about the same as in
1960, despite the unprecedented level of for­
eign shipments and relatively strong domestic
markets for farm products. Somewhat higher
average prices for crops, due chiefly to higher
support prices, were offset largely by lower
average prices for livestock and livestock
products, which in turn reflected expanded
marketings. Broiler and turkey marketings,
for example, expanded sharply with prices
subsequently skidding to unprecedented lows.
Prices of all farm products averaged higher
than year-earlier levels early in 1961. Prices
then dipped, and by June were both below a
year earlier and at the low for 1961. Follow-




Prices received by farm ers for the year as a whole
will apparently average about the same as in I960.

46

’ 48

'5 0

'5 2

'5 4

56

58

60

A n advance In net farm incom e in 1961 resulted
from reco rd m arketing*, higher support prices tor
major crops, and increased governm ent payments.

13

ing the midyear low, prices received advanced,
and by November were only slightly below
a year earlier. As indicated in the accom­
panying chart, however, average prices for
the entire year have been substantially below
the average of the 1946-60 period.
Farm Incom e A d v a n ce s

Net farm income in 1961 apparently will
be up about $1 billion, or 9 percent, from
1960. Cash receipts from the sale of agri­
cultural products are expected to register a
gain of 2 percent as marketings have ad­
vanced to a new high and prices have aver­
aged about the same as in 1960. Contributing
importantly to this year’s gain in cash re­
ceipts are higher returns from hogs and dairy
products which more than offset the lower
level of receipts from poultry products. The
lower cash receipts indicated from the sale
of food and feed grains will be more than
recovered in gains in the receipts from mar­
ketings of cotton, tobacco, soybeans, and
fruits and nuts.
The gain anticipated in cash receipts is
being supplemented by an increase in gov­
ernment payments disbursed to participants
in the 1961 Feed Grain Program, as well as
by preliminary payments on the 1962 wheat
crop in conjunction with the wheat stabili­
zation program.

14




The combination of the gain in cash re­
ceipts plus the increase in government pay­
ments is estimated to have yielded a realized
gross income equivalent to an annual rate of
$39.3 billion in the first three quarters of
1961. Production expenses in the same period
are estimated to have been at an annual rate
of $26.8 billion.
The result has been that net farm income,
which includes a net gain in inventories of
$.4 billion, increased to $12.9 billion, annual
rate, in the first three quarters of 1961. At
this level, net farm income was up nearly
$1.0 billion from the year-earlier period.
With no marked swings indicated in prices
of farm products through November, it seems
probable that net farm income for 1961 will
not vary sharply from the levels posted for
the first three quarters. Such a level of net
farm income for all of 1961 would represent
a substantial rise from 1960, as well as from
the postwar low of 1959, as shown in the
chart. However, it would still be below the
average of the postwar period. The relatively
low level of prices and income during recent
years, when exports have ranged well above
the average for the postwar period, suggests
that further improvement in farm income
rests ultimately with meeting the challenge
of a surfeit of a few of the major farm
products.

ANNUAL INDEX to MONTHLY BUSINESS REVIEW (1961)
INDUSTRY
Slackening in Heavy Industry

FINANCE
January

Local Trends in
Construction Contracts .............March
Inventories and the
Business Recession
Employment Trends in a
Heavy-Industry District
Steel Finishing Capacity in a
Heavy-Industry Area

April
June
July

Rebound in Use of
Bankers’ Acceptances
Patterns of State
and Local Taxation

January
January

The Federal Debt in Review

February

A Year of Cross Currents
in Banking

February

Bank Earnings in 1960

April

The Income Tax in Local
Government Finance

April

A Look at the Foundry Industry

August

Ownership of Demand Deposits

May

Interpreting Recent
Unemployment Data

October

Deposit-Type Financial
Institutions

June

November

Financial Flows in Credit
and Capital Markets

July

December

Postwar Patterns in Homebuilding
and Financing .............................August

Changing Patterns of
Industrial Price Behavior
Unemployment Insurance as an
Economic Stabilizer

Indebtedness of States in the
Fourth District

AGRICULTURE
Case History of Soybean Prices
Farmland Prices Edge Higher

March

October

Trading in Federal Funds

October

June
SPECIAL TOPICS

Downturn in Farm
Production

September

Growing Greens in
Urban Areas

November

Farm Abundance Continues

December




September

A Look at Liquidity

Changes in National Product Related
to Selected Business Series
Progress of the Highway
Program

May

September

15




FOURTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT