View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY

BuomeMftevieuJ
IN T H IS I S S U E

-FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of CLEVELAND—

“D e e e m S e n . W

5 9

How Farmers Fared in '59.................... .

3

Interest Rates, Wage Rates, and
Uncertainty (by Robert V. Roosa). . . .

7

Around the Fourth District.....................

10

Annual Index to Monthly
Business Review (1959).....................

11

NET F A R M I N C O M E
Billions of d o llars
I

I

I

I

I

I

30

O n e of the fe w econ om ic m e a su re s w h ich
has declined in 1959 is the incom e received _
b y fa rm e rs. It is sh o w n h ere in the form
of net re a lize d incom e, w h ich lost a s much
g ro u n d in ’5 9 a s it h a d g a in e d in ’5 8 . — 2 0

0

I

50

I

’51

I

’5 2

I

’5 3

I

’5 4

I

’5 5

I

’5 6

Source: U. S. D epartm ent of A griculture. D a ta e xclu d e ch an g e in inventories.




I

’5 7

I

’5 8

0

’5 9

Additional copies of the MONTHLY BUSINESS
REVIEW may be obtained from the Research De­
partment, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Cleveland 1, Ohio.




How Farmers Fared in ’59
as well as for broad questions of public policy
a y e a r when most business and
(including considerations of farm welfare)
economic measurements have shown a
gain from the previous year (despite the in­are by no means clear-cut or one-sided, and
they lie beyond the scope of this article.
terruptions occasioned by the steel strike)
the total income received by farmers has gone
A factual review of the year 1959 in agri­
down.
culture, as sketched below, starts with de­
velopments on the farm output or production
Such a year-to-year scoring stands in
side.
Next comes a summary of price and in­
marked contrast to the 1958 tally. In that
come developments. Finally the most recent
year, farm income showed a significant rise
trends of farm land prices and of farm debt
from the 1957 figure, at the same time that a
are considered, all against the backdrop of
number of basic indicators of business were
postwar trends in general.
scoring net declines for the year — despite
the fact that during about two-thirds of the
year 1958 the business cycle was in an ex­
Large Farm Output
panding phase. Thus, both of the past two
The total output of the nation’s farms is
years have witnessed a somewhat “ off-beat”
expected to reach a new high in 1959. A
timing for agriculture in relation to industry
marked expansion in the output of pork, as
—a phenomenon which is by no means new.
well as gains of more moderate proportions in
The implications of such a phenomenon for
the production of eggs and broilers, boosted
problems of general balance in the economy,
the combined volume of livestock and live­
stock products to a new high. An outturn of
crops equal to the record of last year was
Farm output advanced slightly to a new high In
indicated November 1, despite less favorable
1959, due chiefly to further gains in the output of
weather, particularly during the fall harvest
livestock products.
period. Modest increases in planting this year,
INDEX 1947-49=100
reflecting the discontinuance of the acreage
reserve of the soil bank, more than compen­
sated for the lower average yields that pre­
vailed.
u r in g

D

The anticipated volume of farm products
this year, although up only slightly from the
record level of 1958, will be virtually onefourth more than in 1950. As shown in the
accompanying chart, growth in output over
the ten-year period was uneven, with nearly
one-half of the total increase taking place in
1958. However, the average annual rate of
increase of nearly 214 percent since 1950 far
surpassed that of any other peacetime decade.

Source of data: U.S. Department of Agriculture




The sharp increases in crop yields that have
been obtained over the past decade (see tabu­
lation) have been a major factor in this ex­
pansion of farm output. Gains in average

3

yields per acre of from 20 percent to 75 per­
cent have been registered by some of the
principal crops. The yield of corn, for exam­
ple, which accounts for a fourth of total crop
production, increased by nearly two-fifths
during the past ten years. The quantity of
wheat harvested per acre increased by more
than a third. Per-acre yield of cotton rose
by more than a half.

Price support holdings In Septem ber of this year
were at new highs fo r the season. Wheat, corn, and
cotton comprise nearly four-fifths of the total.
Billions of dollars

Yields Per Acre
1957-59
Average

Percent Increase
from 1947-49
Average

34
Sorghum grain, bu.
+78%
+ 76
Potatoes, cwt.
176
443
+54
Cotton, lbs.
50
+ 39
Corn, bu.
23
+ 38
Wheat, bu.
1,549
+28
Tobacco, lbs.
+25
18
Sugar beets, tons
24
+ 19
Soybeans, bu.
Higher rates of production per animal have
also contributed to the gain in farm output.
The over-all gain in livestock production per
breeding unit has actually been slightly in
excess of the over-all gain in crop production
per acre.

Build-up of Stocks
Farm production has increased more
rapidly than population since 1950, as output
rose 23 percent in contrast to a 17 percent
gain in population. Supplies of some farm
products have, as a consequence, exceeded use
and stocks have accumulated even though
domestic demand has remained strong and
exports have continued at high levels.
The build-up of stocks has been particu­
larly heavy for corn, wheat, and cotton. That
is the primary reason why those three com­
modities accounted for nearly four-fifths of
the price-support obligations of the Com­
modity Credit Corporation on September 30.
(See accompanying chart.) The CCC’s in­
vestment in inventory and price-support
operations was in excess of $9 billion at the
end of September, in contrast to $7.5 billion
a year earlier.

4




'50
’51 '52
'53
'5 4
'55
'5 6
'57
Plotted as of September 30, each year
Source of data: U.S. Department of Agriculture

'5 8

'59

A further significant rise in obligations of
the CCC is in prospect over the next few
months as substantial quantities of a record
corn crop and a much larger than average
crop of cotton are placed under price-support
agreements. The quantity of wheat placed
under support agreements, however, may be
down from last year, due to a considerably
smaller crop which forced market prices
above year-earlier levels after mid-summer.
Only a little over half as much wheat was
placed under support agreements through
October of this year as was placed under sup­
port during the same period last year.

Prices of Farm Produets Decline
Prices received by farmers this year have
reflected the heavy supplies of crops and live­
stock products. Prices received for all farm
products began moving down about midyear;
for the entire year, prices have averaged
about 4 percent below a year ago, as shown
in the chart. Most of the decline has been due
to lower prices for livestock and products,
which have averaged about 6 percent below
a year ago; prices of crops, taken as a group,

have averaged about 2 percent below a year
ago.
The decline in prices of livestock products
was especially sharp for hogs, eggs, and
broilers. Hog prices so far this year have been
off more than a fourth, egg prices more than
a fifth, and broiler prices more than a sixth
from the levels that prevailed during the
same period last year.
The decline that occurred in the average
prices of crops was offset by increased mar­
ketings; cash receipts from crops, exclusive of
government payments, were, therefore, about
equal to last year. Cash receipts from the sale
of livestock products, however, fell short of a
year earlier, due mainly to price declines re­
sulting from the increased volume of market­
ings of pork and poultry products. The net
effect of these developments will apparently
reduce cash receipts from farm marketings
for the year by about
percent.

2y2

Advance in Prices Paid
Prices paid for goods and services used on
the farm have averaged higher this year than
in any previous year of record. (See chart.)
Prices paid have averaged nearly 2 percent
above last year, continuing the upward trend
of cost rates that has prevailed during most
of the past decade. Most of the rise in cost
rates in 1959 can be attributed to higher
prices for feeder cattle, motor vehicles, farm
machinery, and building and fencing mate­
rials. Increased real estate taxes, interest
charges, and wage rates also contributed to
the advance.

Farm Income Down
The decline in farm income this year vir­
tually erased the gain that occurred last year.
Farmers’ net realized income in 1959, cur­
rently estimated at $11.2 billion on the basis
of the first three quarters, will apparently be
down about 15 percent from 1958, and only
slightly above that of 1957.
The decline in net income this year reflects
a drop of three-fourths of a billion dollars in
cash receipts, a reduction of a half billion




Prices received by farm ers this year declined from
the five-year high of 7958 due to Increased market­
ings. but prices paid fo r items used on the farm
advanced to a new high.
INDEX 1947-49=100

oC
’5 0

’51

'5 2

'5 3

'5 4

’55

’56

’5 7

’58

'5 9

Source of data: U.S. Department of Agriculture

dollars in soil bank payments (as expansion
of the conservation reserve only partially
compensated for the elimination of the acre­
age reserve) and an increase of three-quarters
of a billion dollars in production expenses.
Production expenses have risen 34% since
1950.

Land Prices Advance More Slowly
Farm land prices advanced to a new high
in 1959. The rate of advance during the
spring and summer, however, was only about
half as much as during the same period last
year, suggesting that the recent decline in
income may be causing prospective purchasers
to be less active bidders than heretofore.
The uptrend in farm land prices, which has
been uninterrupted since 1954 despite the lack
of net growth in net farm income over the
period, may be attributed to the influence of
at least three factors. One is the continued
demand for farm land for non-farm uses in
areas of significant urban and industrial ex­
pansion. Another factor is the continued de­

5

mand by farmers for additional land for farm
enlargement. Finally, there is reportedly a
rather widely held belief that farm land is a
good investment as a hedge against inflation.

Billions of dollars
25 -----------------

Farm Debt at New High
The steady upward trend of farm real
estate prices in recent years has contributed
significantly to the expansion of farm debt.
Total farm debt, exclusive of price-support
loans, is expected to reach a new high of
nearly $23 billion by year-end. (See chart.)
Over half of that amount, or $12 billion,
represents the anticipated amount of farm
mortgage debt. Currently about two-thirds of
all land purchases involve some financing and
most of it is secured by a mortgage on farm
real estate.
The continued expansion in non-real-estate
debt this year, as well as in the recent past,
reflects the constantly growing capital re­
quirements of agriculture, with labor making
up a declining proportion of the total inputs.
Farmers continued to increase their use of
production credit this year. The increased
Farm land prices rose to a new high in 1959 despite
a decline la the prices of farm products and Income.
IN D E X 4 7 -4 9 = 1 0 0

FA R M LA N D P R IC ES

„r n ~ T n ~ T ~ ~ r r n ~ r ~ r ~
■50

’51

'52

’53

’54

’55

’56

'57

Based on March 1
Source of data: U.S. Department of Agriculture

6




Farm debt rose sharply in 7958 and again in 1959.
The annual increase In outstandings was larger in
each of the two years than in any other year of the
postwar period.

’58

'59

FARM DEBT
(at ye a r end)

20

it!
■
ill
ll
n

15

NON-REAL -ESTATE

o —1

'50

'51

'52

’53

’54

55

'56

57

’58

’59

Source of data: U.S. Department of Agriculture

numbers of cattle on feed explains much of
the increase in this type of credit. The in­
crease in farm expenditures for tractors,
trucks, machinery, and other equipment has
also been an important factor in lifting nonreal-estate debt to a new high this year. Pricesupport loans of the Commodity Credit Cor­
poration (not shown in the chart) are the
only type of farm debt for which a decline
was indicated in 1959.
Concurrent with the expansion in farm
debt, of course, has been a marked rise in the
dollar value of farm assets. Nevertheless, the
total farm debt now represents about 11.5
cents per dollar of farm assets in contrast to
9.5 cents in 1950. In terms of the relation
of debt to income, there has been an even
more substantial change over the past decade.
Total farm debt now is equal to a little over
two dollars per dollar of annual net income,
whereas ten years ago, when farm debt was
comparatively low, the total debt was about
equal to annual income.

Interest Rates, Wage Rates, and Uncertainty
by Robert V. Roosa
Vice President, Federal Keserve Bank of New York
of criticism that every
central bank in a market economy encoun­
ters when the limits it imposes on further
expansion of money and credit are exerting some
effect. One is that the accompanying rise of inter­
est rates is too great, or unnecessary, or causing
much more harm than good. The other is that
rising wage rates are the primary cause of any
general price increases or particular dislocations
that are disturbing the balance of the economy,
and that restrictions upon the availability of
money and credit are futile gestures without any
real relevance to the basic problem: that is, the
need to limit wages, or the “ cost-push.”
h e r e a r e t w o k in d s

T

It is important, but not enough, to point out in
reply that the central bank cannot purport to
fulfill alone the entire range of ultimate objec­
tives that should be pursued by all economic
policy, nor to remind critics that the better
criterion probably is “ what might have hap­
pened” without some monetary limitation rather
than “ what more should be done” by monetary
and credit policy or by other means. What seems
to me even more important is to ask whether the
criticism has been formulated with a clear view
of its implications for the conditions essential to
the functioning of a market economy. To be sure,
those conditions themselves are not immutable;
they can be, and are, modified by changes in the
framework of public economic policy year by
year. But it should be the economist’s task to sort
out the issues for evaluation, and in that respect,

I question whether we have done enough during
recent years in appraising the role of uncertainty.
Can a market economy function with fullest effec­
tiveness, over time, if the scope for uncertainty
with respect to interest rates, or wage rates, for
example, is narrowed appreciably more than has
already occurred ? Has the United States or some
other countries, perhaps, already gone too far,
so that some pulling back may be appropriate?

