View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 35, No. 1

CONOMIC REVIEW
1999 Quarter 1
The Effects of Vertical Integration
on Competing Input Suppliers

2

by R. Preston McAfee

Banking Consolidation and
Correspondent Banking
by W illiam P. Osterberg and James B. Thomson

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF CLEVELAND

9

Vol. 35, No. 1
http://clevelandfed.org/research/review/
Economic Review 1999 Q1

1999 Quarter 1
The Effects of Vertical Integration
on Competing Input Suppliers

2

by R. Preston McAfee

Banking Consolidation and
Correspondent Banking
by William P. Osterberg and James B. Thomson

9

1

ECONOMIC REVIEW
1999 Quarter 1
Vol. 35, No. 1

The Effects of Vertical Integration
on Competing Input Suppliers

2

by R. Preston McAfee
When a downstream firm buys an input supplier, it can reduce its costs of
using that input. Other input suppliers typically respond by pricing more
aggressively, given the demand reduction, which tends to lower input supply costs to other firms. Thus, a vertical merger may lower rivals’ costs
instead of raising them.

Banking Consolidation and
Correspondent Banking

9

by William P. Osterberg and James B. Thomson
Banking consolidation, spurred on by interstate branching deregulation, is
changing the competitive structure of banking markets. Policymakers and
regulators have focused on the implications of the ongoing consolidation
for customers of banks in retail and wholesale markets. Little attention,
however, has been paid to the impact of interstate consolidation on correspondent banking markets—those markets where banks buy and sell
inputs used to produce banking services. By studying the era of intrastate
branching deregulation, the authors provide some insights on the implications of interstate branching for correspondent banking.

Economic Review is published
quarterly by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland. To receive copies
or to be placed on the mailing list,
e-mail your request to
maryanne.kostal@clev.frb.org
or fax it to 216-579-3050.
Economic Review is also
available electronically through
the Cleveland Fed’s site on the
World Wide Web:
http://www.clev.frb.org/research.

Editors: Michele Lachman
Lisa McKenna
Deborah Zorska
Design: Michael Galka
Typography: Liz Hanna

Opinions stated in Economic
Review are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.

Material may be reprinted if the
source is credited. Please send
copies of reprinted material to
the editors.

ISSN 0013-0281

2

The Effects of Vertical
Integration on Competing
Input Suppliers
by R. Preston McAfee

Introduction
Vertical integration is a booming phenomenon
in many U.S. industries. Massive consolidation
of the defense industry has left only three or
four developers producing many of the components used in military platforms.1 Banking also
is consolidating at a rapid pace, with integration of related financial services (insurance,
credit cards) and input services (check clearing,
payments, electronic funds transfer) into parent
companies. Telecommunications firms’ mergers
combine cable, wireless, local wireline, and
long-distance services. Simultaneously, firms in
other industries are concentrating on their core
competencies and selling off related lines of
business. Automobile manufacturers, for example, are becoming more reliant on independent
or semi-independent parts suppliers.
What are the effects of vertical integration?
The large body of literature on this subject
might reasonably be described as disjointed. It
has focused mostly on providing a rationale for
opposing vertical mergers on antitrust grounds.
When a firm buys an upstream input supplier
that also supplies its downstream competitor,
the vertically integrated firm can raise the price
of the input to its competitor, thereby obtaining

R. Preston McAfee is a professor
of economics at the University
of Texas at Austin. He thanks
Joseph G. Haubrich and James
B. Thomson for their beneficial
comments.

an advantage in the downstream market. This is
the standard “raising-rivals’-cost” argument pioneered by Salop and Scheffman (1987).2 In
extreme cases, the vertically integrated firm
might refuse to sell to competitors and, if the
input supplier’s product was necessary for production, might be able to foreclose its competitors from the downstream market.
This paper examines an opposing effect of
the raising-rivals’-cost theory. In particular, the
analysis focuses on other input suppliers’ reaction to vertical integration. Its main insight is
that vertical integration, by providing easier
access to one input, reduces demand for the
other inputs and tends to lower their prices.
This, in turn, encourages the vertically integrated firm to sell its input at a lower price as
well, which may reduce the costs of all inputs.
Thus, accounting for the reaction of substitute
input suppliers may reverse the traditional conclusions of the raising-rivals’-cost theory.
■ 1 An item like an aircraft or a submarine is a platform, which holds
a variety of weapons systems, detection systems like radar or sonar, and
other systems like landing gear, engines, and so on.
■ 2 Ordover, Saloner, and Salop (1990) is the best-known treatment.
Salinger (1988) and Hart and Tirole (1990) also provide related, and more
general, analyses.

3

F I G U R E

1

Competition Layout
Upstream:

Firm X

Firm Y

Firm 1

Firm 2

Downstream:

Final Consumers

The situation is less clear when firms 1 and 2
compete imperfectly in the downstream market.
There are two direct effects of the merger: First,
the price of x to the combined entity falls, tending to reduce the price of y. Second, the price of
x to firm 2 rises, tending to increase the price
of y. Either effect can dominate, and the price of
y may rise or fall, depending on the extent of
substitution between the outputs of firms 1 and
2 and the substitutability of the two inputs.
Let xi , yi denote the demand for the two
inputs by firm 1. I assume constant returns to
scale. The timing is that the input sellers simultaneously set input prices px , py , respectively.
Then firms 1 and 2 choose their input quantities and output prices.

II. Raising
Rivals’ Costs
The standard raising-rivals’-costs theory is best

I. Structure of
the Model
The model’s general form is set out in figure 1.
Two upstream suppliers, X and Y, sell to two
downstream firms, which in turn sell to the
final consumers. I will focus on the effects of
the vertical integration that occurs when firm 1
purchases firm X. Suppose that the products of
the upstream firms are imperfect substitutes
and that, having purchased firm X, firm 1 will
continue to use some of the inputs supplied by
Y. Then vertical integration will affect firmY’s
pricing decision.3
In this paper, I set aside the incentive to
raise rivals’ costs by assuming that firms 1 and 2
do not compete in the output market. I focus
instead on vertical integration’s effects on the
alternative input supplier and find that vertical
integration tends to lower the prices of both
inputs to firm 2. The intuition is straightforward: The purchase of firm X by firm 1 lowers
the price of input x to firm 1, reducing the
demand for y by firm 1. In response to this
reduction in demand, firm Y lowers the price of
y to both firms. The response of the integrated
firm is to lower the price of x to firm 2.

■ 3 It might seem that services such as check clearing are homogeneous. However, distinct banks have an advantage in being able to clear
their own checks quickly, and large banks may have a greater netting out of
checks. In addition, distinct suppliers of check clearing may have distinct
regional advantages.

explained by eliminating firm Y. In this case,
X is a monopoly supplier of the input. If x is
necessary for production, the merged firm has
the ability to foreclose firm 2 from production.
Even if x is valuable but not strictly necessary
for production, the merged firm can raise the
cost of x to firm 2, thereby increasing firm 2’s
overall costs.
Even in this simple scenario, the price that
firm 2 is charged for x can fall. Suppose 1 and 2
barely compete in the final output market.
Moreover, suppose firm 1 has significantly more
inelastic demand for x, so that the monopoly
price for firm 1 exceeds the monopoly price for
firm 2. Prior to vertical integration, the price of x
will lie between the two monopoly prices. After
the merger, the price of x will fall to approximately the monopoly price for firm 2. Moreover,
insofar as firms 1 and 2 do compete, the monopoly price for firm 2 will fall, since firm 1’s
lower marginal cost will make it a more aggressive competitor after the merger.
The standard analysis focuses on the case
where X and Y are Cournot competitors with
constant marginal costs. In this case, if the
merged firm uses its own inputs and withholds
output from firm 2, firm 2 is facing a monopoly
and will generally experience higher input
prices. This is true even when firm Y is actually
several firms that are in Cournot competition,
although the more firms there are in the input
supply market, the smaller is the effect.
The results concerning Cournot input supply
generalize to increasing marginal costs. With
increasing marginal costs, firm 1 may wish
either to sell to or buy from firm Y, even after

4

the merger with firm X. However, consider the
symmetric case, in which X looks like Y and 1
looks like 2. After the merger, firm 1 does not
need to buy from firm Y, and thus can increase
the costs to firm 2 by refusing to sell.
This literature has played an important role
by showing that vertical mergers could potentially foreclose competition downstream. However, the literature has focused primarily on
mergers’ bad effects on rivals, without examining their potential for good effects.

III. Lowering
Rivals’ Costs
I start the analysis using the demand for inputs
as primitives. To facilitate the analysis, I distinguish between the prices firm X charges to
firms 1 and 2. With independent downstream
demands, the effect of the merger of X with 1 is
to change the input price of x to firm 1. Firm X
earns profits on its sale to firm 2 of
(1)

π = (px2 – cx )x 2(px2, py ).

I divide firm Y’s profits into the components
earned on firm 1 and firm 2:
(2)

ψ 1 = (py – cy )y 1(px1, py ),
ψ 2 = (py – cy )y 2(px2, py ).

Using numerical subscripts to denote partial
derivatives, profit maximization yields
(3)

π 1 = ψ 12 + ψ 22 = 0.

The direct effect of the merger of X and 1 on
the input supply prices is to lower p x1 from its
monopoly level to marginal cost cx . Because
of the assumed independence of demands for
the outputs of 1 and 2, the merged entity will
choose the price of p x2 to maximize π , and firm
Y will maximize the sum of ψ 1 and ψ 2.
I am assuming that firm Y cannot price discriminate. If both input suppliers are able to do
so, nothing changes in the prices charged to
firm 2. If firm Y can price discriminate but firm
X cannot, then the merger permits firm X to
price discriminate, since the only relevant price
is that charged to 2. As a consequence, p x2 will
increase if firm 2’s demand for x is less elastic
than firm 1’s. This will have effects on the price
of y, usually of the same direction.
Differentiating the first-order conditions,
one obtains

(4)

π 11
2
ψ 21

12

π 12
dpx2
0
0
+ 1 dpx1 =
1
2
ψ 22 + ψ 22 dpy
ψ 21
0 .

41 2 1 2

3

This gives

(5)

1 2
dpx2
dpy

=

1
∆

π 12ψ 211
1.
1 dpx
–π 11ψ 21

1

2

Stability implies that
(6)

1 + ψ 2 ) – π ψ 2 > 0.
∆ = π 11(ψ 22
22
12 21

The terms π 12 and ψ 21 are similar in that they
represent the effect of a competitor’s price increase on the marginal profitability of a price
increase for the firm. If the input pricing game
is one of strategic complements, then these
terms are positive. Alternatively (and equivalently), if an increase in the price of one input
makes the demand for the other input less elastic, these cross-partials will be positive.
It can be shown that if the downstream production functions have constant elasticity of
substitution with constant returns to scale, and
demand is constant up to a choke price (which
is tantamount to assuming that the downstream
quantity is exogenous), then the cross-partials
are positive. This special case will be explored
in the following numerical simulation.
When these input profit cross-partials are
positive, then
(7)

dpx2
dpx1

> 0,

dpy
> 0.
dpx1

Thus, the merger, which lowers the price of
x to firm 1 by eliminating firm X ’s marginalization, lowers both of the input prices to firm 2 as
well as the price of y to firm 1.
This result is intuitive. The reduction in the
price of x to firm 1 makes that firm’s demand
for y more elastic, since it now has a less expensive substitute. This causes Y to lower the
price of y.4 The lower price of y induces a reaction from the combined firm—it lowers the
price of x.

■ 4 This is where the assumption that firm Y cannot price discriminate is critical. If Y could price discriminate, the reduction in the price of x
to firm 1 would reduce the price of y to firm 1 but not to firm 2.

5

IV. Numerical
Example

With Vertical
Integration

A numerical example illustrates and quantifies

When firms 1 and X merge, firm 1 can purchase x at price c. In this case, the combined
entity will price x to maximize6

the effects described in the theory. Suppose
that the two downstream firms can sell one unit
each at a price high enough so that each firm
will always buy inputs sufficient to produce
one unit. The downstream firms have a constant elasticity-of-substitution production technology with constant returns to scale and parameter αε [½,1]5:

(13)

π = (px – c)x2

1

= (px – c)

1

q = (x α + y α )α .

(8)

1
α

α
py1 – α
α

α

px1 – α + py1 – α

2

.

As before, this gives the first-order condition
Let the marginal production costs of the
upstream firms be c.

(14) 0 = (1 – α)py1 – α – αpx1 – α + cpx1 – α .

Without Vertical
Integration

Firm Y faces a more complicated problem
because it will generally sell to both firms 1 and
2, and these two firms generally face distinct input prices for x. Firm Y chooses py to maximize

If there is no vertical integration, the downstream firms minimize px x + py y s.t. q = 1.
This gives

(9) x =

y=

1
1

α
py1 – α
α
px1 – α

α
py1 – α

+

α
px1 – α
α
px1 – α

α
py1 – α

+

1
α

2

1
α

2

1

.

(10) π = (px – c)x.
Routine calculations yield
α

2α –1

(11) 0 = (1 – α)py1 – α – αpx1 – α + cpx1 – α .
For α > ½ and px > c, this equation characterizes a maximum. A symmetric solution to the
first-order conditions yields
(12) px = py = 2αc– 1.
As α →1, the goods become perfect substitutes, and prices fall to marginal costs.

2α –1

α

(15) ψ = (py – c)(y1 + y2 ) = (py – c)

1

,

Firm X chooses px to maximize

α

α

1
α

α
c1 – α
α

c1 – α

α

+

py1 – α

α
px1 – α
α
px1 – α

+

α
py1 – α

2

+

1
α

2

.

While closed forms for the first-order conditions exist (and are sufficient to characterize
equilibrium in the range posited), it is not possible to solve the first-order conditions for the
equilibrium prices explicitly because the prices
enter these equations in complex ways. Consequently, I have used Mathematica 3.0 to find
the roots of the first-order conditions and to
plot the outcome as a function of α.
To simplify the calculations, note that c can
be set to unity without loss of generality (prices
measured in cost units). Moreover, for scaling
purposes, it is useful to plot the markup reductions associated with vertical integration rather

■ 5 For α $ 1, only one input is chosen. For α , ½, demand is
inelastic and the input pricing equations solve with infinite prices.
■ 6 Because the vertically integrated firm is assumed not to compete
with firm 2, downstream profits can be ignored. However, if there is a low
level of competition, then downstream profits must be included here, dramatically complicating the analysis.

6

F I G U R E

2

Input Markups under
Vertical Integrationa

a. As a proportion of the markup without vertical integration, plotted against α.
SOURCE: Author’s calculations.

F I G U R E

3

Firm 2’s Marginal Cost
under Vertical Integrationa

a. As a proportion of its marginal cost without vertical integration, plotted
against α.
SOURCE: Author’s calculations.

than the actual prices. Thus, the prices relative
to the nonintegrated prices are plotted; in particular, for z = x, y,
(16) Pz =

(2α – 1)(pz – 1)
pz – c
=
.
c
2(1 – α)
–c
2α – 1

When Pz = 1, there is no cost reduction,
while Pz = 0 would be competitive or marginal
cost pricing. When the outcome is plotted (see
figure 2), several observations emerge. First, the
reductions in input prices are significant, on the

order of 5 percent or 10 percent. Second, firm Y
reduces its prices more than firm X does. This
should be a reasonably general property, since
firm X is responding to firm Y’s price reduction.
In symmetric models like the one examined, the
price of the unintegrated input should fall more
than the price of the integrated input (to the rest
of the world).
In asymmetric models, there is an additional
effect. As an independent firm, X priced to
serve both firms 1 and 2; therefore, firm X’s
price is an average of the two monopoly prices
associated with 1 and 2. After the merger, firm X
will price only for firm 2; this could increase or
decrease the postmerger price. The effect identified in this article, however, should continue to
hold, using as a benchmark the monopoly price
for firm 2 rather than the monopoly price for
both downstream firms.
Third, the markups are not monotonic in α.
This is interesting because the prices are monotonic, with prices diverging as α→½, and prices
going to costs as α→1. Simulations suggest that
the markup on y is below the markup without
vertical integration (as a proportion of the vanishing markup without vertical integration),
even in the limit.
While prices are more indicative of the
asymmetric effects on the individual input suppliers, firm 2 cares primarily about its marginal
cost. In figure 3, the marginal cost is plotted relative to the marginal cost in the absence of vertical integration.
Firm 2’s marginal cost is lowered as much as
8½ percent. This amount is, of course, less than
the reduction enjoyed by firm 1, but substantial
nevertheless.

V. Banking
Applications
The Federal Reserve System recently studied
the implications of its potential exit from the
provision of retail payments services such as
check clearing and electronic payments. In the
case of many community banks, especially
those in rural markets, the remaining providers
of these services would be vertically integrated
competitors. Moreover, as Osterberg and
Thomson (in this issue) show, branching deregulation is leading to consolidation of both
upstream and downstream banking markets.
The extant industrial organization literature suggests that increased vertical integration in banking, coupled with consolidation in the interbank market, may have deleterious effects on
downstream banking competition.

7

However, the literature itself is a poor guide
to the likelihood of anticompetitive effects. First,
much of the research arose from a desire to understand how vertical mergers might matter for
antitrust enforcement. In particular, the Clayton
Act, which gave courts the ability to block a variety of vertical practices, preceded clear understanding of any circumstances in which vertical
integration might be harmful to competition.
Consequently, a literature developed to show
that vertical integration might have a negative
effect, instead of assessing the likelihood that
vertical integration is harmful to competition.
Second, much of the literature focuses on
the Cournot model, primarily for tractability
reasons. While Cournot competition might be a
reasonable characterization of downstream
competition for customers, where firms’ capacities are relatively inflexible (at least compared
to prices), Cournot competition seems a poor
model of the provision of many upstream services like check clearing, where capacity constraints are unlikely to bind. Results from models employing Cournot competition upstream
may not be applicable to integration in the
banking industry.
Third, the key ingredient of the raising-rivals’costs story is that the primary motivation for vertical integration is a wish to damage competitors. One plausible future for the banking
industry features a handful of very large interstate banks, along with a great number of relatively small local banks. The large institutions
will offer banking, mortgage, insurance, finance,
and other services, will mainly operate electronically, and will be vertically integrated into most
or all financial services areas. In contrast, the
local banks will be predominantly rural and will
offer personalized service, creating a market
niche by exploiting the superior information
and goodwill that local interaction provides.
These different styles of banks will probably not
compete with each other in the minds of most
customers. The large banks will compete
strongly with other large banks, at least until
their numbers are whittled down to three or
four in any given region. The rural banks will
only face the threat that their best (largest) customers may be induced to use large, inexpensive banks; for most customers, a given rural
bank will compete with other rural banks.
In this scenario (which does not result from
any study on my part), rural banks will not
compete significantly with large banks. As a result, they are not likely to be the target of anticompetitive vertical integration, nor are they
likely to be harmed by a reduction in the number of large, vertically integrated banks. The

largest banks may try to harm one another
through their pricing of banking service inputs,
but these institutions are in the best position to
fend for themselves.
The lowering-rivals’-costs story is inapplicable to the present analysis as long as the Federal
Reserve continues to provide check clearing
and other services at some reasonable approximation of cost. As a consequence, rural banks
could benefit from vertical integration of large
banks only if the Federal Reserve were inefficient, so that a mechanism for price reductions
existed. Prices cannot be dropped below minimum cost.

VI. Conclusion
The standard analysis of vertical integration’s
effect on competitors emphasizes the vertically
integrated firm’s incentive to foreclose downstream rivals or raise their costs. While this
effect is natural in some applications, there is
an offsetting effect on suppliers of substitute
inputs. If firms 1 and 2 compete weakly
enough in the output market, the effect on
other input suppliers may dominate the foreclosure effect, causing vertical integration to
benefit downstream rivals while harming
upstream competitors. The harm to upstream
competitors, however, lies in reducing their
markups over marginal cost, that is, damaging
their monopoly power.
A significant aspect of the effect of vertical
integration is that both the unmerged input
supplier and the vertically integrated firm lower
their input prices. The mechanism is that the
merger eliminates the markup on the input by
the purchased firm. The other input supplier
reduces its prices in response to this lowerpriced substitute from the merged firm. The
vertically integrated firm lowers its input prices
to the rest of the world in response to the lowered price of the other input supplier.
Simulations with constant-elasticity-ofsubstitution production functions indicate
potential reductions of as much as 8½ percent
in the downstream competitor’s marginal costs.

8

References
Hart, Oliver, and Jean Tirole. “Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue
(1990), pp. 205–76.
Ordover, Janusz A., Garth Saloner, and
Steven C. Salop. “Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure,” American Economic Review,
vol. 80, no. 1 (March 1990), pp. 127–42.
Salinger, Michael. “Vertical Mergers and
Market Foreclosure,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, vol. 103, no. 2 (May 1988),
pp. 345–56.
Salop, Steven C., and David T. Scheffman.
“Cost-Raising Strategies,” Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 36, no. 1 (September
1987), pp. 19–34.

9

Banking Consolidation and
Correspondent Banking
by William P. Osterberg and James B. Thomson

Introduction
Throughout most of the United States’ financial
history, correspondent banking has been an
underpinning of our banking system. Banks use
correspondent banking relationships to deliver
services to customers in markets where the
bank has no physical presence. For example,
international correspondent banking relationships are used by large banks seeking to provide services to multinational corporations and
in the finance of foreign trade. Due in part to
the historical limitations on geographic expansion by banks, correspondent banking has
been an important channel for delivering services to domestic customers who may be operating in markets beyond the bank’s geographic
reach. Correspondent banking markets often
allow banks to purchase intermediate goods
and services at a lower cost than producing
them in-house—hence these markets may have
been critical to the success of community banks.
The ongoing consolidation of the U.S. banking system and the increasing geographic
scope of large banking institutions could have
important implications for the competitive
structure and, in turn, the efficiency of correspondent banking markets. Whether these

William P. Osterberg is an
economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and
James B. Thomson is a vice
president and economist at the
Bank. The authors thank Sandy
Sterk and Guhan Venkatu for
their research support.

changes will lead to more or less competition
in correspondent banking is unclear. On one
hand, consolidation will inevitably lead to a
reduction in the number of banks offering correspondent banking services, thereby increasing the market power of the remaining players.
On the other hand, given that correspondent
banking markets’ services are regionally or
locally based, interstate consolidation may
increase the number of providers in a local
market—even though the total number of suppliers has been reduced nationally. Finally, the
shrinking number and increased average size
of banks may lead to a reduction in the
demand for correspondent banking services.
Banking industry consolidation could have
important implications for the Federal Reserve
Banks in their traditional role as providers of
correspondent banking services. As banking
becomes less fragmented and more nationally
integrated, there is less need for the public correspondent banking network operated by the
Federal Reserve Banks. However, if banking
consolidation appears to have materially diminished the competitiveness of private correspondent banking markets, then the continued role
of Federal Reserve Banks as public competitors
may be warranted.

10

T A B L E

1

FDIC-Insured Commercial Banksa
Bank size

Number of banks

Less than $25 million
$25 to $50 million
$50 to $100 million
$100 to $300 million
$300 to $500 million
$500 to $1 billion
$1 to $3 billion
$3 to $10 billion
$10 billion or more
Total institutions

1,370
2,026
2,251
2,259
400
304
206
104
64
8,984

Total assetsb

22,496
75,077
161,502
371,720
152,924
209,387
332,204
596,790
3,260,657
5,182,759

a. As of June 30, 1988.
b. In millions of dollars
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Statistics on Banking
(http://www.fdic.gov/databank/sob/).

In this article we reexamine some of these
issues, focusing on the impact of regulatory
changes to permit intrastate branching and
interstate banking. Our concern is primarily
with the impact of such changes on concentration in correspondent balances and domestic
deposit markets. We utilize the call report data
compiled by the Federal Financial Institutions
Examinations Council (FFIEC) and the Summary of Deposits data prepared by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). Any
changes in concentration could have important
implications for the efficiency and competitiveness of banking markets.
The paper is organized as follows: Section I
provides an overview of correspondent banking. The correspondent banking literature is
reviewed in section II. Section III furnishes a
description of the data and the empirical strategy. The results are discussed in section IV.
Finally, conclusions and recommendations are
presented in section V.

I. An Overview
of Correspondent
Banking
All firms face the fundamental decision of
whether to make or buy a particular input used
in production. For example, an automobile
manufacturer must decide whether to make its
own engines and transmissions or to buy them
from an outside supplier. Computer manufacturers must decide whether to make or buy the
processors used in their machines. Likewise, a
bank must decide whether to sort and present

for collection checks drawn on other banks that
have been deposited in customer accounts, or
to contract with a third party to perform this
function. For firms, the make-or-buy decision
depends on a number of factors, including the
nature of the input’s production function, the
firm’s demand for the good relative to the market, and the competitive structures of the market for the input good and the market for the
final good.
Banking literature refers to correspondent
banking as the purchase (by banks) of input
from other banks, central banks, and bank clearinghouses. For instance, when a bank in Cleveland sends checks to its local Federal Reserve
Bank for collection, it has purchased correspondent banking services from that Reserve Bank.
Another example is a recent agreement between
J. P. Morgan and Chase Manhattan Bank, in
which Chase provides European currency clearing services for Morgan.1 The main services provided by correspondent banks are discussed in
section II and in the appendix.
Correspondent banking relationships are
relevant to the cost structure of the U.S. depository institutions sector. As table 1 shows, the
legacy of our unit-banking system—a consequence of intrastate and interstate branching
restrictions—is a highly fragmented banking
system with a large number of small, locally and
regionally based institutions. Economies of scale
in the production of inputs associated with the
provision of many types of bank services, especially payments services, exceed the range of
output for most community banks.2 Furthermore, community banks lack the geographic
scope needed to capitalize on network externalities. Hence, in the absence of correspondent
banking markets, community banks would
likely be less efficient providers of financial services and would have more difficulty surviving
in increasingly competitive banking markets.
In a typical correspondent banking relationship, the supplier of services is another bank.
The provider of services in the input market can
be viewed as a vertically integrated firm that
may compete with the community bank in the
output market. For the integrated firm, the
benefits of supplying correspondent banking
services are clear. First, there are economies of
scope between production of input for its own
products and production of correspondent
banking products. Second, providing correspondent banking services may allow the integrated
■ 1 See Steven Marjanovic, “Morgan Taps Rival Chase for Europe
Clearances,” The American Banker, August 11, 1998, p. 1.
■ 2 See Bauer and Ferrier (1996).

11

bank to more fully exploit economies of scale or
network effects. This, in turn, lowers the cost of
producing (or increases the demand for) its own
downstream products.
The competitive structure of the correspondent banking market may also be relevant to
the structure of the markets for bank products.
Industrial organization theory tells us that if
the integrated firm has substantial monopoly
power in the upstream (input) market, then it
may use that power to damage its rival in the
downstream market.3 Thus, if the supplier of
correspondent banking services competes with
its customer (the community bank) in the output market, then it may price its services above
the average cost of production—thereby damaging the community bank’s ability to compete.
The integrated bank’s ability to do this depends
on the competitive structure of the upstream
and downstream markets.

II. Literature Review
A correspondent banking relationship involves
a correspondent bank, which provides the services, and a respondent bank receiving them.
The respondent usually pays for the services by
maintaining correspondent balances at the
larger bank. The mix of services that might be
provided is broad, but appears to emphasize
check processing, especially for smaller banks,
and loan participation. Other services include
providing reports on economic conditions,
making securities recommendations, and safekeeping securities. Correspondents also have
made markets for federal funds, in effect reducing the minimum size of such transactions.4
Correspondent services are not paid for
directly with fees, but rather implicitly through
maintaining deposit balances.5 Some critics
have claimed that greater efficiency would
result from direct payment and have implied
that smaller banks might not always have
known the true cost of the services.6 Banks,
however, historically have opposed the introduction of direct fees.
The early literature on correspondent banking appears to have grown in response to two
developments: One was the decline in Federal
Reserve membership, which led to the establishment of regional Federal Reserve check processing centers in the early 1970s and the passage of the Depository Institutions Deregulation
and Monetary Control Act of 1980. The other
was the prospect of increased merger activity in
banking, rationalized by a purported positive
impact on banking efficiency. Early research

explored whether correspondent banking
allowed smaller banks to gain access, or gain
access at a lower cost, to some of the services
that might be provided through mergers or
acquisitions. This would imply, for example,
that correspondent relationships provided alternatives to mergers permitted by interstate banking, and that the correspondent system might
be affected by such developments. Another
closely related issue was economies of scale in
the production of important banking services.
Certain services, such as processing of international financial transactions or specialized loan
programs, were more likely than others to be
provided at a lower cost by larger banks. An
issue related to the impact of mergers on efficiency was whether holding-company affiliation might allow smaller banks to gain access
to economies of scale in certain services provided by the lead bank, which is presumably
larger. The argument had been made that
allowing small banks to join holding companies would allow them to reduce the number
of correspondent accounts—and the total
amount of interbank balances held—but maintain the same level of correspondent services.
However, evidence as early as 1970 showed
that, contrary to this argument, the average size
of interbank accounts appeared the same for
smaller banks in or out of holding companies.
This suggested that holding-company affiliation
did not provide small banks with meaningful
opportunities to economize on holdings of
interbank balances.7 Another alleged advantage of holding-company affiliation was the
increased ease of getting loan participations.
While some evidence in favor of this was
found, the related claim that banks facing funding or capital constraints would have an easier
time placing loan participations with their
respondents (that is, the banks purchasing correspondent services) could not be supported.
■ 3 See McAfee (this issue) for a discussion of the damage-your-rival
argument and a counterexample.
■ 4 Knight (1970a) reported that about 90 percent of the banks surveyed indicated that their correspondents offered to help with international
banking services, collections, bank wire, and advice on consumer credit,
credit information, and electronic data processing.
■ 5 Implicitly, as was pointed out by Flannery (1983), the correspondent should provide services costing [1 – ρ]r, where ρ is the reserve
requirement and r is the market interest rate.
■ 6 Although fees are not charged directly for correspondent services, detailed account analyses were performed to estimate the revenue
and expenses from correspondent accounts (see Knight [1970a]).
■ 7 See Knight (1970a, 1970b).

12

We are not aware of any studies that directly
tackle the question of whether efficiency is
enhanced by the presence of a correspondent
banking network. A few studies take an indirect
look at efficiency by analyzing overall economies of scale for banks, taking account of the
provision of correspondent banking services—
something that previous work on economies of
scale using functional cost analysis (FCA) data
failed to control for. Dunham (1981) found that
after controlling for the provision of correspondent banking services, noncorrespondent banking services exhibited economies of scale in
production—something that previous studies
were unable to find. This could be the result of
two factors: First, if small banks trade relatively
more correspondent balances for services (with
such payments not reflected in the FCA data),
they would appear more efficient. Second,
larger banks producing more “due to” accounts,
which are more service-intensive, would appear
to have higher costs.
Flannery (1983) also re-estimated bank cost
functions after adjusting for the understatment
the cost to the bank purchasing correspondent
services. He found that branch bank scale
economies were overestimated, but those of
unit banks were not affected. Gilbert (1983)
found economies of scale in the provision of
correspondent services, which he claims were
due to an inverse relation between the amount
of demand balances due to banks and their
short-run variability.
Prior to the move toward interstate banking,
it was already apparent that correspondent
banking might allow smaller banks to overcome the obstacles to geographic diversification
posed by interstate banking restrictions. One
possibility is that correspondent banking would
help effect a transfer of funds from surplus to
deficit areas. Loan participations are a major
vehicle for this. Funds are transferred from the
larger correspondent bank to a smaller respondent bank to meet a loan request that
either exceeds funds available through local
deposits or exceeds legal lending limits. Payment for such correspondent services is made
in terms of the respondent’s balances at the
correspondent bank. Knight (1970b) presents
evidence supporting the hypothesis that correspondent banking provides a channel for
funds to flow from surplus to deficit areas.
This author documents a large net flow of
funds to correspondents, even from respondent banks that originated loan participations.
The appendix provides further detail on this
branch of the literature.

The possibility that correspondent banking
might affect the competitiveness of downstream
markets was recognized early on. Consistent
with occasional concerns that correspondents
might steal business from their respondents,
Knight (1970a) indicates that money market
correspondents would participate only if the
originating bank would reciprocate in participations. Anecdotal evidence suggests that some
correspondents had stated the view that borrowers consistently unable to obtain loans from
the respondent should switch to the correspondent for lending.
Early work presaged a concern over the
impact of regulatory policies on the correspondent banking system. Obviously, any regulatory
change that influenced correspondent services,
such as check-clearing arrangements, might
have a direct effect on the use of private correspondents for such services. Knight (1972)
focuses on the impact of the Federal Reserve
System’s development of regional check processing centers (RCPCs) and the change in Regulation J requiring all banks to pay for cash letters received from Federal Reserve Banks on
the day of receipt in immediately available
funds. The creation of the RCPCs was seemingly intended to improve the efficiency of the
check-clearing mechanism by permitting all
participating banks to route items drawn on
other participating banks to the clearing center
on the day of the deposit. The Regulation J
change may have had the effect of transferring
collected funds from outlying (rural) banks
(which had been granted a delay in paying
after receipt of a cash letter) to city banks. For
Federal Reserve member banks this regulatory
change effectively reduced the burden of
reserve requirements. However, during this
time in most states, nonmember banks could
count correspondent balances toward reserve
requirements set by their state banking regulatory agency. Therefore, a differential impact
might have been felt by outlying nonmember
banks since they would not have had the
advantage of reduced reserve requirements.
Other Federal Reserve System policies have
had key regulatory influences on the development of the correspondent banking system.
Kane (1982) discusses Title I of the Depository
Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control
Act of 1980 (DIDMC), which mandated that the
Fed make its correspondent services available
to all depository institutions and that they be
explicitly priced. Historically, the Fed had
offered correspondent services to members free
of charge, in part to offset costs associated with
then-higher reserve requirements faced by

13

T A B L E

2

State Branching Status

State

Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of
Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana

Current
statusa

Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Statewide
Limited
Statewide
Statewide
Limited

Year
Year
switched switched to
to limited
statewide
branching branching

1987

1991

1988

1994
1991

1988

1990
1990

1987
1987
1990

1990
1991

Effective
date for
interstate
banking

5/31/97
1/1/94
8/31/96
5/31/97
10/2/95
6/0/97
6/27/95
9/29/95
6/13/96
5/31/97
6/1/97
6/1/97
7/1/95
6/1/97
3/15/96
6/1/97
6/1/97
6/1/97
6/1/97
1/1/97
9/29/95
8/2/96
11/29/95
6/1/97
5/1/97
6/1/97
3/21/97

State

Current
status a

Nebraska
Limited
Nevada
Statewide
New
Hampshire Statewide
New Jersey
Statewide
New Mexico Statewide
New York
Statewide
North
Carolina
Statewide
North
Dakota
Limited
Ohio
Statewide
Oklahoma
Statewide
Oregon
Statewide
Pennsylvania Statewide
Rhode Island Statewide
South Carolina Statewide
South Dakota Statewide
Tennessee
Statewide
Texas
Statewide
Utah
Statewide
Vermont
Statewide
Virginia
Statewide
Washington Statewide
West Virginia Statewide
Wisconsin
Statewide
Wyoming
Limited

Year
Year
switched switched to
to limited
statewide
branching branching

Effective
date for
interstate
banking

5/31/97
9/28/95

1991

6/1/97
4/17/96
6/1/96
2/6/96
6/22/95

1991
1990
1993
1990

1990
1990

1988
1990
1991

5/31/97
5/21/97
5/31/97
2/27/95
7/6/95
6/20/95
7/1/96
7/1/96
6/1/97
8/28/95
6/1/95
5/30/96
7/1/95
6/6/96
5/31/97
6/1/97
5/31/97

a. As of June 30, 1996.
SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Annual Reports (various).

member banks. Rising interest rates increased
the opportunity cost of holding reserves. Hence,
rising interest rates during the 1970s would have
increased the cost of Fed membership, and the
ability of banks to leave the System may have
increased pressure on the Fed to offer additional services. These included access to the discount window and the hope of receiving preferential regulatory treatment.8 Other aspects of
Federal Reserve membership and relevant regulation are discussed in the appendix.

III. Framework for
Analysis and Data
Data limitations constrain our choice of an analytical framework likely to have empirical
applicability. Many of the studies cited above
utilize data generated by one-time surveys of
specific geographical regions. “Due to” and
“due from” balances, corresponding to the lia-

bility and assets entries for the deposits of the
respondent with the correspondent, respectively, are provided on the FFIEC’s call report
forms. However, these reports do not allow us
to match up the two banks. In addition, the
due-to numbers are not available for small
banks. Aside from information about organizational structure, location, and mergers and
acquisition history, few of the variables analyzed in the studies cited previously are available in regular reports. Our approach here
focuses on the correspondent balance numbers
and the data on overall domestic deposits. Supplemental data on deposit markets is constructed using the FDIC’s Summary of Deposits
data, which are available on an annual basis.

■ 8 In Kane’s analysis, the fact that private correspondents offer a
wider array of services implies that the balance requirements set by them
exceed the Fed’s reserve requirements on the same balances.

14

T A B L E

3

Banks and Branches
Year

Banks

Branches

Offices

1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997

13,529
13,506
13,479
13,464
13,502
13,602
13,721
13,964
14,218
14,372
14,397
14,397
14,378
14,351
14,421
14,401
14,435
14,454
14,483
14,402
14,193
13,705
13,119
12,697
12,329
11,909
11,449
10,944
10,431
9,921
9,511
9,125

16,842
17,884
18,966
20,149
21,597
23,080
24,566
26,403
28,384
29,929
31,068
32,836
34,524
36,521
38,458
40,500
39,485
40,548
41,485
42,970
44,054
45,017
46,036
47,650
50,017
51,591
51,544
52,467
54,656
56,028
57,258
59,773

30,371
31,390
32,445
33,613
35,099
36,682
38,287
40,367
42,602
44,301
45,465
47,233
48,902
50,872
52,879
54,901
53,920
55,002
55,968
57,372
58,247
58,722
59,155
60,347
62,346
63,500
62,993
63,411
65,087
65,949
66,769
68,898

SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Statistics on Banking
(http://www.fdic.gov/databank/sob/).

T A B L E

4

National Correspondent
Banking Deposit Shares
Yeara

Top 50 banks

1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

28.18
27.79
26.89
26.47
25.53
27.82
29.79
28.61
29.43
30.44
32.64
33.52
36.57

Market share (percent)
Top 10 banks
Top 5 banks

a. As of June 30.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

11.92
14.78
11.87
11.53
10.94
13.15
12.99
12.89
12.38
13.39
13.33
14.94
16.07

7.51
10.51
8.07
7.78
7.05
8.66
8.64
8.95
7.76
7.99
8.40
8.52
9.99

The sample period studied here covers
June 30, 1984, to June 30, 1996, and includes
many shifts from unit banking to limited branching, and from limited branching to statewide
branching. Table 2 details the history of such
regulatory changes during our sample period.
While numerous analyses have focused on
the issue of whether banking efficiency has
been enhanced by the recent wave of mergers
and acquisitions (M&As), the role of correspondent banking has been unclear. Ideally, our
analysis of changing concentration in correspondent banking markets would take this factor into account. It is not possible, however, to
directly examine the effect of M&As on efficiency using the existing data.
One possibility is that M&As would render
unnecessary the pre-existing correspondent
relationships involving the formerly independent banks. On the other hand, they could
reduce the competitiveness and efficiency of the
remaining system. Similar concerns arise with
the changes in branching status that we identify.
Branching economies might be affected. The
presumption is that the largest bank is the correspondent. After the absorption of unit banks as
branches of the new bank, the correspondent
deposits no longer appear on the reports at the
bank level upon which we focus.
Finally, data on market prices charged for
private correspondent banking services do not
exist, especially at the individual market level.
Therefore, we rely on measures of market concentration, such as the Herfindahl index, to
investigate the impact of branching deregulation on the structure of the interbank market. It
is important to note, however, that market concentration measures are not always good proxies for the degree of competition in a market.
Hence, increased concentration may not necessarily indicate a less competitive market—
especially if the event driving market consolidation increases the degree of potential
competition (contestability) in that market.

IV. Results
Tables 3 and 4 illustrate the ongoing consolidation of the domestic commercial banking industry and its implications for the correspondent
banking market nationwide. While the number
of banks has fallen steadily from 1984 to 1996,
the market share of the top 50 correspondent
banks has risen from 28.18 percent to 36.57
percent of all deposits due to banks over the
same time period. Similar results are found
when looking at the market share held by the

15

T A B L E

5

Deposits Due to Banks:
State-Level Herfindahl
Yeara

1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

All
states

Statewide
branching

Limited
branching

Unit
banking

1,814.80
2,060.31
1,989.67
1,863.52
1,861.73
1,826.39
1,549.98
1,580.03
1,622.51
1,396.87
1,679.40
1,665.53
1,611.97

730.67
577.37
632.66
657.61
804.60
612.90
803.99
1,139.21
1,132.74
1,316.83
1,361.66
1,346.11
1,092.68

987.02
632.83
746.03
847.76
1,646.37
1,635.88
2,271.65

1,302.32
1,328.69
1,315.64
1,322.13
1,467.51
1,379.42
1,416.91
1,476.31
1,507.27
1,379.61
1,617.10
1,602.90
1,510.14

a. As of June 30.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

T A B L E

6

Deposits Due from Banks:
State-Level Herfindahl
Yeara

All
states

Statewide
branching

Limited
branching

Unit
banking

1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

2,121.30
2,014.97
2,240.79
2,011.15
1,854.20
1,944.99
2,176.47
2,316.39
2,591.18
2,708.97
2,700.65
3,022.00
2,984.88

3,084.66
3,140.98
3,561.01
2,994.41
2,714.22
2,927.31
2,794.63
2,778.43
2,951.34
3,186.43
3,141.37
3,486.61
3,307.98

1,210.53
968.51
1,021.35
921.99
895.89
772.17
699.32
814.77
1420.68
972.77
893.69
1,117.09
1,660.20

1,160.00
850.74
858.86
863.66
488.00
666.13
787.21

a. As of June 30.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

top 10 and top five correspondent banks nationwide. Despite the increased concentration of
correspondent banking deposits shown in table
4, the national market for correspondent banking remains relatively unconcentrated, with no
firm controlling more than 3.6 percent of
deposits due to banks.
Unfortunately, most markets for correspondent banking services are likely to be local or

regional in scope and, therefore, national concentration measures may prove misleading. For
example, if correspondent banking markets are
effectively segmented by branching restrictions
(intrastate or interstate), then low levels of market concentration at the national level may be
consistent with highly concentrated markets at
the state or local level. Moreover, to the extent
that banking consolidation increases the contestability of correspondent banking markets,
increases in market concentration at the
national level may lead to more competitive
correspondent banking markets at the state and
local levels.
Data on correspondent banking markets
are collected at the bank level, limiting our
ability to accurately gauge the competitiveness
of these markets. Moreover, the degree of
aggregation in the data precludes us from
looking at measures of concentration below
the state level for both deposits due to banks
(correspondent deposits) and deposits due
from banks (respondent deposits).
To examine trends in market concentration
at the state level, we construct Herfindahl
indexes for deposits due to banks (correspondent deposits) and for deposits due from banks
(respondent deposits). Tables 5 and 6 report
the average Herfindahl for all states, states with
statewide branching, states with limited branching, and unit banking states. Table 5 shows that
correspondent banking is more concentrated,
on average, in statewide branching states than
it is in states with more restrictive branching
laws. However, while mean concentration for
the total of all states has risen over the sample
period, holdings of correspondent deposits
have become less concentrated in statewide
branching states. The increasing mean concentration of correspondent deposits for all states
over time likely reflects the ongoing consolidation of the banking system, especially in those
states switching to less restrictive branching
laws during the sample period. Moreover, the
decline in the mean concentration of correspondent deposits for the statewide branching
states over the sample period may simply
reflect the inclusion of new states in the sample. If correspondent deposit markets in states
that switched to statewide branching during the
sample period are less concentrated than the
average statewide branching state in the sample, then mean concentration for the sample
should decrease over time.
Table 6 shows that respondent deposits (deposits due from banks) are also more concentrated in statewide branching states. To the extent that banking markets are more consolidated

16

T A B L E

7

Domestic Deposits:
State-Level Herfindahl
Yeara

All
states

Statewide
branching

Limited
branching

Unit
banking

1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

803.57
839.97
829.74
822.19
874.87
924.22
948.53
975.79
1,037.58
1,035.08
1,079.96
1,165.78
1,301.08

1,413.75
1,476.55
1,434.67
1,341.83
1,363.18
1,431.53
1,216.49
1,175.25
1,254.06
1,208.44
1,233.59
1,318.10
1,449.48

245.13
264.17
290.64
275.91
305.17
324.04
310.75
327.55
334.01
404.70
450.09
541.27
692.67

155.41
146.19
152.30
144.49
191.21
243.95
284.19

a. As of June 30.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

T A B L E

8

Domestic Deposits: Weighted
Average Herfindahls for All Markets
Date

All
states

Statewide
branching

Limited
branching

Unit
banking

1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

2,269.58
2,281.17
1,886.94
1,888.29
2,451.90
2,566.49
2,674.95
2,717.42
2,936.77
2,946.38
3,048.91
3,120.80
3,280.86

2,502.29
2,512.56
1,983.10
1,970.49
2,597.36
2,665.32
2,786.77
2,800.73
3,057.20
3,061.80
3,024.30
3,100.03
3,182.87

2,309.44
2,368.29
2,288.14
2,192.11
2,231.45
2,298.59
1,850.64
1,709.98
1,723.09
1,726.98
2,298.79
2,306.78
2,922.62

1,379.66
1,320.86
1,337.33
1,262.59
1,750.54
2,318.25
2,046.39

a. As of June 30.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

in statewide branching states, one would
expect to see fewer banks placing deposits
with correspondent banks and, therefore,
greater concentration. Unlike correspondent
balances, however, respondent deposits do not
clearly increase or decrease through time either
for the full sample or for statewide branching
states. Therefore, the implication of interstate
branching on the concentration of respondent
deposits is unclear.

The negative relationship between concentration in interbank deposit markets and the
stringency of geographic limitations (that is,
branching restrictions) may simply be a consequence of more concentrated deposit markets.
That is, relaxation of branching restrictions may
increase the concentration of banking deposits
—a likely outcome of a more consolidated
banking system—which, in turn, leads to more
concentrated interbank-deposit markets. Tables
7 and 8 seem to bear this point out: Table 7
exhibits average Herfindahls at the state level
for domestic deposits. Table 8 presents average
market-level Herfindahls grouped by state
branching status.9 In both tables, statewide
branching states tend to exhibit more deposit
market concentration than other states, and the
level of concentration has tended to increase
over the sample period.
Simple correlation analysis confirms a high
degree of correlation between interbank-deposit
concentration and concentration measures of
domestic deposit markets. The Spearman (Pearson) correlation coefficient between the statelevel Herfindahl indexes for domestic deposits
and correspondent deposits is 0.7033 (0.7153).
The Spearman (Pearson) correlation coefficient
between the state-level Herfindahl indexes for
domestic deposits and respondent deposits is
0.7131 (0.6756). Moreover, the structure of the
correspondent deposit market and the respondent deposit market are highly correlated with a
Spearman (Pearson) correlation coefficient of
0.45665 (0.52298).
One problem with looking at time trends
in Herfindahl indexes across states with different branching laws is that a number of states
changed their laws during the sample period.
This is evident from the disappearance of unit
banking in the sample in 1991. All changes in
branching status favored a less restrictive form
of branching regulation. Therefore, a measure
of caution is warranted when comparing trends
in concentration across subcategories in tables
5 through 8.
Fortunately, we can directly test the impact
of relaxing intrastate branching restrictions on
deposit market concentration. For all states that
changed branching status during the sample
period (there were 22 such switches), we constructed state-level Herfindahls for domestic
deposits, correspondent deposits, and respondent deposits two years prior to and two years

■ 9 In table 9, we assume that for bank offices located in MSAs the
relevant market is the MSA. For bank offices located in non-MSA counties,
the market is defined to be the county where the office is located.

17

T A B L E

9

Event Analysis: Change
in Branching Status
2 years
prior to
switch

2 years
after
switch

Domestic
deposits

264.96

Deposits due
from banks
Deposits due
to banks

Variable

Change in
Herfindahl

Percent
change in
Herfindahl

403.33

138.37a
4.50

81.78a
3.78

789.67

791.48

1.82
0.02

1.42
0.17

828.22

1436.55

608.32a
3.17

144.26a
3.27

a. Significant at the 1 percent level
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

T A B L E

10

Regression Results
Dependent Variable: HDEPIDOM
Model 1

Model 2

Model 3

Model 4

Intercept

533.373
7.175

607.623
7.987

578.900
7.581

338.734
3.402

Timedum

–13.546a
–1.546a

–6.202b
–0.698b

–6.987b
–0.790b

–12.697b
–1.424b

1.022
26.267

1.114
24.510

1.028
18.796

0.949
16.730

–328.334
–3.839

–369.127
–4.277

–381.807
–4.457

0.061
2.815

0.070
3.160

HDOMDEP
DSBRANCH
HINTBDEP
HAVGDMKT
Adj-R2

0.108
3.854
0.512

0.522

0.527

0.527

F-Value

348.217

241.887

185.302

145.451

Prob >F

0

0

0

0

a. Significant at the 10 percent level.
b. Not significant.
NOTE: Unless otherwise noted, all coeffcients are significant at the 1 percent
level.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

after the event. We then tested to see if the
change in the Herfindahls due to the change
in branching status was significant. The results
of the analysis are reported in table 9. For domestic deposits and correspondent deposits
(deposits due to banks), a switch to more liberal branching significantly increases the Herfindahl; however, the change in the respondent

deposit (deposits due from banks) Herfindahl
is not significant.
In all, univariate analysis of the data suggests that a relaxation of branching restrictions
is associated with increased concentration in
the market for domestic deposits and in the
interbank deposit market. Neither of these
results is surprising, as the removal of an artificial constraint to geographic consolidation of
the banking system would be expected to
increase concentration in banking markets.
However, increased concentration does not
necessarily translate into less competitive markets, as the removal of branching restrictions
increases the potential for entry.
To separate the effects of branching status
from deposit market concentration, we conduct
a simple regression analysis—with the Herfindahl for correspondent deposits as the dependent variable. The results can be found in
table 10. Model 1 regresses the correspondent
deposit Herfindahl on the state-level Herfindahl for domestic deposits and a time dummy.
Model 2 adds a statewide branching dummy
variable (DSBRANCH = 1 for statewide branching, zero otherwise). A significant coefficient
on DSBRANCH suggests that after controlling
for the structure of the domestic deposit market, branching restrictions affect the structure
of the correspondent banking market. Model 3
controls for the market concentration for respondent deposits. To the extent that there are
scale and scope economies associated with the
provision of correspondent banking services,
increased concentration in respondent deposits
may reduce the number of correspondent
banks that can profitably operate in a market.
Finally, model 4 extends the previous regression by including information on local market
structure—HLOCDEP, the average local deposit market Herfindahl in each state. Inclusion
of HLOCDEP allows us to control for the effect
of local deposit market structure on correspondent banking.
The coefficient on the domestic deposit
Herfindahl (HDOMDEP) is positive and significant from zero in all four models. In addition,
the coefficient on the proxy for local deposit
market structure (HLOCDEP) in model 4 is also
positive and significant. This confirms the univariate results that find increased deposit market concentration associated with increased
concentration in correspondent deposit markets. The negative and significant coefficient
on DSBRANCH in models 2, 3, and 4 suggests
that once domestic deposit market concentration is controlled for, relaxing branching restrictions leads to less concentrated and more

18

competitive correspondent banking markets. Finally, the positive and significant coefficient on
the respondent deposit Herfindahl (HINTBDEP)
index is consistent with the hypothesis that a reduction in the number of respondent banks
reduces the number of correspondents that can
coexist in a market—and hence increases concentration of correspondent deposits.

V. Conclusion
Interstate branching promises to change the
competitive landscape in banking. As illustrated
by the mega-mergers of 1998—which included
the merger of Bank of America and NationsBank
—geographic consolidation of the banking system is well under way. This consolidation will
certainly increase the concentration of deposit
markets at the national and regional level.
Moreover, the preceding analyses suggest that
interstate consolidation may even increase
deposit market concentration at the state and
local level.
The evidence presented here indicates that
intrastate branching deregulation and the subsequent geographic consolidation of the banking industry has led to increased concentration
in the correspondent and respondent deposit
markets. However, this increased concentration
in the interbank market appears to be a consequence of increased concentration in the
domestic deposit market associated with more
liberal branching rights. Controlling for the
level of concentration in the domestic deposit
market, the effect of statewide branching is to
reduce concentration in the correspondent
deposit market. This result is consistent with
the hypothesis that any positive effects of
increased contestability of interbank markets
resulting from the removal of branching restrictions mitigate (and may dominate) any negative
effects on competition from increased concentration in interbank markets.
Overall, the evidence presented here suggests that interstate branching will result in more
concentrated interbank markets, as the geographic consolidation of the banking industry at
the national level will certainly reduce the number of correspondent and respondent banks
nationwide. This increased concentration in correspondent banking markets will not necessarily
reduce the competitiveness of these markets at
the state and local level because branching
deregulation also increases their contestability.
There are several caveats to these results:
First, data limitations preclude our controlling

for important nonbank competitors in the correspondent banking market such as banker’s
banks, private clearinghouses, data processing
firms, and the Federal Reserve Banks. Second,
to the extent that banking organizations use the
multibank holding company to circumvent
branching restrictions, the measured impact of
branching deregulation on market concentration
and contestability will be overstated.
From a public-policy standpoint, if interstate
branching leads to the establishment of truly
national correspondent banks, then there may
be less justification for the Federal Reserve System to provide correspondent banking services.
However, more work needs to be done in this
area before we can begin to seriously reconsider the role that Federal Reserve Banks play
in this market.

