View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

One Proxy at a Time:
Pursuing Social Change
through Shareholder Proposals
PAULA TKAC
The author is a financial economist and associate policy adviser in the Atlanta Fed’s
research department. She thanks Jerry Dwyer, Scott Frame, and Larry Wall for helpful
comments and Carrie Cooper for excellent research assistance.

on’t be evil. This directive is Google’s corporate motto and perhaps the most succinct proclamation of the notion of corporate social responsibility (CSR). While
it seems that no one could argue with the desire for a corporation not to “do evil,” the
related conviction, that corporations should take positive steps in order to “do good,”
is controversial. According to economics and finance textbooks, the sole goal of a corporation is to maximize shareholder wealth. But some investors believe that corporations have the power and responsibility to act to benefit others: workers, the local
community, the environment, and even humanity as a whole. These activists, both
individuals and institutions, alone and in organized groups, seek to reduce pollution,
increase workplace diversity, safeguard human rights around the world, eliminate
animal testing, or improve third world access to medicine, among other goals.
Activist investors operate from within the corporation, using their legal rights as
shareholders to place socially responsible resolutions on corporate proxy statements,
to be voted on by all shareholders at an annual meeting.1
CSR shareholder activism is a little-studied area in modern financial markets.2
This article uses a comprehensive data set to shed some economic light on several
questions, including, Why is CSR controversial? Who are these activist investors?
What firms do they target? What do they ask for, and how successful are they?

D

Should Corporations Engage in Socially Responsible Business Activities?
Socially responsible investors and activists answer this question with a resounding
yes and follow up with one of two reasons: because being socially responsible is good
business practice or because the world will be a better place with socially responsible
corporate behavior. To better understand the motivations, requests, and actions of
social resolution sponsors, let us look at each rationale in turn.
When a business case can be made for CSR, it is in both the firm’s and society’s
best interests for the firm to engage in the recommended behavior, whether it be

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

1

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

increasing the proportion of environmental packaging or strengthening international labor standards. Socially responsible actions will lead to higher profits, benefiting shareholders as well as overall social welfare. Occasionally activists argue that
there is a direct link between a change in corporate operations and cost reductions.
More typically, however, the channels through which an increase in profitability is
claimed to occur are only indirectly related to a firm’s financial performance: building goodwill and trust, increasing exposure (advertising, in effect), and improved
employee satisfaction.
In these indirect business-case justifications, consumers’ and employees’ positive
feelings are claimed to increase sales and profits. Underlying this business case for CSR
is a fundamental assumption that at least
Some investors believe that corporations
some consumers prefer buying products
that allow them to “do good” and may even
have the power and responsibility to act to
be willing to pay a little more for products or
benefit others: workers, the local commuservices that claim to help solve the world’s
nity, the environment, and even humanity
problems.3 Whole Foods Market Inc. and the
Body Shop are examples of businesses built
as a whole.
on this model. Their customers are not only
buying environmentally friendly, premium products but also, perhaps, experiencing
some satisfaction from participating in the stores’ social mission.4
Many firms that do not sell their socially responsible reputation as explicitly as
Whole Foods does also use a business case as a rationale for decisions to have a climate
change policy, to strengthen labor standards, or to make charitable donations. Even
if no direct or easily measurable relation links these actions and firm revenues, the
firm may perceive that being a good corporate citizen results in positive publicity and
the potential for greater customer goodwill and loyalty.
In all of these cases, socially responsible corporate actions are good business that
benefits shareholders. Given the right incentives to maximize profits, corporate management should actively seek out and implement such strategies. Therefore, while
some activist investors will cite a business case for their proposals, such opportunities
are likely to be exploited even without a formal shareholder proposal.
Instead, most proxy proposals implicitly rely on the second rationale for responsible corporate behavior: a corporation has a responsibility to society and the community. CSR advocates believe the world will be a better place if corporations undertake
socially motivated policies and actions. One prominent and definitive statement of
this philosophy was stated in a letter by Google’s founders, Larry Page and Sergey
Brin, to prospective shareholders prior to the initial public stock offering in 2004: “We
believe strongly that in the long term we will be better served—as shareholders and
in all other ways—by a company that does good things for the world even if we forgo
some short term gains.” CSR activists see corporations as powerful tools for social
change because of their economic power and public visibility, and some activists are
quite willing to sacrifice some financial gains in order to achieve these goals.
Not everyone agrees that a CSR agenda benefits society. A notable example of
this viewpoint is Milton Friedman’s well-known 1970 New York Times Magazine editorial titled “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits.”5 At its
heart, the argument is not one over the desirability of doing good deeds but over the
role of corporations in the provision of such services. Opponents argue that charitable
services—for instance, improving the living standard of laborers in Southeast Asia—
are best provided by individuals through other organizations such as charitable organizations and churches. Firms, it is argued, are organized to provide goods and services,

2

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

and everyone is better off if firms limit themselves to pursuing maximizing profits as
their sole objective.
The concern here is not that firm shareholders are necessarily worse off if the
firm pursues a costly socially responsible agenda but rather that the economy as a
whole will suffer.6 If firms have dual objectives, capital will not be allocated according to its most productive use given the general legal and social environment. This
efficiency loss can be translated into a welfare loss for the economy as a whole—a
drag on the level and possibly the growth rate of the standard of living. Often proponents of CSR draw a distinction between what’s good for a corporation (maximizing
profits) and what’s good for society (less pollution, higher wages, etc.) with little or
no regard for the costs of such policies in terms of less production of goods and services.
With an efficient capital market to optimize the production of goods and services and
return maximal profits to shareholders, social goals are in a better position to be met
by other means, including private donations (out of the corporate profits) and nongovernmental organizations.
The conflict between these two opposing views on the social responsibility of
corporations is personified by social activists who would like corporations to maintain a dual objective and firm management who are compensated, both implicitly (in
the labor market for CEOs) and explicitly via their pay packages (such as options,
performance-based pay, etc.), for the financial performance of the firm. CSR activists
have a large toolbox of potential strategies to attempt to influence corporations even
if they are not stockholders. For example, People for the Ethical Treatment of
Animals (PETA) uses advertising, public outreach and education campaigns, and
demonstrations to raise awareness of its concerns and promote change. An important
complement to these strategies, for those activists who are or become stockholders,
is the shareholder proposal (also known as a shareholder-sponsored resolution).
Activists can use these proposals to lobby the management at individual firms to
undertake CSR reform such as tightening environmental controls and implementing
antidiscrimination policies, among others.

1. Many activist investors use shareholder proposals as part of a larger campaign to effect social
change. Some activists use additional strategies such as media campaigns, consumer boycotts, and
divestment programs in which stock is not held in firms that are pursuing socially undesirable policies or activities.
2. Most studies of shareholder activism in the financial research literature focus on shareholder proposals relating to issues of corporate governance. For a survey of such papers see Karpoff (1998),
Black (1997), and Gillan and Starks (1998). Chidambaran and Woidtke (1999) and Thomas and
Cotter (2005) are examples of studies that include statistics on social proposals as well. Other literatures have focused on shareholder activism more from a sociological, rather than an economic,
perspective. Examples include Profitt (2002) and Graves, Waddock, and Rehbein (2001).
3. The 2001 Corporate Citizen Watch Survey (Hill&Knowlton/Harris Interactive) found that 36 percent
of consumers consider corporate citizenship an important factor in their purchasing decisions.
4. Whole Foods’ “Declaration of Interdependence” (www.wholefoodsmarket.com/company/declaration.
html) emphasizes sustainability, stewardship of the environment, and community involvement. The
Body Shop’s values include promoting human rights, eliminating animal testing, and environmental
protection (www.thebodyshopinternational.com/web/tbsgl/values.jsp).
5. New York Times Magazine, September 13, 1970. See also “Rethinking the Social Responsibility
of Business,” www.reason.com/0510/fe.mf.rethinking.shtml, October 2005.
6. If firm shareholders know of the CSR agenda of firm management, they can make their own decision
as to whether to own stock, thus relegating investor “harm” to the cases in which management
takes unobservable or unexpected actions that meet social goals, while decreasing profits, but are
not valued by some shareholders.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

The Basics of Shareholder Proposals
The process of submitting a shareholder proposal to be included on a proxy statement is regulated by Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) Rule 14a-8. Any
shareholder who has continuously held shares for one year worth at least $2,000, or
1 percent of firm value, may submit at most one proposal of 500 words or less per
annual meeting. The costs to the submitting shareholder are not large—the firm pays
for the printing of proxy statements and mailings to shareholders.7 However, the submitting shareholder is required to be preActivist investors use their legal rights as
sent at the annual meeting to present the
proposal to shareholders.
shareholders to place socially responsible
A shareholder cannot submit just any
resolutions on corporate proxy statements,
proposal, however, and be assured that it
to be voted on by all shareholders at an
will be included on the proxy and put to a
shareholder vote. The firm’s management
annual meeting.
can petition the SEC to exclude a proposal
on several grounds, including cases in which the proposal (1) reflects a personal
grievance, (2) requires the firm to violate state, federal, or international law, (3) relates
to operations accounting for less than 5 percent of the firm’s assets, sales, and revenue,
or (4) deals with a “matter relating to the company’s ordinary business operations.”8
This last rationale is the one that most firms cite when seeking to exclude social
activists’ proposals. The pivotal term here is “ordinary business operations,” which
includes day-to-day management of the firm, production, and the workforce as well as
those issues on which stockholders “would not be in a position to make an informed
judgment.” Each exclusion needs to be approved by the SEC and is requested at the
discretion of firm management. This discretion means that some firms will request
permission to exclude proposals that other firms allow to go on the proxy statements.
Proposals that are excluded are said to be “omitted”; examples include a call for NBC
to fire Tom Brokaw and a request for Shoney’s to report on their equal opportunity
employment practices.
Shareholders may resubmit proposals each year, but firms are allowed to exclude
proposals that previously did not receive more than 3 to 10 percent of the vote, depending on how many times the proposal was voted on previously and the amount of time
between submissions. These exclusionary criteria and resubmission requirements
are in place to deter repetitive frivolous proposals and their associated costs to the
firm and ultimately to shareholders in general.
Shareholder proposals, even if they receive a majority vote of the shareholders,
are precatory, or nonbinding, on corporate management. Therefore, shepherding a
proposal through to a vote and even garnering widespread shareholder support are
not guarantees of corporate action or even a response in the form of an open dialogue.
This feature reduces the level of shareholder proposals. Were majority-supported
proposals binding, there would likely be more proposals, more petitioning of the SEC
for omission, more public campaigns to woo shareholder votes, and more firms going
private to avoid this cost of being publicly owned.

Data on Shareholder Proposals
The data used here to study socially responsible shareholder activism are from the
Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC) and include all social shareholder
proposals monitored by the IRRC over the 1992–2002 period. IRRC is an independent
corporation providing research and analysis on corporate proxy activity to a variety
of institutional investors and organizations. This particular data set does not include

4

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

any corporate governance proposals related to issues such as board structure, CEO
compensation, and poison pills.9 The raw data contain information on the proposal
topic (an IRRC code), a more precise statement of the resolution, the proponent/
sponsor, the corporation targeted, year, status (withdrawn/voted on/omitted), and
percentage vote, if applicable. In total, during this period there were 2,829 social
shareholder proposals.
To better organize the analysis, each proposal was assigned an additional topic
code (see the sidebar on page 16). For example, proposals calling for the restriction
of gene-engineered food sales by Procter and Gamble and actions to reduce nuclear
accidents at PG&E power plants were both categorized by IRRC as “energy and environment” proposals. The new topic code in this article places the former proposal in
the “food/agriculture” category while the latter is categorized as an “energy” proposal.
Similarly, I aggregate the IRRC data on proposals concerning withdrawal from South
Africa, maquiladora operations, and human rights for workers in Burma into a topic
titled “international operations.” In addition, a categorization was created to sort the
resolution proponents into the six types described below: Individual shareholders,
pension funds, unions, religious organizations, social organizations, and socially
responsible mutual funds. Finally, the data were expanded via extensive research to
determine the final outcomes of the proposals that were withdrawn by proponents
before the annual meeting. Using Internet searches, proponent and company Web
sites, annual reports, and personal contacts, information was found on 298 of the 859
withdrawn proposals and coded to indicate the type of corporate-proponent interaction
(for example, action by the firm, dialogue, no action) that prompted the withdrawal.

Who Engages in Social Activism via Shareholder Proposals?
The shareholders who sponsor social resolutions can be categorized into several distinct groups according to their goals, motivation, and level of organization.
1.

2.

Individuals—Investors who meet the ownership requirements with their individual stockholdings in a particular firm. These investors typically do not act in a
coordinated fashion. A few, such as Evelyn Davis, have risen to the level of “corporate gadfly” because of their persistent sponsorship and vocal participation at
annual meetings (see Trigaux 2002). Among these activists, the motivation to
pursue shareholder activism stems from personal preferences.
Pension funds and endowments—Large institutional investors consisting mostly
of defined benefit public pension funds (NYC, CalPers, etc). While a pension
fund should arguably be motivated to pursue financial returns on behalf of beneficiaries, some papers have argued that these public pension funds are pursuing
political goals.10

7. The SEC reports that the average estimated cost to the firm of including a shareholder proposal
is $87,000—$50,000 for printing distribution and tabulation of the votes and $37,000 to determine
if the proposal should be included. This cost has fallen more recently because of the SEC’s approval
of the Internet as a means of distributing proxies and shareholder information.
8. Other permissible reasons for exclusion of a proposal include duplication of another proposal,
issues relating to board membership elections, cases where the firm has already implemented the
proposal or the action is not within the power of the firm to implement, and proposals dealing
with specific amounts of cash or dividends. For a full discussion, see SEC Rule 14a-8.
9. The data set does include proposals to increase the ethnic and gender diversity of corporate boards.
10. See Romano (2001) and, for a more detailed study of the activism programs of several public
pensions, Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

3.

4.

5.

6.

6

Unions—Labor unions such as the AFL-CIO and the UBCJWA (carpenters and
joiners) that manage multiemployer defined benefit pension funds. While the data
include proposals from eighteen different unions, only a few sponsored more than
one proposal from 1992 to 2002. In the years since 2002 the unions have withdrawn
from social advocacy and focused entirely on corporate governance proposals.
Unions have engaged in the political process through donations, endorsements, and
policy advocacy since their inception, so their interest in social shareholder activism
is not surprising. While union pensions have the same goal as public and private
pensions (to meet beneficiary obligations), unions also have another well-defined
motive—benefiting union workers, particularly the members of their union. Union
pension funds pursue social shareholder activism most strongly among the firms
that employ their members. For example the Communication Workers of America
submitted proposals at GTE, AT&T, and Ameritech.
Religious organizations—The Interfaith Center on Corporate Responsibility (ICCR)
is the primary coordinator of shareholder proposals by religious organizations.
ICCR is a coalition of 275 faith-based institutional investors; members (and examples) include churches (the Episcopal Church), pensions (the United Methodist
Church pension), orders (the Sisters of Charity), faith-based health care corporations (the Advocate Health Care System), and religious foundations (the Catholic
Foundation/Aquinas Funds). As evidenced by this list, ICCR member organizations
are largely though not exclusively Christian. In their own words, ICCR members
“utilize religious investments and other resources to change unjust or harmful
corporate policies, working for peace, economic justice and stewardship of the
Earth.” The motivations of this group draw on common religious values, and the
goals center on social and economic justice.
Social organizations—Thirty-six different nonreligious organizations, each founded
to promote social change of a relatively limited scope. For example, the mission
of the Jessie Smith Noyes Foundation is to “protect and restore Earth’s natural
systems and promote a sustainable society,” and it sponsors proposals seeking to
restrict gene-modified products and limit environmental hazards. PETA, on the
other hand, is solely interested in issues related to animal rights. Shareholder
activism is a slightly less natural strategy for these groups, compared to religious
organizations, since they may not have a natural pool of invested assets, such as
a pension, on which to base their stockholder activism. Also in contrast to religious
organizations is the individual, noncollective nature of their activism.
Socially responsible mutual funds—Firms such as Calvert, Domini, and Pax that
manage mutual funds for investors who want to invest their money according to
ethical guidelines. Effectively, these firms engage in shareholder activism as a
business, and this motivation distinguishes this group from the others described
here. These funds typically follow a two-part strategy: screening out investments
that are not, by their definition, socially responsible, and investing in some such
stocks while targeting them with proposals to change their behavior. These
mutual funds strive to provide both the performance and social criteria that their
investors demand. This goal may lead socially responsible mutual funds to be
more strategic than other activist investors. Specifically, fund managers likely
weigh costs and benefits, in terms of return performance, to decide which stocks
to screen out and which to pursue with shareholder resolutions. Not surprisingly,
since their shareholder activism is part of the service being sold by these funds,
mutual funds report more information on investment policies, activities, and
results than other socially responsible investor groups.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1
Number of Proposals over Time by Proponent Group
180
Religious organizations

160

Number of proposals

140
120
100
80
Individuals

SR mutual funds

60
Social
organizations

40
Unions

Pensions

20
0
1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

Socially Responsible Shareholder Activism over Time
On average, 257 different proposals were submitted each year between 1992 and
2002. While the yearly number of proposals has remained relatively stable over time,
ranging from 212 in 1995 to 303 in 1997, this stability masks some interesting comparisons and trends across the various proponent groups.
Figure 1 provides a look at the number of proposals made by each type of proponent over the years 1992–2002. A few features of the data stand out. During each
year, religious organizations made the largest number of proposals. This pattern may
reflect the fact that religious organization proponents are predominantly members
of the umbrella organization ICCR and agree on many social issues. The existence
of ICCR therefore facilitates proposals via economies of scale in organization and
implementation. The social organizations group, in contrast, is made up of many distinct groups with no common agenda (for example, PETA and Friends of the Earth).
Thus each group must mount its own campaign to address the issue(s) in which it
is interested. Individuals, like social organizations, are also a diverse group but post
a large number of proposals in aggregate because of the presence of a few very
active investors; for example, Evelyn Davis accounts for 69 (14 percent) of the 507
proposals submitted by individuals.
The second feature that stands out is the recent rise in shareholder activism by
socially responsible mutual funds. In 2001 and 2002 these mutual funds submitted
more proposals than individuals did and nearly two-thirds the number sponsored by
religious organizations. It is unclear what motivated this growth in activism, but it
coincides with the bear market of 2000–02. Socially responsible mutual funds may
have turned to activism as a way to add value for investors when the return performance on the portfolios suffered. The relative inactivity of unions in the social proposal arena is evident as well. In recent years the unions have become much more
active in corporate governance–related proposals rather than the social proposals
analyzed here.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table
Top Fifty Targeted Corporations, 1992–2002
Number of
Shareholder Proposals

Company
General Electric
Chevron/Texaco
Exxon/Exxon Mobil
Philip Morris
AT&T
General Motors
JPMorgan Chase
RJR Nabisco
DuPont (E.I.) de Nemours
Citicorp/Citigroup
PepsiCo
United Technologies
Wal-Mart Stores
Loews
Unocal
Bristol-Myers Squibb
IBM
Johnson & Johnson
GTE
Ford Motor Company
UST
Lockheed Martin
Boeing
Atlantic Richfield
Merck
Procter & Gamble
American Brands
Minnesota Mining & Manufacturing
Raytheon
American International Group
Baker Hughes
Kmart
McDonald’s
Abbott Laboratories
Dillard’s
Donnelley (R.R.) & Sons
American Express
Lilly (Eli)
Time Warner
Caterpillar
Cooper Industries
Disney (Walt)
Eastman Kodak
Aetna
American Home Products
Chrysler
Sears Roebuck
Allied Signal
Dayton Hudson
Anheuser-Busch

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

8

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

86
64
60
54
46
42
38
38
37
35
35
30
29
28
26
25
25
25
24
23
23
23
22
21
19
19
18
18
18
17
17
17
17
16
16
16
15
15
15
15
14
14
14
13
13
13
13
13
13
12

Thus, shareholder proposals are a nontrivial and consistent feature of the modern
financial market. But what are these
activists asking for? What firms are they
targeting? And how successful are they in
prompting a change in corporate behavior?

What Corporations Are Targeted by
Social Activists?
During the period studied, 566 different
corporations were targeted by social proposals. Two hundred one were targeted
only once while seventy-three were targeted
ten times or more (see the table). Recall
that by SEC rules, multiple shareholders
may not submit the same resolution in the
same proxy season. Therefore, these numbers represent distinct proposals and
involve no double counting.
What drives an activist’s decision to target one corporation rather than another?
Foremost among the targets are corporations that are pursuing policies or operations that activists wish to change. These
targets include manufacturing firms producing pollution in their production process and
firms operating in countries where labor is
cheap and abundant. Target firms also may
have market power that activists want to tap
in order to economically force a change in
other agents’ behavior. Among these would
be firms that buy inputs from suppliers that
have vendors in cheap labor countries.
Finally, high-profile target firms are likely
to value consumer goodwill and may undertake actions for this reason; these firms are
not engaging in explicitly irresponsible
behavior but have the “name” to aid in social
change. Therefore, it is not surprising that
manufacturing firms are targeted more than
service or technology firms, which are much
less likely to pollute and employ outsourced
labor. Larger firms are targeted more than
smaller firms with less economic power and
less name recognition.11
For the socially responsible mutual
funds, there may also be an unstated relation between the expected return on a
corporation’s stock and its likelihood of
being screened out of the portfolio. The

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

fund manager’s desire to post good fund performance implies that the higher the
expected return on the stock of a firm, or the lower its correlation with the remainder of the portfolio, the more likely a stock is not to be screened out but rather to be
held by the fund and targeted.
This list shows that activists are actively and directly targeting only a small fraction
of public corporations. While General Electric, the most targeted firm in this period,
faced an average of eight proposals per year, the fiftieth-ranked firm received only an
average of one per year. Indeed, most publicly traded corporations in the U.S. market
did not experience even one proposal in
this time period. It is important to note,
Shepherding a proposal through to a vote
however, that there may well be a larger,
and even garnering widespread shareholder
indirect effect on firms that are economsupport are not guarantees of corporate
ically similar to the targeted firms. Successful activism may alter the actions of some
action or even an open dialogue.
corporations, thereby putting pressure on
their competitors to follow suit because they do not want to be a target in the future.
These positive byproducts of shareholder activism may also guide an activist’s choice
of targets. Firms that attract more media attention and at which success is more likely
will strengthen these indirect effects and are more likely to be targeted.
One measure of whether success is more likely is if a corporation has a reputation
of being a good corporate citizen. If so, the company’s top management may be more
willing to listen and to act on the concerns of socially activist investors. To assess
whether this type of company is targeted, the data on all proposal targets are matched
with a list of the 100 Best Corporate Citizens, compiled each year by Business Ethics
magazine. To be on the list, a firm must score well in its service to four stakeholder
groups: stockholders, employees, customers, and community. In 2000–02, the years
for which Business Ethics created its list, 14.5 percent of the proposals submitted
were targeted at firms that are good corporate citizens. This result suggests that
activists also include the likelihood of success in their calculus when choosing proposal targets rather than targeting only poor corporate citizens.12

What Are the Activists Asking For?
The answer to this question comes in two parts. First, on what topics or social issues
are the activists submitting resolutions? Second, what type of action is being requested?
For example, does the resolution ask for a report to be issued or for a substantive
change in operations?
A full list of all resolution topic categories can be found in the sidebar on page 16.
Overall, the three most common topics for shareholder proposals are international
conduct, environmental issues, and antidiscrimination; the least common topics are
media/TV and animal rights. One way to understand this ranking is to recall that
shareholder activism is a tool to effect social change, a tool that is complementary to
other methods such as political action, publicity campaigns, and boycotts. Important
issues of the day that a large fraction of the population is concerned about are more
likely to be pursued by all methods, including shareholder activism. This reasoning
might explain the prevalence of resolutions involving international conduct during a
11. See Romano (2001), Thomas and Cotter (2005), and Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999) for studies
of the targeting decisions of activist investors in the case of governance proposals.
12. The targeting of these corporations may also reflect some disagreement among activists as to
what constitutes good citizenship.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

period that included the passage of NAFTA and rising concerns over globalization.
The level of public support or awareness is not the only driver of shareholder activism.
The relatively small number of proposals on animal rights, for example, may reflect
both a relative lack of widespread support along with a preference among these
activists for other methods such as reducing consumer demand for animal products.
The characteristics and motivations of the various proponent groups are also
helpful for understanding the distribution of social issues pursued (see Figure 2). As
a group, social organizations have the least concentrated activism strategy, submitting proposals in fifteen of the sixteen topics. This pattern is not surprising considering that social organizations are a very diverse group, each with their own issue of
concern. A similar observation holds for activism by individuals. In some issues, such
as energy, animal rights, or reproductive
issues, social organizations and individuals
Successful activism may alter the actions of
some corporations, thereby putting pressure are responsible for all, or very nearly all, of
the proposed resolutions.
on their competitors to follow suit because
In contrast, pension funds have the
they do not want to be a target in the future. most concentrated proposal strategy, with
almost 70 percent of their proposals within
the topic of international conduct, predominantly related to labor issues and antidiscrimination policies overseas. This concentration aligns with another significant area of
pension fund proposals, domestic antidiscrimination issues. What explains the activism
of pension funds in these areas and not others? These topics are in some ways the least
controversial in the socially responsible universe. It is difficult to find a person who
would mount an argument in favor of discrimination based on age, race, gender, or other
personal characteristics. Since the pension funds pursuing activism are public funds representing government workers in their states, they are subject to the scrutiny of a
diverse group of constituents, including state legislatures. It is plausible that this scrutiny
would lead pension funds to pursue issues on which there is the most consensus.
Unions sponsor a large number of employment-related proposals (for example,
international conduct and domestic labor). Some of these proposals, such as those
asking for higher wages in nonunion jobs or better working conditions overseas, can
be seen both as a concern for economic justice and as a way to benefit union employment. When the nonunion workers are direct substitutes for union labor, a higher
wage for nonunion workers makes the union workers relatively more attractive. In
addition, the labor movement began as a social movement and has long included political activism; issues like economic justice and the need for workers to unite to put
pressure on corporations to act ethically are part of union history and culture. Thus
shareholder activism can be seen as a modern tool in a long history of union activism.13
Like pension funds, socially responsible mutual funds serve a heterogeneous
group of investors or beneficiaries. Mutual fund investors, however, can directly
guide their investments to funds that they prefer—in this case, where their individual preferences include a desire for high performance and some shareholder activism
activity. These mutual funds then would be expected to engage in proposals that
match the priorities of a range of socially responsible investors. Socially responsible
mutual funds do indeed have a diverse strategy, splitting their proposal activity more
evenly than pension funds across environmental issues, antidiscrimination, international conduct, and food/agriculture. Implicit in their choice of activism issues and
targets is, of course, the motivation to invest in firms that are likely to perform well.
On the question of the type of action requested by activists, recall that shareholder
proposals are, for many activists, only one step in a long campaign to effect a change in

10

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2
Distribution of Topics by Proponent
80

Percent of proponent’s total proposal activity

70

Individuals
Pensions
Unions

60

Religious organizations
Social organizations
SR mutual funds

50
40
30
20
10
0
io

at

n

in

c
is

An

tid

rim

En

v

nm
ir o

en

l

r

s
s
c.
ct
re
ns
es
m
ht
is
du
ca
su
po
ar
m
rig
is
on
ea
th
ire
—
c
f
e
al
w
s
al
l
,
iv
e
/
m
e
a
o
t
i
y
u
H
n
r
m
cc
uc
An
ss
io
ta
Do
li
ba
at
od
ili
ia
rn
pr
to
M
l,
oc
te
Re
o
S
In
h
co
Al

ta

bo

tic
es

la

.
y
re
rf
ns
TV
lic
tu
io
pe
a/
ul
po
ut
R
di
b
ic
e
i
S
e
r
g
tr
at
M
y—
or
on
/a
rp
pa
lc
od
Co
ca
Fo
EO
i
t
C
li
Po

En

er

gy

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

corporate policies or actions. Therefore, what activists ask for and what they want may be
two different things. The design of a shareholder resolution is a strategic one: Ask for too
much and you may get nothing, ask for too little and risk leaving your objective unmet.
Often activists claim to adopt the latter strategy as a way to open the door to future proposals or dialogue. Given these considerations, it is plausible that activists are asking
for some corporate action in their proposals that is less than or equal to their final goal.
With this observation in mind, what are activists asking for? Figure 3 displays the
content of shareholder resolutions coded by the requested action. In principle,
activists could ask for any of the following actions in their specific proposal:14
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.

make a contribution or extend financial aid;
disclose information or issue a report;
change a corporate policy unrelated to production or main business;
fundamentally change operations, production, or marketing practices, including
price; or
research or review an issue.

The most common type of action requested is a well-defined change in corporate
policy or a fundamental change in operations (items 3 and 4 above). Examples of a
requested change in corporate policy are the endorsement of the MacBride Principles
(nondiscrimination in Northern Ireland) or a call to increase board diversity. Policy
13. Interestingly, in more recent years (since the end of this data set in 2002), unions have switched
their shareholder activism strategy to sponsor corporate governance proposals rather than call
for socially responsible firm behavior. See Thomas and Cotter (2005).
14. This categorization was designed by the author and each proposal was assigned an action code
based on the description of the resolution supplied by the IRRC.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 3
Action Requested in Shareholder Proposals
1000
900
800

Number of proposals

700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
Contribution/
aid

Disclosure

Change
corporate policy

Change product/
operations

Research/
review

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

changes like this are requests for solid action but do not relate directly to the firm’s
operations or the selling of its main product. In contrast, a proposal asking Philip
Morris to stop selling tobacco products cuts to the core of the firm’s business or
profits. Other examples of these proposals are a request to reduce carbon dioxide
emissions or to change pricing policy to make drugs cheaper in developing countries.
Actions requiring a substantive change in production methods or those that fundamentally affect a firm’s core business are the most likely to be eligible for omission by
the SEC and are hence the least likely to be successful.15
The second most common proposal type is one requesting disclosure of information that the corporation already possesses, such as an equal employment
opportunity report. One of the most common disclosure requests is for information
on environmental impact and compliance with the Ceres Principles, a ten-point
code of environmental corporate conduct formulated by the Ceres organization.16
The disclosure proposal typically serves one of two purposes: either as a first step
in establishing an issue as worthy of corporate concern or to facilitate monitoring as
a follow-up to corporate action.
Much less often, shareholders request that a firm conduct a review of a social
issue (for example, gender pay equity or suppliers’ labor standards). Implicit in these
requests is the ultimate disclosure of information compiled as a result of the review
or research process. Finally, about 4 percent of proposals (105 of 2,826) request that
the corporation initiate or discontinue contributions to a particular social cause; the
most common requests related to reproductive issues. Not surprisingly, perhaps,
these requests come from individual investors and religious and social organizations.
Pension funds, socially responsible mutual funds, and unions did not sponsor any
such proposals during this period, perhaps reflecting a desire to pursue less specific
and potentially controversial proposals.
With the exception of the requests for contributions, all shareholder groups proposed all types of proposals with respect to the actions desired on the part of the

12

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

corporation. Unions, in particular, focused on disclosure requests related to their
interest in labor standards for overseas production operations and corporate political
contributions. This information would not otherwise be available, and, without it, no
further campaign to change corporate policy or operations could be attempted.

How Successful Are Activists?
It is difficult to observe the success of shareholder activism. True success occurs
when the corporation takes the action desired by the shareholder. However, the ultimate
goal of proposal sponsors is not always obvious and often is not confined to the action
requested in the proposal. For example,
an activist asking for a report on radiation
The design of a shareholder resolution is
emissions may be ultimately trying to get
a strategic one: Ask for too much and you
the firm to reduce emissions or perhaps
may get nothing, ask for too little and risk
even to close down a plant. In the analysis
here, the focus is on the final disposition
leaving your objective unmet.
of shareholder proposals as indicators of
activist success: Is the proposal omitted by the SEC? Is it withdrawn by the sponsoring organization? Or is it carried to a vote of shareholders? Finally, does the corporation
actually meet the requests for action?
A few more details regarding the resolution process will be helpful in interpreting the data on activist success. The actual filing of a social resolution depends largely
on the shareholder or group sponsoring the resolution. Institutional shareholders
such as socially responsible mutual funds, pension funds, and religious organizations
often attempt a dialogue with the company prior to pursuing a resolution.17 It is not
unreasonable to assume that individuals may e-mail or call to voice their opinions,
but the likelihood of a corporate response to such an approach is relatively low
versus dialogue with a larger, institutional investor. Thus the fact that a resolution is
even sponsored may indicate that initial attempts to change corporate behavior or
actions have failed. This possibility suggests that some shareholder activism occurs
under the radar and that the analysis of resolution data may understate the success
of activists’ efforts.
Although neither omitted nor withdrawn resolutions result in a shareholder vote,
these two outcomes are very different with respect to assessing activist success. An
omitted resolution is one that has been actively challenged by the firm. Moreover, the
firm’s opinion that this resolution concerns matters that are not within the shareholders’ purview is officially supported by the SEC. Effectively, omitted proposals are
dead proposals and a clear instance of activist failure at using a proxy proposal to
prompt social change. In contrast, a withdrawn resolution usually signals some type
of action on the part of the corporation—dialogue, agreement to resolution, or some
other compromise. Withdrawal can be viewed as indicating some level of success.18
Indeed, as shown below, the data support this association as well.
15. The next section includes a discussion of this issue.
16. See www.ceres.org for more information on the Ceres Principles and the Ceres coalition of institutional investors and corporations.
17. For an interesting case study of TIAA-CREF negotiations on corporate governance proposals, see
Carleton, Nelson, and Weisbach (1998).
18. Further strengthening this view is the low cost of continuing a proposal through to a vote. The
sponsoring shareholder needs only to show up at the annual meeting. Thus, there seems to be no
obvious reason for an activist shareholder to withdraw a resolution other than to please firm management in return for some corporate action.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 4
Distribution of Proposal Outcomes by Proponent
70

Percent of proponent’s proposals

60

Individuals
Pension funds
Unions

Religious organizations
Social organizations
SR mutual funds

50
40
30

20
10
0
Omitted

Voted on

Withdrawn

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

The interpretation of proposals that go to a shareholder vote is even less clear.19
Since a corporation is not bound to enact a shareholder resolution even if it receives
a majority of the shareholder votes, there is no reason to think that a vote percentage
gives much of an indication of the likelihood of corporate action. Vote percentages can,
however, be seen as a measure of the depth of shareholder support, and in this sense
higher totals may be an achievement for certain proposals sponsors, buttressing their
other efforts for social change and allowing the campaign to continue with resubmission
of the proposal in the future.
With these observations in mind, we turn to the data (see Figure 4). Overall,
17 percent of proposals are omitted via petitioning of the SEC. Across proponent
groups, individual investors are the least successful when judged by the percentage
of proposals omitted. Nearly 45 percent of proposals sponsored by individuals are
omitted (as are roughly 20 percent of proposals by unions and social organizations).
In contrast, less than 10 percent of proposals sponsored by socially responsible mutual
funds, religious organizations, and pension funds are omitted. The low levels of omitted proposals by socially responsible mutual funds and religious organizations are
likely the result of their expertise in submitting proposals and choosing targets.
Via the ICCR, religious organizations have a great deal of experience running coordinated activism campaigns and thus can be expected to be selective and efficient in
their proposal activity. Similarly, socially responsible mutual funds are selling their
activism as a service to fund investors, implying that they have a strong profit incentive
to be successful.
The higher omission rates partly reflect the topic of the proposals submitted by
the sponsoring groups. For example, reproductive issues are sponsored by only individuals and a few social organizations, and 78 percent of these proposals are omitted,
most on the grounds of a violation of proxy rules or the ordinary business exemption.
And, as mentioned earlier, pension funds tend to sponsor proposals on less controversial social issues.

14

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Interestingly, of the five types of action, proposals requesting a fundamental
change in production or operations are the least likely to be omitted (12 percent). This
fact might seem surprising given that matters relating to the company’s ordinary
business operations can be omitted under rule 14a-8. The low omission rate of these
proposals may reflect a more nuanced interpretation of the rule via precedent from
prior SEC decisions. Many proposals that directly relate to a firm’s core business are
allowed to continue to a shareholder vote. Examples of such proposals that went to
a vote include a proposal to Gerber Foods to eliminate direct advertising of infant formula and a call for General Electric to withdraw from the weapons business.
Roughly half of all proposals (52 perA withdrawn resolution usually signals
cent) are taken to a shareholder vote. Of
these, the average level of shareholder
some type of action on the part of the corposupport is 8.2 percent while the median is
ration—dialogue, agreement to resolution,
7 percent. Indeed, only four of the 1,472 proor some other compromise—and can be
posals in the data set that went to a shareholder vote won the support of more than
viewed as indicating some level of success.
50 percent of the shareholders.20 The low
vote percentage may reflect little support among the larger group of shareholders or the
withheld votes of large institutional investors. Conventional (non–socially responsible)
mutual funds and many pension funds and endowments commonly withhold votes on
social issues, but this abstention is effectively counted as a vote against the proposal.21
Withdrawn proposals account for almost a third of all social proposals. The relative rates of withdrawal across proponent groups are consistent with the supposition
that withdrawal of a proposal indicates some dialogue, compromise, or action on the
part of the corporations. Individual shareholders and social organizations hold smaller
stock positions than organizations like socially responsible mutual funds, unions, or
religious organizations. Thus their ability to gain the attention of corporate management is much lower. Indeed, individuals and social organizations have the lowest
rates of withdrawal of their proposals, 3 percent and 15 percent, respectively, compared to withdrawal rates of 40 to 45 percent for unions, religious organizations, and
socially responsible mutual funds.
19. Voted-on proposals are often resubmitted in subsequent years, indicating a clear lack of action
on the part of the corporation following the prior submission. These same proposals, however,
disappear from the data at some point; this disappearance may reflect either a satisfactory corporate
response or the termination of an activist campaign due to the lack of the potential for success.
Thomas and Cotter (2005), using data from SEC filings and press releases, report a corporate
response rate of 0.05 percent for voted-on social proposals.
20. Information regarding a corporate response was available for three of these four proposals that
received a majority shareholder vote. CBRL Group Inc. (the publicly traded parent company of
Cracker Barrel) explicitly adopted the antidiscrimination policy requested in the proposal while the
other two firms appear to have substantively undertaken the actions requested. In one case, current
JCPenney rules demand “strict compliance with all applicable laws and regulations of the countries of
manufacture” after a 1996 proposal to report on labor standards for overseas suppliers. Additionally,
while no definitive response of Chase Manhattan Bank (formerly Chemical Bank) was found following
a proposal to “support new international financial safeguards” in 1996, the current environment
initiatives for JPMorgan Chase include participation in several environmental lending standards.
21. For shareholder proposals related to corporate governance, rather than social responsibility,
studies show that the vote totals and the support of institutional investors is much higher. This
pattern is not surprising in that governance proposals are aimed at increasing firm value, an
objective on which all shareholders are presumed to agree. See Karpoff (1998) for a survey and
Thomas and Cotter (2005) for more recent vote totals.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Examples of Proposals by Topic

Diversity/nondiscrimination
• EEO reports
• Board diversity
• Predatory lending
• Report on glass ceiling
• Domestic partner benefits (both pro and con)
• Sexual orientation nondiscrimination (both
pro and con)
Environmental
• Adopt Valdez/Ceres Principles
• Radiation releases
• Greenhouse gases (CO2 emissions)
• “Pure Profit” environment risks
• Alaska National Wildlife Refuge drilling
Domestic labor
• Workplace standards
• Health and safety policy
• Plant closings
International conduct
• World debt crisis (debt cancellation
criteria/policy)
• Foreign operations in Northern Ireland,
South Africa, Burma, China, Nigeria, and
maquilidoras
• NAFTA
• Labor standards for overseas suppliers
• Child/slave labor
• ILO standards
• Implement MacBride Principles
Alcohol, tobacco, firearms
• Decrease youth smoking, tobacco sales
• Smokefree restaurants
• Gun sales
Reproductive issues
• Contributions to abortion providers
• Contraception warnings
Social issues—miscellaneous
• Matching shareholder gifts
• Charitable contributions (both pro and con)
• Social criteria for financial decisions

16

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

Health care
• Health care policy and reform
• Drug pricing/restraint
• Marketing of infant formula
Animal rights
• Animal research
Military
• Foreign military sales and contracts
• Star wars/space weapons
• Land mine production
• Economic conversion of military assets
• Criteria for military contracts
Energy
• Energy conservation
• Nuclear plants (information and closure)
• Sustainable energy policy
• Alternative power sources
Food
• Genetically modified food (label, report,
phase out)
• Milk, dairy pricing
Corporate policy
• Implement ethical criteria for board outsiders
• Money laundering
• Corporate tax benefits and subsidies
Media
• Reduce television violence/raise broadcast
standards
• Eliminate negative images in marketing ads
Political issues
• End or disclose political donations
• Affirm nonpartisanship
• Enact shareholder vote on political donations
Executive pay—tie executive pay to
• Social performance
• EEO record
• Health care quality
• Overseas labor standards
• Reduction in teen smoking

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

In an effort to obtain a clearer picture of the effects of corporate activists and
the type of success that is represented by a withdrawn proposal, the interaction
between firm and proposal sponsors was researched for the 859 withdrawn proposals. Web sites (of both proponents and firms), Google searches, newspaper
databases, and direct contact with proposal sponsors yielded information on 298
(35 percent) of these withdrawn proposals. Given the tendency of proponents to
The total impact of CSR activism is quite
trumpet successes and hide failures and
the tendency of the media to find corpodifficult to measure but likely larger than
rate action more newsworthy than prothe estimates provided here.
ponents who back down from proposals,
this sample of 298 proposals likely contains a high percentage of corporate response. This likelihood provides a lower
bound on the number of withdrawn proposals that were successful (in the sense
that corporations responded sufficiently to prompt a withdrawal) and an upper
bound on the activists’ success rate. With an appropriately broad definition of
“successful,” including any corporate response, dialogue, or action, the absolute
number of successes is likely higher while the success rate overall is likely somewhat lower.
In 79 percent of the 298 withdrawn resolutions for which follow-up information
was obtained, the final outcome was a concrete action on the part of the firm. In most
of these cases the firms agreed to take the action requested by the shareholder,
whether it was, for example, to implement the MacBride Principles, withdraw operations from Burma, or release U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission
(EEOC) data. Another 19 percent of the resolutions resulted in dialogue between
activists and the firm without any commitment to action on the part of the firm. This
outcome may be interpreted as a concession by activists in some sense since the firm
did not change its behavior during the observation period. Activists, however, often
argue that dialogue is a positive step and leads to future changes in corporate behavior. Indeed, the data reveal several cases in which prolonged dialogue resulted in
eventual action on the part of the firm. In only three cases was there a report of no
interaction between the activist and the firm after a proposal was withdrawn. These
data support the idea that withdrawn proposals can be viewed as activist successes.
Therefore, 30 percent, the percentage of withdrawn proposals in the entire data
set, is a reasonable lower bound on the rate of success of socially responsible shareholder activists. If the analysis is restricted to only the nonomitted proposals, this
success rate increases to 36 percent of the proposals that might have gone or did go
to a vote. Moreover, among the withdrawn proposals some evidence was uncovered
of positive corporate responses (action) following shareholder votes even though
these votes are not binding and did not reach majority status in any case. This finding further increases the estimate of activist success.
But how should we interpret this success rate? Is it high? One possible comparison is to shareholder proposals requesting corporate governance reforms. These
proposals request changes in executive compensation, antitakeover measures, and
board structures, among others. Chidambaran and Woidtke (1999) analyze withdrawn corporate governance proposals and find that only 17.6 percent of governance
proposals are withdrawn compared to 43.5 percent of social proposals in their sample
period (1989–95). Used as a measure of firm response or action, these higher levels
of withdrawals for social proposals are not surprising. Governance proposals directly
relate to corporate control and, in some cases, the compensation of top management.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

17

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 5
Percentage of Proposals Withdrawn by Topic
50
45
40

Percentage

35
30
25
20
15
10
5

.
pe
SR

CE

O

pa

y—

tr

lit
ic
a

rf

io
ns

/T
V

ib
ut

ia
ed
M

at
or
Co

lc
on

e

ic
gr
/a
od

Fo

rp

Po

er

ul
tu

po
lic
y

re

gy

ns
En

y/
w
ar
ili
t

M

An
im

al

ea

rig

po

ht

s

re
ca

is
c

al
th

m

is
s
al
ci

He

ue
s—
ue

tiv
uc
od
pr

So

Re

.

s

s
is
s
e

ire
co
,f

l,
to
ba
c

at
rn
Al
co

ho

te

ar

du
on
lc
na

io

m
Do

m

ct

or
la
b

en

es
tic

nm
vi
ro
En

In

An

tid
is
cr
im

in
a

tio
n

ta
l

0

Source: Compiled by the author from IRRC data

Firm management would plausibly be less likely to acquiesce on these issues that
directly affect their status and livelihood.22
Using the withdrawn status of a proposal as a measure of activist success, one
can construct a rough measure of activists’ success rate given the topic of their proposal.23 Figure 5 illustrates the percentage of proposals withdrawn for each of the sixteen proposal topics. Antidiscrimination proposals are the most effective or successful.
Roughly half of all these proposals are withdrawn likely because they often call for a
relatively low-cost response, such as a statement of nondiscrimination policy or a
release of information regarding EEOC practices (which is merely a public disclosure
of information the firm is required to report to the EEOC). The figure clearly shows,
however, that activists are successful and able to effect some corporate change in a
wide variety of categories. The only topics in which activists have a success rate less
than 10 percent are reproductive issues, energy, and political contributions.