Flexibility and Uncertainty
in Interest Rates
The theory of interest rates and the central
bank’s concern with them is much too vast and
exciting a subject for me to undertake here. I
should at least assert, however, on the basis of
fairly continuous observation of the experience of
most leading central banks since World War II,
that flexibility of interest rates, under the play
of shifting competitive pressures, has been essen­
tial to the performance of the market economies.
There were many who attempted, as we did here,
to peg, or stabilize, or support some or all seg­
ments of the maturity range. In the end, every
country that chose to preserve the essence of a
market economy gave up the effort to maintain
interest rates at what were thought to be
“ socially tolerable” levels, when these proved in
practice to be sustainable only by inflating the
rest of the economy with increasing quantities
of central bank credit. Some instead forthrightly
turned to the full apparatus of a planned econ­

EDITOR’S NOTE: Reprinted, by permission of author and publisher,
from Economics and the Policy Maker: Brookings Lectures 1958-1959, pp.
108-114. Copyright The Brookings Institution, Washington, D. C., 1959.
The excerpt printed here is part of Mr. Roosa’s contribution entitled
“ Monetary and Credit Policy” in which he discusses the tools of economic
analysis upon which monetary and credit policy depend. In addition to
Mr. Roosa, the contributors are Sidney S. Alexander, Gerhard Colm, Neil
H. Jacoby, Louis Shere, Sumner H. Slichter, Mark S. Massel and Everett
E. Hagen.




7

omy, and began a proliferation of special devices
for insulating parts of the market, and shelter­
ing others. But even these efforts, in economies
that were extensively “ planned,” have now
largely broken down because a national plan
could not build effective barricades against the
forces of competition at work in international
trade. The actual or suppressed inflation gener­
ated by the effort to hold interest rates down had
done more damage to the domestic economy as a
whole, in its ability to produce goods that could
be sold abroad to pay for essential imports, than
could possibly be offset by any supposed advan­
tages in making low-interest credits available to
all at home.
The evidence would seem persuasive that so
long as a country is heavily dependent upon in­
ternational trade, or if not, so long as it chooses
to have a market economy (which is necessarily
responsive to many of the same forces that are
conspicuously revealed in international trade),
interest rates must be flexible. There must, at any
time, be good grounds for uncertainty as to where
interest rates will be in the weeks or years ahead.
Any attempt to remove or limit uncertainty by
establishing pegs, or ceilings, for interest rates
is, therefore, certain to collapse in time, unless a
country is prepared to shut itself off from the
Western world and convert to a planned economy.
It is quite possible, of course, having recog­
nized the need for flexibility and uncertainty, still
to argue that particular actions of the central
bank, in a particular set of circumstances, have
led, among other things, to limitations upon
money and credit and increases in interest rates
that were unwise. To do so is not to qualify as an
advocate of planning, or the outvoted minorities
in many central banks would find themselves
among the many who might feel quite uncom­
fortable. To be sure, no central bank is always
right. But the issue to be joined with these critics
is whether the central bank has found the best
balance among its ultimate objectives, and
whether it has found the best translation of its
policy judgments into intermediate and opera­
tional objectives. Once the “ right” judgments,
whatever they are, have been found for any given
situation, there should not be any question that

8




any interest rate changes which emerge should
be the result of interaction between the policy
action taken and all other market forces—not an
arbitrary “ given” inserted on the basis of some
independent judgment of “ what ought to be.”
Recently, particularly in the United States,
criticism has centered on the level of interest
rates, not on the need for rate flexibility or rate
uncertainty. Rates are said to be generally higher
than they need to be. They have reached such
levels, so the argument runs, because the Federal
Reserve has let out too little of the marginal
supply of money and credit. With more bank
credit, interest rates would be lower and users
of credit would do more to expand the employ­
ment of men and resources. The Federal Reserve
has failed to permit this expansion because it is
preoccupied with potential inflation. Yet that is
misguided quixotry, we are told, since prices have
been rising mainly because of wage increases.
And the Federal Reserve can do nothing about
that. High interest rates, and a slow growth rate,
it is argued, are the unnecessary price of an un­
successful effort to combat wage inflation. Does
this mean that a stage has been reached for
elevating wage policy to comparable importance
with monetary and credit policy?

