View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

B y cj± i U lll 1 <1

APRIL 1964

IN THIS ISSUE

A Tale of Three Tax Cuts. .2

Thoroughbreds in
Kentucky.................. 16

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF C L E V E L A N D



E C O N O M IC REVIEW

A TALE OF THREE TAX CUTS

HE LARGEST tax cut in the nation's history
(in dollar terms) was implemented last
month. That action is the third major reduc­
tion in income taxes in the postwar period,
and is probably one of the most significant
fiscal steps that the nation has ever taken.
The 1964 tax cut represents an attempt to
move an already expanding economy to a
higher level from which it may continue to

T

expand.
There is a general consensus that initially
the economy will respond favorably to the
tax cut. But there are widely divergent views
regarding both the nature and magnitude of
the response. It is clear that the tax reduction
has created much enthusiasm concerning
the near-term economic outlook. In the ex­
treme, some even view the tax reduction as
a panacea for nearly all our economic ills.
Others see the tax reduction as insurance
against recession in the near term.
2




Any evaluation of the impact of the 1964
tax cut should include a review of the ex­
periences associated with the two tax cuts
that occurred earlier in the postwar period.
This is particularly important in view of the
fact that those experiences indicate that a tax
cut needs to be timed appropriately in order
to be most effective.
The first major postwar tax cut became
effective in April 1948 and the second was
completed in August 1954.* The 1948 tax
cut was aimed primarily at personal income
taxes rather than corporate taxes. Changes in
the law resulted in an average personal tax
reduction of 21 percent. The $4.7 billion re­
duction in Federal revenue amounted to 2.7
* In addition to the tax legislation passed in August,
the higher rates on personal and corporate income (in
the case of the latter, an excess profits tax) included in
the Revenue Act of 1951 expired in January 1954, and
increases in selected excise taxes also adopted in 1951
were allowed to expire in April 1954.

A PR IL 1 9 6 4
1

GROSS N ATIONAL PRODUCT
S e a s o n a lly A d ju ste d A n n u a l R ate s
Bi l li o n s of d o l l a r s

400

300

250

200
19 47
S o u r c e of d a t a :
NOTE:

19 48

19 49

19 53

19 54

1955

1962

1963

1 9 64

U.S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e

S h a d e d a r e a r e p r e s e n t s r e c e s s i o n a n d b l a c k v e r t i c a l line r e p r e s e n t s mo nth of ta x cut

percent of disposable personal income at the
time the measure was passed. The 1954 leg­
islation was more comprehensive, affecting
both personal and corporate income taxes,
with a total reduction in Federal revenue of
$7.4 billion. Social security taxes were also
increased in 1954, however, so that the net
tax reduction totaled $6.1 billion, or 2.5 per­
cent of disposable income.
The 1964 tax reduction also applies to both

and classifications of taxable income. Under
the 1964 tax cut, the reduction in income tax
liabilities has been estimated at $11.5 billion,
or 2.5 percent of disposable income. The
average reduction in individual liabilities
amounts to 19 percent, and in corporate
liabilities to nearly 10 percent.
The underlying rationale of all the postwar
tax reductions has been the same, namely,

personal and corporate income taxes. The
nature of the 1964 tax cut is similar to that of
1948, however, in that actual reductions

that a reduction in taxes would stimulate ad­
ditional spending and investment in the pri­
vate sectors of the economy, and thereby
assure a higher rate of economic growth.

have been made in tax rates; in 1954 the most
important change in the tax structure took the
form of changes in exemptions, deductions,

Even with the similarity of purpose, however,
it is significant that each of the tax cuts oc­
curred at different phases of the business




3

E C O N O M IC R EVIEW
2

CONSUMER SECTOR
S e a s o n a lly A d ju ste d A n n u a l R ate s
B i l li o n s of d o l l a r s
450

400

350

300

D ISP O SA ILi

•ERSON IL INCOME
•9-

N SUMER SP ENDING
*
50

PI RSONAL SA VING
i ■ */Ul.KMl.l*
I .
19 47
S o u r c e of d a t a :

19 48

1949

0
19 53

19 54

1955

19 62

19 63

19 64

U.S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e

cycle, i.e., when economic variables were
not only at different levels but were in dif­
ferent relationship to each other. In the case
of the first two postwar tax cuts, differences
in timing contributed importantly to the actual
turn of events in the economy. Moreover,
such events were also influenced by con­
trasting patterns in both fiscal and monetary
policy.

GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
As Chart 1 shows, the 1954 tax cut oc­
curred at a favorable time, as the economy
was moving out of recession, and thus pro­
vided an additional stimulus to economic
activity. The circumstances surrounding the
4



1948 reduction were different. In 1948 GNP
continued to increase for only three quarters
following the tax cut and then declined in
the first quarter of 1949, reflecting a reces­
sion that set in late in 1948. In contrast, in
1954 a recession ended during the quarter
in which the tax cut was completed, with GNP
then advancing rapidly during the following
year. That advance subsequently carried
into 1957.
Chart 1 also shows the differences in eco­
nomic conditions prior to the 1948 and 1954
tax cuts. GNP increased substantially in the
four quarters preceding the tax cut in 1948,
whereas it declined moderately in the four
quarters prior to the 1954 reduction.

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

At the time of the 1964 tax cut economic
activity was in a strongly rising phase. For
1963 as a whole, GNP amounted to $585
billion, reaching the $600 billion mark in
the fourth quarter, the quarter in which the
largest increase of the year occurred. The
behavior of GNP in the four quarters prior
to the 1964 tax cut was thus more like the
1948 experience than the 1954 experience.

CONSUMER SECTOR
Chart 2 presents the major measures of con­
sumer behavior. During the four quarters
preceding the 1948 tax reduction, income
and consumer spending expanded rapidly.
In the two quarters immediately following the
1948 tax cut, disposable income increased
9 percent, while consumer spending increas­
ed only 3 percent. Two-thirds of the increase
in consumer income was thus channeled into
personal savings. In the third quarter after
the tax cut, the fourth quarter of 1948, dis­
posable income declined, signifying the re­
cession that began in November, seven months
after the tax cut.
In the four quarters preceding the 1954
tax cut, disposable income and consumer
spending each advanced 1 percent. In the
year following, consumer spending increased
nearly 10 percent, while disposable income
advanced 9 percent. Thus, in marked con­
trast to the 1948 experience, the increase in
consumer spending actually exceeded that
of disposable income, as the rate of personal
saving declined.
The behavior of consumers prior to the
1964 tax cut was similar to that preceding the
1948 tax reduction in that both disposable
income and consumer spending were in




strongly rising phases. Anticipations for the
quarters following the 1964 tax cut, however,
are similar to what actually happened in
1954-55, i.e., considerable advances in dis­
posable income and consumer spending. As a
result, many observers believe that the bulk
of any increase in GNP in 1964 will be
derived from consumer spending, largely
reflecting both the direct and indirect (sec­
ondary) effects of the increase in disposable
income due to the tax cut. In this view, a
noticeable uptilt in consumer spending may
take place in the second quarter, as the tax
cut begins to take hold.
The saving pattern of consumers will be a
major factor in short-run economic develop­
ments. Saving rose in the fourth quarter of
1963. This is similar to what happened in
1948, when saving rose slightly in the quarter
preceding the tax cut; at that time, however,
saving also rose in the quarter of and in the
one immediately after the tax cut—and by
significant amounts—thus largely nullifying
the effects of the tax cut. The 1954 situation
was different, with the tax cut not being offset
by increased consumer savings; in fact saving,
which was already in a downtrend, declined
for two more quarters, allowing the tax cut
to stimulate the economy. A major question at
this time is thus: just how will savings patterns
in 1964 respond to the tax cut?
Many observers hold the view that savings
will continue to rise through the second
quarter of 1964. These observers also hold
that savings will then decline steadily, per­
haps sustaining a particularly sharp fall in
the second quarter of 1965, because of the
impact of underwitholding of income taxes
in 1964, before returning to a "normal"
5

E C O N O M IC R E V IEW
3

BUSINESS SECTOR
S e a s o n a lly A d ju ste d A n n u a l R a te s
B i l li o n s of d o l l a r s

70

60

GROSS
DOMESTIC

SO

50

40

40

30

30

20

20

10

+ 20

+ 20

+10

+10

0
-10
-20
19 47
S o u r c e of d a t a :

19 48

1949

19 53

1 9 54

1955

19 62

19 63

U.S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e

level. Others do not visualize such a savings
pattern; rather, they feel it is more likely
that many individuals will spend the addi­
tional income made available by the tax
cut—in the early stages for nondurable goods
and services, and later for durables, after
downpayments are accumulated. This turn of
events would tend to provide more of an
immediate thrust from the consumer sector

rose more than 30 percent, with the bulk of
the increase occurring in the two quarters
immediately preceding the tax cut. As the
lower panel of the chart shows, the largest
share of the increase in investment was
accounted for by business inventories. Thus,
the reduction in taxes seems to have acceler­
ated, but not sustained, an already rapidly
expanding business sector. Two quarters

to the economy than is assumed by some
observers.

BUSINESS SECTOR

following the tax cut, private investment
declined, largely as a result of a slow-down
in inventory accumulation. Within a year
after the tax cut, private investment had re­

Chart 3 shows the major indicators of busi­
ness behavior. In the four quarters preceding
the 1948 tax reduction, private investment

ceded to the 1947 level.
In contrast, in the four quarters preceding
the completion of the 1954 tax cut, private

6




A PR IL 1 9 6 4

investment at first declined and then in­
creased only moderately. Inventory behavior
dominated the pace and direction of invest­
ment in that period as it did in 1948. In the
four quarters following completion of the
tax cut, private investment advanced roughly
35 percent.
As Chart 3 also shows, developments in the
business sector prior to the 1964 tax cut
suggest that more "balance'' exists in the
economy than was present in either 1948 or
1954. For example, the recent advance in
business spending has been based broadly
in construction and spending for heavy
goods; inventory accumulation has continued
to be moderate. The contrast between the
present and 1948 and 1954 is in fact quite
marked.
Of central importance in the near term is
whether balance in the business sector will be
maintained. In this connection, many ob­
servers anticipate a continuation of moderate
inventory building, with a slight rise con­
forming to a widely expected increase in
GNP. On the other hand, if consumers re­
spond more swiftly and more strongly to the
tax cut than these observers foresee, then
additional impetus could be provided for a
larger buildup in inventories—which might
trigger, or accompany, or follow an upsurge
in prices.
The improved outlook for plant and equip­
ment spending is of major significance in the
overall business sector. The 10 percent rise
for 1964 announced in the most recent
S.E.C.-Commerce Department survey should
have a buoyant effect on the economy. This
increase could in turn become even larger
if a general sequence such as the following




evolved fully: tax cut, increased disposable
income, greater consumer confidence and
spending, step-up in business inventory
building, price pressures and sharp upward
thrust in economic activity. It should be
remembered that business firms already have
received a stimulus to investment from liberal­
ized depreciation allowances and investment
tax credits; they are now to have larger after­
tax profits. The continuation of these factors
could result in a capital spending expansion
in excess of that currently envisaged, and
thus provide a strong contribution to an
expanding economy.

WHOLESALE PRICES AND
UNEMPLOYMENT
Chart 4 presents key factors in the eco­
nomic environments of 1948, 1954, and 1964.
In the 12 months preceding the 1948 tax
cut prices rose rapidly, with the wholesale
price index advancing 7 points from 80 to
87. This reflected in part the termination of
wartime price and wage controls. A tax
reduction at that time increased the likeli­
hood of further price increases and instability
associated with sharp price movements. In
marked contrast, in the year preceding the
1954 tax cut, the wholesale price index
scarcely moved.
In the current situation, the recent behavior
of wholesale prices is easy to describe—
virtual stability. In fact, we have now had six
years of virtual stability. The contrast to the
1948 situation is marked; the similarity with
1954 is equally marked. There is much con­
cern in many quarters, however, about the
current price situation. The behavior of some
of the price indexes, and impressions gained
7

E C O N O M IC R EV IEW
4

WHOLESALE PRICES and UNEMPLOYMENT
IN D E X 1957-59=100

WHOLESALE PRICES
A ll Co m odifies

Not S e a so r ally Adju
70
Perce nt of C i v i l i a n L a b o r Force
8

0
1947

19 48

1949

1 9 53

19 54

19 55

19 62

19 63

1 9 64

Sources of data: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of the Census

from business firms and the market place,
taken together, indicate some churning in
prices, but as yet no concrete statistical evi­
dence that price increases are in the ascend­
ancy. Price developments may be a crucial
aspect of economic activity in the near term.
With reference to resource utilization, the
level of unemployment in 1948 was not a
major economic problem. As the lower panel
of Chart 4 shows, the rate of unemployment
had declined in the last half of 1947 and then
rose to less than 4 .0 percent, a level that is
now accepted as full employment. It remained
at that level until early 1949, indicating the
relative absence of cyclical unemployment
at the time of the tax cut. On the other hand,
unemployment reached a peak of 6 percent
8



in the third quarter of 1954, at the completion
of the tax cut; as the economy began to ex­
pand, the rate fell, and by mid-1955 had
receded to a low of 4 percent, the same level
attained before the 1948 tax cut.
In 1964 the rate of unemployment is of
major concern to the economy. While the
unemployment rate of 6 percent at the time
of the 1954 tax cut can be explained as
largely cyclically induced, and the 4 percent
rate in 1948 was the "going rate," the
factors associated with the rate of unemploy­
ment in 1964 are more complex. A major
issue to be resolved in 1 9 6 4 —and in 1 9 6 5 —
is the ability of the tax cut to reduce unem­
ployment. It does not appear to be simply a
matter of just increasing economic activity

A PR IL 1 9 6 4
5

N ATIO NAL INCOME BUDGET
S e a s o n a lly A d ju ste d A n n u a l R a te s
B i l li o n s of d o l l a r s

50

RECEIPTS

40
30

PAYM ENTS
20
+15

+10
+ 5

0

n n

IIIIH

- 5

-10

-15
1 9 47
of d a t a :

19 48

1949

1953

1 9 54

1955

19 62

1963

19 64

U.S. D e p a r t m e n t o f C o m m e r c e

and thereby reducing unemployment. On
the contrary, the unemployed include a
large number of those who lack the educa­
tion, training, or skills necessary to qualify for
available employment opportunities. And this
condition may not be closely connected with
the level of aggregate demand. Over and
above such structural problems, however, it
is also difficult to estimate the combined
effects of rising economic activity, the crea­
tion of new jobs, labor force developments,
changes in productivity, and changes in
hours worked on unemployment. Many ob­
servers at this time do not envisage much
improvement in the unemployment situation,
at least in the near term. On the other hand,
other observers have supported the tax cut




in the belief that it would provide a lift to the
economy sufficient to reduce unemployment
significantly.
In addition to differences in economic con­
ditions, there were significant dissimilarities
in the conduct of fiscal and monetary policy
in 1948 and 1954, both before and following
the tax cuts.

NATIONAL INCOME BUDGET
Chart 5 shows the total receipts, total pay­
ments, and resulting deficit or surpluses of the
Federal government on a national income
budget basis. In the period preceding the
1948 tax cut, the Federal budget was in
substantial surplus. Thus, fiscal policy was
deflationary, in large part due to an effort to

9

E C O N O M IC R E V IEW

avoid further price pressures and reduce the
national debt. As the tax cut became effective
however, fiscal policy became less deflation­
ary as evidenced by the significantly smaller
surpluses during the rest of 1948. A deficit
was not recorded until the first quarter of
1949.
The situation in 1954 contrasted sharply to
1948. The Federal budget had been in deficit
for a considerable period of time preceding
the completion of the 1954 tax action. Follow­
ing the tax reduction and the improvement
in economic conditions, however, fiscal
policy first became less expansionary, and
then moderately restrictive, as indicated by
the reduction in the size of deficits and the
eventual surpluses beginning in the first
quarter of 1955.
Chart 5 also shows the current budget
situation. Recent quarters have been ones of
increasing receipts and payments, with gradu­
ally declining budget deficits beginning in the
first quarter of 1963, i.e., a progressively less
expansionary impact of the budget on the
economy. Present indications are that the
budget deficit widened somewhat during the
first quarter of 1964, and will widen by a very
considerable amount in the second quarter.
This turn of events will represent a major
fiscal stimulus to the economy. The budget
deficit should begin to decline in the third
quarter and to move toward balance, as
receipts respond to rising economic activity.
The turnabout in the Federal fiscal position
suggests that the budget stimulus to the econ­
omy will be receding after midyear 1964. It
also suggests that the economy may be sub­
jected to whipsawing by fiscal developments.
10




INTEREST RATES
Each of the periods under review was in­
fluenced by different sets of financial market
conditions and monetary operations. For
example, in 1947-48 the Federal Reserve
System was concerned with the behavior of
prices and the inflationary potential resulting
from large holdings of liquid assets by the
public. The situation was seriously complica­
ted by the fact that the System was unable to
combat these problems effectively because of
the continuation of the policy of supporting or
pegging the price of U. S. Treasury securities.
The Federal Reserve, like the Administration,
feared that a tax cut would merely add to the
already high liquidity of the economy and
result in increased inflation. Despite the
handicaps under which it was operating,
the System attempted to adopt a more res­
trictive monetary policy in 1948.
As Chart 6 shows, the discount rate was
increased twice in 1948. The Board of Gover­
nors also raised requirements for all member
banks on both demand and time deposits.
The upward movement of both the new cor­
porate bond issue rate and the 9 1 -day Treas­
ury bill rate prior to the tax cut reflected the
demands for credit associated with the accel­
erated pace of investment, as well as the
increased restrictiveness of monetary policy.
In 1954 the situation was different in that
the timing of the tax cut was such that mone­
tary policy was able to play a complementary
role and thereby help bring about the desired
expansion without the risk of too much stimu­
lation. The System's role was made easier of
course by the fact that the policy of pegged
rates had been abandoned in 1951. As Chart

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

INTEREST RATES

%

\/'*v

r.

1 9 47
S o u r c e of d a t a :

19 48

1 9 49

19 53

1 9 54

1955

19 62

r

1 9 63

1 9 64

B o a r d o f G o v e r n o r s of the F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s t e m

6 shows, the discount rate was lowered twice
in 1954, remaining at 1.50 percent until the
expansion was well underway in 1955. In
addition, reserve requirements were lowered
on both demand and time deposits, thus free­
ing about $1.5 billion in reserves.
Prior to the 1954 tax cut, both short- and
long-term interest rates declined, as indicated
by the chart. O nce the expansion was under­
way, however, interest rates rose in response
to increased demands for credit, and the dis­
count rate was increased as monetary policy
became less expansionary.
At the time of the 1964 tax cut, the behavior
of short-term interest rates reflects the general
stability of interest rates that has character­



ized recent years. The bill rate has moved in
a narrow range slightly above the discount
rate during the past 4 months. On balance,
it has shown little tendency to break out of
this range, even with the recent increase in
the British bank rate. The discount rate was
raised in 1963, the first change since 1960,
and the first increase during the current
expansion. The cost of short-term funds is
currently higher than at the time of the tax
cut in either 1948 or 1954. As indicated
earlier, the behavior of interest rates at the
time of the 1948 tax cut was influenced by
some attempted monetary restraint, however
mild it may have been, while the behavior in
1954 reflected mainly monetary expansion.
11

E C O N O M IC R E V IEW

Based on the corporate new issue rate, the
cost of long-term funds is also higher now
than in either 1948 or 1954. As Chart 6
shows, however, the rate is no higher now
than 2 years ago. In contrast, at the time of
the 1948 tax cut, the new issue rate was in a
rising phase (turning down after the peak);
and in 1954 after having moved down, the
rate was in a level phase (turning up with
economic activity).

MONETARY POLICY
In evaluating the role of monetary policy
at the time of previous tax cuts, it may be
suggested that monetary policy complemen­
ted the tax reduction in stimulating the econ­
omy in 1954; on the other hand, monetary
policy was required to work at cross purposes
in 1948, although its influence may have
been limited.
The 1948 and 1954 experiences indicate that
a tax reduction by itself may not be enough
to sustain economic expansion unless prop­
erly timed in relation to existing economic
circumstances. These would include the con­
duct of monetary policy, which in turn also
reflects the pace and direction of economic
activity at the time of a tax cut. Timing and
circumstances, therefore, became particu­
larly crucial elements in the influence of a
tax cut on the economy. In the case of 1954,
the economy was operating below capacity,
with sufficient slack to permit a substantial
increase in aggregate demand without fear
of overstimulation. In contrast, in the latter
part of 1947 and early 1948, strong business
expansion was already underway, and the
economy was operating near full capacity;
this was evidenced by rising prices and
12



relative absence of unemployment. In that
case, tax reduction subjected the economy
to a risk of overstimulation. Sentiment of this
type may have prompted the President to
veto the tax cut twice before it was finally
passed.
In the current situation, monetary policy is
a moderately expansionary factor in the
economy. In fact, regardless of the measure
used—two widely used measures are shown
on Chart 7 —monetary policy has been ex­
pansionary during the past three years. In
short, the Federal Reserve System has sup­
plied large amounts of financial resources in
order to help support the business expansion.
It is noteworthy that the discount rate action
in mid-1963 appears to have had little effect
on the behavior of either of the measures
shown on the chart.
The rapid growth in the money supply plus
time deposits in the four quarters prior to the
1964 tax cut surpassed by a very large margin
that which occurred in similar time periods
prior to the two earlier tax cuts. The amount
of liquidity in the economy at the time of
the 1964 tax cut is relatively high—as illus­
trated by the relation of liquid assets to GNP—
but not nearly as high as in 1948, which
reflected the after-effects of the high liquidity
built up during World War II, or as in 1954,
which was at the bottom of a recession when
liquidity should be very high. Liquid assets
have been increasing faster than GNP since
late 1961, a development that is quite
atypical for a period of business expansion.
Moreover, the liquid asset-GNP ratio is
currently at the highest level since 1958.
The 1964 tax cut has occurred at a time
when monetary policy is moderately ex-

A PR IL 1 9 6 4
7

MONETARY INDICATORS
S e a s o n a lly A d ju ste d
B i l li o n s of d o l l a r s
280
270
260
250
240
230

150

M o n t h ly
_a____

140
RATIO
120
110

1947
of d a t a :

19 48

19 49

19 53

19 54

1955

19 62

1963

19 64

B o a r d of G o v e r n o r s o f the F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s t e m

pansionary. In contrast, the 1948 tax cut took
place when the authorities had moved to­
ward restraint; the 1954 tax cut was accom­
panied by policy that remained expansionary
until recovery was well under way.

U. S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
An additional factor in the current eco­
nomic environment that did not pose a
challenge in either 1948 or 1954 is high­
lighted in Chart 8. In 1948, our balance of
payments accounts were still in surplus,
reflecting mainly the large export balance of
the immediate postwar years. In 1954, al­
though there was a deficit in the balance of
payments, it was not considered a problem
situation; this was the period of dollar




shortage and planned deficits. In 1964, the
U. S. has a balance of payments problem—
one which has been of serious proportions
since 1958. This situation has had important
implications for both monetary and fiscal
policy, and should be reckoned with in any
appraisal of the tax cut. There are alternative
ways the tax cut can affect the balance of
payments. For example, one logical sequence
is: rising business activity, higher imports,
deterioration in the trade balance, and an
adverse influence in the payments balance.
There is also a logical sequence in the follow­
ing: improved incentives from better returns,
additional domestic investment, less capital
outflow, and a favorable influence on the
payments balance.
13

E C O N O M IC R E V IEW
8

U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
Bi l li o n s of d o l l a r s
+ 5 ------------------

-5
’4 7
S o u r c e of d a t a :

’4 8

'4 9

’5 0

'51

’52

’53

’5 4

’55

'5 6

'5 7

’5 8

’59

'6 0

'61

’6 2

’6 3

’6 4

U.S. D e p a r t m e n t of C o m m e r c e

NOTE: 1 963 includes net receipts from nonmarketable securities.

The 1964 tax cut has occurred at a time
when the economy is in a strongly rising
phase. Most measures of business activity

The 1964 tax cut has received broad sup­
port from business, banking, labor, and
economists. The rationale of the tax cut is
that, even with considerable expansion,
economic activity is not as high as it should

have been chalking up new records, week
after week or month after month, with re­

be, and a gap exists between actual and
potential activity. That is to say, our rate of

assuring regularity. Despite the momentum
of business activity, the economic situation
appears to have been reasonably well bal­

growth has been insufficient to utilize to an
adequate extent our human and physical
resources, or to absorb additional ones.
To bring about a more favorable situation,
it is necessary to improve incentives to spend
and invest—and this can be done best by
reducing the high tax rates that may have

CONCLUSION

anced. If there is imbalance, it may be in the
monetary area, where extended monetary
expansion has raised some questions con­
cerning the possibility of financial excesses
and deterioration in the quality of credit.
14




been dampening economic incentive.

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

The tax cut was implemented in full
recognition of the risks involved in such a
course of action during a period of economic
expansion, and when the Federal budget is
already in deficit. Perhaps for that reason,
the 1964 tax cut has been described as the
"greatest fiscal experiment". However, this
still leaves a number of questions unanswered.
Has the tax cut been timed properly? Will
unemployment decline, and if so, how fast
and how much? Will prices remain stable or
will there be price inflation, and if so, how
fast and how much? Will we face a situation
like 1948? Or will the economy respond as
in 1954? What problems will be created for
monetary policy and for the balance of
payments?
These questions will remain unresolved
until the events of the next few months actu­
ally unfold. If the forecasts of the Administra­
tion and other observers materialize, the
overall pattern for 1964 and into 1965 would
seem to be that of a gradual and sustainable
buildup in the economy, in other words, con­
tinued balance and continued expansion, but




at a higher level.
Another pattern could emerge. The econ­
omy could become "overheated" or "overstimulated" by the tax cut, i.e., too rapid an
acceleration of rates of spending and investing
could occur. This could come from the com­
bination of large-scale fiscal stimulus (pri­
marily in the timing), considerable liquidity
in the economy, and a pervasive optimism in
response to the tax cut and in anticipation
of an expected upsurge in economic ac­
tivity. Such a turn of events could create
difficulties for the economy. For example, at
prevailing levels of output, a substantial rise
in aggregate demand may induce speculative
activity or temporary shortages, and in turn
price pressures. Developments associated
with conditions of this type could nullify
gains expected from the tax cut. More sig­
nificantly, they could reintroduce a cyclical
instability that was characteristic of the 1950s.
If this were to occur it would complicate the
role of public policy, particularly monetary
policy in both its domestic and international
considerations.

15

THOROUGHBREDS
KENTUCKY
Note: Photo by Skeets Meadors, courtesy of Keeneland Association

HIS IS the time of year when attention is
focused on the nation's best three-yearold Thoroughbred race horses as they pre­
pare for the annual running of the Kentucky
Derby on the first Saturday in May. In the state
of Kentucky, however, Thoroughbreds are
of year-round interest. Kentucky ranks as the
nation's largest producer of Thoroughbred
race horses and is the center of the industry.
This article is primarily concerned with the
Thoroughbred race horse industry in Ken­
tucky. Attention is focused on size, location,
and types of farms in the Kentucky Thorough­

persons with an annual payroll of $375
million.2

bred farm complex.1
For the United States and Canada, capital
investment in race tracks, farms, and stock of
the Thoroughbred industry is estimated at
$ 1 .7 billion; employment totals about 75,000

in the Thoroughbred breeding industry.
Approximately one-fourth of the U. S. and

T

1 A definition of Thoroughbred as well as other relevant
terms are found in the glossary at the end of this
article.

16




The Thoroughbred race horse industry is
comprised of two parts—racing and breeding.
A total investment of $1.2 billion in the
racing portion is accounted for largely by
race tracks whose value is estimated at $1.0
billion. The remainder represents horses in
training, as shown in Table I. The aggregate
investment in breeding amounts to roughly
$500 million, and is equally divided between
breeding farms and breeding stock.
Kentucky is by far the most important state

2 Estimated by the Thoroughbred Racing Association.
This figure includes people employed at Thoroughbred
race tracks and on breeding farms as well as those
employed in related enterprises such as printing,
publishing, transportation, and feed; seasonal help
hired in local areas is not included.

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

Canadian Thoroughbred foal crop is pro­
duced in Kentucky, exceeding by a sub­
stantial margin that produced in secondranked California, as shown in the accom­
panying map. Although investment figures
are not available for the state, it has been
estimated that the total investment in Ken­
tucky's breeding farms and breeding stock
is approximately $ 1 2 5 million, or one-fourth
of total investment in the breeding portion of
the Thoroughbred industry in the U. S. and
Canada.
In contrast to the prominent position in the
breeding of Thoroughbred horses, only a
minor portion of Thoroughbred racing takes
place in Kentucky. The state's five race tracks
account for only 3 percent of the total attend­
ance and pari-mutuel handle at U. S. tracks.
In comparison, New York ranks first in terms
of racing, with about one-fifth of U. S. attend­
ance and mutuel handle.

KENTUCKY’S THOROUGHBRED
COMPLEX
Most of the Thoroughbred horse farms in
Kentucky are located in the "inner bluegrass
area" which encompasses Bourbon, Fayette,
and Woodford counties. Thoroughbred pro­
duction is particularly heavy in the triangle
framed by the cities of Versailles, Lexington,
and Paris. The local climate, soils, and topo­
graphy played a significant part in the devel­
opment of the industry in this region. Soils in
particular are thought to be an important
influence in the early growth of the industry;
underlying limestone formations result in a
high level of soil phosphates and calcium
that contribute to the good physical quality of
horses raised in the area.




The Kentucky Thoroughbred breeding in­
dustry is comprised of approximately 250
farms, of which some 200 are located in the
three-county area. The size of farms ranges
from less than 5 acres to more than 3 ,0 0 0
acres. Management of the farms is also diver­
sified—some are owner-operated while others
are operated by managers for absentee
owners.
As with many industries, the growth and
continuance of the breeding industry in
central Kentucky have been helped by the
advantages and economies that result from
concentration in a single area. For example,
some of the best Thoroughbred stallions are
located in the Lexington horse farm complex.
The nation's leading sire in 1963 in terms of
money won by offspring was Bold Ruler, a
Kentucky-based horse. In addition, eight
other Kentucky stallions, Nasrullah, Johns
Joy, Spy Song, Double Jay, Royal Charger,
Swaps, My Babu, and Greek Song were also
Table I

Investment in the Thoroughbred Industry
United States and C a n a d a
Estimated Value in Millions of Dollars
1963
Racing
36.000 horses in training................ $
101 r a c e t r a c k s ..........................
Breeding
2.000
3.000
1 8,000
1 1,000
14.000

breeding f a r m s ................
s t a ll io n s ..........................
broodm ares.......................
y e a rlin g s ..........................
f o a l s .............................

200
1,000
250
50
127
55
28

Total In v e stm e n t.......................$1,710
Sources: Thoroughbred Racing Association and
Cromwell Bloodstock Agency

17

E C O N O M IC R EV IEW

THOROUGHBRED FOAL REGISTRATIONS
Selected States and Canada
Percent of Total Crop

Source o f data: The Blood-H orse

among the nation's top ten sires for 1963
according to data compiled by Triangle
Publications. The availability of such outstanting stallions obviously is an advantage
to breeders in the area.
The concentration of horse farms in this
region also has resulted in the establishment
of specialized businesses to serve the industry.
For example, veterinarians who specialize in
the diseases and injuries of the race horse
have established practices in the region,
as well as clinics that provide medical treat­
ment to horses. Local vanning companies
offer virtually any type of transportation for
horses, while specialized insurance com­
panies protect owners of highly valued

18




horses against loss. The local and regional
feed companies and feed manufacturers
cater to the horse industry. Other enterprises
set up in connection with the horse farms
include printing and publishing of Thorough­
bred magazines, auction sales, blacksmithing,
fencing, and specialized barn construction
firms. Another feature of area concentration
has been development of a labor force, from
managers to grooms, skilled in handling
Thoroughbreds.

HORSES TO RACE OR TO SELL
There are two types of breeding farms; one
type raises Thoroughbreds to sell while the
other raises stock to race for the farm's

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

racing stable. On farms where horses are
raised to sell, the intensity of the enterprise
varies from farms that concentrate mainly on
horses to those where one or two broodmares
are kept as a sideline to a general farm
operation.
Most market breeders attempt to sell their
animals at one of two Keeneland yearling
sales. These two sales account for more than
half of all the yearlings sold at auction each
year in the U. S. and Canada and almost 40
percent of the entire yearling crop raised in
Kentucky. In 1963, for example, of the 2,267
yearlings sold (15 percent of the entire
yearling crop), more than one-half— 1 ,178—
were sold at Keeneland. At the Keeneland
summer sale in luly, a limited number of
yearlings (usually 2 7 5 to 300) are sold.
Yearlings are selected for this sale primarily
on the basis of pedigrees but conformation is
also considered. In 1963 yearlings marketed
at the July sale averaged $14,191 per head,
substantially higher than all other sales, as
shown in Table III. The Keeneland fall sale
in September is open to all yearlings, and
(as also shown in Table III) more yearlings
are sold at this auction than at any other sale.
The higher prices paid for these yearlings
reflect the high quality of Kentucky-bred
horses. Typically, a measure of quality is the
number of stakes races won by a Thorough­
bred. Stakes races offer the most money and
prestige to winners, and consequently attract
the best horses. In 1963 Kentucky-bred
horses won 54 percent of all stakes races
although the state produces only 22 percent

yearlings at the selective Keeneland summer
sale or otherwise at the Keeneland fall sale.
To obtain a high price for his crop the market
breeder must offer a sound, sleek yearling
with fashionable bloodlines or parentage.
What is fashionable depends largely on
success in racing as measured by earnings;
a fashionable sire's popularity, for example,
may be due to high winnings of his offspring.
Bloodlines offered by a particular market
breeder are largely determined by his ability
to purchase popular parentage. Popular sires
have the most expensive stud fees, ranging
up to $12,500. Another limitation on the
individual market breeder's selection of
bloodlines may be his inability to forecast
what will be popular or fashionable in the
future.
The owner who raises horses to race as part
of an integrated farm operation places a
different emphasis on the environment in
which his horses are raised. In contrast to
the market breeder who prepares for the

of the foal crop.
As would be expected, most Kentucky
market breeders attempt to market their

The popularity of Thoroughbred horse
racing, measured by attendance at races and
the volume of pari-mutuel betting, has re­




yearling sales, the racing breeder aims
directly for the race track; he can raise a
tougher yearling since the animal does not
have to be sleek and fat at sale time. In
addition, the racing breeder controls the
breaking, training, conditioning, and racing
phases of his horses' development. Con­
versely, the market breeder has no control
over racing conditions of horses he breeds
although his reputation is built on the success
or failure of his animals.

GROWTH IN RACING

19

E C O N O M IC R EV IEW

corded substantial growth in recent years, as
shown in Table II. Attendance at Thorough­
bred race tracks reached a record 35.5
million in 1963, 10 percent above 1962 and
27 percent higher than in 1954. Pari-mutuel
handle registered a 7 percent year-to-year
gain and advanced 35 percent from the
1954 level. The number of racing days (also
shown in Table II) and consequently the
Table II

Thoroughbred Race Track Statistics
United States
1963
35.5
Attendance (mil.)
Pari-mutuel
$ 2.8
handle (bil.) .
Racing days . . . 4,060

% Change from
1962
1954
+ 10%

+ 27%

+
+

+ 35
+ 46

7
8

Source: National Association of State Racing Commissioners

Table III

M a jo r Yearling Sales
Number
Sold
in
1963
Keeneland summer
(Kentucky) . .
Saratoga
(New York) . .
Del M ar
(California) . .
Keeneland fall
(Kentucky) . .
Maryland . . .
Canada . . . .
O th e rs.............

Average Price
Paid
% Change
from
1962
1963

.

275

$14,191

+

9%

.

254

12,815

+

4

.

120

8,286

+

9

.
.

903
184
113
418

3,613
2,298
1,955
2,563

+ 10
— 4
— 10
— 20

Total . . . 2,267

$ 5,790

Sources: The Blood-Horse and Keeneland Association

20



+

4

number of races run also advanced sub­
stantially. Prices paid for Thoroughbred year­
lings have advanced sharply, despite large
gains in the number sold, reflecting the
growth in racing and subsequent increase in
the demand for race horses (see Chart).

RECORD SALES VOLUME
In 1963 auction sales of yearlings totaled
a record $13.1 million, up 5 percent from a
year earlier. Average price paid advanced to
$5 ,7 9 0 per head, second only to 1946 when
only one-half as many yearlings were sold.
Yearling sales in Kentucky grossed $7.2
million in 1963, compared with $6.2 million
a year earlier. As previously mentioned,
more than half of the yearlings sold by auction
are consigned to the Keeneland summer and
fall sales. These two sales, along with the
Del Mar (California) sale held in August,
recorded sharp year-to-year gains in average
prices paid, as shown in Table III.
The growth in the Thoroughbred industry
and the increased demand for yearlings are
further reflected in the higher prices paid for
larger numbers of breeding stock. In 1963,
842 animals, mainly broodmares, were sold
at public auction, and the average price
received was $4,616; ten years earlier, 398
horses were sold for an average price of
$3,431.

GEOGRAPHIC DIVERSIFICATION
The Thoroughbred breeding industry has
become less concentrated geographically.
Although the number of foals born in Ken­
tucky each year has continued to increase,
the state's proportion of the total foal crop has

A PR IL 1 9 6 4

A v e r a g e Pric e

N u m b e r Sold

6000

4000

2 000

1000

Source o f data: The Blood-Horse

declined. From 1957 to 1962, the Kentucky
crop increased from 3,061 to 3 ,1 7 3 foals, but
dropped from 29 percent to 22 percent of the
total (see Table IV). The largest gains by
Table IV

Foal C rop and Stakes W inners
Selected States and C a n a d a
Percent of Total
Foal Crop
1957 1962
Kentucky . . . . 2 9 %
California . . . 14
Canada . . . .
8
Virginia . . . .
6
Illin o is.............
3
Florida.............
2
Texas .............
3
Maryland . . . 5
Source: The Blood-Horse




22%
15
8
6
5
4
4
4

Stakes Winners
1958 1963
58%
15
7
3
0
1
2
4

54%
18
6
5
1
3
1
3

other states producing Thoroughbred foals
were 2-point advances recorded in Illinois
and Florida which moved to 5 percent and 4
percent, respectively, of the total crop.
The proportion of stakes winners accounted
for by Kentucky-bred horses has also declined
(see Table IV). Kentucky horses won 58 per­
cent of the stakes races in 1958 but only 54
percent in 1963. The largest gains in breeding
stakes winners during the period were made
by California and Virginia. In 1963 Californiabred horses won 18 percent of the elite
stakes races while the figure for Virginia
was 5 percent (see Table IV).
Despite the state's smaller share of the
industry, the outlook for Thoroughbreds in
Kentucky appears bright. Seemingly, the
decline in Kentucky's share has resulted from
faster growth in other areas—not an outflow
21

E C O N O M IC R EV IEW

of Kentucky breeders. Growth in areas such
as Florida and California reflects expanding
population and racing. In addition, states
such as Illinois, Florida, California, and Mary­
land encourage growth in the breeding indus­

try by holding stakes races restricted to
horses bred in the state. Despite gains in
other areas, however, Kentucky remains by
far the nation's leading producer of Thorough­
bred foals and stakes winners.

G LO SSARY

The term bloodlines is used to describe a direct
sequence of ancestors in a pedigree.
A broodmare is a female horse kept for breeding
purposes.
A colt is a young male horse before reaching an
arbitrarily designated age of maturity.
Conformation describes the outline or form of a
horse and how he is constructed.
Fashion describes ancestry or bloodlines currently
in demand because of success in winning races.
For example, a stallion or broodmare may be
fashionable because of a successful racing career,
because offspring have won consistently, or both.
A filly is a young female horse usually less than
four years old.
Foals are young horses from the time they are
born until they are one year old.
Pari-mutuel handle is the sum of all money bet on
a race or may be the entire amount of money bet
over a period of time.
A pedigree is a record of the ancestry of a horse,
while registration papers are official certification
of an animal’s parentage.

22




Sire is the male parent or father. Technically,
use may be limited to a stallion having at least
one colt who has won a race.
A stakes race is a sporting event in which a prize
(trophy, money, or both) is put up for the winner.
Stallions are male horses kept for breeding pur­
poses.
A studhorse is a male horse kept for breeding,
especially for public use for a fee.
Thoroughbreds are a light, speedy breed of
horse used chiefly for racing. The breed originated
from crosses between English mares and Arabian
stallions imported into England at the end of the
17th century. All Thoroughbreds must be able to
trace their ancestry to three stallions, Matchem
(1758), Herod (1758), and Eclipse (1764),
descended from the imported Arabian stallions.
A yearling is a race horse between his first and
second birthday. Since a race horse is one year
older on January 1 of each year, actual age of a
yearling can range from a few days to almost two
years depending on when the foal was born.




Additional copies of the E C O N O M IC

REVIEW

m ay be obtained from the Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Cleveland,
O hio 4 4 1 0 1 . Permission is granted to reproduce
any material in this publication.




F o u r t h F e d e r a l R e s e r v e D i s t r i c t -----