View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

IN

THI S

I S S U E

Another Look A t Bank
C a sh M a n a g e m e n t

. . 2

The Tightening
Labor M a rke t . . . .

FEDERAL



RESERVE

BANK

OF

14

CLEVELAND

E C O N O M IC REVIEW

ANOTHER LOOK AT
BANK CASH MANAGEMENT
In June 1962, the Federal Reserve Bank of

In order to provide a standard for com ­

Cleveland introduced a system of "daily re­

parison, it was necessary to'utilize a control

porting" for member banks in the Fourth

group of member banks located in an area

Federal Reserve District. Under daily report­

where daily reporting was not in use for a

ing, District member banks each day report

specified period of time. In other words,

figures on deposits, vault cash, and related

characteristics of banks in the control group

items to the Federal Reserve Bank of C leve­

were compared with characteristics of se­

land. By so doing, and with the information

lected Fourth District banks. Specifically, the

on maintained reserves and required reserves

two groups of banks were (1) those Fourth

provided by this Bank in return, member

District member banks located in the Cleve­

banks are afforded the opportunity to manage

land territory (the portion of Ohio served by

cash

particularly

this Bank's main office), and (2) member banks

through the minimization of cash reserves in

located in the portion of Indiana served by the

excess of legal requirements. This article

Federal Reserve Bank of C hicago.2 These

presents the results of a research project de­

areas are shown by the shaded parts of the

signed to find out whether District member

accompanying map.

assets

more

efficiently,

banks did in fact manage their cash assets

The findings of this study, while perhaps

more tightly; by so doing, the article evaluates

not conclusive, strongly suggest that a notice­

the influence that daily reporting had on the

able im p r o v e m e n t did n o t o ccu r in the cash

cash management practices of District banks.1
1 As background for this article, the reader may wish
to consult other articles on cash management that ap­
peared in previous issues of the Economic Review.
See "Bank Management of Cash Assets," ''Management
of Cash Assets at Reserve City and Country Member
Banks," and "Management of Cash Assets at Fourth
District Reserve City and Country Member Banks,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Cleveland, Ohio,
April, July, and December 1965. The first article provides
a general discussion of the cash management function.

2



2 Considerations of data availability made it desirable
to limit the study to member banks located in the area
covered by this Bank's Cleveland office. Member banks
located in that part of Indiana served by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago were chosen as a control group
because "daily reporting" is not in effect in the Seventh
Federal Reserve District and because of Indiana's simi­
larities and proximity to Ohio.
The Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland acknowledges the cooperation of its
Chicago counterpart in supplying data and technical
advice.

AUGUST 1966
banks (14 days). In the case of loan demand,
a proxy measure derived from Call Report
data was used—the ratio of loans (net) to de­
posits. The data on loan demand, in contrast
to the data on reserves, were as of a certain
date (the date of the Call Report).
Because bank size significantly influences
the performance of cash management, banks
in each group were distributed in seven size
classes. The total of gross demand and time
deposits—averaged for three selected periods
—was used to measure bank size. The ranges
management performance of Ohio banks

of the size classes and the number of member

(compared with Indiana banks) in th e p e r io d

banks in each class are shown in Table I.

follow in g th e sta rt o f daily rep o rtin g . That

Because the relative distributions (Column 5)

is to say, and as will becom e more evident later,

left Indiana poorly represented by very small

daily reporting in the Fourth District did not

banks (size class 1) and, more importantly, by

widen the performance differential between

very large banks (size class 7), all-bank aggre­

Ohio and Indiana banks that had already ex­

gates would easily be misleading. This situ­

isted at the time daily reporting was introduced.

ation strengthened the decision to focus on

Nevertheless, as a by-product of the consid­

individual size classes. It should be noted that

eration of daily reporting, the study did yield

all banks in size classes 1 through 6 are

some interesting findings of a broader nature,

Country member banks, whose legal reserve

which becom e the major emphasis of this

calculation periods cover two-week intervals.
Member banks in class 7, on the other hand,

article. In capsule form, the findings show
that member banks in Ohio, in the time period
studied, managed their cash balances more
aggressively than member banks in Indiana.

TABLE I
Size Classes and Number of Banks
Selected Banks in O h io and In dian a

More aggressive performance of the cash
management function in turn reflected the
influences of deposit composition, deposit
instability, and the intensity of loan demand.

CHARACTERISTICS OF THE DATA
The data used in this study are for the years
1961-63, inclusive. Except for measures of

(1)

(2)

Size
Class Gross Deposit Ranges
1

Less than $1 million

2

$ 1 -$ 5 million

(3)

(4)

(5)

Number o f Banks
(4) as a
O hio Indiana
Percent o f (3)
6

2

101

66

65
67

33%

3

$5-$ 10 million

55

37

4

$ 1 0 -$ 2 5 million

52

32

62

5

$ 2 5 -$ 5 0 million

18

10

56

6

$5 0-$ 100 million

9

6

67

7

$1 00 million and over

11

3

27

loan demand, the data are reserve period
averages of daily figures, with the reserve
period in all cases that for Country member



252

1 56

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

3

CASH RATIOS for SELECTED BANKS in OHIO and INDIANA
Size Class 3

M A IN T A IN E D RESERVES
TOTAL DEPOSITS

________

IN DIA N A

REQUIRED RESERVES
TOTAL DEPOSITS
_____ ________ ^
s
--------------- -— s

OHIO
T ^

IN D IA N A

OHIO

VAULT CASH
TOTAL DEPOSITS
OHIO

IN DIA NA

CORRESPONDENT BALANC ES

1/26/61

S o u r c e s of data:

June 1962
Daily Reporting

Federal

Reserve




Bank

of Clev elan d

and Federal

Reserve

Bank

of C h i c a g o

12/12/63

lb.

CASH RATIOS for SELECTED BANKS in OHIO and INDIANA
Size Class 7

M A N A G E D CASH

M A IN T A IN E D RESERVES

—

—

REQUIRED RESERVES

VAULT CASH

CORRESPONDENT BALANCES

2/2/61

Digitized
S o u r c e s o for
f daFRASER
ta:
Federal Reserve B ank


June 1 9 6 2
D a i l y R e p o rt in g

of C l e v e l a n d

and

Federal

Reserve

Bank

of C h i c a g o

12/19/63

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
are all Reserve City banks (Country banks in

classed Indiana banks. For example, during

Ohio with over $100 million in deposits were

the three-year period, 1961-63, the managed

excluded), whose legal reserve positions must

cash ratio averaged 13.31 percent for Indiana

be adjusted over a, seven-day period. For

banks in size class 3 compared with 8.74 per­

banks in the latter size class, each observation

cent for Ohio banks in that size category. In

was computed from daily averages covering

the case of the largest size banks, those in

two reserve calculation periods.

Indiana operated with managed cash ratios
averaging 7.21 percent compared with 3.59
percent for Ohio banks.

CASH M ANAGEM ENT PERFORMANCE

Table II also presents average values of the

Since performance variation among the

component ratios (with the appropriate com ­

size classes is largely in the details, and the

putational sign of each) that enter into the

basic essentials of performance are reason­

measurement of the managed cash ratio. The

ably consistent throughout all size classes,

first three component ratios (Columns 2, 3,

the graphic presentation is limited to only

and 4) are more easily and effectively con­

two size classes. Thus, data for member banks

sidered when combined into the ratio of ex­

in size classes 3 and 7 are used to illustrate

cess reserves (maintained reserves -f- vault

differences in cash management performance

cash — required reserves) to total deposits

between member banks in the two groups

(Column 5). The existence of excess reserves

(see Charts la and lb ). From the charts, it is

causes banks to forego income that could be

clear that Ohio bankers were more aggressive

earned if such reserves were loaned out or

than their counterparts in Indiana in manag­

invested; bank management therefore prefers

ing discretionary (managed) cash assets.3

to keep such balances to the minumum con ­

This is evidenced by the substantially higher

sistent with various operating considerations.

proportions of managed cash to total deposits

As Table II reveals, in the period under re­

held by both relatively small (size class 3) and

view all classes of Indiana banks showed ex­

very large (size class 7) Indiana banks.4

cess reserve ratios that were larger (between

As shown by the values of the managed

47 percent in the case of class 2 banks, and

cash ratios in Table II (Column 1), Ohio banks,

143 percent in the case of class 7 banks) than

in every size class, outperformed similarly

the ratios of similar size banks in Ohio. In all

3 See the articles referred to in footnote 1. Discretionary,

larger proportions of total deposits as demand

cases, Indiana banks also kept substantially
or managed, cash assets are defined as the sum of cor­
respondent balances plus excess reserves, with the
latter calculated as the difference between the total of
balances maintained at the regional Federal Reserve
bank plus vault cash and the volume of required reserves.
4 The start of daily reporting in June 1962 did not widen
the differential in favor of Ohio banks— particularly
smaller banks— as can be seen from the charts.


6


balances at correspondent banks (Column 6).
Thus, the pattern prevailing in the case of the
managed cash ratio was also clearly evident
in the two major component ratios.
At this point, it is appropriate to ask the
seemingly obvious question, why? That is to
say, what reasons can be found to explain the

AUGUST 19 66
TABLE II
M anaged Cash and Component Ratios
Selected Banks in O h io and Indiana
(M e a n V a lu e s o f Reserve Period A v e ra g e s, 1 9 6 1 -6 3 )
(1)
M a n a g e d Cash-rTotal Deposits
=

(2)

(4)

(3)

Maintained
Reserves-;Total Deposits +

Vault Cash-rTotal Deposits

Required
Reserves -fTotal Deposits

(5)
Excess
Reserves-TTotal Deposits +

( 6)
Correspondent
Balances-H
Total Deposits

( 2 + 3 — 4)
Size Class 1
Ohio

11.91

6.26

Indiana

22.29

12.37

+
+

3.11

3.94

5.43

6.48

2.51

5.01

9.87

12.42

Size Class 2
Ohio

10.30

6.54

Indiana

13.95

9.45

+
+

2.15

4.75

3.94

6.35

2.18

5.83

5.80

8.14

+
+

2.17

5.04

3.17

5.58

2.13

5.90

5.36

7.94

2.33

4.88

2.91

5.85

2.42

5.51

5.59

6.05

Size Class 3
O hio
Indiana

8.74

6.04

13.31

9.13

Size Class 4
Ohio
Indiana

8.76

5.46

11.65

8.68

+
+

Size Class 5
Ohio
Indiana

7.59

5.51

12.21

8.41

8.24

5.07

12.61

8.06

+
+

2.25

5.02

2.74

4.85

2.48

5.56

5.33

6.87

+
+

2.60

4.93

2.74

6.04

2.11

5.71

4.46

8.13

+
+

1.32

8.61

1.36

2.23

1.64

9.45

3.30

3.91

Size Class 6
Ohio
Indiana
Size Class 7
O hio

3.59

8.65

Indiana

7.21

11.11

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland and Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

more aggressive cash management perfor­

2, time and savings deposits held by all size

mance of member banks in Ohio. (The criterion

classes of Ohio banks comprised considerably

for "m ore aggressive," it should be reiterated,

larger proportions of total deposit liabilities

is that lower ratios indicate less income fore­

than in the case of Indiana banks. The con ­

gone.)

sistency in the differential between the pro­
portions during the 1961-63 period suggests

DEPOSIT COMPOSITION

that structural factors played an instrumental

A marked difference in the deposit mix of

role. W hile there does not seem to be a com ­

banks in the two groups would appear to be of

plete explanation for the (locational) differ­

particular importance in explaining the better

ence in deposit composition, one known in­

performance of Ohio banks. As seen in Chart

fluence does offer some possibility and merits




7

2.

TIME DEPOSITS as a PERCENT of TOTAL DEPOSITS
for SELECTED BANKS in OHIO and INDIANA

1/26/61
60

12/12/63

S iz e C la s s 3

_______________________

.

50

OHIO

40

IN D IA N A
30
1/26/61

12/12/63

S ize C la s s 4

60
___________________________________________________ ________________

50
^

—

_______

40

OHIO

—

IN D IA N A

30
1/26/61

Si ze C la s s 5

60
50

OHIO

40

IN D IA N A
30

S o u r c e s for
o f dFRASER
ata:
Federal Reserve B an t
Digitized


12/12/63

_____________ ._________ _

of C l e v e l a n d

and

Federal

Reserve

Bank

of C h i c a g o

AUGUST 1966
TABLE III
Growth of Time and Savings Deposits, 1961-63

TABLE IV
Growth of Gross Demand Deposits

Selected Banks in O h io and Indiana

Selected Banks in O h io and Indiana

(in thousands o f dollars)

(in thousands o f dollars)

Size
Class

Ohio

Indiana

Size
Class

Indiana

Ohio

1

T i= $ 4 0 8 . 5 + $ 2 . 1 t

T i'= $ 2 9 3 . 2 + $ 0 . 7 t

1

T i= $ 3 4 0 . 7 + $ 1 . 0 t

T V = $502.1 + $ 0 .5 t

2

T2= 1 ,5 2 6 .0 + 5 .8t

T2'= l , 0 2 6 . 9 + 3 . 8 t

2

T2= 1,167.2 + 3.3t

T2' = 1,592.1 + 4 . 6 t

3

T3= 3 , 5 2 7 .0 + 1 6.5t

T3' = 2,570.1 + 7 . 8 t

3

T3= 3 ,2 1 8 . 9 + 7 . 9 t

Ts ' = 3,945.1 + 8 . 9 t

4

T4= 6 ,8 9 1 .8 + 3 2 .6 t

T4' = 5 , 5 6 1 .3 + 2 1 .Ot

4

T4= 6,593.8 + 15.0t

T4' = 7 , 3 7 5 .6 + 2 6.7t

5

T5= l 5,028.1+ 7 8 .3 t

T5' = 1 3 ,6 0 7 .6 + 3 3 .1 1

5

T5= 1 4 ,0 2 9 .4 + 4 4 . 3 t

T5'= 2 0 , 8 5 8 . 6 + 4 6 . 9 t

6

T6= 2 8 ,2 7 0 .8 + 1 1 1.8t

V = 2 4 ,2 2 9 .6 + 6 6 .2 t

6

T6= 33,057.1 + 4 1 . 9t

T6'= 3 8 , 7 0 6 . 7 + 5 0 . 7 t

7

T7= 306,3 3 8 .9 + 1 ,9 1 1.8t

T7' = 17 7 ,8 8 3 .2 + 3 5 3 .3 t

7

T7= 4 8 3 , 8 9 2 .5 + 5 3 7 .6 t

T7'= 5 4 4 , 6 9 2 .0 + 3 3 6 . 6 t

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

comment. The lesser importance to Indiana

interval (the duration of a Country bank's re­

banks of time and savings deposits partly re­

serve adjustment period) increased, on aver­

flects the regulation by the State of Indiana—

age, by about $21 thousand. The $5,561.3

affecting all commercial banks in the State—

thousand figure in the equation is a constant

that sets (what have turned out to be compara­

that represents an estimate of the amount of

tively low) maximum interest rates payable on

time and savings deposits as of the base period

time and savings deposits. Thus, until Jan-

(January 1961).

uary 1, 1964, the maximum rate payable on

The numbers reveal two important points.

passbook (savings) accounts was 3 percent;

First, for each size class, Ohio banks began

since that date, the maximum rate has been

the year 1961 with more time and savings

raised to 3 % percent. The maximum rate on

deposits than did Indiana banks of similar

time deposits (including negotiable certifi­

size. Second, member banks in Ohio achieved

cates of deposit) with maturities of 90 days or

larger additions to time and savings deposit

more has been fixed at 4 % percent since

liabilities than did Indiana banks. (For ex­

December 29, 1964, while a 4 percent ceiling

ample, class 5 banks in Ohio experienced

is in effect for shorter maturities.

average reserve period gains of $78.3 thou­

The consequences of this situation, as well
as the influence of other factors, are suggested

sand compared with $33.1 thousand for Indi­
ana banks in the same class.)

in Table III. The data presented in the table

Similar equations for gross demand de­

are estimates of the average dollar increase

posits are presented in Table IV. As can be

in total time and savings deposits (T* and T /)

seen quickly, there is not the same consistency

for the range of size classes 1 through 7 dur­

of behavior as revealed by time and savings

ing the 1961-63 period. For Indiana banks in

deposits.

size class 4, for example, the equation indi­

Identification of the relative prominence of

cates that during the period under review

time and savings deposits in the liability struc­

time and savings deposits in each two-week

ture of Ohio banks is the first step in explain­




9

EC O N O M IC REVIEW
ing differences in cash management perfor­
mance between member banks in that State

requirements.
But it also would seem that deposit mix in­

and those in Indiana. It will be recalled that

fluences cash management performance in

the required reserve ratios of Indiana banks

ways other than through the required re­

exceeded those of O hio banks of similar size

serve route. As a general matter, and assum­

in the period under review. Since reserve

ing all other things do not change, positive

requirements against demand deposits and

relationships may be asserted to exist between

against time and savings deposits were the

the ratio of demand to total deposits and the

same for all member banks of the Federal

ratios of maintained reserves and corre­

Reserve System during the period studied,

spondent balances to total deposits. Consider

the higher required reserve ratios of Indiana

first the deposits a member bank keeps with

member banks reflected the greater propor­

its correspondent bank. These balances com ­

tions of demand deposits in the total deposit

pensate the correspondent for the various

mix of those banks. This is the case because

services the latter provides. Probably the

legal reserve ratios set against demand d e­

single most used service is that of check

posits (presently, 12 and 16}^ percent for

clearance. In part, then, the demand bal­

Country and Reserve City member banks,

ances a bank may keep at its city correspon­

respectively) are substantially higher than

dents compensate for the costs incurred by

the legal reserve ratio applied to time and

the latter and, closely related, provide the

savings deposits (in the period studied, 4 per­

correspondent with ready cash to settle n eg­

cent) .