Are Wage Policy and Credit Policy
Complementary?
Most other countries have, indeed, gone much
further toward the formulation of a national
wage policy, and toward various means of making
such policy effective, than has ever been con­
templated in this country except in wartime. In
some, the traditional patterns of wage bargain­
ing— industry by industry on a national scale—
seem to lend themselves more readily to pro­
cedures for joining spokesmen for management
and labor from a number of industries in con­
sultations, at which the public interest is also
represented, to determine the basic conditions of
the wage bargain for the country as a whole. In
some, long-established procedures of arbitration
provide a basis for giving effect to nation-wide
“ norms” worked out by consultative groups, or
by cabinet ministers. In some, strong national
labor confederations and employer groups re­
spond to appeals of “ national interest” , particu­

larly with a view to maintaining exports, and
voluntarily establish restraints of their own upon
the general pace of advance in wage rates. And
at the other extreme, there are instances of legal
authorization for ministerial intervention to set
wage rates, as well as prices and profits, al­
though little use has apparently been made of
such powers.

though wide differences in national conditions
make generalization dangerous, there does seem
to be some basis for a conclusion that the best
results have been achieved in those countries
where the government’s role has been to provide
improved data and emphasize the relevance of
certain broad criteria, with the wage bargain left
to contending forces in the market.

Enough has happened in the other market
economies to justify a question whether some
method may be needed, and appropriate, for re­
flecting national considerations with respect to
economic stability and growth in the wage bar­
gaining process, year by year. But this question,
too, should be referred back to the essential ele­
ments of a market economy, as outlined early in
this paper and as further elaborated in apprais­
ing the concept of uncertainty as it relates to
price stability and interest rate flexibility. Though
quite unqualified to say, I should think that any
independently determined pegs, or arbitrary in­
crements, for wage rates or other labor benefits
would be as contrary to the conditions needed
for the functioning of a market economy as fixed
prices, or pegged interest rates, or arbitrary
profit margins. The risk even in any search for
“ norms” is that they then become universal
minima, with most contracts set at the “ norm”
or higher. And yet it may be important for the
vitality of a market economy that the range of
variable wage demands and settlements be kept
uncertain—both as a spur to the introduction of
newer techniques of higher productivity, and as a
spur to labor mobility and exertion.

Actual experience in dealing with “ cost-push”
on the wage side has, at the least, provided an­
other stem reminder that there are no easy
choices between absolute solutions for the causes
of instability. It appears doubtful that a national
wage policy could be developed and implemented,
within the framework of a market economy, that
could achieve a degree of general effectiveness, or
of general acceptability, comparable to that of
monetary and credit policy. The most effective
corrective for distortions among the various parts
of the price mechanism, so long as the elements
of a market economy are preserved, is to be
found in the functioning of the price mechanism
itself. In time, any industry that prices itself
out of its market will find its own correction, and
the same may apply to labor, so long as no arti­
ficial props are erected to support or perpetuate
a distorted situation.

Perhaps it is when single contracts become so
important as to exert a general and notable in­
fluence upon wages and prices throughout the
country that any consideration of new approaches
is justified. That seems to have been the case
abroad. But even then, the various formalized
approaches to a national policy for wages do
not appear to have been successful, either in
noticeably limiting the actual averages of wage
increases or in reducing the burden still to be
carried by the central bank through limiting the
availability of money and credit. The outstanding
instance of governmentally imposed cost-of-living
factors in wage contracts, for example, has been
abandoned after many years of trial. And al­




That proviso brings me back to monetary and
credit policy. For it does have a responsibility to
avoid being used as one of the props. Can it,
should it, when unemployment seems large but
wage rates are rising, add to the supply of money
and credit in the hope of providing quick em­
ployment opportunities? If existing credit is al­
ready fully used, what are the chances that new
increments will result mainly in general price
increases, in an accentuation of cyclical in­
stability, and in stunting longer-range projects
that could otherwise provide part of the basis
for sustained growth? These are the questions
that a responsible central bank must try to re­
solve, when confronted by a “ cost-push” situa­
tion. It does not, in practice, have the choice of
merely deciding that, because “ cost-push” forces
are operating, it can give up the effort to find
that limit for money and credit which will provide
the best balance among all objectives, in the light
of all the existing circumstances. It cannot sim­
ply open the valve and step aside.