Conclusion
Enticed by the economic power corporations wield, many social activists and organizations have embraced the potential for corporations to be agents for social change.
Pursuing this goal through shareholder proposals and the corporate ballot box has
often been a successful strategy, especially for religious organizations, unions, and
socially responsible mutual funds. When sponsored by these organizations, 40 to 45
percent of proposals during the 1992–2002 period were withdrawn, likely indicating
some type of corporate response. For the 35 percent of withdrawn proposals for
which information on the activist-firm interaction could be located, almost 80 percent
resulted in a concrete corporate response, including either an ongoing dialogue with
the sponsoring group or the implementation of the proposal itself.

18

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

To maximize the impact of their campaigns, activists most commonly target
large, well-known corporations. Achieving a corporate response from these firms
increases publicity and puts pressure on competitor firms to follow suit in order to
avoid negative publicity and yield a potential competitive advantage to their rivals.
For example, in 2004 Bank of America and Citigroup, facilitated by the Rainforest
Action Network, competed to formulate increasingly comprehensive and strict climate
change policies. Thus the total impact of CSR activism is quite difficult to measure
but likely larger than the estimates provided here.
As discussed, social responsibility is not universally accepted as a desirable objective for corporate decision making. Perhaps the most telling development regarding
the increasing power of CSR activists is the new phenomenon of anti-CSR shareholder
proposals.24 What was once taken as a given—that the sole objective of corporate management was to maximize the profits of the firm—is now clearly in doubt.

22. Carleton, Nelson, and Weisbach (1998) find that TIAA-CREF, the pension fund for university
faculty and administrators, was very successful in negotiating with firms to adopt governance
changes during the period 1992–96. Seventy-one percent of firms they targeted with proposals
took action prior to a shareholder vote; however, these proposals concerned the relatively less
contentious issues of board diversity, the issuance of blank check preferred stock, and confidential voting.
23. This measure does not include the proposals that were voted on by shareholders, which cannot
be confidently assessed as either successes or failures.
24. The Free Enterprise Action fund has targeted several corporations in an effort to eliminate CSR
policies and programs. See www.freeenterpriseactionfund.com/advocacy.html.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

REFERENCES
Black, Bernard S. 1997. Shareholder activism and
corporate governance in the United States. In The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the
Law, edited by Peter Newman, vol. 3, 459–65. New
York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Carleton, Willard T., James M. Nelson, and Michael S.
Weisbach. 1998. The influence of institutions on corporate governance through private negotiations:
Evidence from TIAA-CREF. Journal of Finance 53,
no. 4:1335–62.
Chidambaran, N.K., and Tracie Woidtke. 1999. The
role of negotiations in corporate governance: Evidence
from withdrawn shareholder-initiated proposals. New
York University Center for Law and Business Working
Paper No. 99-12, December.
Del Guercio, Diane, and Jennifer Hawkins. 1999.
The motivation and impact of pension fund activism.
Journal of Financial Economics 52, no. 3:293–340.
Gillan, Stuart L., and Laura T. Starks. 1998. A survey
of shareholder activism: Motivation and empirical evidence. Contemporary Finance Digest 2, no. 3:10–34.

20

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

Graves, Samuel B., Sandra Waddock, and Kathleen
Rehbein. 2001. Fad and fashion in shareholder activism:
The landscape of shareholder resolutions, 1988–1998.
Business and Society Review 106, no. 4:293–314.
Karpoff, Jonathan. 1998. The impact of shareholder
activism on target companies: A survey of empirical
findings. University of Washington Business School
working paper.
Proffitt, W. Trexler, Jr. 2002. Discourse as resource in
U.S. corporate governance: Institutional divergence in
the investor activism field. University of California,
Riverside, working paper.
Romano, Roberta. 2001. Less is more: Making shareholder activism a valuable mechanism of corporate
governance. Yale Journal on Regulation 18,
no. 2:174–251.
Thomas, Randall S., and James F. Cotter. 2005.
Shareholder proposals post-Enron: What’s changed,
what’s the same? Vanderbilt University working paper.
Trigaux, Robert. 2002. Executives cower from this
gadfly in the ointment. St. Petersburg Times, May 22.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

How Resilient Is the
Modern Economy to Energy
Price Shocks?
RAJEEV DHAWAN AND KARSTEN JESKE
Dhawan is the director of the Economic Forecasting Center and an associate professor of
managerial sciences at the J. Mack Robinson College of Business at Georgia State
University. Jeske is a research economist in the macropolicy section of the Atlanta Fed’s
research department and a visiting professor of economics at Emory University. The
authors thank Thomas Cunningham, Pedro Silos, and Ellis Tallman for helpful comments.

conomists and policymakers alike have noticed the striking correlation between
energy prices and U.S. business cycles. Since 1973 every recession has been preceded by a rise in energy prices (see Figure 1). Conversely, almost every energy price
hike has been followed by a recession. A large literature confirms this casual observation of energy prices driving business cycles with econometric methods, including
Rasche and Tatom (1977), Hamilton (1983, 2003), Rotemberg and Woodford (1996),
and Hamilton and Herrera (2004).1
Despite the empirical link between energy prices and business cycles, the existing literature on dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models has either
abstracted from modeling energy or found little effect of energy price shocks on the
macroeconomy. Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott, who are the pioneers of studying business cycles in the DSGE framework, showed in their seminal paper (Kydland
and Prescott 1982) that a large share of business cycle fluctuations is accounted for
by using one single exogenous shock, total factor productivity. Given that they had
abstracted from modeling energy use, Kim and Loungani (1992) add energy use on
the firm side and a second exogenous shock, the energy price, to the Kydland and
Prescott framework. They confirm the original finding that productivity shocks still
explain a major portion of business cycle fluctuations.2
Both views—that of the DSGE-type researchers who claim that energy price shocks
do not matter and that of the empiricists who claim that these shocks are the primary
reason for business cycles in the United States—are not entirely convincing. On the one
hand, it must have been a very unfortunate coincidence for theorists that the weak productivity observed in 1973–74 and 1979–82 occurred right after the energy price shock.
On the other hand, the empiricists would have to address why in 1986, when energy
prices declined sharply, we did not observe a major boom in the economy.
Mork (1989), who investigated the 1986 anomaly, shows that an asymmetric
effect of energy price increases and decreases exists: The frictions in the economy

E

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

21

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1
Growth Rates and Energy Prices
8

50
GDP year-over-year growth (percent)

GDP year-over-year growth (percent)

30
4
20
2

10

0

0
–10

–2

Real energy price (percent deviation from mean)

–20
–4
–30
–6

Real energy price (percent deviation from mean)

40

6

–40

–8

–50
1971

1975

1979

1983

1987

1991

1995

1999

2003

Notes: Recessions are indicated by the vertical bars. Recession dates are based on NBER business cycle dates. The real energy price is
demeaned and based on the authors' calculations.
Source: GDP growth rates from the Bureau of Economics Analysis (BEA); energy price data from the BEA and the Energy Information
Administration

cause a negative effect on growth if energy prices go up but provide no benefit when
energy prices decline.3 However, the empiricists still need to address why the recent
run-up in energy prices has not caused a recession or even a slowdown so far. Real gross
domestic product (GDP) has grown at a solid 3.5 percent rate since the end of 2002
whereas energy prices have risen by a magnitude similar to that observed in 1979.
One potential explanation for this lack of energy effects would be the low energy
intensity of the modern economy. For example, energy use measured in British thermal units (BTU) per dollar of real GDP in 2005 is about half of the value observed in
the 1970s. But this share argument is still unsatisfactory: If the impact of an energy
price shock is proportional to the energy intensity, we should still have observed half
of the drop observed in the 1970s, which certainly would have made for a severe
growth slowdown, if not a recession. It is difficult to characterize growth of 3.5 percent over the past few years as being below trend by any metric.
Who is right—the empiricists who claim that energy price hikes have strong and
significant effects on business cycles or the DSGE economists who claim that it is
mostly productivity that matters? This article will reconcile the two competing views
in the following manner. The DSGE-type explanation remains intact if we construct
a “proper” series for productivity or Solow residuals by explicitly taking into account
energy use in the production function, which has been absent from standard productivity accounting exercises done before. In particular, these productivity shocks
continue to be the prominent force behind business cycles. However, during the
years 1970 to 1985, productivity itself was negatively affected by energy price hikes.
In the model constructed here, a Kim and Loungani–type economy, we allow for a
negative correlation between energy price shocks and productivity based on our
empirical evidence from 1970 to 1985. This simulation experiment confirms the findings of the econometric literature that energy price shocks reduced real output

22

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

growth prior to 1985. The correlation between energy price shocks and productivity
disappeared completely after 1985. Our model simulation incorporating this lack of
correlation explains why in 1986 there was no major increase in growth rates and,
most important, why there was no recession in 2005. Therefore, we conclude that the
modern economy, represented by the period after 1985, is very resilient to energy
price increases.

Constructing the Model
The model used here is based on a version of the DSGE model in Kim and Loungani
(1992) that incorporates energy use on the firm side as well as a stochastic process
for energy prices.
Throughout the article, the term “energy price” refers to the price of energy relative to other goods. The process for the price of energy P varies exogenously over
time. Specifically, we assume that energy prices follow an autoregressive moving
average (ARMA) process of the following form:
(1) log Pt = ρplog Pt–1 + εp,t + ρεεp,t–1,
where the shocks εp,t are normally distributed with mean zero and standard deviation
σp. This specification is standard in the literature.4
The model economy has a representative household that obtains utility from consuming C and disutility from working H hours. Specifically, we assume that at any
time t the household obtains period utility,
(2) u(Ct, Ht ) = ϕlogCt + (1 – ϕ)log(1 – Ht ),
where ϕ is the weight the household puts on consumption. Over time the household
discounts period utility at a constant rate β, with 0 < β < 1. Thus, the household maximizes expected discounted utility:

(

)

(3) U = E ∑ t=0 βt u Ct, Ht .
∞

The model economy also has a representative firm that has three inputs, labor H,
the service flow from physical capital K, and energy Ef . The firm purchases its energy
input at relative price P. We choose the following form for the production function:

(

)

α/ψ

1−α
ψ
ψ
(4) Yt = Zt Ht ⎡⎣ ηK t−1 + 1 − η E f, t ⎤⎦ ,

which is standard in the literature (see Kim and Loungani 1992 and Dhawan and
Jeske 2006). Our functional form implies that the elasticity of substitution between
capital and energy is 1/(1 – ψ). Thus, if we choose ψ < 0, capital and energy will be

1. See Hamilton (2005) for an exhaustive list of references.
2. Dhawan and Jeske (2006) include household energy use and durable goods consumption and confirm
the Kim and Loungani results. Leduc and Sill (2004) add monetary shocks and nominal wage and
price rigidities but find that energy price shocks still do not play a major role.
3. Mork conjectures that a model like Hamilton’s (1988) can produce an asymmetry in the energy
price response.
4. The following section will elaborate on the time series properties of energy prices that justify this
particular functional form.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

23

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

complements. In addition, the firm is subject to an exogenous productivity shock Z,
also called total factor productivity (TFP), as is the norm in the literature. Kydland
and Prescott’s (1982) seminal research views business cycle fluctuations as the result
of movements in TFP. We assume that the Z evolves according to
(5) log Zt = ρz logZ t–1 + εz,t ,
where the shocks εz,t are normally distributed with mean zero and standard deviation
σp. We do not include a constant term because we assume that the model is scaled in
such a way as to make log productivity equal to zero on average.
We make a distinction between the service flow of capital and the investment. The
entire stock of capital K is used in the production function while investment shows
up in the national income and product accounts as the spending on new capital stock.
The stock K and capital investment Ik are related via the following equation:
(6) Kt = (1 – δk)Kt–1 + Ik, t ,
where δk is the annual depreciation rate of physical capital.
To close the model we assume investment in fixed capital Ik as well as consumption C, and energy expenditures P · Ef are all financed by current production Y. The
numerical techniques involved in solving the model are beyond the scope of this
paper. We refer the interested reader to Dhawan and Jeske (2006).

Calibration and Time Series Properties of Shocks
The next step is to calibrate this model economy to match data measured at an annual
frequency. Calibration means matching the steady state ratios such as K/Y, Id /Y,
hours worked H, and so on to the characteristics in the U.S. data between 1970 and
2005.5 The specifics of the calibration exercise are in Dhawan and Jeske (2006), and the
exercise produces the parameter values shown in Table 1.6
An integral part of this model is the calibration of the shock processes. We now
study some time series properties of the two shock processes for energy prices P and
productivity Z. This analysis will guide us in finding realistic specifications of the
shock processes used to simulate the dynamic model. We start by estimating a
stochastic process for energy prices. The series for annual energy prices comes from
the Energy Information Administration (EIA). We take the total nominal energy
spending (household plus firm level) and divide by the total energy consumption in
BTUs to obtain a series for the nominal energy price per unit of energy for
1970–2005. We then divide this series by the GDP deflator to obtain the real relative
energy price P.7
Estimating the ARMA(1,1) process in equation (1) via the maximum likelihood
method, we find that
(7) log Pt = 0.8784 log Pt−1 + ε p,t + 0.5256 ε p,t−1 .
(9.6114)

(2.6150)

The t-statistics are in parentheses below the point estimates, and εp,t has a standard
error of 0.0753. Finding a statistically significant parameter estimate on the lagged
shock (the moving average part of the ARMA) is consistent with the findings in Kim
and Loungani (1992) and Dhawan and Jeske (2006), who also use an ARMA process
for their energy prices. One can show that estimating only an AR(1) process, thus
dropping the regressor εp,t–1, generates serially correlated error terms.
24

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

For this estimated ARMA process, an
Table 1
Calibrated Parameters
innovation εp of one standard deviation
would, all other things being equal, raise
α
0.3600
energy prices by 7.53 percent in the curβ
0.9606
rent year and by 10.6 percent in the folϕ
0.3382
lowing year before slowly decaying after
η
0.9940
that. The reason that energy prices rise
ψ
–0.7000
for two periods in a row is that the moving
δk
0.0656
average term ρεεp, t–1 also shocks next period’s energy price, and that effect is
stronger than the decay of the initial shock.
Another ingredient in the model is the stochastic process for productivity Z. From
the production function above, we back out the values of Z from the following equation:
Yt

(8) Zt =
H

1−α
t

⎡ ηK
⎣

ψ
t −1

(

)

+ 1 − η E ψf, t ⎤⎦

α/ψ

,

where we use the time series for annual real GDP from the Bureau of Economic
Analysis (BEA) for Y and the index for “Nonfarm Business Sector: Hours of All
Persons” from the BLS for H. As a measure for the capital stock K, we use the BEA’s
estimate of the “Net Stock of Fixed Assets.” Moreover, we subtract the BEA series for
household nominal energy expenditures from the EIA total nominal energy expenditures series. We then divide by the price per BTU to compute real firm energy usage.
With this measure we generate a time series Zt for productivity from 1970 to 2005.8
The essential points of this article will be made by emphasizing that slightly different formulations of the productivity process generate vastly different results in the
response of output to an energy price shock. We start with the most basic specification in equation (5), using Z as measured in equation (8) and estimate it via ordinary
least squares to obtain the following equation:
log Zt −1 + ε z ,t ,
(9) log Zt = 0(.88083
.3768 )
where the error terms εz, t have a standard deviation of 0.0126.9
Typically, when simulating the model one assumes that the innovations to the two
shocks P and Z are independent. To check whether this assumption is adequate, we
back out the residuals necessary to generate the observed paths for energy prices
and productivity. In specification A, the two residuals display a sizable negative correlation of about –0.5, as shown in Figure 2. Thus, the independence assumption is
clearly violated, and feeding these shock processes into the model will miss an important link between energy prices and productivity.

5. For a formal exposition of a calibration process, see Cooley and Prescott (1995).
6. This model corresponds to model E-I in Dhawan and Jeske (2006), though on an annual basis. We
also performed a sensitivity analysis along the energy share in the economy, which declined over
the 1970–2005 period. We find that the numerical results are robust to this decline in energy share.
7. This is the series plotted in Figure 1.
8. This exercise also requires knowledge of the parameters α and ψ. We use the values as specified
in the calibration above.
9. Cooley and Prescott (1995), using quarterly data, find ρz = 0.95, σz = 0.007, which corresponds to
ρz = 0.81, σz = 0.014 on an annual basis, almost identical to our results.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

25

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2
Scatter Plot for Error Terms, 1970–2005
.03
.02
.01

εz

0
Correlation –0.5029

–.01
–.02
–.03
–.04
–.05
–0.10

–0.05

0

0.05

0.10

ερ

0.15

0.20

0.25

Source: Authors’ calculations

What is the source of the negative correlation between shocks? To investigate
this question, we first plot the error terms for the two different subsamples (1970–85
and 1986–2005) in Figure 3. Notice that in the pre-1985 subsample the two error
terms display an almost perfect negative correlation (–0.8618) while in the second
subsample the correlation is essentially zero (0.0039). Consequently, we estimate
another specification in which shocks in the energy price process are allowed also to
spill over to the productivity process. Specifically, we regress current productivity
not just on lagged productivity but also on the current shock from the energy price
equation, multiplied by an indicator variable for the years before 1985. In other
words, εp, t is included as an additional regressor, which is the error from the price
equation times an indicator variable I(t ≤ 1985):

(

)

(10) log Zt = 0.8238 log Zt −1 − 0.1915 ε p,t I t ≤ 1985 + ε z ,t .
( 12.8555 )

( −6.6480
0)

According to our estimates, the coefficient on the spillover term is significantly
negative; that is, a rise in energy prices was associated with lower productivity before
1985. Even though the coefficient may appear to be small in absolute value, the spillover
effect from energy prices to productivity is substantial. To see this effect, consider the
following example. A positive innovation to energy prices by one standard deviation
reduces productivity by about 1.5 percent, or about 1.76 times a standard deviation of
the productivity shock. Thus, according to our estimates, energy price shocks determine most of the fluctuations prior to 1985.

A Discussion of the Results
The model is simulated by feeding in the shock processes for energy prices and TFP.
Specifically, we perform experiments for two alternative specifications of the TFP process. Specification A uses the estimated process above without the correlation term
while specification B includes the correlation term. The specifications are as follows:

26

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 3
Scatter Plot of Error Terms during Two Subsamples
1970–1985

1986–2005

.03

.03

.02

.02

.01

.01

0

0
Correlation –0.8618

–.01

εz

εz

Correlation 0.0039

–.01

–.02

–.02

–.03

–.03

–.04

–.04

–.05

–.05
–0.1

Source: Authors’ calculations

0

ερ

0.1

0.2

–0.1

0

ερ

0.1

0.2

Specification A: log Zt = 0.8238 log Zt −1 + ε z ,t (post-1985);
Specification B: log Zt = 0.8238 log Zt−1 − 0.1915ε p,t + ε z ,t (pre-1985).
We then report impulse response functions to an energy price shock over a time horizon of forty years under the two alternative specifications. The philosophy behind
impulse response functions is as follows. The model constructed earlier was calibrated
to match steady state properties to those observed in the data. At the steady state, all
disturbances or shocks to the system are set to zero by definition. From this equilibrium state, the model is subjected to a shock, in this case an energy price shock, and
the model’s response for key variables is tracked over time.10 One can view this exercise as an economic laboratory experiment, studying the response to one shock while
switching off all other noise in the economy.
We are primarily interested in the response of output to an energy price increase
and therefore report the output impulse response functions to a positive one-standarddeviation shock to energy prices. This shock translates into a 10.6 percent hike in the
energy price. The top panel in Figure 4 displays the path for the energy price following this one-time shock. Notice that because of the ARMA(1,1) structure, the
price increases for two periods before it decays toward its old value in steady state.
The middle panel displays the effect on total factor productivity Z based on the two
alternative specifications, as detailed in the previous section. Notice that the impulse
response for Z is entirely due to the energy price shock and not its own innovation
εz, t, which we set to zero along the transition path. Therefore, TFP (Zt ) stays at zero
for specification A, where energy price innovations had no effect on productivity. In
10. Technically, this procedure means that one solves the first-order conditions to find the decision
rules using an appropriate numerical approximation method. Iterating over the decision rules
when given a shock generates the desired impulse response functions.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

27

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 4
A One-Time Positive Energy Price Shock and Its Effect on
Productivity and Output for Two Different Specifications of the TFP Process
Energy price

Percent

10
5
0

Productivity

.5
Specification A: Post-1985 (without correlation)

Percent

0
–.5

Specification B: Pre-1985 (with correlation)

–1
–1.5

Output
Percent

0
Specification A: Post-1985 (without correlation)

–1

Specification B: Pre-1985 (with correlation)

–2
0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Time
Source: Authors’ calculations

specification B, however, productivity drops dramatically because of the correlation
and its negative implications on TFP, as described in the previous paragraph.
The lower panel in Figure 4 plots the drop in output caused by this energy price
hike. Notice that the energy price hike does not cause any major output drop in specification A because there is no effect on the TFP process. The biggest drop occurs in
the year after the initial energy price hike but amounts to only a 0.43 percent drop
in output before converging back to zero. This result is consistent with previous
research showing that DSGE models with energy use do not produce major output
fluctuations if energy price shocks are uncorrelated with TFP.11
Under specification B, however, output drops by almost 2.4 percent. Even eight
years after the shock, output is still 1 percentage point below the level where it would
have been without the energy price shock. The technical reason for this big and persistent effect is that the energy price shock substantially reduces TFP, which in turn
affects output. Recall from the calibration section that for the 1970–85 period, a positive
one-standard-deviation shock to the energy price equation, given the spillover effect,
is equivalent to a –1.76 standard-deviation shock to TFP, which is big enough to drag
down GDP substantially. Hence, the impulse response function in specification A can
be interpreted as the outcome of energy price hikes in an economy set to match data
characteristics after 1985; similarly, specification B is for an economy with characteristics from 1970 to 1985. The fact that energy price hikes were associated with
major recessions in 1973 and 1980, but seemingly did not have any major output
effect in the most recent episode from 2002 to 2005, is thus entirely consistent with
our modeling structure.

28

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 5
Estimated Standardized Energy Price Shocks and
Their Estimated Marginal Effect on Growth Rates

Energy shocks (standard deviations)

Standard deviation/percent

2

0

–2
Marginal effect on growth (percent)

–4

–6

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

Source: Authors’ calculations

So what do these results mean in regard to the question posed in the article’s
title? In the context of our model, the economy today is far more resilient to energy
price hikes than it was before 1985. Even a major energy price hike—caused by, say,
a two-standard-deviation shock to the energy price process in equation (1)—represents a drag of a mere 0.8 percentage points in the second year of the impact in
the modern era (defined as 1985 to 2005). If the negative correlation observed in the
1970s had prevailed, this price hike would have caused a precipitous 4.8 percent
drop in output.
We can also use the model to determine the marginal impact energy prices had
on growth between 1970 and 2005. In other words, how have the “observed” energy
price shocks between 1971 and 2005 affected output growth in these thirty-five
years? To answer this question, we generate a total impulse response function, that
is, not with one single shock but with the thirty-five energy price shocks εp, t one after
the other, as derived from our ARMA(1,1) estimation. Consequently, the impact of
energy price changes in each year is the impact of the current year shock in addition
to the impact from all lagged shocks. In this simulation we assume that specification B for the technology process prevails, that is, the pre-1985 era, when there is a
negative spillover from energy price shocks to the technology. After 1985 technology
is unaffected by energy prices because the indicator variable in the regression equation (10) is zero. Figure 5 plots the standardized energy price shocks εp, t and their
marginal impact on output growth rates predicted by the model.
11. Specifically, Kim and Loungani (1992) show that energy price shocks do not produce a sizable fraction of business cycle fluctuations. Dhawan and Jeske (2006) show that modeling durable goods on
the household side even softens the impact of energy price shocks because households have more
margins to adjust their behavior. Particularly, households reduce new durable goods investment
sharply to cushion the fall in fixed-capital investment, which mitigates future output losses.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

29

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Evidently, energy price hikes had very
adverse effects on growth in 1974, 1979,
and 1980, knocking multiple percentage
Actual
Counterfactual
a
points off output growth rates. For exam(percent)
(percent)
ple, energy price shocks reduced output
growth in 1974 by an estimated 6.6 percent,
2003
2.51
–1.08
2004
3.91
3.98
meaning that in the absence of energy
2005
3.22
–0.64
price shocks, output growth would have
been more than 6 percent instead of the
a
For the counterfactual growth rate, energy price shocks affect TFP.
actual 0.5 percent decline. Likewise, in
the recession year 1980, the actual output
drop was 0.2 percent. The model simulation reveals that the growth rate that year
would have been 3.2 percentage points higher, well outside of recession territory, if
there had been no energy price shocks.
After 1985, however, energy price shocks had a much smaller effect on output
growth rates. The simulation implies that energy prices did not play any role in the
1991 and 2001 recessions. The most recent run-up in energy prices, while quite dramatic, with three positive energy shocks in a row from 2003 to 2005, did not cause
an obvious reduction in real GDP growth. The cumulative impact of energy price
shocks on 2005 growth has been a mere 0.5 percentage points. The energy shock in
1980 (and 1979), about equal in magnitude to those observed in 2003 or 2005, did far
more damage, as discussed previously.
We can also ask how much damage the energy price hike from 2002 to 2005
would have done had there still been the same type of negative correlation between
TFP and energy price shocks as observed in the data before 1985. To answer this
question we compute the marginal impact on output growth of energy price shocks,
as discussed earlier, but assume that beginning in the year 2003 the economy reverts
to the same shock process as observed in the pre-1985 era; namely, TFP is negatively
affected by energy price shocks εp, t . Table 2 reports growth rates for GDP for 2003
through 2005 under this scenario. The first column is the actual growth rate as
reported by the BEA. The second column is the growth rate under the assumption
that TFP is negatively affected by energy price shocks, the same way it had been
before 1985.12 Had the TFP process been of the same structure as before 1985, the
recent energy price hikes would have dragged the economy into recession both in
2003 and 2005. Thus, the correlation between energy price shocks and TFP makes
all the difference, and recessions would likely have occurred in 2003 and 2005, while
without the correlation, the economy showed resilience to energy price shocks.
So far we have stated only statistical facts about a spillover from energy price hikes
into reduction of TFP. We have not developed any theory about the causes for a negative correlation between technology and energy price shocks before 1985. One can view
this negative correlation as a reduced form representation for other omitted factors in
the model. For example, Hamilton (1988) develops a model with multiple sectors in the
presence of frictions for reallocating production inputs, primarily labor, between sectors.
If energy prices have a differential effect on sectors, the economy has to spend a sizable
amount of resources to overcome these frictions. This explanation, of course, raises
a question about why these frictions suddenly disappeared after 1985.
An alternative explanation for energy price hikes having vastly differential effects
on growth in the two subperiods is that different policies were in place to address the
price hikes. Most notably, the 1970s were marked by price controls on energy from
1973 to 1981 and wage controls during the Nixon era. Not surprisingly, during the oil

Table 2
Growth Rates: Actual versus Counterfactual

30

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

shocks in both 1973 and 1979, gasoline was rationed, while after 1985 prices were
allowed to move more freely. Evans (1982) studies the impact of general price and
wage controls (not during the 1970s but during World War II) and finds that they
caused a substantial output loss.
One can see how price controls have negative effects on productivity. In a market without price controls and any other frictions, the price of a good like oil or a service like labor provides an efficient way of rationing scarce resources because the
market allocates them to the most productive use. Specifically, only those firms with
the highest productivity are willing to hire workers and purchase energy at a given
market price. If, by contrast, the price is not allowed to work as an allocation mechanism, inputs may be used by inefficient firms. For example, if there are lines at the
gas pumps, those agents who are the most patient or just plain lucky get the gasoline, while the most productive agents may either get no gasoline or waste precious
time and resources while waiting in line. This situation affects businesses directly if
they purchase gasoline but also indirectly if it creates uncertainty about whether
employees arrive at work on time. If the rules of supply and demand are suspended,
then idled resources and misallocation of energy lead to less productive use of energy,
which shows up as lower productivity or TFP.
If indeed all of the differential impact on growth is due to price controls, an implication from our model is that price controls not only harm output growth, but their
indirect impact on growth (measured as the difference between the impulse
response functions from specifications A and B) is larger than the direct effect of
energy price hikes (the impulse response function of specification A).

Conclusions
The general equilibrium analysis in this study shows that energy price shocks can cause a
large drop in output if and only if they also affect the underlying productivity (TFP) trend.
Thus, today’s economy is very resilient because the TFP process is not being affected by
energy price shocks, as it was from 1970 to 1985. Even the major energy price increases
of 2003 and 2005, which are comparable in magnitude to those in 1974 and 1979, did not
cause a recession as the underlying trend in TFP has been positive since there were no
negative spillovers from energy prices to TFP like those experienced before 1985.
The article discusses that a possible reason for this negative correlation was the
energy price controls observed in the 1970s in response to energy price shocks. Thus,
if the drop in TFP is due to a bad policy, then the implication from our analysis is that
energy price shocks themselves are far less damaging than the policies that may be
implemented to address them. This is an example of the medicine likely doing more
harm than the condition it was supposed to cure.
Do we believe that the U.S. economy is shielded from any future recessions?
Certainly not! While the economy is more resilient to energy price shocks than before
1985, it is still subject to fluctuations in TFP unrelated to energy price hikes. In addition,
if policies were to be implemented that inhibit the functioning of free markets, say,
through price controls or other measures that lead to energy rationing, the economy
will again be susceptible to energy price–induced recessions.
12. This figure is computed by first subtracting the marginal impact as reported in Figure 5 from the
observed annual GDP growth rates, as reported by the BEA. This result can be viewed as a model
estimate for the growth rate that would have prevailed in the absence of all energy price shocks.
Then we add to that number the marginal impact computed under the counterfactual assumption of a negative correlation between εp,t and TFP in 2003–05.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

31

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

REFERENCES
Cooley, Thomas F., and Edward C. Prescott. 1995.
Economic growth and business cycles. In Frontiers of
business cycle research, edited by Thomas F. Cooley.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Dhawan, Rajeev, and Karsten Jeske. 2006. Energy
prices and the macroeconomy: The role of consumer
durables. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working
Paper 2006-9, August.
Evans, Paul. 1982. The effects of general price controls in the United States during World War II.
Journal of Political Economy 90, no. 5:944–66.
Hamilton, James. 1983. Oil and the macroeconomy
since World War II. Journal of Political Economy 91,
no. 2:228–48.
———. 1988. A neoclassical model of unemployment
and the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy
96, no. 3:593–617.
———. 2003. What is an oil shock? Journal of Econometrics 113, no. 2:363–98.
———. 2005. Oil and the macroeconomy. University
of California, San Diego, Department of Economics,
unpublished working paper. <http://dss.ucsd.edu/
~jhamilto/JDH_palgrave_oil.pdf> (August 23, 2006).
Hamilton, James, and Anna M. Herrera. 2004. Oil
shocks and aggregate macroeconomic behavior: The

32

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

role of monetary policy: A comment. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 36, no. 2:265–86.
Kim, In-Moo, and Prakash Loungani. 1992. The role of
energy in real business cycle models. Journal of
Monetary Economics 29, no. 2:173–89.
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott. 1982. Time
to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50,
no. 6:1345–70.
Leduc, Sylvain, and Keith Sill. 2004. A quantitative
analysis of oil-price shocks, systematic monetary policy,
and economic downturns. Journal of Monetary
Economics 51, no.4:781–808.
Mork, Knut Anton. 1989. Oil and the macroeconomy
when prices go up and down: An extension of
Hamilton’s results. Journal of Political Economy 97,
no. 3:740–44.
Rasche, Robert H., and John A. Tatom. 1977. The
effects of the new energy regime on economic capacity,
production, and prices. Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review 59 (May): 2–12.
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1996.
Imperfect competition and the effects of energy price
increases on economic activity. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 28, no. 4, part 1:549–77.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

The Federal Home Loan
Bank System: The “Other”
Housing GSE
MARK J. FLANNERY AND W. SCOTT FRAME
Flannery is the Bank of America Professor of Finance at the University of Florida in
Gainesville. Frame is a financial economist and associate policy adviser in the Atlanta
Fed’s research department. They thank Gerald Dwyer, David Feldhaus, Richard Fritz,
William Jackson, Christopher McEntee, Joseph McKenzie, Wayne Passmore, Steven Patrick,
and Larry Wall for comments on an earlier draft. The authors also thank Stella Lang at the
Federal Home Loan Bank of Atlanta, staff at the Federal Home Loan Banks Office of
Finance, and Ellen Hancock and Joseph McKenzie at the Federal Housing Finance Board
for helpful background information, and Brandon Lockhart for valuable research assistance.

he federal government has played an active role in residential mortgage finance
since the Great Depression.1 Prior to that time, mortgages typically had short
terms (often less than five years), carried variable rates, and required final “balloon”
payments that were generally refinanced. In the early 1930s residential real estate
values (and financial asset values generally) fell dramatically. Coupled with limited
refinancing opportunities, this decline generated a wave of mortgage defaults and
foreclosures, further depressing the housing market. The federal government
responded to this crisis by creating several financial institutions to promote the use
of long-term, fixed-rate, fully amortizing residential mortgages. The first of these new
institutions was the Federal Home Loan Bank System (FHLB System), which was
created in 1932 as a collection of cooperatively owned wholesale banks.
Historically, the twelve Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLBs or Banks) primarily
acted as a reliable provider of long-term funding to specialized mortgage lenders.
Specifically, the Banks made (over)collateralized loans, known as “advances,” to thrift
institutions and a few insurance companies. While the advance business has endured,
the FHLB System has evolved since the resolution of the 1980s thrift crisis.
The Financial Institutions Recovery and Reform Act of 1989 (FIRREA) included
two provisions that precipitated lasting changes for the FHLBs. First, the law opened
FHLB membership to all depository institutions with more than 10 percent of their
portfolios in residential mortgage-related assets. This change allowed many commercial banks and credit unions to join the FHLB System for the first time.
Membership increased from 3,200 to more than 8,000 between 1989 and 2005
despite the declining number of federally insured thrifts, which were legally required
to be FHLB members until 1999. The transition from mandatory to voluntary FHLB
membership also arguably forced the Banks to become more attuned to their members’ desire for attractive advance rates and dividend payments. Second, FIRREA
imposed “income taxes” on the individual FHLBs. They must now pay 20 percent of

T

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

33

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

net earnings to cover a portion of the interest on the Resolution Funding Corporation
(REFCORP) bonds used to finance the thrift cleanup; another 10 percent is set aside
for low- and moderate-income housing programs.
The statutory changes in FIRREA encouraged the FHLB System to grow and to
increase its attention to profitability. Between 1989 and 2005 FHLB System total
assets increased from about $175 billion to
$1 trillion, and its composition of assets
Financial economists recognize that public
changed. Besides a secular increase in
guarantees of a private firm’s debts can
advances, FHLB balance sheets have also
come to include substantial investment in
lead the insured firm to take greater risks
marketable securities (especially mortgagethan it otherwise would.
backed securities) and member-guaranteed
mortgage pools. This shift, in turn, has
resulted in the Banks managing an increasing amount of interest rate risk, including
the embedded call options associated with mortgage prepayment.
The FHLBs’ growth and profitability trends have been further reinforced by the
advances in information technology and financial practice that contributed to financial services consolidation. Even though they are the largest users of FHLB advances,
the very largest U.S. depository institutions maintain regional or nationwide branch
networks and access to various other wholesale borrowing mechanisms. Furthermore,
many of these institutions maintain charters in more than one Bank district, thereby
allowing for multiple channels into the FHLB System. These trends have served to
heighten competitive pressures within the cooperative and suggest that the FHLB
advances are but one of many different sources of nondeposit funding. While the
FHLB System has grown in size, complexity, and risk over time, very little research
has been published about this institution.2
A government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) is a financial institution chartered
by Congress but owned by private shareholders (cooperative members or outside
investors, depending on the ownership arrangement). Today three GSEs serve housing (the FHLB System, Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac), and two others serve agriculture
(the Farm Credit System and Farmer Mac).3 GSE debt securities are commonly
described as “U.S. agency” obligations, which are perceived by investors to be implicitly guaranteed by the U.S. government despite explicit, legally prescribed denials in
offering materials. Financial economists recognize that public guarantees of a private
firm’s debts (either explicit or implicit) can lead the insured firm to take greater risks
than it otherwise would (“moral hazard”).4 This moral hazard, in turn, imposes a
potential cost on taxpayers in the event of financial distress.
The public has recently learned of several significant financial or accounting
problems at housing GSEs. In 2002 Fannie Mae disclosed a significant exposure to
interest rates as measured by their “duration gap.”5 The following year the GSEs’ regulator, the U.S. Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO), found that
Freddie Mac had engaged in questionable accounting practices that allowed the company to manage its earnings by deferring $5 billion of income into future years.6 Most
recently OFHEO determined that Fannie Mae inappropriately applied hedge
accounting rules and misclassified assets, overstating its equity by $10.8 billion.7
Problems have also arisen within the FHLB System during this time. Standard &
Poor’s has downgraded derivative counterparty ratings for three FHLBs (Chicago,
New York, and Seattle) from AAA to AA+ and currently maintains a “negative outlook” on six FHLBs (Chicago, Dallas, Des Moines, Indianapolis, Pittsburgh, and
Seattle).8 In all but one instance (New York), the downgrades and outlook changes

34

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

were triggered by concerns about individual FHLBs’ ability to manage their interest
rate risk exposures.
The troubles experienced by some FHLBs came as a surprise to many observers
since cooperatives and mutuals are often viewed as less risky than stock-owned
firms. Perhaps more precisely, the operation and incentives of cooperative firms are
less well understood than those of traditional firms. Recent testimony by former
Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan (2004), for example, noted that
the FHLBs are more “complex to analyze than other GSEs and hence raise additional issues.”
The principal contribution of this article is to identify and analyze differences in
the FHLBs’ risk-taking incentives vis-à-vis those for Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. We
begin by characterizing housing GSEs generally and then examine the structure,
activities, and risks of the FHLB System in particular.

Housing GSEs
The history of U.S. housing GSEs began during the Great Depression with the creation of the FHLB System in 1932. That system has operated for nearly seventy-five
years with essentially the same corporate structure (described below). The National
Housing Act of 1934 then created the Federal Housing Authority (FHA) to operate a
mortgage insurance program; the act also provided for the chartering of national
mortgage associations as entities within the federal government. The only association
ever formed was the National Mortgage Association of Washington in 1938, which
eventually became the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae). In 1968
Fannie Mae was converted into a private corporation, with publicly traded shares listed
on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE). Freddie Mac was chartered by Congress
in 1970 to securitize mortgages originated by thrifts. During the 1970s and 1980s,
Freddie Mac was technically a private company although its equity shares were held
1. For a discussion of the development of U.S. mortgage markets since the 1930s, see, for example,
Quigley (2005) and Green and Wachter (2005).
2. An EconLit search uncovered seven published academic articles primarily concerning the operation
of the FHLB System itself: Silber (1973), Jaffee (1976), Goldfeld, Jaffee, and Quandt (1980), Mays
(1989), Hoffman and Cassell (2002), Frame (2003), and Nickerson and Phillips (2004).
3. The Student Loan Marketing Association (Sallie Mae) is also a GSE serving education, but it is in
the process of privatization under the name SLM Corporation.
4. This moral hazard may also allow the guaranteed firm to grow abnormally large. In the case of
housing GSEs, their large scale has resulted in systemic risk concerns as the institutions have
become the central players in the U.S. housing finance system and markets for certain U.S. dollar
interest rate derivatives.
5. Duration gap is the difference between the weighted-average duration of assets and the weightedaverage duration of liabilities for a given change in interest rates. Frame and White (2004) provide
a brief summary of Fannie Mae’s duration gap episode while Jaffee (2003) provides greater detail
on the practice of interest rate risk management at both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
6. See Baker-Botts LLP (2003) for a detailed discussion of the questionable financial transactions and
an evaluation of their treatment under generally accepted accounting principles. Baker-Botts was
retained by the board of directors of Freddie Mac. See U.S. OFHEO (2003) for the supervisory
analysis of these issues.
7. Kopecki (2005) reports an estimated cumulative after-tax write-down of $10.8 billion for the
2001–04 period. See U.S. OFHEO (2004) and Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton, and Garrison LLP
(2006) for discussions of the problems with Fannie Mae’s accounting policies, internal controls,
and financial reporting processes.
8. Moody’s has neither downgraded any FHLBs nor placed any of the institutions under a “negative
outlook.”

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

35

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

The Housing GSEs’ Federal Charters

ongress has bestowed some benefits on the
housing GSEs that result in lower costs. In
terms of operating costs, the three housing GSEs
are exempt from paying state and local corporate
income taxes and are not required to register
their debt and mortgage-backed securities issues
with the Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC).1 Several other features of the GSE charters cumulate to much larger savings by lowering
the housing GSEs’ funding costs.
The markets appear to believe that the GSEs’
obligations carry an implicit federal guaranty.
Why? First, the U.S. Treasury is authorized to purchase housing GSE securities up to $2.25 billion
for both Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and up to
$4 billion for the FHLB System. Second, housing GSE securities are considered government
securities under the Securities and Exchange
Act of 1934 (hence their exemption from registration). This status means that housing GSE
securities can be used as collateral for public
deposits, can be bought and sold by the Federal
Reserve in open market operations, and may be
held in unlimited amounts by federally insured
depository institutions. Third, housing GSE
securities are eligible for issuance and transfer through the Federal Reserve System’s bookentry system, the same used by the U.S. Treasury.
Finally, housing GSEs are not subject to the
bankruptcy code since they are considered to

C

be “federal instrumentalities.” No resolution
mechanism has been specified in the event that
one of these firms fails, and hence congressional
action would be required.2 This action is unlikely
to occur quickly.
The housing GSEs’ federal charters also
impose some important limitations. First, the
activities of each institution are largely limited to
residential mortgage finance. Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac securitize and invest in only “conforming” mortgages (or securities backed by
such mortgages) or those below $417,000 for
2006; the FHLBs make advances collateralized
(almost exclusively) by mortgages or investment
securities and invest in mortgages and mortgagebacked securities. Second, each housing GSE
has certain social obligations. For example, in
2006, 53 percent of Fannie Mae’s and Freddie
Mac’s business must benefit low- and moderateincome families, 38 percent must benefit underserved areas, and 23 percent must serve “special
affordable” needs. The FHLBs contribute at least
10 percent of their net earnings to low- and
moderate- income housing programs and are
also responsible for paying interest on the REFCORP bonds that were issued in the early 1990s
to resolve the savings and loan crisis. Finally, all
three housing GSEs are subject to safety-andsoundness oversight, which may entail further
restrictions on their scale or activities.

1. Until recently none of the housing GSEs registered their equity securities with the SEC. Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac volunteered to do so in July 2002 although only Fannie Mae, to date, has followed through on that commitment, registering in March 2003. In 2004 the Finance Board required each FHLB to register its equity with the
SEC—a process that should be completed by the end of 2006.
2. In the case of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, their federal safety-and-soundness supervisor (OFHEO) does not
have receivership authority. By contrast, as noted by Carnell (2005), the Finance Board has broad authority to
liquidate or reorganize any Federal Home Loan Bank (12 U.S.C. 1446).

solely by the twelve FHLBs and their thrift members.9 Freddie Mac was converted
into a publicly traded company in 1989, with its shares listed on the NYSE.
Each of the three housing GSEs operates under its own federal charter, which
both limits its permissible activities and bestows several institutional benefits (see
the sidebar above). The most valuable of these benefits arises from the financial markets’ perception that the federal government implicitly guarantees housing GSE obligations. As a result, GSE senior debt obligations are rated AAA even though their
stand-alone ratings would be lower.10 The implicit guaranty allows the GSEs to borrow

36

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

at favorable interest rates and then pass some of these savings on to their customers.
Hence, by chartering a specific GSE, the federal government can target benefits
toward a specific sector of the economy without recognizing the attendant opportunity costs in the federal budget.11 However, potential costs remain if Congress were
to provide support to an insolvent GSE. In the late 1980s, for example, the Farm
Credit System received a $4 billion taxpayer bailout.12
The market’s perception of an implicit guaranty of housing GSE obligations distorts
the institutions’ risk-taking incentives in a way that may increase the probability of financial distress. A similar situation is well understood in the context of federally insured
depository institutions. The idea is that a federal guaranty induces bondholders (depositors) to accept artificially low (perhaps even risk-free) promised interest rates regardless of an institution’s true risk of default. GSEs and insured depositories can then
increase the riskiness of their activities—which promise high shareholder returns if the
risks turn out well—without needing to share those rewards with liability holders in the
form of higher coupon rates on their debt (deposits or bonds). The firms’ equity holders thus perceive a greater-than-normal benefit from risk taking, and their investment
decisions can distort capital flows and decrease the expected benefits of financial intermediation in the economy. If this increase in risk occurs, taxpayers effectively subsidize
the equity holders of GSEs and insured depository institutions.
It is important to recognize that insured entities need not explicitly decide to
increase their risks. Such a move could be inadvertent. For example, growing businesses often do not improve their infrastructure as quickly as they raise new revenues.
If the creditors of a fully private firm felt that its risk-management systems had
become inadequate, they could pressure the firm to improve those systems. If the
firm failed to respond, its bond and stock prices would fall, raising the possibility of
a hostile takeover. Federally guaranteed firms, by contrast, do not benefit from this
market discipline, through which outsiders’ concerns about such errors of omission
can be expressed. If the federal guaranty is considered sufficiently strong, bond
claimants may not bother to examine the firm’s infrastructure.
The federal government recognizes these potential moral hazards and has created
safety-and-soundness regulators to limit potential taxpayer exposure. Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac are regulated by OFHEO, an independent agency within the U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD).13 The FHLB System is
overseen by the Federal Housing Finance Board (Finance Board), an independent
9. Moreover, Freddie Mac’s board of directors consisted of the three board members of the FHLB
Board, which regulated the FHLBs and the thrift industry during that time.
10. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac receive AA– ratings from Standard and Poor’s in terms of their risk
to the government. However, such ratings incorporate whatever government support or intervention the entity typically enjoys during the normal course of business. See Frame and Wall (2002)
for a discussion. Those two GSEs also receive “bank financial strength” ratings from Moody’s (on
an A–E scale), which are B+ (Fannie Mae) and A– (Freddie Mac).
11. The appendix to the federal budget, however, discusses each of the five GSEs and provides basic
information about their mission, history, and financial condition. Although additional costs result
from resource misallocations in the real sector, such costs are not recognized in the budget.
12. The U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO) (1990, 90–91) discusses this episode as well as one
in the late 1970s, when Fannie Mae was insolvent on a market-value basis and benefited from
supervisory forbearance.
13. OFHEO was created by the Federal Housing Enterprises Financial Safety and Soundness Act of
1992. Prior to 1992 HUD maintained exclusive regulatory oversight responsibilities for Fannie
Mae and (for 1989–92) Freddie Mac. HUD continues to act as the mission regulator of the two
institutions. Before FIRREA’s passage Freddie Mac was the responsibility of the FHLB Board.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

37

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 1
Federal Home Loan Bank System Combined Balance Sheet as of March 31, 2006

Assets
Advances
Mortgage loans (net)
Investments
Mortgage-backed securities
Federal agency securities
Other investment securities
Federal funds
Interest-bearing deposits
Reverse repurchase agreements
Other assets
Total assets
Liabilities and capital
Consolidated obligations (net)
Other liabilities
Membership capital stock
Retained earnings
Other comprehensive income
Total liabilities and capital

Dollars
(in millions)

Percent
of assets

614,653
103,530
279,012

61.2
10.3
27.8

124,364
20,203
10,051
86,925
34,470
2,998

12.4
2.0
1.0
8.7
3.4
0.3

6,588

0.7

1,003,783

100.0

918,162
40,342
42,602
2,814
(138)

91.5
4.0
4.2
0.3
0.0

1,003,783

100.0

Source: Federal Housing Finance Board

agency within the executive branch.14 Each regulator is authorized to set risk-based
capital standards, conduct examinations, and take certain enforcement actions if
unsafe or unsound practices are identified. Nevertheless, both regulatory agencies
have been criticized for their alleged ineffectiveness.15
Ironically, federal supervision of the GSEs may encourage investors’ faith in a federal guaranty, despite the government’s and the GSEs’ explicit disavowals. As a theoretical matter, it is unclear whether the presence of these safety-and-soundness regulators
increases or decreases expected taxpayer exposure (Frame and White 2004).

Structure, Activities, and Risks of the FHLB System
The FHLB System includes twelve regional wholesale Banks and an Office of Finance
that acts as the FHLBs’ gateway to the capital markets.16 Each Bank is a separate
legal entity, cooperatively owned by its member financial institutions, and has its own
management, employees, and board of directors. Historically, the individual FHLBs
did not compete for members. Each Bank is assigned a distinct geographic area, within which it tries to attract members by offering various credit products, investment
products, payments services, and custody services.17 The FHLB System is often
viewed as a whole because most Bank financing takes the form of debt for which the
twelve Banks are jointly and severally liable.
Table 1 presents a combined balance sheet for the FHLB System as of March 31,
2006.18 The largest asset category is member advances ($615 billion, or 61.2 percent

38

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

of total assets), which constitute the primary avenue by which the FHLBs may support housing and community development. Advances are available in various maturities, carry fixed or variable rates of interest, sometimes contain embedded options,
and are fully collateralized. In terms of maturities, as of March 31, 2006, 39.8 percent
of advances were due in less than one year, 46.6 percent were due in one to five
years, and 13.6 percent were due thereafter. Put and call options that can alter
The troubles experienced by some FHLBs
the duration and yield of an advance were
came as a surprise to many observers since
included in 21.2 percent of the Banks’
combined advance book at the end of the
cooperatives and mutuals are often viewed
first quarter of 2006.19 The most common
as less risky than stock-owned firms.
forms of advance collateral are mortgagerelated assets (whole loans and mortgagebacked securities) and U.S. Treasury and federal agency securities.20 Beyond their
explicit collateral, the FHLBs also have priority over the claims of depositors and
almost all other creditors in the event of a member’s default (12 U.S.C. 1430[e]).21 No
FHLB has ever suffered a credit loss on an advance.
Each FHLB maintains a portfolio of investments, which on a combined basis
totaled $279 billion at the end of the first quarter of 2006. For liquidity, the FHLBs
hold $124.4 billion in short-term investments, such as federal funds and certificates
of deposit, issued by highly rated institutions. The Banks also hold longer-term
investments to enhance interest income ($154.6 billion), especially residential mortgagebacked securities.
The FHLB System’s combined balance sheet has come to include a substantial
proportion of residential mortgages (10.3 percent) since the introduction of the Chicago
FHLB’s Mortgage Partnership Finance Program in 1997. The Banks now purchase
14. The Finance Board was established by FIRREA in 1989 as the regulator of the FHLB System,
thereby replacing the FHLB Board. A five-member board of directors governs the Finance Board;
the president appoints four full-time members with the advice and consent of the Senate for
seven-year terms, designating one of the four as chair. The secretary of HUD is the fifth member.
15. For example, U.S. Treasury Secretary Snow (2003) testified before Congress that there is a “general recognition that the supervisory system for the housing GSEs neither has the tools, nor the
stature, to effectively deal with the current size, complexity, and importance of these enterprises.”
16. The twelve FHLBs are located in Atlanta, Boston, Chicago, Cincinnati, Dallas, Des Moines,
Indianapolis, New York, Pittsburgh, San Francisco, Seattle, and Topeka. The Office of Finance is
located in Reston, Virginia.
17. The specific products and services offered by the individual FHLBs can often be found on their
respective Web sites. Visit www.fhfb.gov/FHLB/FHLBS_banks.htm for links to all twelve FHLBs
and a list of states served by each individual Bank.
18. This information was provided by the Finance Board. Audited financial statements for the combined FHLB System are unavailable pending the completion of each Bank’s registration with the
Securities and Exchange Commission.
19. Putable advances, which provide the FHLB with an option to require the borrower to repay on
prespecified exercise dates before maturity without a fee, made up 16.6 percent of advances. The
Atlanta and New York FHLBs together account for more than half of putable advances outstanding.
Callable advances, which provide the member with an option to prepay on prespecified exercise
dates, made up 4.6 percent of advances. The Cincinnati Bank is responsible for three-quarters of
these loans.
20. See 12 U.S.C. 1430(a)(3) for a complete list of eligible collateral. Federal agency securities are
generally synonymous with debt and mortgage-backed securities issued by GSEs.
21. Bennett, Vaughan, and Yeager (2005) describe how FHLB advances may increase the probability
of bank default and raise the FDIC’s expected losses given default.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

39

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 2
Federal Home Loan Bank Holdings of Mortgages and MBS as of March 31, 2006
Mortgages
(millions of dollars)

MBS
(millions of dollars)

Mortgages + MBS
(millions of dollars)

Mortgages + MBS
(percent of assets)

Atlanta
Boston
Chicago
Cincinnati
Dallas
Des Moines
Indianapolis
New York
Pittsburgh
San Francisco
Seattle
Topeka

2,855
4,838
40,931
8,425
518
12,714
9,867
1,457
7,440
5,079
7,003
2,409

18,728
6,403
8,199
12,395
8,510
5,147
6,805
9,127
9,381
27,072
6,599
5,999

21,583
11,214
49,130
20,820
9,028
17,861
16,672
10,584
16,821
32,151
13,602
8,408

15.50
18.31
55.95
26.31
15.88
40.35
34.37
12.40
23.19
14.15
25.48
17.49

FHLB System

103,537

124,364

227,901

22.70

Source: Federal Housing Finance Board

conforming fixed-rate mortgages on single-family properties from participating member institutions under several distinct programs.22 Roughly speaking, the seller guarantees most of the mortgages’ credit risk, while the interest rate risk is borne by the
FHLBs (Frame 2003). This mortgage-related interest rate exposure is reinforced by
substantial FHLB holdings of mortgage-backed securities (MBS). Table 2 shows that
nearly one-quarter of FHLB System assets were mortgage related at the end of the
first quarter of 2006: $103.5 billion in whole mortgages plus $124.4 billion in MBS. All
twelve FHLBs invest more than 12 percent of their asset portfolios in mortgage-related
assets. The largest concentrations are the Chicago (56.0 percent), Des Moines (40.4 percent), and Indianapolis Banks (34.4 percent).
The FHLB asset portfolios are largely funded with debt, almost all of which takes
the form of “consolidated obligations” issued by the Office of Finance and for which
the twelve Banks are jointly and severally liable. As of March 31, 2006, the FHLB
System had $918.2 billion in consolidated obligations outstanding. Discount notes
(maturities up to one year) represented 17.1 percent of consolidated obligations, and
bonds (maturities almost exclusively between one and ten years) the remaining 82.9
percent. The FHLB System also maintained $45.3 billion in equity capital at that time
(4.5 percent of total assets). Member stock subscriptions are the dominant form of
equity, making up 94 percent of total FHLB System equity. History can readily explain
the unusually small contribution of retained earnings to total capital: Congress previously took the Banks’ retained earnings to help pay for the thrift bailout. Thereafter the
FHLBs began to pay out almost all earnings as dividends. The Financial Modernization
Act of 1999 clarified that a particular class of FHLB shareholders would legally own
the institutions’ retained earnings (as well as surplus, undivided earnings, and equity
reserves) going forward.23
The FHLBs face little credit risk in their asset portfolios. As shown in Table 2,
however, they hold substantial amounts of mortgage-related assets. The interest rate
risk from these assets requires careful treatment because changes in interest rates
influence borrower prepayment behavior, which in turn has implications for the

40

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

expected life of mortgage assets. For example, when interest rates rise, mortgage
investors experience losses in value because they are holding fixed-rate debt instruments yielding a below-market rate of return, and the duration of the asset increases
because of lower expected borrower prepayments. In a falling-rate environment, the
normal value gains associated with holding fixed-rate debt instruments are reduced
by an associated increase in expected prepayments. This phenomenon of additional
adverse effects on mortgage investors from decreases or increases in interest rates is
often described as the “negative convexity” of the mortgage instrument.
Callable bonds provide one important and straightforward way for the FHLBs to
hedge mortgage-related interest rate risk.24 By issuing callable bonds, if interest rates
fall and mortgages prepay, the Banks can replace their higher-cost bonds with new ones
bearing a lower rate of interest. The Banks also regularly use interest rate derivatives
to transform their liability maturities and to hedge some of the negative convexity
associated with fixed-rate mortgages. On March 31, 2006, the FHLB System had
$867.6 billion in total (notional amount) interest rate exchange agreements outstanding—mostly interest rate swaps.
It is very difficult to discern how much interest rate risk the FHLB System actually retains. The FHLBs’ primary measure of interest rate risk exposure is the duration of equity, or the sensitivity of a theoretical market value of a Bank’s equity to
changes in interest rates (FHLB Office of Finance 2004, 47). However, as discussed
in Frame and Wall (2002) and elsewhere, duration analysis may not be well suited to
measuring interest rate risk for portfolios containing numerous embedded options.
Moreover, these duration positions are reported to the Finance Board only quarterly,
and individual FHLBs’ measurements are not directly comparable across institutions.
A review of these figures as of March 31, 2006, suggests that there is significant variation across FHLBs—either in terms of their exposures or reporting practices.
The Finance Board protects FHLB solvency by enforcing leverage and risk-based
capital requirements. Two leverage requirements are set in statute at 4 and 5 percent
of total assets, respectively, depending on the form of equity.25 The Finance Board
also computes a risk-based capital requirement based on each Bank’s credit, market,
and operational risks. On March 31, 2006, required risk-based capital for the individual
FHLBs ranged from 0.4 to 1.2 percent of total assets—well below their leverage capital
standards. Capital adequacy could alternatively be evaluated in the context of each
Bank’s fair value balance sheets. On March 31, 2006, these fair values (as estimated
by the Banks and reported to the Finance Board) ranged between 76.7 percent and
100.7 percent of book value across the FHLB System. In addition, a positive/negative

22. As of late 2004 eight FHLBs exclusively offered the Mortgage Partnership Finance Program in
conjunction with the Chicago FHLB, while three exclusively offered their own Mortgage Purchase
Programs. The Atlanta FHLB offers both options to its members. Conforming mortgages have
principal amounts that are eligible for purchase by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. For single-family
mortgage loans, the conforming loan limit is $417,000 in 2006.
23. The Finance Board recently issued a proposed rule to increase retained earnings (see www.fhfb.
gov/GetFile.aspx?FileID=4476). However, Paletta (2006) reports that the twelve FHLBs collectively sent a letter to their regulator in opposition.
24. During the first six months of 2004, 57.5 percent of FHLB System bond sales were callable, 16.6 percent were fixed rate, 13 percent carried floating rates, and 9.3 percent were “step-ups/step-downs.”
25. The “unweighted” requirement is that total capital (class A stock, class B stock, retained earnings, and general loan loss allowances) must be at least 4 percent of total assets. A “weighted”
requirement sets this standard at 5 percent but has permanent capital (class B stock and retained
earnings) multiplied by 1.5.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

41

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

200 basis point change in interest rates is estimated to affect these fair values by 0.5 to
9.8 percent in absolute value, depending on the institution and direction of interest
rate shock.
To summarize, the FHLB System is a very large and highly leveraged financial
institution. This GSE appears to face little credit risk but a material amount of interest rate risk arising from its mortgage-related asset holdings. The individual FHLBs
manage their interest rate risk by issuing callable debt and entering into interest rate
derivative contracts, although their net exposure is unclear.

Ownership and Governance of the FHLB System
The financial markets’ perception of an implied federal guaranty of FHLB System
debt, coupled with the joint-and-several liability of these same obligations, insulates
individual FHLBs’ funding costs from their exposure to risk. While the incentives created by such a guaranty for profit-maximizing firms like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
are reasonably well understood, the FHLB System has a different organizational structure and hence most likely responds differently to changing circumstances.
Ownership. Each FHLB is a mutual organization owned by its financial institution members. By statute, membership is restricted to banks, thrifts, credit unions,
and insurance companies that are chartered within the FHLBs’ legally defined service
area. A stock purchase is required for membership, and formal control of each Bank
lies with an elected board of directors. The Financial Modernization Act requires
each Bank to design a stock purchase requirement for its members, based on two
classes of stock: Class A stock is redeemable on six months’ written notice from the
member, and class B stock on five years’ notice.26 Members resigning their membership are subject to a five-year lockout from the FHLB System.
Table 3 summarizes the new capital structure plans developed by the eleven
FHLBs that had them in force as of March 31, 2006.27 Despite significant variation in the
specific stock purchase requirements across districts, most of the plans share some
general characteristics. First, almost all of the FHLBs rely exclusively on the more permanent class B shares. Second, the stock purchase requirements contain both “membership” and “activities” components. The membership component is generally tied to
a measure of member size (for example, total assets or total mortgage assets), while
the activity-based component tends to depend on activities that directly affect the size
of a Bank’s balance sheet, such as advances or purchased mortgages. Finally, each of
the requirements is specified with ranges to allow each Bank to adjust stock purchase
requirements without having to seek Finance Board approval.
The new capital plans also include some noteworthy differences. Most obviously,
the capital requirements for similar activities often vary across the Banks. For
example, the activity requirement for FHLB-acquired mortgages varies especially
widely, from 0 to 4.5 percent. Additionally, some FHLBs require members to purchase the sum of their membership and activities requirements, while other FHLBs
require the greater of the two subrequirements. Such variation in member stock
purchase requirements is unlikely to be problematic if institutions can apply for
membership only in a single FHLB. But as we will see below, this proviso may be
becoming outdated.
Governance. Table 4 shows that the twelve FHLBs differ substantially in both
asset size and number of members. The San Francisco FHLB is the largest in terms
of total assets ($227.2 billion), but it has the fourth-fewest number of members
(376). Conversely, the Des Moines FHLB has the smallest balance sheet ($44.3 billion) but the largest membership (1,251). Perhaps even more important to note is

42

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

that each FHLB has a small group of large members. The five largest equity holders
provide between 29 percent and 74 percent of the individual FHLBs’ total equity, and
the five largest borrowers are similarly prominent.
An elected board of directors controls the operations of each FHLB. Given the
concentration of equity holdings noted in Table 3, one might suspect that each FHLB
is easily controlled by a small group of large member institutions, but this is not true.
Two important voting limitations make effective control much more diffuse than the
equity ownership data would suggest (see 12 U.S.C. 1427[b]). First, no member may
vote more than the average number of shares owned by members in its state as of the
prior year’s end. This rule limits concentration of voting rights because every state has
large numbers of small institutions. Second, voting occurs on a state-by-state basis,
and each state must have at least one director. To the extent that large members are
not equally distributed among the states, therefore, concentrated control is even
more limited.
Limiting voting rights does curtail direct control of the FHLBs by the very largest
members: As of midyear 2004, only four of the ten largest FHLB shareholders held a
Bank directorship. This fact does not indicate, however, that the desires of the very
largest members go unheard since these institutions often have competitive wholesale funding alternatives.
Competition. Competitive pressures have been felt increasingly by the individual FHLBs. In terms of the asset portfolio, FHLB advances compete with secured and
unsecured wholesale funding provided by investment banks, commercial banks, and
brokered deposits. This competition is most intense for large depository institution
members, which generally have extensive branch networks and ready access to public capital markets. One way that the FHLBs have responded to this development is by
introducing more complicated advances, such as those with embedded options, which
are attractive to institutions funding fixed-rate mortgage portfolios. FHLB mortgage
programs are also in competition with securitization via Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
as well as outright whole loan sales through a nationwide secondary market.
Competition for members has also escalated. Prior to the Financial Modernization
Act of 1999, federally insured thrift institutions were required to become FHLB members. Today, however, FHLB membership is voluntary. The commercial banks, thrifts,
and credit unions chartered in a Bank’s geographic territory will join only if they
receive valuable services. In addition, some acquisitive financial institutions have
retained charters in multiple FHLB districts, a practice that permits them to borrow
from the FHLB offering the cheapest advances.28 Today about 100 such cases exist, in
effect creating a degree of inter-FHLB competition.29 This practice has also spurred
policy discussion about whether FHLB membership should be opened further to allow
26. Prior to this act, the law allowed for only one class of stock, which was redeemable on six months’
written notice. The Chicago FHLB continues to be subject to this old framework.
27. The Chicago FHLB has not yet converted to the new capital structure. The Bank had originally
received regulatory approval in 2002 for a capital plan that relied on members’ discretionary
stockholdings (excess stock) to support its mortgage portfolio. However, the Bank agreed in early
2005 to delay implementation to the new structure as part of a three-year business plan. Over this
period the Bank expects to substantially reduce its ratio of excess stock to regulatory capital
before converting to a revised capital plan.
28. For example, Washington Mutual Inc. currently maintains membership in four FHLBs: San
Francisco, Seattle, Dallas, and New York.
29. See U.S. GAO (2003) for a discussion of competition within the FHLB System, including the role
of the price and nonprice terms of credit.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

43

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Panel A: Boston, New York, Pittsburgh, Atlanta, Cincinnati, and Indianapolis

Third Quarter 2006

Boston

New York

Pittsburgh

Atlanta

Cincinnati

Indianapolis

Date of conversion

April 19, 2004

Dec. 1, 2005

Dec. 16, 2002

Dec. 17, 2004

Dec. 30, 2002

Jan. 2, 2003

Classes of stock

All B

All B with 2 subclasses

All B

All B with two subclasses

All B

All B with two subclasses

Membership investment
requirements

0.35% of “membership stock
investment base” (range: 0.05
to 0.50%)

0.20% of “mortgage-related
assets” (range: 0.10 to 0.25%)

0.55% of unused borrowing
capacity (range: 0 to 1.5%)

0.20% of total assets (range:
0.05 to 0.40%)

Cumulative sliding scale that
varies inversely with member’s
asset size

1% of total mortgage assets
(range: 0.75 to 1.25%)

Membership stock investment
base is the total nondiscounted
assets eligible to secure
advances (single- and multifamily
mortgage loans, Treasury and
agency securities, and MBS).

Mortgage-related assets are
defined as “residential housing
finance assets” (12 CFR 950.1)
plus loans secured by manufactured housing, nonresidential nonfarm real property, and other mortgage-related securities.

a. Minimum membership
requirement

$10,000 (range: $5,000 to
$50,000)

$1,000

$10,000

None

None

$1,000

b. Maximum membership
requirement

$25 million (range: $5 million
to $100 million)

None

None

$25 million (range: $15 million to
$35 million)

None

$35 million

Activity requirements

At time of conversion scale was
$0–$25B in assets: 0.15%;
>$25B–$50B in assets: 0.10%;
>$50B–$75B in assets: 0.07%;
>$75B–$100B in assets: 0.05%;
>$100B in assets: 0.03%
(range: 0.03 to 0.30%)

Ratio of par value of members’
activity stock to members’
mission asset activity must be
between the minimum allocation
percentage and the maximum
allocation percentage.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

44

Table 3
Federal Home Loan Bank Capital Plans: Membership Requirements, Activity Requirements, and Total Requirements

Third Quarter 2006

New York

Pittsburgh

Atlanta

Cincinnati

Indianapolis

a. Advances

3% of outstanding principal
balance of overnight advances
plus 4.5% of outstanding principal
balance of nonovernight advances
(range: 3 to 6%)

4.5% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 4 to 5%)

4.55% of all loans (range: 4.5
to 6.0%)

4.5% of outstanding principal
balance (range 3.5 to 6.0%)

Requirement for minimum
allocation percentage is 2%;
requirement for maximum
allocation percentage is 4%
(range: 1 to 6%)

5% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 2 to 5%)

b. Mortgage purchases

0% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 0 to 6%)

4.5% of outstanding principal
balance for loans delivered or
commitments in effect after the
effective date of the plan (range:
4 to 5%)

0% of AMA delivered and held by
Bank (range: 0 to 4.0%)

0% of outstanding principal
balance (range 0 to 6.0%)

Requirement for minimum
allocation percentage is 0%;
requirement for maximum
allocation percentage is 4%
(range: 0 to 6%)

0% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 0 to 5%)

c. Standby letters of credit

4.5% of face/notional amount
adjusted for conversion factor in
12 CFR 932.4(f) Table 2 (range: 3
to 6%)

0% for contingent liabilities, including lines of credit (range: 0% to
risk-based capital
requirement)

N/A

N/A

N/A

5% of commitment amount
(range: 2 to 5%)

d. Exchange agreements

4.5% of the Bank’s current
exposure calculated per 12 CFR
932.4(h)(1) plus Bank’s
potential exposure calculated
per 12 CFR 932.4(h)(2) (range: 3
to 6%)

0% of carrying value of derivatives
(range: 0 to 5% of book value)

N/A

N/A

N/A

5% of the amount of collateral
required from the transaction
(range: 3 to 5%)

e. Other

Advance or delivery commitments:
0% of face/notional amount
adjusted for conversion factor in
12 CFR 932.4(f)
Table 2 (range: 0 to 6%)

N/A

N/A

Targeted debt/equity investments:
8.0% of outstanding
principal balance (range: 6.0
to 9.0%)

Advance commitments:
Requirement for minimum allocation percentage is 2%; requirement for maximum allocation percentage is 4% (range: 1 to 6%)

N/A

Total stock purchase
requirement

Membership requirement plus
activity requirement

Membership requirement plus
activity requirement

Membership requirement plus
activity requirement

Membership requirement plus
activity requirement

Membership requirement plus
activity requirement

Greater of membership requirement or activity requirement

(continued on next page)

45

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Boston

Panel B: Des Moines, Dallas, Topeka, San Francisco, and Seattle
ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

Des Moines

Dallas

Topeka

San Francisco

Seattle

Date of conversion

July 1, 2003

Sept. 2, 2003

Sept. 30, 2004

April 1, 2004

June 30, 2002

Classes of stock

All B

All B

A and B

All B

All B with two subclasses

Membership requirements

0.12% of member assets
(range: 0.10 to 0.25%)

0.09% of total assets (range: 0.05
to 0.30%)

0.2% of total assets (range: 0.1
to 0.4%)

1% of “membership asset value,” or
assets qualified as FHLB collateral
(range: 0.5 to 1.5%)

0.50% of home mortgage loans (range:
0.5 to 1.0%)

May only purchase class A stock to fulfill this requirement.
a. Minimum membership requirement

$10,000 (range: $10,000 to $30,000)

$1,000

$1,000

None

$500

b. Maximum membership requirement

$10 million (range: $10 million to
$30 million)

$25 million (range: $10 million to
$50 million)

$1 million (range: $500,000 to
$2.5 million)

$25 million (range: $10 million to
$50 million)

None

a. Advances

4.45% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 3 to 5%)

4.10% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 3.5 to 5%)

5.0% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 4 to 6%)

4.7% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 4.4 to 5%)

2.5% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 2.5 to 4.5%)

b. Mortgage purchases

4.45% of outstanding principal
balance (range 3 to 5%)

4.10% of outstanding principal
balance (range: 0 to 5%)

2% of principal amount sold to Bank
subject to cap of 1.5% of total assets
as of preceding year-end (ranges: for
req. 0 to 6%; for cap 1 to 3%)

5.0% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 5.0 to 5.7%)

5.0% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 0 to 6.0%)

c. Standby letters of credit

0.15% (range: 0 to 0.175%)

N/A

0% of outstanding principal balance
(range: 0 to 1%)

N/A

N/A

d. Exchange agreements

N/A

N/A

0% of notional principal amount (range:
0 to 2%)

N/A

N/A

e. Other

Advance commitments: 0%
(range: 0 to .35%)
Mortgage purchase commitments: 0%
(range: 0 to .60%)

N/A

N/A

Provision for capital assessment if capital level insufficient for Bank to meet
minimum regulatory requirements or
target ratios

N/A

Total stock purchase requirement

Membership requirement plus activity
requirement

Membership requirement plus activity
requirement

Greater of membership requirement or
activity requirement; member only
required to hold class B stock equal to
the amount by which the activity
requirement exceeds the membership
requirement

Greater of membership requirement
or activity requirement

Membership requirement plus activity
requirement

Activity requirements

Note: The table does not include the Chicago FHLB because that bank has not yet adopted the capital structure plans described.
Source: Federal Housing Finance Board and individual FHLB capital plans

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

46

Table 3 (continued)

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table 4
Federal Home Loan Bank Membership as of March 31, 2006

Atlanta
Boston
Chicago
Cincinnati
Dallas
Des Moines
Indianapolis
New York
Pittsburgh
San Francisco
Seattle
Topeka

Total assets
(billions of dollars)

Number of
members

Membership
concentration as a
percent of capitala

Membership
concentration as a
percent of advancesa

139.3
61.4
87.8
79.1
56.9
44.3
48.5
85.3
72.5
227.2
53.4
48.1

1,210
467
879
742
887
1,251
434
299
334
376
367
896

38.9
36.7
29.2
50.0
49.4
37.8
46.5
40.3
54.4
73.7
53.8
40.3

49.0
47.3
39.7
60.4
61.8
24.1
52.9
40.1
61.1
80.7
65.1
51.4

a
Percentages for the five largest members
Source: Federal Housing Finance Board

any eligible financial institutions to access the FHLB System through multiple channels
(multidistrict membership).30
Recent troubles at the Seattle FHLB illustrate how inter-Bank competition may
induce risk taking. In 2002 the Seattle Bank decided to change its portfolio structure
by substituting mortgage assets for advances. It shed advances by raising the interest rates on them. Washington Mutual, the largest borrower from the Seattle FHLB
at that time, responded by moving a substantial part of its advance borrowings to
other FHLBs in which its affiliates held memberships, although it maintained its
stock investment. The low-interest-rate environment and mortgage refinance wave of
2003, coupled with imperfect hedging, resulted in a material decline in the Seattle
FHLB’s market value. The Seattle Bank responded by reducing its mortgage purchases, but instead of redeeming excess capital, the institution sought to boost
returns by investing in callable FHLB System consolidated debt obligations funded
largely with shorter-term, noncallable instruments. The flattening of the yield curve
during 2004 resulted in additional market-value losses, which totaled $260 million by
the end of that year.

Risk-Taking Incentives in the FHLB System
An important cost associated with financial institutions operating with government
guarantees (implicit or explicit) is the aforementioned moral hazard incentive for
such institutions to increase their risk exposure—on purpose or inadvertently—in
order to maximize shareholder returns. The recent financial troubles at all three

30. This discussion started with some petitions by acquiring depository institutions to retain FHLB
membership in the district of the target even though the target’s charter would be dissolved; see
U.S. GAO (2003). The Finance Board subsequently issued an advanced notice of proposed rule
making about multidistrict membership in October 2001, but the regulator never promulgated
regulations. Bair (2003) discusses in detail and analyzes the question of whether the Finance
Board has the statutory authority to permit multidistrict membership.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

47

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

housing GSEs may reflect this moral hazard. The difficulties experienced by some
FHLBs are notable, however, because cooperatively owned firms are often thought to
be less risky than stock-owned firms. Here we discuss some unique features of the
FHLB System that may act to enhance or subdue FHLB risk-taking incentives relative to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Ownership structure. Some of the FHLBs have argued that their cooperative
structure mitigates moral hazard incentives. In 2003 the president of the Federal
Home Loan Bank of Dallas testified before Congress that
the [Federal Home Loan] Banks’ cooperative corporate structure reinforces our
conservative approach to risk management and eliminates many of the incentives
that a publicly traded company might have to increase its risk profile in hopes of
achieving higher returns for its shareholders. There is no stock compensation for
management, directors, or employees of the Banks. (Smith 2003, 31)

Two years later, the president of the Atlanta FHLB expressed a similar view:
The cooperative structure of the FHLBanks eliminates many of the incentives a
publicly traded company might have to raise its risk profile in search of higher
returns. (Christman 2005, 7)

Under some circumstances, cooperatively owned financial institutions can be
less prone to risk taking than their stock-owned counterparts. Moral hazard arises
because the shareholders and bondholders (or their guarantor) have conflicting preferences about risk taking. Many leveraged cooperative and mutual financial institutions combine the equity and debt claims to eliminate this potential conflict. For
example, credit union and mutual thrift depositors (liability holders) are also owners
(equity holders). Empirical evidence for thrifts and insurance companies strongly
supports the notion that such cooperative and mutual firms are less risky.31
Unfortunately, the analogy between these cooperatives and the FHLB System is
not precise. The Banks’ equity holders are the member financial institutions, while
their bondholders are widely dispersed throughout the capital markets. These two
groups remain distinct in the FHLB structure, rendering the “bundling of claims”
argument inapplicable. Hence, the cooperative structure of the FHLB System does
not necessarily insulate the Banks from excessive risk taking.
Joint and several liability. The cross-guarantee provision in the FHLB System’s
consolidated debt obligations likely reinforces the moral hazard arising from the perceived federal guaranty.32 Funding costs for the individual Banks reflect the average
risk of the FHLB System rather than the exposure of any one institution. Hence, any
FHLB System-wide incentive to increase risk because of the perceived implied federal guaranty is further accompanied by an incentive at the individual FHLB level to
increase risk relative to its sister institutions, as might be induced by competition for
members. In this way, moral hazard incentives could be heightened relative to Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac.
Equity market discipline. For publicly traded firms, share prices may act as a
disciplining force; for example, financial difficulties can spur a price decline and signal
to management that it should reduce risk. However, for financial institutions that
operate with (implicit or explicit) government guarantees, such as the housing-related
GSEs, this relationship is less clear. Since the cost of their liabilities is not risksensitive, these institutions may be inclined to respond to share price declines by

48

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

actually increasing risk. Regulators are charged with monitoring such behavior. In
any event, equity market discipline is not even present for the FHLBs since the stock
is not traded. Indeed, Bank equity is always exchanged at par so that neither the public
nor the regulators will ever see a price decline signaling potential trouble.
Each member’s FHLB stock can be separated into a required component (as
described in Table 3) and an “excess” component. In order to redeem its required
membership stock, the institution must resign from the FHLB and may not rejoin it
for five years. This lock-out period represents a significant opportunity cost that
It is important to recognize that insured
renders equity market discipline through
entities need not explicitly decide to
membership withdrawal unlikely.
Some members also hold “excess”
increase their risks. Such a move could
stock as an investment, which a Bank can
be inadvertent.
leverage to generate additional earnings.
Under most circumstances, members can
redeem their “excess” stock at par upon demand.33 So, if a Bank suffers losses or
becomes more risky, some members may try to withdraw their excess stock. This
action would force the Bank to reduce its scale of operations—a general form of market discipline. However, this avenue is also partially blocked. The FHLB may deny
early redemption requests (before six months for class A and before five years for
class B shares) at its discretion (12 U.S.C. 1426[e][1]), and, if a Bank’s safety and
soundness becomes questionable, both the Bank and the Finance Board can limit
redemption indefinitely (12 C.F.R. 931.8). This discretion limits market discipline
because it provides time for a troubled FHLB to gamble for resurrection.
The recent episode at the Chicago Bank illustrates the lack of market discipline
associated with excess stock. When that FHLB experienced accounting difficulties,
excess stock redemption requests increased, but the Bank halted redemptions in late
2005 (see FHLB of Chicago 2005). In June 2006, the Finance Board permitted the
Chicago FHLB to issue $1 billion of ten-year subordinated debt (for which the Bank
is sole obligor) and to use the proceeds to repurchase excess shares.34 One interpretation of this transaction is that it allowed the Chicago FHLB to increase its risk by
substituting debt for equity. However, FHLB excess stock itself has debtlike features,
31. Esty (1997) examines the riskiness of thrifts during the 1980s and finds that stock-owned institutions had both riskier portfolios and higher failure rates than mutuals. Lamm-Tennant and
Starks (1993) study property-liability insurers and uncover that stock-owned firms have riskier
future cash flows as proxied by the variance of the loss ratio. Lee, Mayers, and Smith (1997) find
that risk in the asset portfolios of stock-owned property-liability insurers increased markedly relative to their mutually owned counterparts following enactment of state guaranty fund laws.
32. One counterargument to this assumption is that joint and several liability may induce the FHLBs
to monitor one another. However, the Banks may lack the willingness to do so because of standard “free-rider” problems, the presence of the conjectural federal guaranty, and the fact that
they have no authority to directly discipline each other.
33. For this reason, excess stock is actually treated as a liability by the Banks according to Financial
Accounting Standards Board Statement 150, Accounting for Certain Financial Instruments
with Characteristics of Both Liabilities and Equity. The Finance Board, however, treats
excess stock as equity for purposes of determining compliance with minimum regulatory capital
requirements. Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee (2006) has called on the Finance Board
to rethink this position.
34. In doing so, the regulator granted certain waivers that will allow these debentures to be used in
determining compliance with the Chicago Bank’s regulatory leverage requirement (see Federal
Housing Finance Board 2006).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

49

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

and the lack of market pricing for these claims limits their value as market discipline
tools. In any event, the future importance of excess stock holdings is currently questionable as the Finance Board recently proposed a rule that would limit excess stock
to 1 percent of a Bank’s total assets.
Charter value. Marcus (1984) identifies a factor that may reduce a guaranteed
financial institution’s interests in increasing its portfolio risk: nonmarketable charter
value. This effect depends on the supervisor being able to close a firm whose book
value of equity falls to zero even if the
Cooperative ownership itself does not reduce institution has “off book” assets that would
remain valuable if the firm did not fail. In
FHLB risk-taking incentives because, unlike
Marcus’s example, a bank’s charter value
derives from its ability to borrow at subsimany mutuals, the FHLB System does not
dized (guaranteed) rates in the future,
bundle its equity and debt claims.
provided it remains in operation. Financial
institutions with charter value effectively
have more capital at risk than the book value of capital shown on their balance
sheets. Since greater levels of capital reduce the incentive to engage in risky behavior, other things being equal, financial institutions with charter value will tend to be
less risky.
Frame and White (forthcoming) discuss the presence of charter value in the
case of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The FHLBs may similarly derive charter
value from their ability to borrow at attractive rates in the agency debt market as
well as from geographic membership restrictions. However, any disciplining role of
charter value is likely to be less for the FHLBs than it is for Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. First, the Banks’ cooperative structure and diffuse control may result
in less of the charter value actually accruing to owners because cooperative firms’
managers can more easily capture economic rents for themselves (see, for example,
Hansmann 1996). The limited competition for members among the Banks due to
geographic boundaries creates similar issues. Second, in the event that a Bank’s
member-owners lost charter value because of a Bank’s insolvency, these members
would almost certainly have an opportunity to join the reconstituted institution or
another FHLB.
Managerial incentives. Managerial incentives can sometimes counterbalance
shareholders’ incentive to take excessive risks. When they are paid a fixed salary,
managers tend to avoid risk. They do not share in the good outcomes, and a bad outcome can substantially harm a manager’s career prospects. Managerial preferences
can thus diverge from shareholder preferences. To align managers’ interests with
those of shareholders, executive compensation often includes a performance-based
element such as stock options.35 Strictly speaking, cooperative and mutual institutions cannot provide equity-based compensation since they do not have traded equity.
However, even a cooperative firm’s executives can be offered incentive payments
that may be correlated with risk taking.
Before 1999 the Finance Board limited the amount and the form of compensation packages that FHLB directors could offer Bank presidents. A base salary cap was
established annually for each institution, and the president’s incentive payments
could not exceed 25 percent of that cap. The Financial Modernization Act rescinded
the Finance Board’s direct role over FHLB executive compensation. Since that time
the incentive component of the FHLB presidents’ actual compensation has roughly
doubled relative to salary, from a mean of 22 percent of total compensation in 1999
to almost 40 percent in 2005.

50

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Recent SEC filings provide detailed information on the criteria underlying incentive payments at some of the FHLBs. Much like publicly traded corporations, the
reported FHLB incentive payments are tied primarily to the Banks’ profitability and
growth. For example, the Indianapolis FHLB awards incentive compensation to
seven officers with the following weights on four goals: profitability (50 percent),
increase in average total advances (25 percent), increase in mortgage purchase production (20 percent), and community investment advances originated (5 percent).36
Some of the FHLBs also provide longer-term incentive payments, such as the Chicago
FHLB’s “Stock Equivalent Account”:
A Stock Equivalent Account (“SEA”) shall be established for each award recipient hereunder. Payments to the SEA shall be credited as “shares” at $100 per
share. “Shares” in the SEA shall earn interest at the same rate as the Bank’s net
return on equity after REFCO during each corresponding quarter. Interest shall
be paid in the form of additional and fractional “shares” in the SEA. The interest
calculation method herein shall apply to all existing SEA balances as of January 1,
1996. . . . SEA “shares” and interest thereon are vested on March 1 in the year
following the year in which such “shares” were first credited to the SEA. . . .
SEA “shares” may be converted to cash and withdrawn, at the option of the
award recipient, as follows: (1) 50% upon vesting and (2) the balance one year
after vesting.

SEA payments are similar to stock awards made by public corporations, although
SEA value is based only on past earnings (and not expected future earnings) and
cash-outs are subject to a one-year delay.
FHLB executives have been offered increasing incentives for profitability and
growth, and both of these are correlated with risk taking. However, it is important to
point out that FHLB incentive payments are much lower in both absolute and relative terms than those at Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac or at the typical large bank.
Furthermore, FHLB executives are not granted stock options, which provide particularly strong risk-taking incentives. Emmons and Sierra (2004) report that in 2003
the chief executive of Fannie Mae (Franklin Raines) was paid a salary of $1 million,
a bonus of about $4.4 million, and stock and options worth $15 million. Indeed, at the
end of that year, Raines owned $17.4 million in stock outright plus options exercisable within sixty days to control another $113 million in stock. The authors also
report that executive compensation arrangements at Freddie Mac were similar at
that time.
Overall, there are some important differences between the FHLBs and Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac that influence each institutions’ risk-taking incentives. Some
differences suggest stronger risk-taking incentives at the Banks, while others do not.
The extent to which each housing GSE gears its managerial compensation toward
risk taking seems to be especially important. In any event, effective and timely supervision by the Finance Board will be even more critical going forward.

35. According to Murphy (1999, 2489), most executive pay packages contain four basic components:
a base salary, an annual bonus tied to accounting performance, stock options, and long-term incentive plans (including restricted stock plans and multiyear accounting-based performance plans).
36. Profitability targets generally tend to be based on the difference (spread) between pre-FAS 133
net income (per dollar of equity) and LIBOR. Many of the plans also tend to leave significant discretion to the board of directors to determine annual incentive compensation.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

51

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Conclusion
Historically, the twelve Federal Home Loan Banks provided low-cost liquidity to the
mortgage market via collateralized advances to specialized mortgage lenders. Credit
losses on those advances have literally been zero since 1932. However, legislative
changes in the wake of the thrift crises spurred the Banks to expand in terms of both
size and scope. In addition to advances, FHLB balance sheets have also come to
include a substantial investment in mortgages and mortgage-backed securities. The
attendant interest rate risk has created financial and accounting difficulties at some
of the Banks. These troubles caught many observers off guard because they have
come to think of the cooperatively owned FHLBs as low-risk institutions.
Like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the FHLB System is a GSE that funds itself
largely with federal agency debt obligations that are perceived by investors to be
implicitly guaranteed by the U.S. government. While the incentive effects of such
guaranteed liabilities on investor-owned firms are quite well understood, the impact
on cooperatively owned firms is less obvious and dependent on the firms’ structure.
We identified some differences between the FHLB System and Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac that can result in differential risk-taking incentives. Importantly, we find
that cooperative ownership itself does not reduce FHLB risk-taking incentives
because, unlike many mutuals, the FHLB System does not bundle its equity and debt
claims. We also find that Bank risk-taking incentives may be heightened by the jointand-several liability provision in their consolidated debt obligations and a lack of
equity market discipline, including a weakened role for nonmarketable charter value.
However, the FHLBs cannot avail themselves of equity-based managerial compensation (particularly stock options), which creates high-powered risk-taking incentives in
stock-owned firms. Thus, it is unclear whether the FHLBs’ risk-taking incentives are
necessarily weaker than those at Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
The Federal Home Loan Bank System has been financially sound since its inception in 1932. However, the Banks’ incentives and ability to take risk expanded in
recent years, and no claimant appears well positioned to provide strong discipline.
This situation makes the Finance Board’s supervisory task all the more challenging
and important.

52

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

REFERENCES
Bair, Sheila. 2003. Is the Federal Home Loan Bank
System forsaking its roots? <http://www.fanniemae.com/
commentary/pdf/071403.pdf;jsessionid=XTZUWWAAC
KXRJJ2FQSHSFGI> (August 18, 2006).

Frame, W. Scott, and Larry D. Wall. 2002. Fannie Mae’s
and Freddie Mac’s voluntary initiatives: Lessons from
banking. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic
Review 87, no. 1:45–59.

Baker-Botts LLP. 2003. Report to the board of directors
of the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation:
Internal investigation of certain accounting matters,
December 10, 2002–July 21, 2003. <www.freddiemac.
com/news/board_report> (August 18, 2006).

Frame, W. Scott, and Lawrence J. White. 2004.
Regulating housing GSEs: Thoughts on institutional
structure and authorities. Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta Economic Review 89, no. 2:87–102.

Bennett, Rosalind L., Mark D. Vaughan, and Timothy J.
Yeager. 2005. Should the FDIC worry about the FHLB?
The impact of Federal Home Loan Bank advances on
the Bank Insurance Fund. FDIC Center for Financial
Research Working Paper 2005-10. <www.fdic.gov/
bank/analytical/cfr/2005/wp2005/CFRWP_2005_10_
Bennett_Vaughan_Yeager.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
Carnell, Richard S. 2005. Handling the failure of a
government-sponsored enterprise. Washington Law
Review 80 (August): 565–642.
Christman, Raymond R. 2005. Testimony before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,
U.S. Senate. April 20. <http://banking.senate.gov/
_files/christman.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
Emmons, William R., and Gregory E. Sierra. 2004.
Executive compensation at Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Supervisory
and Policy Analysis Working Paper 2004–6.
<www.stlouisfed.org/banking/SPA/WorkingPapers/
SPA_2004_06.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
Esty, Benjamin C. 1997. Organizational form and risk
taking in the savings and loan industry. Journal of
Financial Economics 44, no. 1:25–55.
Federal Home Loan Bank of Chicago. 2005. 3rd quarter dividend and capital stock actions announced.
News release, October 18. <www.fhlbc.com/fhlbc/
docs/press_release/general/2005/2005_3Q_FHLBC_
dividend.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
Federal Home Loan Banks Office of Finance. 2004.
Federal Home Loan Banks: Quarterly financial report
for the six months ended June 30, 2004. <www.fhlbof.com/specialinterest/finreportframe.html> (August
18, 2006).
Federal Housing Finance Board. 2006. FHFB authorizes debt issuance by the Federal Home Loan Bank
of Chicago. News release, April 18. <www.fhfb.gov/
GetFile.aspx?FileID=4579> (August 18, 2006).
Frame, W. Scott. 2003. Federal Home Loan Bank mortgage purchases: Implications for mortgage markets.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review
88, no. 3:17–31.

———. Forthcoming. Charter value, risk-taking incentives, and emerging competition for Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking.
Goldfeld, Stephen M., Dwight M. Jaffee, and Richard
E. Quandt. 1980. A model of FHLBB advances:
Rationing or market clearing? Review of Economics
and Statistics 62, no. 3:339–47.
Green, Richard K., and Susan M. Wachter. 2005. The
American mortgage in historical and international
context. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19,
no. 4:93–114.
Greenspan, Alan. 2004. Government-sponsored enterprises. Testimony before the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate. February 24.
<www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/testimony/
2004/20040224/default.htm> (August 18, 2006).
Hansmann, Henry. 1996. The ownership of enterprise.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Hoffmann, Susan, and Mark Cassell. 2002. What are
the Federal Home Loan Banks up to? Emerging views
of purpose among institutional leadership. Public
Administration Review 62, no. 4:461–70.
Jaffee, Dwight. 1976. The Federal Home Loan Bank
System since 1965. Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy 4:161–203.
———. 2003. The interest rate risk of Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac. Journal of Financial Services
Research 24, no. 1:5–29.
Kopecki, Dawn. 2005. Fannie says $2.4B in additional
losses possible. Dow Jones Newswires, March 17.
Lamm-Tennant, Joan, and Laura T. Starks. 1993. Stock
versus mutual ownership structures: The risk implications. Journal of Business 66, no. 1:29–46.
Lee, Soon Jae, David Mayers, and Clifford W. Smith Jr.
1997. Guaranty funds and risk-taking: Evidence from
the insurance industry. Journal of Financial
Economics 44, no. 1:3–24.
Marcus, Alan J. 1984. Deregulation and bank financial policy. Journal of Banking and Finance 8,
no. 4:557–65.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

53

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Mays, Elizabeth. 1989. A profit-maximizing model of
Federal Home Loan Bank behavior. Journal of Real
Estate Finance and Economics 2:331–47.
Murphy, Kevin J. 1999. Executive compensation. In
Handbook of labor economics, vol. 3B, edited by Orley
Ashenfelter and David Card. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Nickerson, David, and Ronnie Phillips. 2004. The
Federal Home Loan Bank System and the Farm Credit
System: Historic parallels and implications for systemic risk. In Too big to fail: Policies and practices
in government bailouts, edited by Benton Gup.
Westport, Conn.: Praeger Books.
Paletta, Damian. 2006. FHLBs “strongly urge” FHFB
to pull retained earnings plan. Dow Jones Newswires,
May 4.
Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton, and Garrison LLP.
2006. A report to the Special Review Committee of
the Board of Directors of Fannie Mae, February 23.
<http://download.fanniemae.com/report.pdf>
(August 18, 2006).
Quigley, John M. 2005. Federal credit and insurance
programs: Housing. Paper presented at Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis conference “Federal
Credit and Insurance Programs,” October 20–21.
<http://research.stlouisfed.org/conferences/policyconf/
papers2005/quigley.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee. 2006.
Strengthening the capital structure of Federal Home
Loan Banks. Statement no. 232, May 8. < www.aei.org/
research/shadow/projectID.15/default.asp>
(August 18, 2006).

54

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

Silber, William L. 1973. A model of the Federal Home
Loan Bank System and Federal National Mortgage
Association behavior. Review of Economics and
Statistics 55, no. 3:308–20.
Smith, Terry. 2003. Testimony before the Subcommittee
on Financial Institutions of the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate. September 9.
<http://banking.senate.gov/_files/ACFC.pdf>
(August 18, 2006).
Snow, John. 2003. Testimony before the Committee
on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives.
September 10. <www.treas.gov/press/releases/
js716.htm> (August 18, 2006).
U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO). 1990.
Government-sponsored enterprises: The government’s exposure to risks. Washington, D.C.: U.S. GAO.
———. 2003. Federal Home Loan Bank System:
Key loan pricing terms can differ significantly.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. GAO.
U.S. Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight
(OFHEO). 2003. Report of the special examination
of Freddie Mac. December. <www.ofheo.gov/media/
pdf/specialreport122003.pdf> (August 18, 2006).
———. 2004. Report of findings to date: Special
examination of Fannie Mae. September 17.
<www.ofheo.gov/media/pdf/FNMfindingstodate17
sept04.pdf> (August 18, 2006).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Official Dollarization
and the Banking System
in Ecuador and El Salvador
MYRIAM QUISPE-AGNOLI AND ELENA WHISLER
Quispe-Agnoli is a research economist and assistant policy adviser in the regional section
of the Atlanta Fed’s research department. Whisler is the retail payments project coordinator
in the Federal Reserve System’s Retail ACH Payments Office. They thank Stephen Kay, Melinda
Pitts, John Robertson, Pedro Silos, and Diego Vilán for helpful conversations and comments.

ince Ecuadorian president Jamil Mahuad announced the adoption of the U.S. dollar as legal tender in January 2000, the discussion about the pros and cons of full
dollarization has intensified. In 2001 El Salvador engaged in full dollarization to
enhance its economic reform process. The two economies adopted the U.S. dollar as
their currency for diametrically opposite reasons: In Ecuador full dollarization occurred
in the midst of an economic and banking crisis. In contrast, in El Salvador full dollarization was expected to enhance the set of previous structural reforms put in place
to support economic stability and thus attract foreign investors. This article studies
the evolution of the banking system in these two countries before and after the adoption
of full, or official, dollarization.1
Under full or official dollarization, a country adopts as legal tender another country’s currency, in this case the U.S. dollar. The adopted currency takes over all the
functions of domestic currency: a unit of account, medium of exchange, and store
of value. The country’s policymakers thus give up any possibility of monetary and
exchange rate policies. Official dollarization is equivalent to pegging the domestic
currency to the U.S. dollar, but it is different from a currency board because it is irreversible. This irreversibility theoretically makes full dollarization a credible economic
policy and a way to avoid currency and balance-of-payments crises.
The expected benefits of full dollarization include the elimination of exchange
rate risk, contributing to the decline of the country risk premium and interest
rates, as well as the reduction of the inflation rate and inflationary expectations.
These outcomes are expected to encourage foreign investment and a stable capital
flow. One cost of full dollarization is the elimination of the government’s ability to
generate seigniorage—that is, revenue from issuing domestic money—to finance
its fiscal deficit. Without this possibility, the dollarizing country must look for alternative revenue sources or reduce government expenditures. By giving up control
of its money supply, a full dollarization regime encourages fiscal discipline (enhancing

S

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

55

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

policy credibility) but also constrains the fiscal response to stabilize the economy
in difficult times.
Some initial conditions could be relevant in the decision to implement official
dollarization. Minda (2005) and Edwards and Magendzo (2006) observe that small
countries with close trade or financial ties to the United States could favor official
dollarization, as Panama did in 1904. Ecuador, El Salvador, and Panama, the largest
countries that have implemented official dollarization, are still relatively small and
are very open to U.S. trade and finance,
with an average gross domestic product
The restriction on the role of the monetary
(GDP) of $11 billion (in 2000 dollars) and
authority as lender of last resort is one of
an average population of 7 million in 2004.2
the costs of full dollarization.
A relevant factor in policymakers’
decision to adopt full dollarization is the
depth and type of partial dollarization already present in the economy.3 A banking
system with a large portion of deposits or loans denominated in foreign currency
might have a smaller adjustment with the adoption of official dollarization than a
system whose share is small or negligible. Banks in a dollarized economy might
have internalized the costs of operating in such environment. They could already
have foreign currency liquid assets, or the financial system could have adopted
other prudential regulations to control or reduce liquidity and solvency risks. In
addition, a country that is experiencing a currency or banking crisis might be more
likely to implement official dollarization. Edwards (1995) points out that policymakers might be willing to make radical decisions in times of crisis rather than in
times of economic stability. The realization and timing of expected benefits from
full dollarization might depend on whether a country implemented it after an economic crisis, such as the currency and banking crisis in Ecuador, or as part of its
structural reform process.

Official Dollarization and the Banking System
Three effects on the banking system under full dollarization are considered in this
article: restrictions on the central bank as lender of last resort, the effect of economic
stability on the performance of banks, and the promotion of financial integration with
the world economy.
The restriction on the role of the monetary authority as lender of last resort is
one of the costs of full dollarization. Central banks provide loans to banks facing liquidity problems. Under official dollarization, printing money is no longer a feasible
source of liquidity, and the central bank needs to look for alternative responses to
episodes of financial distress. Chang and Velasco (2000) study the case of an economy
under a fixed exchange rate regime with a central bank that does not act as a lender
of last resort, concluding that this regime is more prone to bank runs than a currency
board. In this case, the liabilities of the banking system as a whole are, implicitly, obligations in international currency. Consequently, a bank run is possible if the banking
system’s implicit liabilities are greater than its liquid assets (in foreign currency).
Under full dollarization, the economy is shielded from a currency or balance-ofpayments crisis, but the risk of a banking crisis is real. Financial instability is endemic
to this regimen.
The solution includes external lines of credit with banks from abroad and reserve
funds from taxes or other revenues (Calvo 2001). In their analysis, Chang and
Velasco show that a policy of high bank reserve requirements dominates over a policy
of large international reserves. “The intuition is that increasing the international li-

56

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Dollarization: Some Definitions and Measurements

fficial or full (de jure) dollarization is
a country’s adoption of another country’s
currency as legal tender.
Under partial (de facto) dollarization, a
country’s domestic currency remains the official legal tender, but transactions can also be
carried out in foreign currency, effectively giving the country a bicurrency system.
Other types of dollarization can be distinguished:

O

•

•
•

Currency or payments dollarization,
sometimes referred to as currency substitution, is a country’s use of foreign currency
for transaction purposes.
Real dollarization is the indexing, formally
or de facto, of prices and wages to the dollar.
Financial dollarization, also called asset
substitution, occurs when a country’s resi-

dents hold financial assets and liabilities in
foreign currency. Financial dollarization
can be external (using the dollar in claims
between residents and nonresidents) or
domestic (using the dollar in claims
between residents).
Data limitations on cash holdings in foreign currency restrict the measurement of
currency or payments dollarization. Financial
dollarization can be measured in several different ways. Domestic financial dollarization
can be measured as the ratio of foreign currency deposits or loans to GDP or to total
deposits or to total loans. External financial
dollarization can be measured as the ratio of
foreign assets held by banks to foreign currency
deposits or cross-border deposits to foreign
currency deposits.

Source: Gulde et al. (2004) and Minda (2005)

quidity of the banking system has a social opportunity cost. Under a policy of high
reserve requirements, banks internalize this cost; under a policy of large international
reserves, they do not” (2000, 3).
Paradoxically, even though full dollarization limits the central bank’s role as lender
of last resort and therefore monetary authority responses to financial crises, it might
make banks runs less likely because consumers and businesses may have greater
confidence in the domestic banking system. The reason is that official dollarization
reduces the moral hazard present in highly dollarized banking systems. In a partially
dollarized economy, the impact of a large depreciation is widespread in the banking
system. Banks expect that the monetary authority would come to the rescue of troubled banks or would delay any sharp devaluations. However, under official dollarization and without exchange rate risk, banks would have to manage their own solvency
and liquidity risks better, taking the respective precautionary measures.
Gale and Vives (2002) show that dollarization provides a credible commitment
not to help banks in trouble even though it would be ex ante optimal to do so. Their
study concludes that dollarization is beneficial when the costs of establishing a reputation for the central bank are high, monitoring by the central bank is important in
improving returns, and the cost of liquidating projects is moderate.
Under official dollarization, the lack of a lender of last resort encourages changes in
the way supervisory and regulatory institutions manage liquidity and solvency risks.
1. In this article, the terms “official” and “full” dollarization will be used interchangeably.
2. Minda (2005) points out that full dollarization affects small countries and territories; a majority are
insular (such as the Marshall Islands and Micronesia) and are closely connected to another country
(Guam, Puerto Rico, San Marino).
3. See the sidebar above for a description of the types and measures of dollarization.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

57

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 1
Country Risk and Full Dollarization
6,000
Ecuador’s
full dollarization
announcement

Ecuador’s
full dollarization
implementation

5,000

EMBI spreads

4,000

3,000
Ecuador

2,000

1,000
Latin America

El Salvador

0
17 Mar 98 02 Mar 99 15 Feb 00

30 Jan 01

15 Jan 02

31 Dec 02 16 Dec 03 30 Nov 04 15 Nov 05

Source: Bloomberg

Prudential norms to manage liquidity risk include higher reserve requirements, liquidity
requirements, and deposit insurance.4 Gulde et al. (2004) point out that these norms
reduce banks’ profits because banks have to hold more liquid assets, which have a lower
return, and required reserves that pay below-market rates and must increase their
expenditures to pay for insurance. Official dollarization also eliminates banks’ exchange
rate services, a good source of revenues, especially in partially dollarized countries.5
Banks ultimately benefit from the reduction of inflation, the elimination of inflationary expectations, and price stability, which fosters an environment beneficial to
financial intermediation. With the return of confidence in the currency and financial
stability, one expects an increase in bank deposits and loans supporting the development of the banking system. In addition, the elimination of currency risk and currency
mismatch contributes to a more efficient banking system. As a net result, reserve
requirements are expected to be lower given that banks do not have to distinguish
between foreign and domestic currency deposits. Moreno-Villalaz (1999) points out
that official dollarization in Panama allowed banks to reduce their reserves by an
equivalent of 5 percent of GDP.
Official dollarization also lowers transaction and information costs, encouraging
trade and financial integration. According to Minda (2005), even if the risk of external
shocks cannot be eliminated, full dollarization contributes to diminishing their impact
and lowering contagion risk by eliminating exchange risk, signaling to international
markets the country’s commitment to currency stability. This commitment could foster foreign investment and stable capital flows, promoting the integration of the
domestic financial market with the world.

Official Dollarization in Ecuador and El Salvador
In 2000 and 2001, Ecuador and El Salvador, respectively, implemented official dollarization for diametrically opposite reasons. In this section, we discuss the economic background before and after the adoption of the U.S. dollar as their domestic currency.

58

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Ecuador. During the 1990s, attempts to open the Ecuadorian economy to international trade and capital markets failed, for the most part. Large fiscal deficits and
increasing external debt led to imbalances that became unsustainable with the decline
of world oil prices and El Niño’s devastating impact on production and infrastructure
in 1998. These external shocks resulted in low economic growth, inflation, and liquidity
problems in an already fragile banking sector. Several developments contributed to
Ecuador’s economic collapse in 1999: the devaluation of the sucre in February, a
freeze on bank deposits in March, a default on external debt payments in September,
and the country’s overall political uncertainty and lack of policy direction.
In Ecuador, the lag in the adjustment of
In January 2000, in an environment of
administered prices and the increase in
social unrest and lacking congressional
support for the implementation of strucfiscal spending have delayed the convergence
tural reforms, then President Jamil Mahuad
of prices to international levels.
called for full dollarization to avoid the collapse of the banking system. Days later,
Mahuad was deposed. Congress confirmed Gustavo Noboa, the elected vice president,
as the new president. Noboa continued with full dollarization to promote a return to
economic stability. In this already partially dollarized economy, the exchange rate was
set at 25,000 sucres per U.S. dollar. Along with full dollarization, the Economic
Transformation Law (Ley de Transformación Económica) introduced reforms that provided incentives to private investment in the energy sector, encouraged privatization of
state enterprises, and made labor markets more flexible. Over the course of the year,
the central bank repurchased almost all the outstanding stock of sucres, and all bank
accounts were converted into dollars. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) signed
a standby agreement with the Ecuadorian government to support economic stability
and recovery, helping to attract additional funding from other multilateral institutions.
Ecuador started enjoying the expected benefits of full dollarization even before
the U.S. dollar was officially adopted on September 9, 2000. As a sign of the enhanced
credibility provided by full dollarization, the release of frozen bank deposits in March
did not translate into a bank run. Economic recovery in the first quarter of 2000 and
lower inflation in July represented the stabilizing effect of full dollarization. Ecuador
also restructured its external debt in August 2000, reducing the total external debt
ratio from 106 percent of GDP at the end of 1999 to around 98 percent in 2000.
Full dollarization eliminated currency risk in Ecuador although country risk did
not decline immediately with the announcement of full dollarization in January 2000.6
However, country risk became less volatile after dollarization took effect in
September and diminished after debt renegotiations with international organizations
(see Figure 1).
Initially, dollarization did not help reduce inflation; the adjustment to lower rates
has taken some years. The lag in the adjustment of administered prices and the
increase in fiscal spending have delayed the convergence of prices to international levels.
By 2003 the inflation rate reached 7.9 percent, the first year since 1972 to have only

4. These norms reduce banks’ profits, but banks have to face this level of protection voluntarily given
that full dollarization has removed currency risk.
5. Duncan (2003) notes that in Peru, a highly dollarized economy, currency exchange transactions
represented 2.1 percent of the banks’ revenues.
6. The indicator for country risk is the interest rate spread in basis points between Ecuador’s emerging market bond index and thirty-year U.S. treasury instruments.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

59

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 2
Inflation in Fully Dollarized Countries
120

30
Full dollarization
in Ecuador

Full dollarization
in El Salvador

100

80

20
El Salvador

15

60

10

40

Ecuador (percent)

El Salvador and USA (percent)

25

Ecuador (right axis)

20

5
USA

0

0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank

single-digit growth. In 2004 inflation rose only 2.7 percent for the year, thus converging to U.S. inflation rates (see Figure 2).
In addition to a more stable and lower inflation rate, clear signs of economic
recovery emerged in 2001, with the country reporting real GDP growth of 5.1 percent
in 2001. While economic growth reached only 3.4 percent and 2.7 percent in 2002
and 2003, respectively, the economy bounced back in 2004 with almost 7 percent
growth, with the help of an increase in oil output from the new oil pipeline, the
Oleoducto de Crudos Pesados. Currently, high global commodity prices continue to
support economic growth, but the economy had an estimated growth of 2.9 percent
in 2005 and is expecting similar growth of 3.0 percent in 2006, according to Economic
Intelligence Unit forecasts.
El Salvador. After reaching a peace agreement in the early 1990s resolving a
civil war, El Salvador implemented comprehensive structural reforms in the mid1990s in an attempt to rebuild and stabilize the economy. These reforms included the
simplification of the tax structure, reprivatization of the financial system, and financial and trade liberalization (IMF 1998). In addition, in 1993, the central bank adopted
a fixed exchange rate policy with respect to the U.S. dollar to minimize exchange rate
risk and to foster price stability.7
These structural reforms and overall political and economic stability helped bring
El Salvador back into the global economy. Export growth and diversification and the
growth of the maquila industries helped the economy become less dependent on coffee production.8 Additionally, stability and comprehensive reforms have contributed
slightly to improvements in per capita income and social conditions. However, even
after a decade of steady growth, most measures of poverty and social conditions have
not fully recovered from the deterioration of the civil war in the 1980s.
Since 1992, El Salvador’s economy has enjoyed stability and a steady decline of
inflation rates, from 18.5 percent in 1993 to 2.3 percent in 2000. Interest rates have
remained high, however, mainly because of the lack of confidence in the fixed