ative clearing balances on the bank it is ser­
vicing. Because checks are written against

If deposit composition influenced only the

demand deposits, only correspondent bal­

required reserve ratio, and if in all other

ances will tend to increase with the proportion

respects member banks in the two states were

of demand to total deposits.

alike, the managed cash ratios of Indiana
banks, by definition, would be lower than

Deposits at the Federal Reserve bank, on

those of O hio banks of similar size (the re­

the other hand, serve both a regulatory func­

quired reserve ratio is a deduction item in the

tion and a check-clearing function generally

computation of the managed cash ratio).

similar to that served by correspondent bal­

However, deposit composition also influences,

ances (the Federal Reserve System operates

both directly and indirectly, the other com ­

check-clearing facilities that both complement

ponents of the managed cash ratio. To some

and supplement those offered by the corres­

extent, the higher effective required reserve

pondent network). A member bank's main­

ratios of Indiana banks explain their higher

tained reserves, like its correspondent bal­

maintained reserve ratios, since it is the de­

ances, act somewhat like a sponge—absorb­

posit of cash at the regional Federal Reserve

ing net clearing surpluses on some days and

Bank, plus the holding of vault cash, that

providing immediate liquidity needed

allows member banks to meet legal reserve

other days to meet unforeseen deficits.


10


on

AUGUST 1 9 6 6
TABLE V
Estimates of Gross Deposit Instability
Selected Banks in Ohio and Indiana
(Coefficient of Variation)
( l)

(2)

Size Class

Ohio

Indiana

1

3 .3 4 %

4 .1 7 %

matter, the estimates of deposit instability
(measured by the magnitude of the coefficient
of variation) shown in Table V, suggest that
short-term (reserve calculation period) fluctu­
(3)

(2) as a Percent o f (1)

period under review than for Ohio banks.

125%

2

1.97

2.03

103

3

1.36

1.83

135

4

1.26

1.68

133

ations were larger for Indiana banks in the
With the exception of size classes 2 and 6
(where differences were slight), the deposit
instability of Indiana banks exceeded that of

5

1.31

1.59

121

6

1.49

1.55

104

Ohio banks of similar size by between 21 per­

7

1.26

2.18

173

cent (class 5) and 73 percent (class 7).

Note: As implied, the coefficient o f variation (V) is a measure of
relative dispersion— in this instance, a measure o f short-run
deposit-level instability. In making the estimates, the following
procedure was used:
(1) Trend was eliminated from each deposit series;
(2) For each series, the standard deviation (0) of the residuals
about the trend line was estimated;
(3) Because, even within a size class, a ve ra g e size o f bank
differs between the two states (see the following table),
V instead o f 0 w as selected as the more meaningful
statistic for comparison purposes. For with everything
else the same, the larger a bank’s deposits, the more
absolute volatility in its levels is to be expected. A
relative measure o f variation (V) was calculated for
each series, as well as for each size class and state, by
dividing the ave rag e deposit magnitude into 0.

1

of time and savings deposit levels. This situ­
ation coupled with the greater relative im­
portance of time and savings deposits in total
deposits of Ohio banks explains the lesser d e­
posit volatility for Ohio banks (see Table V).
The data in Table VI are interesting in two
for demand deposit volatility to decline sharply

Ohio
$

stability of demand deposit levels, as shown
in Table VI, is substantially greater than that

additional respects. First, there is a tendency

A verage Size of Bank
(in thousands of dollars)
Size Class

The influence of deposit volatility is not
independent of deposit mix. Short-term in­

867

Indiana
$

with the first increases in bank size (as well

842

2

3,045

2,941

3

7,686

7,158

4

15,318

14,772

5

33,777

37,546

6

67,245

67,434

7

884,536

749,123

TABLE VI
Estimates of (a) Demand Deposit and
(b) Time and Savings Deposit Volatility
Selected Banks in Ohio and Indiana
(Coefficient of Variation)

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

DEPOSIT INSTABILITY
Deposit instability, that is, fluctuations in
deposit levels, also influences the size of a
bank's managed cash ratio. The more a bank's
deposits fluctuate day-to-day and week-toweek, the more cash it must hold to meet
sudden net deposit withdrawals. As a general



Demand Deposits
Size Class

Time and
Savings Deposits

Ohio

Indiana

1

6 .1 9 %

7 .0 2 %

2 .4 9 %

1 .1 5 %

2

4.37

3.43

0.88

0.41
0.52

Ohio

Indiana

3

3.22

3.06

1.17

4

2.94

2.92

0.85

1.20

5

2.87

2.77

1.54

0.74

6

2.68

2.62

2.17

1.57

7

2.53

2.93

1.61

0.77

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

1 1

EC O N O M IC REVIEW
as for time and savings deposits), and for
these declines to continue, though more
gradually, as bank size increases. The con ­
siderably greater deposit instability observed

TABLE VII
Net Loans as a Percent of
Total Deposits— June 30, 1962
Selected Banks in O h io and Indiana

at the smallest banks (in both groups) is, per­
haps, explained by the lack of diversification
in deposit ownership and by the dependence
of small banks in rural areas upon agricultural
activities.
Second, except for member banks in size
class 4, member banks in O hio experienced
greater instability of time and savings deposit
levels than like size institutions in Indiana.

(1)

(2)

Size Class

Ohio

Indiana

(3)
(1) as a Percent

1

5 3 .9 %

2 1 .7 %

2

51.5

43.5

118

3

54.1

39.7

136

4

54.2

44.1

123

5

53.1

47.0

113

6

48.5

43.7

111

7

49.3

50.6

97

248%

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland and Federal Reserve
Bank o f Chicago

Only for one size class (6) was the volatility

sidered by most observers to be a bank's most

of time and savings deposits at Indiana banks

profitable, and most socially desirable, use

more than one-half of what it was at Ohio

of acquired funds; or (2) as some indication

banks; conversely, for all other classes the

of the circumstances or conditions surround­

coefficients of variation of time and savings

ing loan demand, for example, the intensity

deposits at O hio banks were more than double

or lack of intensity of loan demand. For pres­

what they were at Indiana banks of com pa­

ent purposes, the latter interpretation is given

rable size. Possibly, the relatively low rates

more weight, particularly because there is no

paid on time and savings deposits by Indiana

reason to expect managerial com petence to

banks discouraged corporate money man­

vary among states (bank size has already been

agers and other holders of temporarily idle

isolated out).

funds who are sensitive to interest rate dif­

It is clear from the data in Table VII that,

ferentials from holding time deposits (partic­

with the exception of member banks in size

ularly certificates of deposit) in banks in that

class 7, net loan to deposit ratios were higher

State.

for Ohio banks. It can also be noted that the
differences tend to narrow with increases in

LOAN DEM AND

bank size, becom ing relatively insignificant

Differences in cash management perfor­

in the case of the very largest banks. Thus,

mance between member banks in Ohio and

the net loan to deposit ratio maintained by

Indiana may also be a consequence of dif­

Ohio banks in size class 1 exceeded that of

ferences in loan demand. Table VII presents

similarly classed Indiana banks by about 150

the average net loan to deposit ratio for each

percent, while in the case of class 6 banks the

size class of bank, as of June 30, 1962. The

differential was only 11 percent. The 3 per­

ratio may be interpreted in at least two ways:

cent differential in favor of Indiana banks in

(1) as reflecting bank management's aggres­

size class 7 can perhaps be best interpreted,

siveness in making loans—a function con-

in the absence of other information, as sug­

Digitized for12
FRASER


AUGUST 1966
article,5 that the way to maximize total profits

gesting no significant difference among the
largest institutions with respect to loan de­

is to maximize each income element and to

mand. In the case of small banks, where loan

minimize each cost element.

demand is more or less confined to the sur­

As businessmen, bankers obviously like to

rounding locale, community characteristics,

make profits. That they seek to maximize

for example, industrial-agricultural mix, may

profits, at least in some short-run sense, is

account for the lower loan ratios observed

quite another matter and considerably less

for relatively small banks in Indiana. Local

certain than the first statement. Like everyone

factors are less dominant in the case of the

else, bankers have various objectives and

larger banks, and in the case of the largest

goals, all of which may not be mutually com ­

banks virtually completely give way in im­

patible. Moreover, like everyone else, bankers

portance to national econom ic circumstances

are creatures of habit, to say nothing of in­

and conditions.

ertia. In short, it should hardly be surprising

With the making of loans viewed as the

if bankers, viewing the making of loans as the

"first" business of commercial banking, it is

basic banking function, were to reveal some

to be expected that, unless and until consid­

slackness in managing their bank's cash

erations of liquidity and solvency demand

position, and were to exercise more success­

otherwise, higher loan demand will result in

ful management only under the pressure of

compression of the managed cash and invest­

intense loan demand.6

ment ratios. Banks might, of course, always
seek to maximize profits by placing any and
all idle balances into liquid, interest-bear-

5 See "Management of Cash Assets at Reserve City and
Country Member Banks," Economic Review, July
1965, pp. cit.

ing assets, for example, U. S. Treasury bills
and Federal funds. But this assumes both that
the maximization of profits is the goal of bank
management and, as pointed out in an earlier




6 Thus, it may not be surprising that daily reporting was
not found to have the type of results, with respect to
improved cash management by Country bankers, that
some individuals suspected it would have.

13

EC O N O M IC REVIEW

THE TIGHTENING LABOR MARKET
During the first five years of the current
business expansion—from the first quarter
of 1961 to the first quarter of 1966—total
employment in the U. S. rose from 66.8 mil­

TABLE I
Employment and Unemployment, U. S.
First Quarter Averages, Selected Years
Seasonally Adjusted

lion to 73.6 million persons, and unemploy­

In Millions o f Persons

ment declined from 4.9 million to 2.9 million
persons.

Total
Employment

Payroll employment in nonagri-

cultural industries over the same time span

Nonfarm
Payroll
Employment

Unemployment

1961

66.8

53.5

4.9

rose by an even larger amount than total em­

1964

69.8

57.5

4.0

ployment, or from 53.5 million to 62.5 million

1965

71.4

59.6

3.6

1966

73.6

62.5

2.9

persons. Expressed as annual averages, total
employment increased by almost 1.4 million

Y ear-to-year change
19 61-6 6 (avg.)

+

1.4

+

1.8

— 0.4

persons per year (an annual growth rate of

1 9 61-6 4 (avg.)

+

1.0

+

1.3

— 0.3

2.0 percent), nonfarm payroll employment

1 9 64-6 5

+

1.6

+

2.1

— 0.4

19 65-6 6

+

2.2

+

2.9

— 0.7

increased by 1.8 million persons (3.1 percent

Source: U. S. Department o f Labor

growth rate), and unemployment declined by
nearly 0.4 million persons.

increase in total employment was substan­

The changes in total and nonfarm employ­

tially larger than that of the entire five-year

ment over the five-year period were not evenly

period. Similarly, the gain from the first

distributed, the averages nothwithstanding.

quarter of 1965 to the first quarter of 1966

For example, as shown in Table I, during the

amounted to 2.2 million persons, a gain ex­

most recent two years the annual average

ceeded only once before (between the first
quarters of 1955 and 1956), and was more

Note: Employment and labor force data for the second
quarter of 1966 that have become available since
this article was prepared do not completely fit the
pattern prevailing through the first quarter. For
example, while the labor force continued to grow
at a slackened pace, the increase, for the first
time since 1964, was larger than the increase in
employment (employment increased by an un­
usually small amount in the second quarter). While
these developments do not invalidate the retro­
spective analysis presented in this article, they
could influence prospective developments, de­
pending of course on whether the second quarter
was a temporary departure or a turning point.

Digitized for
14FRASER


them double the annual average increase
during 1961- 64. The decline in unemployment
during the 1965-66 period amounted to 0.7
million persons, or considerably more than
the earlier annual averages shown in Table I.
The accelerated pace of employment growth
in the four-quarter period under review was
accom panied by a noticeable tightening of
the labor market, which at this time shows
little sign of abating. It is the purpose of this
article to examine some aspects of that tight-

AUGUST 1966
l.

business recession.

CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE, EMPLOYMENT,

The effect of public policy measures (for

and UNEMPLOYMENT

example, reductions in income taxes) intro­

M i l l i o n s of p e r s o n s

M illio n s of p e rs o n s

tivity, which in turn would stimulate employ­

NU M BE R of U N E M P L O Y E D

__

duced after 1963 to stimulate econom ic a c­
ment growth and reduce unemployment, is

Scale

evident from the chart. As the chart shows,
employment gains exceeded labor force ex­
pansion in each quarter beginning in 1964,
|- A N N U A I CHANGES

and the level of unemployment declined cor­
respondingly.1Interestingly, the recent widen­

Q U A RTERLY CH/I NGES

J k lfll l l ,
( ^—E M P L O Y 1A ENT

> 1

ICIVILIAN L AB0R FORCE

Hi i

ing of the margin between employment gains

1

and labor force growth did not result from a

SEASONAL LY ADJUSTED

IQ 2Q 30 40 10 20 30 40 IQ 20 30 40 IQ 20 30 40
1963

S o u rce of d a t a :

1964

1965

1966

rising pace of employment increases but from
a slowing down in labor force growth. Thus,
employment gains remained fairly steady
throughout the last five quarters shown in the

U .S . D e p a r t m e n t o f L a b o r

chart—between 500,000 and 600,000 per­
ening and to explore some of the implications

sons per quarter—in contrast to a progres­

for the economy, both in retrospect and in

sive reduction in civilian labor force expansion

prospect.

from nearly 500,000 in the first quarter of

CHANGES IN THE LABOR MARKET

1965 to 300,000 in the first quarter of 1966.

The degree of labor market tightness re­

(See also Table II.)
The quarterly increases in the labor force

flects the amount of balance—or lack of bal­

in 1965, when combined, more than met the

a n ce—between the supply of and demand for

goal of a 1.5 million average annual rise pro­

manpower. Expansion of the civilian labor

jected by the U. S. Department of Labor for

force (labor supply) and gains in total civilian

the second half of this decade, but the annual­

employment (reflecting, although not directly

ized increase in the first quarter of 1966 fell

measuring, labor demand) are shown in

considerably short of the mark.2 The shortfall,

Chart 1 for the period since 1963. Employ­

of course, may be made up by the expected

ment gains fell short of labor force expansion
during 1963, so that the number of unemploy­
ed (shown in the upper portion of the chart)
failed to decline. In fact,

unemployment

moved slightly higher, lending some support

1 There was a net gain in employment in the third
quarter of 1964 despite the unusual appearance of the
data plotted in the chart. The phenomenon reflected the
late occurrence of the survey week in relation to the end
of the school year, which shifted normal third-quarter
employment increases into the second quarter.

to the then widely held view that unemploy­
ment would continue to settle on a progres­
sively higher plateau after each



postwar

2 In the second quarter of 1966, the gain in the civilian
labor force was even smaller than in the first quarter.

15

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
TABLE II
Civilian Labor Force and Employment, U. S.
Q u a rte rly C h an ge s, 1 9 6 4 - 1 9 6 6
S e a so n a lly Adjusted
In Thousands of Persons
Adult Men

Adult W om en

Teenagers

All Groups

Labor Force Employment

Labor Force Employment

Labor Force Employment

Labor Force Employment

1st Q

+ 138

+243

+ 136

+ 108

+ 116

+ 158

+390

2nd Q

+ 161

+253

+ 330

+ 388

+ 100

+

44

+591

+685

3rd Q

+

69

+ 103

— 159

—

98

—

40

+

23

— 130

+

4th Q

+

24

+

73

+ 163

+ 177

+

74

+

46

+261

+ 296

5

+

+509
28

1st Q

+246

+318

+226

+ 255

+

7

+477

+580

2nd Q

+

+ 102

+ 103

+ 130

+296

+278

+431

+510

3rd Q

— 157

—

63

+248

+298

+302

+336

+393

+571

4th Q

— 191

—

29

+ 151

+ 188

+402

+ 379

+362

+538

1st Q

+ 193

+268

+

+ 178

+

+ 138

+ 308

+584

32

64

51

Source: U. S. Department o f Labor

large influx of young people into the labor

and older, increased retirement from work

force after mid-1966. On the other hand, the

resulted in reduced labor force participation,

shortfall may also be a warning signal that

while a decline in the 35-44 year labor force

the labor force is losing its elasticity in sup­

group followed steady shrinkage of that age

plying the manpower needs of the economy.

group in the population. Normal growth of the

If the latter were the case, it would be a re­

remaining portion of the adult male labor

versal of the situation prior to 1964 when

force was too small to offset the com bined

labor force expansion, although much below

losses in the three age groups that showed

the recent rate, was too fast for employment to

declines.

keep abreast.
The recent slowdown in growth of the civil­

In contrast, labor force participation of
adult women has continued to rise, and,

ian labor force can be traced to one specific

coupled with rapid growth in the number and

component group—adult men. For example,

labor force participation of teenagers (in re­

a decline for that group occurred in the third

sponse to more job opportunities suitable for

and fourth quarters of 1965, instead of normal

that group), has produced the overall increase

expansion in line with population growth

in the labor force shown in the table. Thus,

(see Table II). The decline mainly involved

while a decline in the adult male labor force

three age brackets within the adult male

did not halt total labor force growth between

group. In the 20-24 year group, it reflected

the first quarters of 1965 and 1966, it did

increased manpower demands of the armed

necessitate adjustments on the part of em­

forces as well as shifts from part-time to full­

ployers to a supply of additional manpower

time student status. Among males 65 years

that was largely teenagers (70 percent).

Digitized for
16FRASER


AUGUST 1966

2

cially in the prime age groups where labor

EMPLOYMENT
Change

fro m

F ir s t Q u a r t e r 1 9 6 5

to F i r s t Q u a r t e r 1 9 6 6
M il l io n s of P e rs o n s

*,»■.

force participation is 95 percent or higher.
The steep rise in teenagers' share of total
new employment—from less than one-tenth
a year earlier to one-half in the 1965-66 peri­

+2 . 0 -

od (first quarters) — underscores the comingof-age of the record baby crop of the mid1940's. It also points to the importance of

+1. 5 -

young people as a source of additional man­
power in the next several years. The large
rise in employment between 1965 and 1966

+1. 0 -

would not have com e about except for the
availability of young people, since the gain
in adult employment in that period was less

+0 . 5 -

than the gain in the same time span a year
earlier. In percentage terms, during 1965-66
0-

(first quarters)

SEASONALLY ADJUSTED
S o u rce of d a t a :

U . S . D e p a r t m e n t of L a b o r

teenage

employment rose

much more than adult employment, while
adult males recorded a smaller gain than
adult women.

Composition of Employment Gains. Shifts

Chart 2 further indicates that two out of

within the labor force left their mark on the

every three adult women and more than nine

composition of the employment gain from

out of every ten young people constituting the

1965 to 1966 (first quarters), as Chart 2
shows. Teenagers, representing about 9 per­

employment gain during 1965-66 reflected
net additions to the labor force. The remaining

cent of the labor force, accounted for one-

portion in each group consisted of persons

half of total new employment, while adult men
—roughly 60 percent of the labor force—

previously unemployed.3 In contrast, the en­
tire net increase in employment among adult

contributed only one-eighth of the gain. The

men was accounted for by the unemployed,

latter represented a sharp drop in the share of

including an additional number of persons

new employment that had been accounted
for by men in previous years (40-45 percent).
It also meant that for the second year in a row
the contribution by men was smaller than
that by adult women. For one thing, this situ­
ation reflects the relative depletion of the
supply of suitable male workers among the
unemployed; it also indicates that few un­
tapped sources of male labor are left, espe­



3 These numbers show that the predicted midyear in­
vasion of the labor market by teenagers, which in the
spring of last year was viewed with alarm by most ob­
servers, was harmlessly channeled into employment
without damage to the unemployment rate. There were
even a few jobs to spare for reducing teenage unemploy­
ment over the year. It must be remembered, however,
that many of the new teenage workers found employ­
ment in Neighborhood Youth Corps and similar Gov­
ernment-financed projects
assist young people.

designed

specifically

to

17

EC O N O M IC REVIEW
needed to offset the decline in the male labor
force mentioned earlier.
About 45 percent of additional employ­

TABLE III
Employment Change by Occupation
First Quarter Averages, 1965-1966

ment during 1965-66 went to white-collar

In Thousands
o f Persons

occupations, while a slightly smaller per­
centage filled blue-collar jobs. The balance

White-collar workers

Percent
+ 2 .9 %

+921

Professional and technical

+ 164

+ 1.8

M an age rs, proprietors

—

64

— 0.9

represented additional employment in service

Clerical

+588

+ 5 .4

occupations. The largest relative gains o c ­

Sales

+233

of the gain, reduced by the loss in farm jobs,

curred among clerical, sales, service, and

Blue-collar workers

+ 5 .2
+ 3 .4

+851

semiskilled blue-collar workers, with each

Craftsmen, foremen

+254

O peratives

+714

+ 5 .5

registering employment gains of over 5 per­

Nonfarm laborers

— 117

— 3.4

cent between the first quarter of 1965 and the
first quarter of 1966 (see Table III).
M anpow er Needs in 1966. In order for the

Service workers

+ 5 .2

+471

+ 5 .8

+397

Service exd. household
Farm workers

+ 2 .9

— 196
+ 2 ,0 4 7

economy to expand in 1966 at the same pace

TOTAL

as in 1965 and to attain currently estimated

Source: U. S. Department o f Labor

— 5.5
+ 2 .9 %

levels of total output, it will be necessary to

As Chart 2 indicates, unemployment con ­

have an increase in total labor input that

tributed about one-third of the employment

matches the combination of last year's rates

g a in d u r in g 1 9 6 5 -6 6 , i n c l u d i n g a b o u t

of growth in manhours and in productivity.
Stated differently, econom ic growth could be

400,000 adult men, 200,000 adult women,
and less than 100,000 teenagers. Consider­

retarded and production could fail to reach

ing only the numbers involved, it should be

estimated goals if one or all of the ingredients

possible to shift about one-fourth of the

of total labor input should slacken, or if an

present approximately three million unem­

insufficient increase in one is not offset. If

ployed persons into employment this year,

labor productivity, or output per manhour,

thereby reducing the unemployment rate to

continues to advance at last year's rate—a

about 3 percent, assuming continuation of

rather bold assumption, perhaps, in light of

current labor force trends.4 Given the com ­

some of the observations discussed later in

position of the unemployed pool, however,

this article—the manhours variable (number

potential difficulties becom e readily appar­

employed times hours worked per employee)

ent. Unlike the labor force, the unemployed

will be the other key factor in assuring that
this year's output goals will be met. Specifi­
cally, achieving the number of manhours
needed will require a net addition of at least
two million employed persons this year, who
would com e either from the unemployed or
from persons outside the labor force.
Digitized for 18
FRASER


4 A reduction of the unemployment rate below 3 per­
cent, or very close to the absolute minimum, was antici­
pated in May by the chairman of the President's Council
of Economic Advisers, if output were to continue to
advance at recent rates. The Secretary of Labor two
months earlier had associated "full employment" with
an unemployment rate of "about 2.5 percent."

AUGUST 1966
TABLE IV
Percent Distribution of Unemployed Persons
First Quarter Averages, 19>65 and 1 9 6 6
Seasonally Adjusted
1965

1966

By a g e and sex:

p e rce n ta g e of short-term unem ploym ent
(under five weeks) increased during 1965-66.
The decline in duration, coupled with the
very low levels to which unemployment rates
of specific age or occupation groups have

Men, 20 years and over

43%

40%

dropped, suggests that unemployment in at

Women, 20 years and over

30

30

least some segments of the labor force is ap­

Both sexes, 14 -19 years

27

30

proaching the frictional level, and represents

Less than 5 weeks

48%

53%

5 to 14 weeks

29

26

unemployment rates are far from a frictional

15 to 26 weeks

12

11

11

10

level for such groups of workers as nonwhite

27 weeks and over

By duration o f unemployment:

Source: U. S. Department of Labor

pool is not a self-replenishing source of man­

to a large degree labor turnover. In contrast,

or young people, although a ''frictional"
level for teenagers should probably be pegged
higher than for other workers in view of the

power. W hen the level of the pool declines in

known propensity of young workers for fre­

response to strong demand, its composition

quent job changing. Secondary worker cate­

is apt to change, with primary workers—

gories—those lacking in training, educational

particularly adult males with previous work

attainment, or significant work experience—

experience in a skilled or semiskilled o ccu ­

are likely places where additional manpower

pation—in greater demand and likely to be

may be found, especially if further efforts are

withdrawn sooner than secondary workers.

made to bridge the gap between job require­

As shown in Table IV, the total number un­

ments and qualifications of available persons

employed in the first quarter of this year in­
cluded proportionally more persons under

by redesigning jobs and by training workers.
It should not be overlooked, however, that

20 years of age and fewer adult men than

reduced productivity and upward pressure

was the case one year earlier. Compared

on unit labor costs are likely consequences of

with the age-sex composition of the labor

employing workers who lack experience or
skill.

force—six adult men, three adult women, and
one person under 20 in every ten persons—

Further difficulty in culling the manpower

the unemployed group for the first quarter

needed this year from the unutilized labor

was distorted in that it included three teen­

supply stems from the gap between occu ­

agers and only four adult men in every ten

pational skills available among the unemploy­

persons.5
The decline in total unemployment has also

ed and skills needed to fill new jobs. This is
illustrated by a comparison of the distribution

affected the length of time individuals are un­

of the present three million unemployed (by

employed (see Table IV). For example, the

reported occupation of last job) with the o c­

5 In the second quarter, the proportions moved still

cupations represented by the two million

closer toward equality: 33 percent teenagers and 36

additional jobs created during 1965-66 (see

percent adult men.

Table V). It would appear that demands in




19

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
TABLE V
Unemployment and Changes in Employment,
by Occupation
First Q u a rte r A v e ra g e s, 1 9 6 5 and 1 9 6 6

White-collar workers

710

percent appears to leave some room for fur­
ther expansion, considering that as much as
63 percent participation was achieved in
1944 (with over 11 million persons in the

In Thousands of Persons

Unemployed
1966*

total labor force participation of about 57

Employment
Change
19 65-1 966
+921

armed services). Such a high level of partici­
pation, however, is likely to be reached only
in a period of emergency, if at all. Thus, for

Professional, technical

110

+164

1966, an amount of labor force expansion

M anagers, proprietors

100

—

close to the projected rate of 1.9 percent is

Clerical

34 0

+588

Sales

160

+233

possible although by no means assured, in

64

+851

view of the rather slow gain during the first

Craftsmen, foremen

410

+254

half of this year and the uncertain contri­

Operatives

720

+714

Nonfarm laborers

35 0

— 117

bution of the adult male segment of the labor

Blue-collar workers

1,480

Service workers

470

Service exd. households

380

Farm workers
N o previous work experience

+397
100

400

TOTAL

+471

— 196
—

3,160

+ 2 ,0 4 7

*Calculated from percent distribution of total number unemployed.
Source: U. S. Department o f Labor

force due to its vulnerability to fluctuating
military demands.
Longer Workweek. The scarcity of skilled

labor in general, as well as shortages of work­
ers in specific occupations, cannot be quickly
remedied by even the most elastic labor force.
Such stringencies can be removed only
through training of new workers and, pos­

few (if any) of the categories shown could be

sibly, more efficient utilization of present

substantially met from the unemployed, es­

work forces, including a lengthening of the

pecially if it is remembered that a portion of

workweek

the unemployed in each group are merely

workers from retirement. Chart 3 presents

changing jobs and thus are not really avail­

average weekly hours of production workers

able to fill new jobs. Resort to untapped

in manufacturing industries, a group that

and possibly recall

of skilled

sources of supply, as well as to more training,

accounts for about one-fifth of total employ­

particularly for occupations in short supply,

ment and whose behavior is considered as a

again appears to be an inescapable condition

reliable indicator of the general trend in

for meeting this year's manpower demand.

employment. The chart shows that a longer

Since the unemployed pool is slowly dry­

workweek has indeed been resorted to in

ing up and is becom ing an increasingly un­

order to find a partial substitute for unavail­

certain source of additional manpower, the

able skilled workers. Total weekly hours (as

labor force assumes more importance as a

well as overtime hours) have risen almost

source of supply, both through natural growth

without interruption since 1963, with the

in numbers and through increased partici­

pace picking up in the middle of 1965, notably

pation of specific groups. The present rate of

in the durable goods industries.


20


AUGUST 1966
—during the Korean War and W orld War II
— shows that weekly hours in both durable
AVERAGE WORKWEEK in MANUFACTURING
T otal w e e k ly hours

and nondurable goods in the first quarter of
this year6 had already surpassed the highest
level of hours attained in any month of the
K orean p eriod . H ow ever, they w ere still
below peak levels recorded during 19431945, when the workweek climbed as high
as 47 hours in the durable goods sector, and
above 43 hours in the nondurable goods sector.
A further expansion in weekly hours would
thus not seem impossible. There are serious
doubts, however, as to whether such a devel­
opment would be advisable or desirable in
view of the fatigue effect of sustained overtime
work on labor productivity, as well as the in­

S o u r c e of d a t a :

U .S . D e p a r t m e n t of L a b o r

direct effect on labor cost and the direct cost
pressure due to premium pay for overtime
hours. There is the further question as to how

W hile the rise in hours per week in manu­

long an extended workweek can be main­

facturing since 1963 may not appear exces­

tained before leisure time begins to look more

sive, the aggregate tends to conceal substan­

attractive to employees than a fatter pay en­

tially larger increases in individual industries

velope.

that have been faced with rising production

Rising Compensation. In addition to the up­

requirements and an insufficient supply of

ward pressure on labor costs due to increased

labor. In the machinery industry, for example,

overtime work and employment of workers

the increase in hours is twice as large as for

possessing only marginal productivity, there

all of manufacturing. An even larger rise has

is a tendency in periods of tight labor supply

occurred in the metalworking machinery sub­

for wage and salary levels to rise generally.

section of that group, where the average work­

A recent study by the U. S. Department of

week has been as high as 46 hours and indi­

Labor shows that, between 1954 and 1965,

vidual plant schedules have run as high as

average negotiated wage rate adjustments

50 hours per week.

tended to change inversely with changes in

How much higher is the workweek likely
to be pushed in an effort to raise total manhours in general or in specific labor-starved
industries in particular? A comparison of the
current level of weekly hours with the work­
week in previous periods of labor stringencies



6 A slight easing of weekly hours, as well as overtime
hours, in manufacturing was reported in the second
quarter of 1966. The reduction, part of which reflected
curtailed work schedules in the auto industry, does not
alter the comparison of the length of the workweek
between the current and previous periods of short
labor supply.

21

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
the unemployment rate.7 Thus, negotiated
wage settlements in the first quarter of 1965
resulted in larger percent increases both for

TABLE VI
Average Hourly Earnings
in Selected Industries*

the first contract year and over the entire life

Earnings

of the contract than in the corresponding
periods of 1964 and 1963.

1965

1966

$2.59

$2.67

2.77

2.86

Percentage Increase
1 9 65-6 6
(First
Quarters)

1960-64
(Annual
A verages)

An appraisal of the outcome of wage n e­
gotiations in the early part of 1966, under­
taken by a private research organization,
found that the average increase in wage rates
negotiated from January through March 1966
was larger than gains negotiated during last
year's first quarter. O f a somewhat larger

Manufacturing
Durable goods

3 .3 %

2 .9 %

3.3

2.9
2.7

Primary metals

3.16

3.24

2.6

Machinery

2.92

3.04

4.0

3.1

Electrical equipment

2.55

2.62

2.7

2.5

Transportation
equipment

3.18

3.29

3.5

3.2

Nondurable goods

2.33

2.41

3.3

2.9
2.7

Printing and
publishing

3.02

3.11

3.0

Chemicals

2.85

2.93

2.8

3.0

of 1965 and 1966, hourly earnings in manu­

Rubber

2.59

2.64

2.1

2.4

facturing industries rose by 0.4 percentage

Construction

3.65

3.79

3.8

3.8

Communication

2.80

2.90

3.5

4.0
4.1

order of magnitude, between the first quarters

points more than the annual average increase

Electric utilities

3.17

3.29

3.7

W holesale trade

2.57

2.67

3.9

3.1

Banking

2.10

2.18

4.0

3.3

Laundries and
dry cleaning

1.47

1.55

5.4

4.0

remainder of the year, with organized labor

Hotels and motels

1.34

1.40

4.5

4.6

pressing for sizable raises by pointing to in­
creases in profits and living costs. Moreover,

*Production or nonsupervisory workers only.

between 1960 and 1964.8 (See Table VI.)
The trend toward more expensive wage
settlements is likely to continue during the

Source: U. S. Department o f Labor

the pressure for higher rates of pay will not be
confined to large unionized industries, but

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE ECONOMY

will likely affect smaller industries and non-

The developments in labor markets just

unionized plants as well, as has already been

reviewed have an important bearing on cur­

the case for some nonmanufacturing indus­

rent problems of containing inflation. The

tries. Finally, individual wage and salary rates

tightening of labor markets and the bidding

can be expected to go up as employers com ­

up of wage rates move in the direction of in­

pete with each other for their share of the

creasing labor costs, thereby adding fuel to

limited supply of workers.

the inflationary problem. It should be recog ­
nized that increasing labor costs are not the

7 "Major Collective Bargaining Settlements, 1965,”
April 1966, p. 372.

only source of inflationary pressure, and that

M o n t h l y L a b o r R e v ie w ,

the magnitudes involved in the problem are

8 During the second quarter of this year, average hourly
earnings in manufacturing were three cents higher than

important to retain a sense of correct pro­

sometimes unintentionally exaggerated. It is

in the first quarter; the increase amounted to 4.5 per­
cent on an annual basis.

Digitized for 22
FRASER


portion in dealing with the matter, and to con­
sider the evidence in its proper perspective.

AUGUST 1966
Labor costs make up one element, and an
important one, in price determination. Labor
costs are not the same thing as wage rates.
Interrelations of wage rates, labor costs, and

4.

COMPENSATION and OUTPUT PER MANHOUR
and UNIT LABOR COST
IN D EX 1 9 5 7 - 5 9 = 1 0 0

prices are not mechanical or rigid. To what
extent increases in labor compensation may
be absorbed or counteracted without raising
prices, or without dangerously depressing
profits, is a question of strategic econom ic
importance. The relevant measure of offset to
rising wage rates is increased output per manhour ("productivity"), although that measure
reflects the influence of modernized equipment
as well as labor and management efficiency.
Output Per Manhour. In recent years, and

S o u r c e s of d a t a :

U. S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e ;

apparently right up to the present, the record

U. S. D e p a r t m e n t of L a b o r ;

of achievement in increasing output per man-

B o a r d of G o v e r n o r s of th e
F e d e r a l R e s e r v e System

hour is quite remarkable. Annual changes in
output per manhour in manufacturing since

ment under mounting demand pressures, as

1957, expressed on an index-number basis,

well as loss of the initial advantage of a sharp

are shown in Chart 4. The continued rise is

rate of increase in volume—are again being

clear, although the gain of 3.6 percent for the

advanced under 1966 conditions of even

year 1965 was somewhat less than the 4.5
percent gain in 1964. An annual gain of 3.6

tighter pressures. This time, the outcome m a y
be different, but again it may not.

percent during an advanced stage of busi­

Unit Labor Costs. The gains in output per

ness expansion is highly unusual; in most

manhour in manufacturing during 1961-65

previous expansions a marked tapering off

slightly more than offset the rise in labor com ­

or even decline in output per manhour o c ­

pensation, as indicated in Chart 4. The result

curred in the mid-stages or late stages of the ex­

was that labor cost p e r u n it o f o u tp u t reg­

pansion. Indeed, many analysts had expected

istered a slight decline over those years.9

that a serious slackening or decline would
occur in 1964 or 1965, but it did not.
Thus, for a protracted period the econom y
has seemed to some observers to be on the
verge (as it has turned out, a "moving verge")
of a deterioration in productivity gains. The
same factors that were previously advanced
as heralding a slackening in productivity
gains—resort to less efficient labor and equip


9 It is generally recognized that the favorable showing
of unit labor costs in manufacturing during recent years
played a highly significant role in making possible the
relative stability of prices as well as maintenance or
increase in corporate profits. Neither the price nor the
profit picture is under direct consideration in this article.
It may be noted, however, that the industrial component
of the Wholesale Price Index, although showing a re­
newed tendency to rise in late 1965, scored an average
increase for the year of only 1.3 percent.

23

AUGUST 1966
Labor costs make up one element, and an
important one, in price determination. Labor
costs are not the same thing as wage rates.
Interrelations of wage rates, labor costs, and

4.

COMPENSATION and OUTPUT PER MANHOUR
and UNIT LABOR COST
IN D E X 1 9 5 7 - 5 9 = 1 0 0

prices are not mechanical or rigid. To what
extent increases in labor compensation may
be absorbed or counteracted without raising
prices, or without dangerously depressing
profits, is a question of strategic econom ic
importance. The relevant measure of offset to
rising wage rates is increased output per manhour ("productivity"), although that measure
reflects the influence of modernized equipment
as well as labor and management efficiency.
Output Per Manhour. In recent years, and

S o u r c e s of d a t a :

U. S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e ;

apparently right up to the present, the record

U. S. D e p a r t m e n t of L a b o r ;

of achievement in increasing output per man-

B o a r d of G o v e r n o r s of th e
F e d e r a l R e s e r v e System

hour is quite remarkable. Annual changes in
output per manhour in manufacturing since

ment under mounting demand pressures, as

1957, expressed on an index-number basis,

well as loss of the initial advantage of a sharp

are shown in Chart 4. The continued rise is

rate of increase in volume—are again being

clear, although the gain of 3.6 percent for the

advanced under 1966 conditions of even

year 1965 was somewhat less than the 4.5
percent gain in 1964. An annual gain of 3.6

tighter pressures. This time, the outcome m a y
be different, but again it may not.

percent during an advanced stage of busi­

Unit Labor Costs. The gains in output per

ness expansion is highly unusual; in most

manhour in manufacturing during 1961-65

previous expansions a marked tapering off

slightly more than offset the rise in labor com ­

or even decline in output per manhour o c ­

pensation, as indicated in Chart 4. The result

curred in the mid-stages or late stages of the ex­

was that labor cost p er u n it o f o u tp u t reg­

pansion. Indeed, many analysts had expected

istered a slight decline over those years.9

that a serious slackening or decline would
occur in 1964 or 1965, but it did not.
Thus, for a protracted period the econom y
has seemed to some observers to be on the
verge (as it has turned out, a "moving verge")
of a deterioration in productivity gains. The
same factors that were previously advanced
as heralding a slackening in productivity
gains—resort to less efficient labor and equip


9 It is generally recognized that the favorable showing
of unit labor costs in manufacturing during recent years
played a highly significant role in making possible the
relative stability of prices as well as maintenance or
increase in corporate profits. Neither the price nor the
profit picture is under direct consideration in this article.
It may be noted, however, that the industrial component
of the Wholesale Price Index, although showing a re­
newed tendency to rise in late 1965, scored an average
increase for the year of only 1.3 percent.

23

EC O N O M IC REVIEW
TABLE VII
Employee Compensation and Output Per
Manhour and Unit Labor Cost— Manufacturing
Monthly, 1964-1966
Index 1957-59 = 100, Seasonally Adjusted

including fringes, per manhour is divided by
physical output per manhour, yielding a
figure for labor cost per unit of output.
The question now arises as to whether a
continuation of the favorable record is occu r­

Employee
Compensation
Per Manhour*

Output Per
Manhour

Unit
Labor
Cost

ring when recent monthly figures are ex­

1964-J

123.8

124.3

99.6

some changes are in process, but that they

F

123.0

123.4

99.7

M

123.6

124.3

99.5

have not appreciably altered the picture.

A

124.5

125.4

99.2

Data for recent months appear to indicate the
following. The series on compensation per

amined. The data in Table VII indicate that

M

125.5

126.6

99.1

J

126.0

126.5

99.6

J

126.1

127.4

99.0

manhour is rising at a slightly faster pace than

A

126.7

127.5

99.4

previously, which is in accord with the dis­

S

127.9

127.2

100.6

O

128.0

126.3

101.4

N

127.4

127.5

99.9

time, output per manhour, despite forebod­

D

127.8

128.7

99.3
99.2

ings, has continued to rise at a rate only

1965-J

cussion earlier in this article. At the same

127.5

128.5

F

128.1

128.7

99.5

slightly less than last year's general experi­

M

128.5

129.4

99.3

ence. Introduction of modernized equipment,

98.9

A

128.9

130.4

M

129.1

130.6

98.9

made possible by the large capital spending

J

129.2

130.9

98.8

of recent years, has been an important factor

J

129.4

131.6

98.4

A

130.0

131.8

98.6

in this performance. Nevertheless, the com bi­

S

130.2

131.0

99.4

nation of compensation and output per man-

O

130.3

131.2

99.3

hour has resulted in a slight rise in labor cost

N

130.5

131.0

99.6

D

130.3

132.0

98.7

1966-J

131.7

132.5

99.4

F

132.3

132.5

99.9

per unit of output thus far this year, in con­
trast to a decline in the year-earlier period.

M

132.7

133.4

99.4

A

133.6

133.9

99.7

M

134.0

134.7

99.5

rising unit labor costs in manufacturing marks

J

134.1

135.0

99.3

a new trend is an important question for the

Whether or not this short experience with

* W a g e s and salaries plus supplements.

outlook. Some qualified observers feel that a

Note: Figures in the third column (unit labor cost) are close to, but
not identical with those shown by Series No. 62 published
monthly in Business Cycle Developments, U. S. Department
o f Commerce.

new trend is definitely in the making, and

Minor differences are traceable to alternative methods o f
seasonal adjustment of the constituent series.
Sources: U. S. Department o f Commerce; U. S. Department of
La bor; Board of Governors of the Federa I Reserve System

that it is based b o th on rising compensation,
on the one hand, and a slackening in the rate
of gain in output per manhour, on the other.
It is important to remember that these three
variables are connected in such a way that an

(See lower portion of Chart 4.) Arithmetically,

outright decline in output per manhour is not

the relationship of the three lines in Chart 4

required to produce an increase in labor cost

may be identified as follows: compensation,

per unit of output.


24


AUGUST 1966
Relation to Broader Measures. Beyond the

downward. The broader fact that last year's

impact on manufacturing, a question may be

increase in real output resulted in about equal

raised as to repercussions of recent labor

proportions from gains in manhours worked

market developments upon the economy,

and in productivity is also unusual, reflecting

more broadly measured. This subject could

especially the large employment gains of last

be raised in various forms, but, for the pur­

year. The general tendency for a considerable

pose at hand, one question may be stated this

number of years, including even some of the

way: What proportion of last year's real gain

early 1960's, was for a larger part of the gain

in output of the econom y may be traced to

in real output to be ascribed to productivity

gains in employment and the increase in

than to employment increases.

hours worked (described earlier), and what

The outline of the 1965 performance, with

proportion may be ascribed to improvement

respect to the relative roles of productivity

in productivity? What can be said about the

gains and manhour gains in facilitating out­

prospects for this year, in the same terms?
For this type of measurement, the most

put growth, helps to shape the nature of the
problem being faced in 1966. If the gains in

practical unit of coverage is the total "private

total manhours worked and in productivity

econom y," that is, Gross National Product

turn out to be about the same as experienced

deflated for price changes and less the gov­

last year,11 the total real gain in output might

ernment accounts. The starting point is the

also be very close to last year's gain of 6.2

fact that the real output of the private econom y

percent for the private economy, or 5.9 per­

("G ross Private Product") is estimated to have

cent for GNP. But if at the same time the rise

increased last year at a rate of 6.2 percent.

in GNP, in current dollars, should be as much

(Total real GNP rose by 5.9 percent.)
Of the 6.2 percent gain last year in real

as 8.5 or 9.0 percent, to an annual total of
$740 billion or more,12 as many (although not

output of the private economy, about half is

all) business analysts have suggested as fore,

estimated as due to the increase in manhours

casts, it is obvious that such an outcome im­

worked, while the other half stemmed from

plies that the accompanying rise in the price

the increase in output per manhour. The 3.1

level will be considerably larger than last

percent gain ascribable to increase in man-

year's rise of 1.8 percent in the GNP deflator.

hours worked, in turn, may be broken down

The central point is that the possibility of an

as follows: 2.6 percent was due to the increase

unusually large increase in GNP, b o th in

in numbers of people employed, while 0.5
percent may be ascribed to the net rise in
weekly hours worked.10 The increase in
weekly hours worked was quite marked in
1965, as described earlier, and ran counter
to the recognized long-run trend, which is
10 Source of these estimates is the U. S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics.




11 Such an assumption resolves a number of doubts on
the favorable side. Average working hours, for example,
are certainly not expected to rise as much as they did
last year, and may even decline in accordance with the
more customary showing of recent years.

12 A figure of $740 billion or more would be roughly
equivalent to the $735 billion forecast which was com­
mon before the July revisions in the GNP accounts.

25

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
dollar terms and real terms, is open to some

pressure on resources and reemergence of

doubt in view of the labor market develop­

the inflationary problem, public policy has
shifted toward holding down the expansion

ments discussed earlier.

TOWARDS IMPROVEMENT OF LABOR
FORCE A N D LABOR MARKETS

of aggregate demand. Unemployment, how­
ever, is not completely vanquished as a prob­
lem, especially for some of the well-known

O ne of the goals of public and private

disadvantaged groups. Therefore, the relative

policy for many years has been a general

importance of the structural approach is

improvement in the quality of the labor force

coming to the fore. As events have unfolded,

and the functioning of labor markets, includ­

it would seem that the basic distinction be­

ing such targets as the upgrading of qualities

tween the two approaches does not turn on

and skills of the labor supply, enhancement

which one is better, but rather on which one

of the mobility of labor, and a more efficient

came first in terms of emphasis.

matching of people and jobs.

2. A second converging set of considera­

As a consequence of the recent tightening

tions stems from the pressing need of employ­

of the labor market, such a set of endeavors

ers for a better qualified and more mobile

has taken on certain new angles and new

labor supply. These are management angles,

emphases. Outstanding is the marked accent

but they point in the same direction, in terms

on the acknowledged desirability of stepping

of needs and goals, as the first set of social

up such efforts. Three sets of considerations

policy considerations. So far as a better quali­

converge toward this end. They may be out­

fied labor supply is concerned, the desires of

lined as follows.

employers are clear and uncontested. In re­

1.

Efforts to reach the goal of full employ­ spect to mobility as a desideratum, there may

ment have necessarily involved a relative

be crosscurrents from management's point of

shift in emphasis from the "aggregate d e ­

view, insofar as one employer's need to hold

mand" approach to the "structural" approach.

his workers may offset another's stake in

During the 1960's until this year, the aggre­

greater mobility. But the general desirability

gate demand approach (accompanied by con ­

of an efficient matching of people with jobs,

siderable debate)

which implies mobility, commands a consider­

was favored in

public

policy over the structural approach, although

able degree of agreement.

the latter was presumably not to be altogether

3. A third set of considerations, pointing

neglected. In retrospect, it can be seen that

in the same direction as the other two, lies in

the advocates of aggregate demand have

the relationship between the quality of labor

much in the record to support the validity of

markets and the central problem of stability

their contentions of the early 1960's, insofar

versus inflation. To the extent that production

as unemployment has, in fact, been dramati­

bottlenecks can be broken by improvements

cally reduced, largely by methods involving

in labor markets, and to the extent that pro­

the expansion of aggregate demand. Now,

du ctivity gains ca n b e m aintained or in ­

however, with the em ergence of increased

creased under conditions of a better qualified


26


AUGUST 1966
labor force, inflationary pressures are less­

lations that tend to limit the earnings of retired

ened to that degree. Although no miracles

persons. Suggested changes would be aimed

may be expected from this approach, and

at providing incentive for job retention or

although the realization of gains in this di­

possible job resumption by skilled older

rection may be hard to measure, it is none­

workers. A few years ago, when unemploy­

theless true that even small advances in a

ment was a major problem, the social advan­

many-sided approach to the containing of in­

tage of early retirement programs was given

flation are helpful. Any appreciable gains in

much stress. Now that shortages of skilled

this direction would relieve some of the bur­

labor have come to the fore, attitudes toward

dens of more rigorous anti-inflationary mea­

the relative desirability of early and late re­

sures such as tighter monetary policy or tax

tirement are undergoing a marked change,

increases.

for obvious reasons.

In the light of the foregoing considerations,

3. Under the Manpower Development and

much greater attention (and in some cases a

Training Act of 1962, as amended in 1963

different kind of attention) is being paid to a

and 1965, the Federal Government has under

number of interrelated specific measures,

way a number of pilot projects for financially

both public and private. A few of them are

assisting the relocation of workers in econom i­

mentioned here for illustrative purposes, with

cally distressed areas. This type of program,

no attempt at a comprehensive listing or an

involving efforts to move the worker to the

order of priority.
1. On-the-job training of employees is now

job, rather than bringing the job to the worker,
is a new-style version of attempts to promote

a matter of recognized importance. Under the

mobility of the labor force in the process of

gun of necessity, numerous employers have
broken new ground in this direction; much

dealing with pockets of unemployment. So far,
the scale of operations has been small. Ex­

ingenuity has been exercised, and more will

perience in other countries, especially Great

be needed. Also, the Federal Government

Britain and Sweden, indicates that solid re­

has a program of providing assistance to em­

sults of such programs can be achieved.

ployers in setting up such training facilities,

4. From numerous quarters has com e ad­

both on the arrangements side and on the

vocacy of programs for the vesting of pen­

finance side, while the control of the operation

sions, or the adoption of transferable pensions,

remains with the employer. Although still

to facilitate labor mobility. It has been argued

relatively small in extent, the Federal pro­

that when there are serious shortages of

gram shows signs of gathering momentum,

skilled construction workers in upstate New

especially since a turn has been made toward

York, for example, accompanied by surpluses

industry-wide frameworks of cooperation be­

in New York City, it is undesirable to have

tween the Government and a number of

pension considerations interfere with mobility.

national trade associations.

As mentioned previously, there may be cross­

2. Numerous suggestions have been made

currents in management's view of this type of

for altering the present Social Security regu­

question. Costs of such programs may be




27

E C O N O M IC REVIEW
large, and management often feels that its

measures or programs may be involved in the

past investment in pensions entitles it to the

current approach to improvements in the

full benefits of retention of existing employees.

labor force and the functioning of labor mar­

At least, however, the pension question is

kets. Indicative of the enlarged attention paid

getting a new look under the newer circum ­

to such matters at levels of national policy­

stances.

making is the fact that the Council of Eco­

5.

Improved statistical information about nomic Advisers, which had devoted only

job needs and personnel availability con ­

about one page to such matters in each of the

tinues to be a recognized goal. But here also

1962 and 1963 annual reports, gave ten

efforts are being made in new directions. A

pages of attention to the subject in its 1965

vigorous attempt by both public and private

Annual Report (under the heading of "Toward

agencies to improve statistical data on specific

a More Productive Use of Our Labor Force"),

job vacancies is one such instance.

and in the 1966 Annual Report devoted an

In addition to the five sets of illustrations
just mentioned, numerous other types of


28


entire chapter of 22 pages to the subject of
"Strengthening Human Resources."

Additional copies of the E C O N O M IC REVIEW may
be obtained from the Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland,
Ohio 44101. Permission is granted to reproduce any
material in this publication.