9

A 'u u u td th e . tf-044/U U ^ b tib u c t—
BANK DEBITS IN OCTOBER
(12 Medium-size Cities, Fourth District)

Covington-Newport
Mansfield
Lorain
Zanesville
Middletown
Springfield
New Castle
Lima
Lexington
Hamilton
Warren
Wheeling

Ky.
Ohio
Ohio
Ohio
Ohio
Ohio
Pa.
Ohio
Ky.
Ohio
Ohio
W . Va.
• •

October 1959
% change from
year ago

3 months ended Oct. ’59
% change from
year ago

+14%

+10%
+14
+ 9
+14
+ 13
+ 11

+11
+11
+11

+
+
+
+
+
+

11
8
7
6
6
3

+

1

-

3

+11

+ 6
+16
+12

+
+

6
3

•

The level of Fourth District department store sales in October was un­
changed from September, after seasonal adjustment. Preliminary estimates indi­
cate that a slight increase occurred in November.
•

#

•

The withdrawal of Christmas club savings during November resulted in a
seasonal dip in savings deposits of individuals at 47 reporting banks in the
Fourth District. Savings are nevertheless still at relatively high levels. This is
indicated by the fact that volume at the end of October had established a new
record high for the ninth consecutive month, and by the further increase in timedeposit accounts of individuals which offset about one-third of the Christmas
club withdrawals.
* * *
In the first half of December, barometers of activity in the industrial sector
of Cleveland business recorded substantial increases. Electric power output
climbed to a new record, while steel production and railroad freight traffic scored
further advances.
* # *
Although the spread of unemployment in Cleveland appears to have been
arrested, claims for unemployment compensation in early December were still
about twice as high as before steel inventories became depleted in mid-October.
The resumption of steel production has improved the employment outlook, but it
will be some time before all types of finished and semi-finished steel mill products
will be available in quantities sufficient to enable full-scale manufacturing activ­
ity and full-scale employment.
* « #
An Ohio State University agricultural forecast for 1960 states that net
incomes of farmers will probably decline further. Prices to farmers may average
somewhat lower in 1960 than in 1959, primarily because of lower prices for
cattle and hogs. However, receipts from milk and eggs will be up somewhat.
(The above items are based on various series of District or local data, which are assem­
bled by this bank and distributed upon request in the form of mimeographed releases.)




ANNUAL INDEX to MONTHLY BUSINESS REVIEW (1959)
INDUSTRY
Heavy Industry and
Employment in ’58 ........................January

FINANCE
Cross Currents in Banking ................ February
Bank Earnings in 1958 ..............................April

Construction Headed for
New Records ................................. February

A Fourth Surge of Consumer Credit .......July

A Decade of Manufacturing in
Western Pennsylvania ......................March

Public Debt Management
(Statement by Wm. McC. Martin) .....July

Steel Capacity ...........................................March

Trends in State Government
Expenditures ................................September

Exports and Imports of S teel......................May
Three Measures of Employment
in Cleveland ...........................................May
The Ebbing of Unemployment .................. July
Building Trends in Cleveland
and Other Cities ..............................October
Expansion by Electric Utility
Companies ....................................... October
Impact of the Steel Strike on Business
in Cleveland ................................. November

AGRICULTURE
The Fertilizer Industry in Ohio,
Pennsylvania and Kentucky .............. April
Production Loans to Farm ers................ August
Another Year of Farm Abundance ....September
How Farmers Fared in ’5 9 .................. December




Ownership of Demand Deposits.................. June

Bank Debits in Heavy Industry
Areas .............. ..............................November
Interest Rates, Wage Rates, and
Uncertainty (by Robert V. Roosa,
reprinted from Brookings Lectures
1958-1959)
December
TRADE
Department Store Trade in ’58 ...........January
Changing Seasonal Patterns of
Department Store Sales........................ May
Sales of Hard Goods and Soft Goods
at Department Stores .................November
GENERAL
Rounding Out a Year of Price Stability.....June
Urban Renewal in Three Large Cities ....August

11




FOURTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT " ■