View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F E D E R A L R E S E RV E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Economic
Review
Number 3, 2010

Estimating the Effect of
Mortgage Foreclosures on
Nearby Property Values:
A Critical Review of the Literature
W. Scott Frame

PRESIDENT AND CHIEF EXECUTIVE OFFICER

Dennis L. Lockhart
SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT AND
DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Economic Review
Volume 95, Number 3, 2010

David E. Altig
RESEARCH DEPARTMENT

Thomas J. Cunningham, Vice President and
Associate Director of Research
Michael Bryan, Vice President
John C. Robertson, Vice President
Michael Chriszt, Assistant Vice President
Paula Tkac, Assistant Vice President

Estimating the Effect of Mortgage Foreclosures on
Nearby Property Values: A Critical Review of the Literature
W. Scott Frame*

PUBLIC AFFAIRS DEPARTMENT

Bobbie H. McCrackin, Vice President
Lynn H. Foley, Editor
Nancy Condon, Assistant Editor
Jill Dible and Peter Hamilton, Designers
Mark Andersen, Marketing and Circulation
Charlotte Wessels, Administrative Assistance

The Economic Review of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta presents analysis of economic and
financial topics relevant to Federal Reserve policy.
In a format accessible to the nonspecialist, the
publication reflects the work of the bank’s Research
Department. It is edited, designed, and produced
through the Public Affairs Department.

In response to the wave of residential mortgage foreclosures in the past few
years, federal, state and local government intervention programs have aimed to
reduce the presumed social costs of foreclosures. Before the recent crisis, there
was little economic research documenting foreclosure spillover effects.
This article takes a critical look at the recent literature that seeks to
estimate the negative effects of residential mortgage foreclosures. This review
suggests that foreclosed properties sell at a discount, likely because such
properties are in worse condition than surrounding properties. What’s more,
very nearby foreclosures appear to depress the sales prices of nondistressed
properties, but this effect diminishes rapidly over physical distance and time.
The author suggests that the considerable variation in foreclosure discount
and spillover estimates that occurs from study to study may be related to data
limitations (specific places and times) and poorly specified empirical models in
some studies. He notes that studies using a repeat-sales approach seem to hold
greater promise than those using hedonic regressions; the former approach is
more likely to hold property and neighborhood characteristics constant and
make it easier to examine multiple geographies and longer time periods.

JEL classification: G21, G28
Key words: residential mortgages, foreclosures, foreclosure spillovers, negative
externalities

Views expressed in the Economic Review are not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System.
Material may be reprinted or abstracted if the
Economic Review and author are credited.
To sign up for e-mail notifications when articles
are published online, please visit www.frbatlanta.
org and click the “Subscribe” link on the home
page. For further information, contact the Public
Affairs Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta, 1000 Peachtree Street, N.E., Atlanta,
Georgia 30309-4470 (404.498.8020).
ISSN 0732-1813

*The author is a financial economist and policy adviser in the Atlanta Fed’s research
department.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Estimating the Effect of Mortgage Foreclosures
on Nearby Property Values:
A Critical Review of the Literature
W. Scott Frame
The author is a financial economist and policy adviser in the research department of the Atlanta Fed.
He thanks Dan Immergluck, Kris Gerardi, Joe Tracy, and an anonymous reviewer for comments on a
previous draft and Whitney Mancuso for research assistance.

T

he United States has experienced a tremendous wave of residential mortgage foreclosures in
recent years.1 Based on data from the Mortgage Bankers Association, as of year-end 2006, just
over a half million residential mortgages were in foreclosure, representing 1.2 percent of all such
loans. Just three years later, as of year-end 2009, more than two million residential mortgages were
being foreclosed upon, or 4.6 percent of all such loans.
In response to these developments, federal, state, and local governments have created
programs aimed at keeping families in their homes and/or reducing the increased stock of vacant
homes. Two prominent examples are the U.S. Treasury’s Home Affordable Modification Program
(HAMP) and Neighborhood Stabilization Program (NSP) grants distributed to states and some
local governments through the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). Such
policy interventions may be justified on economic efficiency grounds if there are either (1) frictions
preventing efficient renegotiations between lenders and delinquent borrowers or (2) social costs,
or externalities, associated with foreclosures.
Recent papers by Cordell et al. (2009) and Gerardi and Li (2010) discuss potential barriers
to efficient renegotiation of residential mortgages. By contrast, this article provides a critical
review of the literature seeking to estimate foreclosure externalities. The article first provides
some background information about the recent foreclosure wave and the associated public sector
response. The discussion then summarizes the literature on “foreclosure discounts,” which
presumably must exist for foreclosures to have negative price effects on nearby properties.
Next, I synthesize the empirical evidence measuring the effect of foreclosure on nearby property
sales prices. Overall, the evidence is consistent with the existence of social costs related to
foreclosure activity although the study identifies various methodological issues, data limitations,
and curious results.

Background
U.S. mortgage foreclosures began to rise in late 2006 at the same time that national house prices
began to fall.2 Figure 1 presents quarterly data on the percent of mortgages entering foreclosure
(flow) and in the process of foreclosure (stock) for 2000 through 2009. While both foreclosure
measures have markedly increased, the series have diverged in recent quarters because of
expanding foreclosure timelines. Figure 2 illustrates temporal variation in house prices over the
same 2000–9 period as measured by two popular indices—the Federal Housing Finance Agency
(FHFA) and S&P/Case-Shiller. The latter series, which is clearly more volatile, having peaked
higher and fallen farther, suggests that U.S. house prices have returned to 2003 levels.
The patterns in the national aggregates presented in Figures 1 and 2 are also observable when
looking at state-level cross-sectional data. Figure 3 shows this by way of a scatter plot of the
change in the stock of foreclosures and the change in the FHFA house price index between 2006

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

1

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1

U.S. mortgage foreclosure rates

Percent of total loans, not seasonally adjusted

5

4
Percent of mortgages in foreclosure

3

2

1
Percent of foreclosures started

0

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association

and 2008. Clearly, the four so-called sand states (Arizona, California, Florida, and Nevada) have
experienced both the most dramatic home price declines and foreclosure rate increases.
Foreclosures rise when house prices fall because homeowners begin to see their stock of home
equity erode. Highly leveraged borrowers, or those with little equity at the time of the house
price declines, begin sliding into a position of “negative equity,” or owing the lender more than the
property is worth. CoreLogic estimates that as of year-end 2009, 11.3 million residential properties—
representing 24 percent of all residential properties with mortgages—were in a negative equity
position. Research has shown that a negative equity position is a necessary condition for mortgage
default, although a second trigger like a shock to the borrower’s monthly income or expenses is
generally required for a foreclosure to occur (see, for example, Foote, Gerardi, and Willen 2008).
The foreclosure process is costly to both borrowers and lenders and perhaps even society as
a whole. Borrowers incur search costs and moving expenses, face family disruptions, and have
difficultly accessing credit in the future. Lender costs include the shortfall between the ultimate
sales price and the mortgage balance and carrying costs (for example, legal, property management,
and sales expenses and forgone interest). Social costs associated with foreclosure may arise
from both direct municipal expenses as well as any reduction in the value of nearby properties.
These costs would seem to be especially acute for vacant properties, which are more likely to
attract criminal activity (resulting in higher municipal costs) and be in worse physical condition
(depressing property values).
Importantly, borrowers and lenders generally have an incentive to prevent the realization of
private foreclosure costs through debt renegotiation although borrowers’ home equity position
and cash flow as well as lender incentives shape the renegotiation process. Cordell et al. (2009)
and Gerardi and Li (2010) provide detailed discussions of the economic issues surrounding
residential mortgage renegotiations, such as forbearance plans and loan modifications, and
identify potential barriers to efficient workouts. The U.S. Treasury’s Home Affordable Modification
1. Foreclosure is the legal process by which the mortgage lender repossesses a property from the borrower because of
nonpayment, or default. This process can vary significantly from state to state.
2. Notably, after housing prices began falling and foreclosures rising, the U.S. economy entered a recession, which then
likely begat additional foreclosures and house price declines.

2

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2

U.S. home price indexes, non–seasonally adjusted
220

240

200

225
210
195

FHFA purchase-only home price index

160
180
140

165

120

100
2000

FHFA Index

S&P Case-Shiller Index

S&P Case-Shiller 20-MSA composite

180

150
135
2002

2004

2006

2008

Note: FHFA U.S. Purchase-Only Home Price, January 1991 = 100; S&P Case-Shiller 20-MSA composite, January 2000 = 100
Source: Standard & Poor’s and Fiserve Inc., Federal Housing Finance Agency

Program (HAMP) is a federal initiative aimed at reducing workout barriers and hence minimizing
unnecessary foreclosures.
A less well-known federal program is more squarely focused on reducing the social costs
associated with foreclosed properties. The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development’s
Neighborhood Stabilization Program (NSP) provides grants to state and local authorities to acquire
land and property, demolish or rehabilitate abandoned properties, and provide down payment or
closing cost assistance to low- and moderate-income families. The original NSP program (NSP1)
was authorized by the Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008 and has awarded $4 billion in
grants to state and local governments. NSP2, which was created by the American Recovery and
Reinvestment Act of 2009, provided an additional $2 billion and established a technical assistance
program that provides grants to private assistance providers to help municipalities improve their
use of NSP funds.
The NSP is predicated on the belief that foreclosures in general and vacancies in particular
can generate significant social costs in the form of increased municipal expenses and reductions
in the value of nearby properties. Determining potential municipal expenses associated with
foreclosures and vacancies is largely a survey exercise to tabulate the prices for various public
services. Apgar and Duda (2005), for example, do this tabulation using information from Chicago.
By contrast, estimates of the spillover effect of foreclosures on nearby property values require the
use of multivariate regression techniques. Remarkably, prior to the foreclosure crisis, there had
been little economic research connecting the incidence of foreclosure to nearby property values.

Foreclosure discounts: Do foreclosed properties sell for less?
If foreclosed residential properties are to have a negative effect on the value of nearby properties,
they themselves should trade at a discount. Our review of the foreclosure discount literature
suggests that this is the case although estimates and interpretation vary.
There are three primary explanations for why a property foreclosure discount should exist:
(1) systematic differences in property characteristics, (2) lower average property condition or
quality, and (3) a liquidity discount. A thin empirical literature has generally sought to identify
any such discount by estimating hedonic (log) sales price regressions that include a foreclosure
indicator and a large number of control variables representing key property features (for example,

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 3

Change in foreclosure rate and FHFA House Price Index by state, 2006Q1–2008Q4
20

Percent change in FHFA Home Price Index

WY
ND

10
0
–1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

–10
RI

–20

MI
AZ

–30
–40

FL
CA

NV

–50
Change in foreclosure rate

Source: Mortgage Bankers Association, Federal Housing Finance Agency

lot size, the square footage and age of the home, and the number of bedrooms and bathrooms)
and neighborhood characteristics. Notably, studies vary significantly in their coverage of property
and neighborhood features—with the latter often simply proxied for using location indicators like
ZIP code. Nevertheless, if one thought these property and neighborhood characteristics were
well controlled for, any statistically and economically significant foreclosure discount could then
presumably be ascribed to differences in property quality or liquidity. Note that, to date, there has
been only limited investigation seeking to identify these two effects separately.
Two early studies of foreclosure discounts conditioned only on property characteristics.
Shilling, Benjamin, and Sirmans (1990) estimate a 24 percent foreclosure discount for condominium
sales in Baton Rouge, Louisiana, during 1985, while Forgey, Rutherford, and VanBuskirk (1994)
similarly report a 23 percent discount for residential sales in Arlington, Texas, between July 1991
and January 1993. (Note that the coefficient estimates in this latter study are clouded by the fact
that they attempted to control for neighborhood characteristics using actual ZIP codes rather
than ZIP code dummies.) Carroll, Clauretie, and Neill (1997) study HUD home sales in Las Vegas
between 1990 and 1993 and find no statistically significant foreclosure discount after controlling
for various property characteristics and location using ZIP code indicators. This result is unusual
relative to the other studies in this literature.
Two more recent studies using hedonic methods examine larger samples and richer sets of
neighborhood characteristics. Sumell (2009) estimates a 50 percent foreclosure discount for
property sales in Cuyahoga County, Ohio, between 2004 and 2006. Likewise, Campbell, Giglio,
and Pathak (2009) report a 22 percent foreclosure discount for single-family properties in
Massachusetts during 1987–2007. (Note that for this latter study, the hedonic characteristics were
measured only in 2007.) Unlike these previous studies, Pennington-Cross (2006) uses a repeatsales method that differences out (and hence assumes constant) property and neighborhood
characteristics. Comparing the change in prices from initial purchase to real estate–owned (REO)
sale for a nationwide sample of foreclosed homes in relation to their metro area house price index,
the author also finds a cumulative appreciation discount of 22 percent.3
3. The author subsequently finds that this discount is positively related to loan size, time in REO, local house price movements, and being located in a judicial foreclosure state.

4

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

One plausible explanation for the existence of these (conditional) foreclosure discounts is that
such homes are, on average, of lower quality. Distressed homeowners are less likely to maintain the
property in both obvious and nonobvious ways, and this tendency will lead to a lemons discount. Two
recent studies include indicators of observable subjective quality and find that foreclosed homes
rated as fair or poor have larger-than-average foreclosure discounts (Clauretie and Daneshvary
2009; Sumell 2009). While a step in the right direction, controlling for property quality remains a
significant challenge for this literature.
Related to the quality issue is occupancy status—that is, owner, renter, or vacant. Nonowneroccupied—and especially vacant—homes that are foreclosed upon are expected to be of lower
quality. Knight (2002), Anglin, Rutherford, and Springer (2003), and Clauretie and Daneshvary
(2009) all provide evidence supporting a vacancy discount. (The latter paper also finds evidence
of a renter discount.) One suggestion here would be to also include interaction terms of occupancy
status with foreclosure to distinguish an independent effect of occupancy status from the observable
quality of the property.
It has also been suggested that the foreclosure discount may be due, in part, to certain sellers
being willing to accept a lower price in order to sell faster and avoid holding costs (for example,
property taxes, insurance, and maintenance). Notably, this explanation requires some “limit to
arbitrage” opportunities since sales at below-market prices imply positive economic rents to
intermediaries of foreclosed properties. Under this “liquidity hypothesis,” one would expect to see
foreclosed properties have a shorter time on the market. (That said, there is also evidence that
time on the market also sends a negative signal about quality, so one would need to be careful in
specifying an empirical model.)
There may also be a cash discount insofar as this reduces uncertainty about the sale and
economizes on certain closing costs. Forgey, Rutherford, and VanBuskirk (1994) and Clauretie and
Daneshvary (2009) both provide some evidence for the existence of cash discounts for home sales.
However, it’s not clear based on their specifications that this effect is any different for foreclosed
properties. Again, the use of an interaction effect between cash and foreclosure indicators would
be helpful.
Clauretie and Daneshvary (2009) report a conditional foreclosure discount of less than 10
percent after controlling for various property and neighborhood characteristics, property condition
(quality), occupancy status, time on the market, and cash sales. While this study represents the
most comprehensive analysis in terms of explaining residential sales prices using hedonic methods,
the study is limited to data for Clark County, Nevada, between 2004 and 2007.
Overall, it seems likely that foreclosure discounts exist although the magnitude may vary
significantly by location and time period. The estimated effects likely reflect a lemons discount,
with foreclosed properties having lower observable and unobservable quality. It is also possible
that some of the measured discount is related to the sellers of foreclosed properties being less
patient than a typical homeowner. Future research should strive to identify the extent to which
foreclosure discounts separately reflect quality differences or impatient sellers.

Foreclosure externalities: Do foreclosure discounts affect the value of nearby property?
Given that foreclosed properties generally sell at a discount, a natural question arises as to whether
these distressed properties, in turn, put downward sales price pressure on nearby properties,
resulting in a negative externality. According to Lee (2008), three potential channels by which such
spillover effects might occur are through poor property maintenance or negligence leading to blight,
weak property appraisals based on comparables, and an increased supply of available properties for
sale. Leonard and Murdoch (2009) further suggest that changes in nearby foreclosures foreshadow
(negative) changes in neighborhood quality, leading to an expectations effect.
Several recent papers have documented a negative relationship between nondistressed residential sales prices and the number of nearby foreclosures using hedonic regressions that control

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

for various property and neighborhood characteristics. (One other study uses the repeat-sales
method.) The studies also vary along other dimensions: the locations and time periods they evaluate,
the definitions they use for “nearby” and “foreclosure,” and whether they account for the effect of
multiple foreclosures.
Immergluck and Smith (2006) relate sales price data for 9,600 single-family properties in
Chicago sold in 1999 to foreclosures in the two prior years; the study controls for a large number
of property and neighborhood characteristics. The authors identify the number of foreclosures
at distances of one-eighth mile (one block) and one-quarter mile (two blocks). The authors find
that each foreclosure associated with a conventional loan within one-eighth mile is associated
with a 0.9 percent to 1.1 percent property price decline, depending on whether or not the median
house price in the census tract is controlled for or not. Foreclosures associated with conventional
loans located one-eighth to one-quarter mile away from a sale are estimated to have only modest
spillover effects (0.1 percent to 0.2 percent). Interestingly, foreclosures associated with governmentguaranteed loans appear to have no effect on nearby sales prices. It is not clear why foreclosures
associated with different types of loans should have differential effects; this difference merits
further investigation.
Schuetz, Been, and Ellen (2008) study residential (single- and multifamily) property sales and
foreclosure notices in New York City between 2000 and 2005. The authors identify properties with
foreclosure notices nearby nondistressed sales in both physical space (within 250 feet, 250–500
feet, and 50–1,000 feet) and time (less than and greater than eighteen months). The authors find
evidence of foreclosure spillover effects although, strangely, these measured effects appear to be
larger for foreclosures located farther away in both physical space and time. Such nonintuitive
results suggest that there may be some issues with the empirical specification—for instance, the
authors control for very few neighborhood characteristics (borough and ZIP code indicators and
physical distance to subway) and ignore recent house price movements.4 The authors also provide
some results suggesting that the negative price pressure associated with foreclosure notices is
larger when there are more of them.
Mikelbank (2008) is the first to empirically separate the spillover effects of foreclosures from
vacant/abandoned properties, using 2006 property data for Franklin County, Ohio. Intuitively,
the author finds that the negative effect of vacancies is more severe than foreclosure but is
concentrated nearby (up to 500 feet), while foreclosure-related effects are modest but persist
over longer distances (up to 1,000 feet). An important strength of this paper is the ability to
control somewhat for property quality in terms of condition and construction. The author includes
limited neighborhood-level control variables (capturing trends in demand for owner-occupied
housing) but does provide estimates using special econometric techniques designed to account
for unobserved neighborhood characteristics. Nevertheless, the use of spatial error specification
techniques has little effect on the estimated effects.
Leonard and Murdoch (2009) study sales of single-family homes in Dallas County, Texas, during
2006. Their hedonic price analysis is conditioned on a large number of property and neighborhood
characteristics, including recent house price trends. The authors delineate nearby foreclosures in
physical space according to the number located within 250, 500, 1,000, or 1,500 feet of the sale.
The authors find that properties in some stage of foreclosure depress sales prices and that each
foreclosure within 250 feet appears to have an effect of about –0.5 percent on sales prices. The
results suggest that spillover effects may exist at modest levels (–0.1 percent) even farther out in
physical space although interpretation is difficult given the model specification.
Rogers and Winter (2009) examine the effect of foreclosures on sales prices of nonforeclosed
homes in St. Louis County, Missouri, between 1998 and 2007. Foreclosure effects are measured by
rings that are jointly measured in both physical space (yards between the foreclosure and sale) and
4. In one specification, the authors include postsale foreclosure notices as an additional neighborhood control.

6

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

time (months between the sale and foreclosure). The authors consistently find that foreclosures
that are physically closer to a sale have negative price effects although (counterintuitively) the
estimated effects are as strong or stronger two years after foreclosure than six months after
foreclosure. The authors also find that the marginal impact of foreclosures decline as the number
of foreclosures increases. One shortcoming of Rogers and Winter’s analysis is the apparent lack of
temporal control variables. Another weakness is a lack of neighborhood control variables although
the authors do reestimate their empirical models using spatial generalized methods of moments
(GMM) techniques that are intended to capture some of these
effects. GMM estimation yielded results qualitatively similar The foreclosure process is costly
to ordinary least squares (OLS), although quantitatively the
to both borrowers and lenders and
measured effects were about one-half, suggesting that the lack
perhaps even society as a whole.
of neighborhood control variables is an issue.
Lin, Rosenblatt, and Yao (2009) explore property sales data
for the Chicago MSA for 2003 and 2006 and delineate foreclosure spillover effects along physical
and temporal dimensions. The authors find spillover effects for foreclosures located within ten
blocks (physical distance) and five years (temporal distance), with a nearby foreclosure in a bad
year (such as 2006) having a –8.7 percent effect on nearby property values. Foreclosure spillover
estimates for a good year (such as 2003) are found to be only half as large, thereby illustrating
the importance of housing cycles. These effects are by far the largest estimated in this nascent
literature, likely owing to limited hedonic property characteristics, the use of only ZIP code
indicators for neighborhood characteristics, and the lack of control for local property price trends.
Indeed, a literal interpretation of these results would suggest that the externalities may exceed the
value of the foreclosed property itself.
Campbell, Giglio, and Pathak (2009) study twenty years of single-family property sales from
Massachusetts (although with hedonic property and neighborhood characteristics measured
exclusively as of 2007). The authors first estimate the effect of foreclosures on sales prices without
controlling for either common (unobserved) shocks driving foreclosures and house prices or the
reverse causality from house prices to foreclosures. This preliminary exercise suggests a 7–9 percent
foreclosure discount. (This incredible result is consistent with the estimates provided by Lin,
Rosenblatt, and Yao 2009.) However, using two different “differences-in-differences” approaches
that aim to net out such confounding effects, the authors more plausibly estimate that foreclosures
within 0.05 mile lower sales prices by about 1 percent.
As an alternative to a hedonic regression, Harding, Rosenblatt, and Yao (2009) use a repeatsales approach that ostensibly holds the house and neighborhood characteristics constant. The
authors relate the difference between the sales price of each residential property and the “expected
price” based on a house price index to nearby foreclosure activity differentiated in physical space
(0–300 feet, 300–500 feet, 500–1,000 feet, and 1,000–2,000 feet) and time (the stage in the
foreclosure process). For a set of seven MSAs, they find that property sales located within 300 feet
of a foreclosed property experience about a 1 percent discount per foreclosure. (Furthermore,
the average discount falls to 0.5 percent at a distance of one-eighth mile [the same distance used
by Immergluck and Smith 2006]). The authors also find that the peak discount occurs at the time
of the foreclosure sale (before the REO sale); they attribute this peak to property neglect and
uncertainty relating to the future owners.
Overall, the empirical evidence relating to foreclosure effects on nearby property sales
prices suggests a discount. Moreover, such discounts likely dissipate quickly the farther away the
foreclosed property is from the sale in space and time. Hedonic regressions—especially those
with limited controls for property and neighborhood characteristics—likely suffer from omitted
variables problems. Repeat-sales approaches may represent an improvement insofar as they do
not require a rich set of property and neighborhood covariates. The results also highlight the
importance of controlling for local house-price trends that influence the probability of default by

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

all mortgage borrowers. (Note that this control is especially important when studying the recent
experience, which included a large number of borrowers taking extremely leveraged positions just
prior to a nationwide house price decline.)
The measured spillover effects of foreclosure are likely due to the condition of the foreclosed
property. In future research, it would be helpful to control for property quality and/or occupancy
status since it is widely conjectured that vacant foreclosed properties are of especially low quality
and attract other social problems. The remaining two other explanations for foreclosure spillovers
(lowered appraisals as a result of a foreclosure sale being treated as a comparable and an increased
supply of homes on the local market) have also not been formally investigated. The repeat-sales
approach seemingly holds more promise than the hedonic approach because it does not require
a large set of property and neighborhood covariates and can more easily be applied to many
geographic areas and over longer time periods. However, the repeat-sales approach does require
a long time series.

Conclusions
The public sector has responded in various ways to the tremendous rise in mortgage foreclosures
in recent years. The economic rationale for such interventions rests with the notion that there are
social costs, or negative externalities, associated with such events. Remarkably, prior to the recent
foreclosure crisis, there had been little economic research documenting foreclosure spillover
effects although the literature has evolved rapidly since.
This critical review of the literature suggests that foreclosed properties sell at a discount,
likely because such properties are in worse condition. Moreover, very nearby foreclosures appear
to depress the sales prices of nondistressed properties although this effect decays rapidly in
physical distance and time. That said, a good deal of variation occurs in estimates, with some being
implausibly large likely because of poorly specified empirical models. Repeat-sales approaches
also seem to hold greater promise than hedonic approaches because they are more likely to
hold property and neighborhood characteristics constant and it is easier to examine multiple
geographies and longer time periods.
A literature studying the effect of nearby foreclosures on property values has emerged over
the past five years. While its results are compelling, it can certainly be improved and expanded. As
a result, the next five years of research into this topic can be expected to be even more fruitful.

8

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

References
Anglin, Paul M., Ronald Rutherford, and Thomas M.
Springer. 2003. The trade-off between the selling price
of residential properties and time-on-the-market.
Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 26,
no. 1:95–111.
Apgar, William, and Mark Duda. 2005. Collateral
damage: The municipal impact of today’s mortgage
foreclosure boom. Report to the Homeownership
Preservation Fund, Minneapolis, Minn.
Campbell, John, Stefano Giglio, and Parag Pathak.
2009. Forced sales and house prices. NBER Working
Paper No. 14866, April.
Carroll, Thomas, Terrence Clauretie, and Helen Neill.
1997. Effect of foreclosure status on residential selling
price: Comment. Journal of Real Estate Research 13,
no. 1:95–102.
Clauretie, Terrence, and Nassar Daneshvary. 2009.
Estimating the house foreclosure discount corrected
for spatial price interdependence and endogeneity of
marketing time. Real Estate Economics 37, no. 1:43–67.
Cordell, Larry, Karen Dynan, Andreas Lehnert, Nellie
Liang, and Eileen Mauskopf. 2009. Designing loan
modifications to address the mortgage crisis and the
Making Home Affordable program. Federal Reserve
Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series
No. 2009-43, October.
Foote, Chris, Kristopher Gerardi, and Paul Willen. 2008.
Negative equity and foreclosure: Theory and evidence.
Journal of Urban Economics 64, no. 2:234–45.
Forgey, Fred A., Ronald C. Rutherford, and Michael
L. VanBuskirk. 1994. Effect of foreclosure status
on residential selling price. Journal of Real Estate
Research 9, no. 3:313–18.
Gerardi, Kristopher, and Wenli Li. 2010. Mortgage
foreclosure prevention efforts. Federal Reserve Bank
of Atlanta Economic Review 95, no. 2:1–13.
Harding, John, Eric Rosenblatt, and Vincent Yao. 2009.
The contagion effect of foreclosed properties. Journal
of Urban Economics 66, no. 3:164–78.

Knight, John. 2002. Listing price, time on market, and
ultimate selling price: Causes and effects of listing price
changes. Real Estate Economics 30, no. 2: 213–37.
Lee, Kai-yan. 2008. Foreclosure’s price-depressing
spillover effects on local properties: A literature review.
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Community Affairs
Discussion Paper No. 2008-1, September.
Leonard, Tammy, and James Murdoch. 2009. The
neighborhood effects of foreclosure. Journal of
Geographical Systems 11, no. 4:317–32.
Lin, Zhengou, Eric Rosenblatt, and Vincent Yao. 2009.
Spillover effects of foreclosures on neighborhood
property values. Journal of Real Estate Finance and
Economics 38, no. 4:387–407.
Mikelbank, Brian A. 2008. Spatial analysis of the impact
of vacant, abandoned, and foreclosed properties. Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland Office of Community Affairs
working paper. www.clevelandfed.org/Community_
Development/publications/Spatial_Analysis_Impact_
Vacant_Abandoned_Foreclosed_Properties.pdf.
Pennington-Cross, Anthony. 2006. The value of
foreclosed property. Journal of Real Estate Research
28, no. 2:193–214.
Rogers, William H., and William Winter. 2009. The
impact of foreclosures on neighboring housing sales.
Journal of Real Estate Research 31, no. 4: 455–79.
Shilling, James, John Benjamin, and C.F. Sirmans.
1990. Estimating net realizable value for distressed
real estate. Journal of Real Estate Research 5,
no. 1:129–40.
Schuetz, Jenny, Vicki Been, and Ingrid Gould Ellen.
2008. Neighborhood effects of concentrated mortgage
foreclosures. Journal of Housing Economics 17,
no. 4:306–19.
Sumell, Albert. 2009. The determinants of foreclosed
property values: Evidence from inner-city Cleveland.
Journal of Housing Research 18, no. 1:45–61.

Immergluck, Dan, and Geoff Smith. 2006. The external
costs of foreclosure: The impact of single-family
mortgage foreclosures on property values. Housing
Policy Debate 17, no. 1:57–79.

E C O N O M I C

R E V I E W

Number 3, 2010

9