Appendix
Loan Participations,
Federal Reserve
Membership, and
Other Determinants
of Correspondent
Balances
Early literature indicates that loan participations are the second-most important service
offered by correspondents. However, information about this activity is not available on the
periodic reports submitted by banks. Knight
(1970b) reports that 75 percent of banks experiencing an increased need for loan assistance
cited the size of the loan as the main factor.
The percentage of banks requiring loan assistance increased with bank size, and requirements for assistance are positively related to the
loan-to-deposit ratio, the latter possibly indicating the importance of liquidity constraints.
Knight (1970a) indicates that although most
loan participations originate with the smaller
banks, banks that do not experience excess
loan demands can still buy loans or participations from their correspondents. Many respondents maintained credit lines or borrowed
directly from their correspondents.
The correspondent services offered by the
Federal Reserve System to its member banks
have differed somewhat from those offered by
private correspondents, and this has been a subject of contention and regulatory reform. Access
to the discount window is probably the most
obvious correspondent service that at some time
might have been available only to members.

19

Federal Reserve membership has been identified as an important factor by several authors.
The two reasons most often cited for nonmember banks being more likely to use correspondent services were the possibility that states
with reserve requirements would allow nonmembers to count balances due as reserves,
and the granting of immediate credit by correspondents for cash letters received from
respondents. Lawrence and Lougee (1970)
found that balances due from banks, but not
the number of correspondent ties or their geographical distribution, is related to Fed membership. Member banks have higher balances
due if balances at the Fed are included, but not
if they are excluded. Knight (1970a) confirms
this finding and also reports that the benefits of
Fed membership appear to increase with bank
size since, unlike overall banks, nonmember
banks over a certain (small) size have correspondent balances that increase with bank size.
Knight (1970a) reported that about 90 percent
of banks surveyed preferred to send checks
drawn on nonlocal banks through correspondents rather than the Fed, apparently because
immediate credit was offered by the former.
Although larger banks appear to have a greater
preference for using the Fed, this could be misleading if correspondents send checks received
from smaller banks on to the Fed for clearing.
Summers and Segala (1979) focus on the
determinants of usage of Fed correspondent
services. They find that bank size, holding-company affiliation, and metropolitan location
increase the probability of a bank using Fed
check-clearing services. However, only bank
size affected usage of Fed wire services. Size is
interpreted as indicating administrative capacity
to manage the services.
Several other determinants of correspondent
balances have been identified in the literature.
For example, Lawrence and Lougee (1970)
report that for banks in the Denver area, bank
size, ratio of demand to total deposits, and distance of the bank from Denver are positively
related to the amount of domestic “due from”
balances. The number of correspondent ties is
related to the first two characteristics. Meinster
and Mohindru (1975) conclude that correspondent balances are influenced by liquidity considerations as well as the need to pay for correspondent services. The volatility of deposits is
another factor: Kane (1982) found that suppliers
of correspondent services imposed higher
reserve requirements on more volatile deposits,
a practice which is presumably consistent with
volatility being related to the benefits derived
from the services. Gilbert (1983) identifies a rela-

tionship between deposit volatility and the scale
of correspondent services, with transaction cost
being lowered by a larger number of respondents and thus a higher level of variability.
Geographic variables also play a role. Distance from the correspondent obviously is related to the cost of providing certain services,
as well as familiarity with the correspondent.
Size of city could, at times, be related to sophistication and consequently to the need for certain services.

References
Auerbach, Robert. “Changes in the Provision
of Correspondent-Banking Services and
the Role of Federal Reserve Banks under
the DIDMC Act: A Comment on Kane,”
Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, vol. 16 (Spring 1982),
pp. 127–36.
Baker, George, Robert Gibbons, and
Kevin J. Murphy. “Implicit Contracts and
the Theory of the Firm,” Harvard Business
School, Working Paper No. 98-009, December 1997.
Bauer, Paul W., and Gary D. Ferrier. “Scale
Economies, Cost Efficiencies, and Technological Change in Federal Reserve Payments
Processing,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, vol. 28, no. 4 (November 1996),
pp. 1004–39.
Dunham, Constance. “Commercial Bank
Costs and Correspondent Banking,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston, New England Economic Review (September/October 1981),
pp. 22–36.
Finney, Katherine. Interbank Deposits: The
Purpose and Effects of Domestic Balances,
1934–54. New York: Arno Press, 1958.
Flannery, Mark J. “Correspondent Services
and Cost Economies in Commercial Banking,” Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 7,
no. 1 (March 1983), pp. 83–99.
Gilbert, R. Alton. “Economies of Scale in Correspondent Banking,” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, vol. 15, no. 4 (November 1983), pp. 483–88.

20

Kane, Edward J. “Changes in the Provision of
Correspondent-Banking Services and the
Role of Federal Reserve Banks under the
DIDMC Act: Rejoinder,” Carnegie–Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 16
(Spring 1982), pp. 93–126.
Knight, Robert E. “Correspondent Banking
Part I: Balances and Services,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Monthly
Review (November 1970a), pp. 3–14.
———- . “Correspondent Banking Part II: Loan
Participations and Fund Flows,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Monthly
Review (December 1970b), pp. 12–24.
———- . “Correspondent Banking Part III:
Account Analysis,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Monthly Review (December
1971), pp. 3–17.
———- . “The Impact of Changing Check
Clearing Arrangements on the Correspondent Banking System,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City, Monthly Review (December
1972), pp. 14–24.
Lawrence, Robert J., and Duane Lougee.
“Determinants of Correspondent Banking
Relationships,” Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking, vol. 2, no. 3 (August 1970),
pp. 358–69.
McAfee, R. Preston. “The Effects of Vertical
Integration on Competing Input Suppliers,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review, vol. 35, no. 1 (1999), pp. 2–8.
Meinster, David R., and Rajesh K.
Mohindru. “The Determinants of the Demand for Correspondent Balances by Small
and Medium Sized Banks,” Journal of Bank
Research, vol. 6, no. 1 (Spring 1975),
pp. 25–34.
Merrett, D. T. “Global Reach by Australian
Banks: Correspondent Banking Networks,
1830–1960,” Business History, vol. 37, no. 3
( July 1995), pp. 70–88.

Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts. Economics, Organization and Management. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice–Hall, 1992.
Moulton, Harold G. Principles of Money and
Banking. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1916.
Redlich, Fritz. The Molding of American
Banking: Men and Ideas. History of American Business Leaders Series, vol. 2. New
York: Hafner Publishing Company, 1951.
Summers, Bruce J., and John P. Segala.
“Determinants of Correspondent Banking
Relationships with the Federal Reserve System,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
Working Paper No. 79-1, March 1979.
Thomson, James B. “Interbank Exposure in
the Fourth Federal Reserve District,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary, August 1, 1987.
Todd, Walker F., and James B. Thomson.
“An Insider’s View of the Political Economy
of the Too Big to Let Fail Doctrine,” Public
Budgeting and Financial Management: An
International Journal, vol. 3, no. 3 (1991),
pp. 547–617.
Williamson, Oliver E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: The Free
Press, 1985.