60

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 3
Real GDP Growth
10
Full dollarization
in Ecuador

8

Full dollarization
in El Salvador

El Salvador

6

Percent

4
2
0
Latin America

–2
–4
Ecuador

–6
–8
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank

exchange rate regime. Interest rates declined slightly from 19 percent in 1993 to 14 percent in 2000. Remittances from abroad also increased significantly, growing approximately 155 percent from 1992 to 2000. In 2000, total remittances reached $1.75 billion,
approximately 13 percent of real GDP. GDP growth averaged 6 percent between 1990
and 1995. In 1998 Hurricane Mitch caused widespread flooding and landslides, affecting agriculture, the transportation infrastructure (mainly highways), and housing. But
the economy continued growing, albeit at a slower pace, averaging 3.7 percent between
1998 and 2000.
Beginning January 1, 2001, the Salvadoran government implemented the Monetary
Integration Law (Ley de Integración Monetaria), which established a fixed exchange
rate of 8.75 colones per U.S. dollar and made the dollar legal tender and the only unit
of account in the financial system. The colón is still considered legal tender and continues to circulate alongside the dollar, but dollars have gradually replaced colones,
which are no longer printed. All financial operations are denominated in dollars, and
currently the use of the colón is generally limited to some rural areas.
Unlike Ecuador, which adopted the dollar as a policy alternative to bring economic stability, El Salvador had enjoyed economic stability and low inflation rates
before official dollarization (see Figures 2 and 3). (Further, El Salvador is currently
one of four investment-graded countries in Latin America, a status that demonstrates
the confidence of international investors.) The government decided to dollarize in
an attempt to lower interest rates, increase foreign investment, improve financial

7. Even before 1993, the historical preference was a fixed exchange rate with respect to the U.S. dollar,
in which the rate changed only during the period of the civil war from 2.5 colones per U.S. dollar to
8 colones per U.S. dollar. In 1993, the exchange rate became fixed at 8.75 colones per U.S. dollar. See
IMF (1998) for more details.
8. Maquila industries are plants that assemble imported materials and parts and re-export the finished
product to the original market.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

61

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

conditions, and decrease transaction costs in international trade, thereby further
accelerating economic growth and stability (see Towers and Borzutzky 2004). In
addition, the government argued that dollarization would protect wages and savings
against devaluations. Dollarization would also benefit Salvadorans living in the United
States by making their remittance transfer costs cheaper.9 Officials also pointed out
that full dollarization was the logical next step, considering that historically the colón
has been pegged to the dollar, especially since 1993. Moreover, the country’s economy
is closely linked to the United States: Twothirds of total exports are sent to U.S.
While economic growth in El Salvador has
markets, and the United States is the oridecelerated, interest rates, inflation rates,
gin of a large portion of remittances.
Right after the adoption of dollariand remittances have improved since full
zation, El Salvador faced several severe
dollarization was adopted.
shocks, including two earthquakes, declining international coffee prices, increasing
oil prices, and the slowdown of the U.S. economy. These shocks dampened economic
growth and other expected benefits from full dollarization. Real GDP grew by only
1.8 percent in 2004 and has averaged less than 2 percent since 2001. Trade growth
has also been sluggish, with export growth averaging only 3 percent and imports
averaging 6.7 percent since 2001—a sharp contrast to the 17.5 percent export growth
in 2000. Foreign investment growth has also been slow, with gross fixed capital formation increasing slightly more than 1 percent since 2001.
While economic growth has decelerated, interest rates, inflation rates, and remittances have improved since full dollarization was adopted. In 2004, lending interest rates
(in foreign currency) averaged 6.3 percent, declining considerably from 11 percent in
2000.10 Although inflation increased slightly to 4.5 percent in 2004, it has averaged
around 3 percent since 2001 compared to 7.8 percent from 1992 to 2000. Remittance
inflows have also improved significantly, reaching $2.55 billion (approximately 16 percent of GDP) in 2004, according to the central bank. Economic growth is expected to
increase in the coming years as the implementation of the Dominican Republic–Central
American Free Trade Agreement (DR-CAFTA) and reforms to deepen the financial sector, along with prudent fiscal policies, support productivity gains and investment.11
Comparing results. For Ecuador and El Salvador, the implementation of official dollarization has resulted, as expected, in lower inflation rates, lower country risk
premiums, and gains in policy credibility. The expected benefits have taken longer to
materialize in Ecuador than in El Salvador, however. In Ecuador, even though inflation rates started to decline in 2000, not until 2004 did the rates reach levels similar
to the U.S. inflation rate. In addition, the fall in the volatility of monthly inflation in
Ecuador also was noticeable only after February 2003. El Salvador, on the other
hand, continued to enjoy low inflation rates, and inflation volatility declined smoothly
after full dollarization.
The same picture can be drawn for country risk; in Ecuador it took eight months
after President Mahuad announced full dollarization in January 2000 for international
markets to show lower levels of risk premiums, which declined sharply the day that
the debt was renegotiated with international organizations in September 2000. But
country risk reached levels of below 1000 basis points only after May 2004.12 In El
Salvador, country risk has been below the average spread for the Latin American
region since country risk for the country was introduced in May 2002 (see Figure 1).
Economic growth has been influenced heavily by internal and external conditions. In Ecuador the persistence of high oil prices has helped anchor official dollar-

62

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

ization in the last two years, thus compensating for the lack of external financing and
increases in fiscal expenditures. Higher oil exports have helped pay down public debt
and stimulate the economy during a period of political instability. In El Salvador the
slow recovery of the U.S. economy, political uncertainty surrounding the elections,
low coffee prices, and high oil prices have decelerated economic activity. Figure 3
shows lower, but less volatile, economic growth for El Salvador in 2000 and 2004 than
for Ecuador and Latin America. Under official dollarization, both economies continue
to be vulnerable to external and internal shocks. But policy credibility and economic
stability brought by full dollarization can encourage reforms to promote competitiveness
and productivity to overcome such vulnerabilities.

Banking Systems before Official Dollarization
In Latin America, banks are the most significant institutions in the financial system, representing approximately 70 percent of total financial assets. Latin American banks, however, do not reach levels of financial deepening and development observed in developed
economies. Throughout the 1960s and 1970s, banks in Ecuador and El Salvador faced a
period of stability, which gave way to disruptions caused by the external debt crisis in
the 1980s in Ecuador and by a civil war in El Salvador late in that decade. The economic
instability, high inflation, and depreciation of the domestic currency that ensued, along
with other political and external shocks, did not foster an environment of financial deepening. In this section, we will analyze the banking systems in Ecuador and El Salvador
after this period of instability.
Banking crisis in Ecuador. In Ecuador, the banking crisis of the late 1990s
really began a decade earlier and had “[its] roots in a ‘boom and bust’ cycle in the middle of financial liberalization, coupled with lax financial surveillance and bad banking
practices” (Jacome 2004, 12). De la Torre, Garcia-Saltos, and Mascaró (2001) argue
that the banking crisis can be explained in three dimensions: failure to establish an
effective regulatory and supervisory environment in the face of financial liberalization, a credit boom and sudden stop phenomenon, and the exacerbation of financial
vulnerability during 1997 and 1998 due to lax fiscal policy and failure to introduce
financial reform.
In 1994 the General Law of Financial Institutions (Ley General de Instituciones
del Sistema Financiero) created the legal basis for financial liberalization, fostering
financial intermediation and investment allocation. Banks could then perform dollardenominated services, and commercial banks were now legally allowed to have offshore operations. The central bank also underwent significant reform, retaining the
ability to provide monetary support to banks in liquidity and solvency troubles (see
Beckerman and Solimano 2002). In addition, the law established a modern framework for the development of risk-based prudential regulations.
But the implementation of these new prudential regulations did not materialize
quickly. Regulations continued to be outdated, and enforcement continued to be
extremely lax, deficient, and uneven. Monitoring difficulties and lack of information

9. There would be no foreign exchange transaction cost associated with sending remittances after
dollarization.
10. The interest rate for loans in domestic currency was 14 percent in 2000.
11. The Central American countries involved in DR-CAFTA are Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala,
Honduras, and Nicaragua.
12. JPMorgan raised Ecuadorian debt from underweight to market weight, despite political uncertainty. In addition, the government was negotiating a new standby agreement with the IMF.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

63

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 4
Bank Deposits as a Percentage of GDP
45
Ecuador

El Salvador

Latin America

40
35

Percent

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Source : Financial Structure Database, World Bank

from banks, mainly from their offshore branches, limited the ability to produce an
accurate assessment of the soundness of the financial system. In addition, the
supervisory authority had no proper strategy or power to intervene in a troubled
bank, thus restricting the use of preventive measures to avoid bankruptcies and
bank failures.
With lax prudential supervision and regulation, banks increasingly performed
risky transactions, encouraged by moral hazard stemming from successive bailouts
granted over the 1980s. Related-party lending intensified, loan portfolios became
heavily concentrated in certain economic sectors, and dollar-denominated operations
increased without the proper measures to hedge currency mismatches, mainly with
borrowers earning in local currency but acquiring loans in dollars.
Financial liberalization coincided with a period of foreign capital inflows attracted
by higher domestic returns in an environment of domestic macroeconomic stability.
The rapid monetization of the economy brought in a sizable credit boom. Credit
increased in real terms by 40 percent in 1993 and 50 percent in 1994. The increase
in liquidity was encouraged by a decline in reserve requirements from 28 to 10 percent in domestic currency deposits and from 35 to 10 percent for foreign currency
deposits (see Jacome 2004).
In 1995, as risky activities intensified in the banking system, Ecuador experienced a sudden stop and reversal of capital inflows, mainly because of domestic political problems, the short but costly war with Peru, and the Mexican Tequila crisis. In
addition, the continued depreciation of the currency under the new exchange rate
regime created difficulties for banks with currency and maturity mismatches. In an
environment of political and economic instability, residents began to shift their
deposits to stronger and more stable banks and to dollar-denominated deposits.
Nevertheless, the money was kept in the banking system. But the failure of two banks
in 1995 and 1996 increased residents’ fears. Liquidity pressures on the banking system
increased as residents began to panic, triggering deposit runs.

64

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Figure 5
Bank Credit to the Private Sector as a Percentage of GDP
50
Ecuador

El Salvador

Latin America

45
40
35

Percent

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Source : Financial Structure Database, World Bank

In early December 1998, the government passed the “AGD Law,” which established a blanket guarantee through the Guarantee of Deposits Agency (Agencia de
Garantía de Depósitos)(AGD), in an effort to restore a sense of stability in the banking system (see Jacome 2004). The government also included a 1 percent tax on
financial transactions (debits and credits) to substitute for income tax. In an effort
to avoid the tax, residents began to store money in foreign currency outside of the
banking system, further hurting bank liquidity. Deposits contracted 15 and 60 percent in 1998 and 1999, respectively. However, as shown in Figure 4, bank deposits as
a percentage of GDP remained at 23 percent in 1998 and 1999 because of the decline
in GDP of 7.3 percent.
Since the AGD Law was not helping the banking system, the government imposed
a widespread deposit freeze in March 1999. Time deposits and repurchase agreements
were locked for at least one year, and savings deposits in excess of U.S.$500 and half
of checking account balances were frozen for six months. Despite the deposit freeze,
only three banks became insolvent and had to shut down.
An examination of banking system data shows the effects of the crisis. From 1995
to 1997, loans grew 29 percent but fell 31 percent in 1998 and 1999 (see Figure 5).
Total assets also grew 29 percent from 1995 to 1997 but fell 9 and 29 percent, respectively, in 1998 and 1999. Bank assets’ share in total financial assets went from 98 percent in 1997 to 77 percent in 1999, a 22 percent decline. In addition, past-due loans’
performance also deteriorated quite sharply; past-due loans increased a dramatic
307.6 percent in 1999, reaching $1.1 million.
In summary, prior to official dollarization the banking system in Ecuador underwent a crisis that resulted in a reduction in the system’s size (in terms of both assets
and number of banks), in a deposit freeze to avoid a bank run, and in a decline in
banks’ lending activities.
Banking stability in El Salvador. In the first half of the 1990s, the Financial
System Reform Program (Programa de Fortalecimiento y Privatización del Sistema

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

65

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Financiero) was initiated as part of the country’s structural reform, which established
a new role for the central bank; redefined monetary, credit, and exchange rate policies; readjusted the legal and institutional framework; and strengthened and privatized the banking system.13 In 1990 the Organic Law for the Superintendence of the
Financial System (Ley Orgánica de la Superintendencia del Sistema Financiero) was
approved, establishing an autonomous institution to oversee banks, financieras
(formerly known as savings and loans associations), the central bank, and other institutions of the financial system. In addition,
commercial banks and financieras were
Policy credibility and economic stability
privatized
through a process that involved
brought by full dollarization can encourage
several stages, from analyzing each bank’s
reforms to promote competitiveness and
loan portfolio to institutional restructuring. According to the central bank, ownerproductivity to overcome vulnerabilities
ship was returned to the private sector by
to shocks.
distributing the largest banks to individual
shareholders and bank employees. During the 1990s financial liberalization was consolidated by implementing laws that established the autonomy of the central bank
and its limitations on public financing.
The process of financial liberalization promoted growth in the banking system.
Assets rose from 27 percent of GDP in 1990 to 51 percent in 2000. In the first half of
1990s, nonperforming loans were small while indicators of liquidity, efficiency, solvency, and profitability were satisfactory. Assets performed well, and total deposits
increased dramatically (see SAPRIN 2001).
In the second half of the 1990s, however, adverse economic conditions affected
the performance of the banking sector. Two bank failures in 1997 and 1998 brought
to light some weaknesses of the banking system and its supervision and regulation.
Banco Fincomer and Insepro-Finsepro were linked to illegal transfers of funds from
corporate firms to bank branches, highlighting the fact that resources could be transferred outside the surveillance of supervision and regulation.
While deposits and loans continued to grow, their growth rates declined. From
rates of 19.6 percent in 1996, deposits’ growth rates slowed to 5.4 and 5.1 percent in
1999 and 2000, respectively. Loan activity growth demonstrated a similar pattern,
declining from 20.1 percent in 1996 to only 4.3 percent in 1999 and 1.8 percent in
2000. The performance of nonperforming loans also began to deteriorate along with
asset quality.
In response, the 1999 Banking Law (Ley de Bancos) was established, bringing
greater transparency in financial activities and forcing banks to monitor credit risk.
The law, one of the most progressive in Central America, brought the banking system
in line with internationally accepted standards.

Banks after Official Dollarization
The previous discussion raises several questions: Did the banking system introduce
changes to overcome the restrictions imposed on the central bank in the role of
lender of last resort? Given the expected reduction in inflation, interest rates, country risk, and volatility that ensued from dollarization, how did the banking system
evolve? Did banks in fact perform better in an environment of expected economic
stability? And, finally, did full dollarization help in the financial integration of the
banking system with international markets?
Lender of last resort. In Ecuador the Economic Transformation Law that supported the implementation of full dollarization in September 2000 included changes

66

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

in the role of the central bank, the development of a liquidity fund, and the modernization and tightening of banking supervision and regulation. Under the new law, the
central bank is able to conduct liquidity operations with banks, including transactions
in stabilization bonds with commercial banks and repurchase operations. In addition,
a separate Liquidity Support Fund was established to supplement the central bank’s
capacity during liquidity problems (see Beckerman and Solimano 2002). Banks are
required to allocate 1 percent of their deposit base to the fund.14
Under full dollarization, banking regulations were restructured and tightened,
and regulators were given more power to take preventive measures against banks that
showed signs of instability. More stringent capital adequacy regulations (which are
now much closer to Basel standards) and new credit risk centers were established to
improve prudent supervision. In addition, the General Law of Financial Institutions
was overhauled in 2001, including reforms such as a prohibition against related-party
lending, more stringent loan-loss reserves and capital definitions and requirements,
and mandatory consolidated financial reporting. These reforms improved transparency
and brought the banking system closer to international standards. Deficiencies do
remain, however, and while regulations were updated, actual implementation and
enforcement continue to be poor (see Fitch Ratings 2003). Bank accounting standards
continue to deviate from international norms while some regulations continue to be
lenient, including rules for loan write-offs.
Compared to the experience in Ecuador, where full dollarization supported the
banking system in its rebuilding process, full dollarization in El Salvador supported the
performance of an already well-established banking system. The absence of a lender
of last resort has encouraged Salvadoran banks to hold a growing proportion of their
assets in highly liquid instruments. Also, banking system deposits are now insured
under the Deposit Guarantee Fund (Instituto de Garantía de los Depósitos) (IGD) set
by the 1999 Banking Law. The IGD guarantees deposits up to U.S.$6,700, or roughly
three times GDP per capita.15 One of the main weaknesses of the fund is that it does
not provide adequate coverage for the deposits that it currently insures (U.S.$2.2 billion). In case of need, it would cover only about 2 percent of the insured funds.
The banking environment. In Ecuador, after the banking crisis and during the
initial stages of full dollarization, the government initiated an evaluation process to assess
banks’ solvency. External auditors determined that the government should intervene
in sixteen banks, with all but two closing soon afterward. This restructuring process
removed the weakest, most problematic banks from the system. But none of the banks
was exempt from the devastating impact of the crisis, and those that remained in operation were weakened by asset quality problems, liquidity pressures, and a sharp decline in
the level of activity and, thus, sustainable operating profitability.16 Consequently, immediately after dollarization, the size of the banking system (in terms of financial penetration)
shrank. In 2001, total assets fell to 28.6 percent of GDP (from 38.2 percent in 2000). By
2003, total assets declined to 21.4 percent of GDP, levels similar to those in the 1980s.
Since then, deposit growth and loan growth reached 86.4 percent and 111.7 percent,
respectively, from 2000 to 2004 in response to the rebound in investor confidence and

13.
14.
15.
16.

See the historical outline at the central bank of El Salvador’s Web site, www.bcr.gob.sv.
This fund is in addition to the reserve requirement of 8 percent.
Offshore deposits are not insured.
Most banks remained in profit thanks to hefty gains on foreign currency positions when the sucre
devalued and to inflation adjustments, which were used to boost capital and increase loan-loss
reserves (see Fitch Ratings 2003).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

67

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

more robust economic growth. Nonperforming loans over total loans have declined,
indicating better asset quality and more stability in the banking system.
Although prior to 2001 Salvadoran banks already operated in an environment of
free capital flows and low inflation, full dollarization contributed to a reduction in
banks’ intermediation margins. On the deposit side, local banks compete among
themselves within the domestic market. Although large banks have a comparative
advantage with their expansive networks, small banks have benefited from full dollarization as their funding costs have converged with those of their larger competitors. Lower lending rates and recent depressed credit have given Salvadoran banks a
comparative advantage versus other Central American banks, encouraging larger
Salvadoran banks to expand their lending to neighboring countries (Honduras,
Guatemala, and Nicaragua). Recent reforms to the banking law in 2003 have limited
cross-border lending; however, banks are circumventing restrictions by establishing
holding companies in Panama. This practice results in additional risk to the Salvadoran
operations of these institutions.
As a response to lower intermediation margins, there has been a process of consolidation to allow banks to compete more effectively. Between 2000 and 2002 four
mergers occurred that resulted in a high concentration: Four banks now account for
more than 80 percent of the sector’s assets and deposits. These banks are among the
largest in Central America but are still small by international standards.
Financial integration. Foreign bank presence in El Salvador remains negligible despite the absence of barriers to entering the market. The country has only two
foreign-owned institutions that have operated for some time. It is also estimated that
about fifty other foreign banks that do not have a local presence provide financing to
El Salvador’s private sector, on the order of $1.8 billion as of June 2002, nearly double the amount at the end of 1999 (see Fitch Ratings 2003). Ecuador has twenty-five
private banks, of which two are foreign.
Overall, full dollarization helped the stabilization of the banking system in Ecuador
by stopping the collapse of the economy. In 2005, despite political uncertainty, financial
conditions remained stable, deposits had grown steadily over the previous four years,
and banks continued to maintain high levels of liquidity and to improve asset quality. But
the long-term sustainability of this policy remains uncertain as institutional weaknesses
in the economy and banking system continue. In El Salvador, banks have improved their
performance despite the economic deceleration, gaining competitiveness in the Central
American region. The regulatory and supervisory institutions have set up regulations
comparable to international standards.

Did Official Dollarization Have an Impact on Bank Performance?
To examine how full dollarization and other macroeconomic and institutional factors
affected bank performance indicators such as profitability, liquidity, and asset quality,
we use panel data including all banks in Ecuador and El Salvador from 1995 to 2004.
Following Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (1999), we define bank performance Yit for
bank i at time t as follows:
(1) Yit = f (DOLLt , MACROt , BANKit ) + errorit ,
where Yit is the dependent variable—bank performance—measured by its profitability, loan quality, and loan growth. Profitability or before-tax profits can be decomposed as net interest income plus noninterest income minus overhead costs minus
loan-loss provisions, usually as a ratio of total assets. The indicator for loan quality is

68

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

loan-loss provisions as a ratio of total loans (LLP), and, for liquidity, net loans as a
ratio of total deposits.
The explanatory variables are a dollarization dummy indicating when the country implemented official dollarization. We also include macroeconomic variables
reflecting the state of the economy, including economic growth rates, inflation rates,
interest rates, gross domestic product (GDP) per capita, and trade as a percentage
of GDP. As indicators of financial structure, we use credit to the private sector as a
percentage of GDP, bank deposits as a percentage of GDP, and bank assets’ share in
Full dollarization helped the stabilization
the banking system. Another set of variables is specific to banks’ activity. These
of the banking system in Ecuador by stopinclude loan-to-asset ratios and equity-toping the collapse of the economy.
asset ratio indicators of capital strength as
well as bank size variables such as individual banks’ share of loans and deposits as a portion of loans and deposits in the banking system. Country and year dummies are included to capture idiosyncratic effects.
These bank activity variables are lagged one period to prevent simultaneity, in particular because balance-sheet variables refer to year-end balances.
The data set, published by Latin Finance, includes information from all banks
from 1995 to 2004 in Ecuador and El Salvador. Macroeconomic variables come
from International Financial Statistics published by the IMF, financial structure
variables come from the Financial Structure Database of the World Bank (2004),
and data on dollarization ratios come from the Web sites of the central banks of
Ecuador and El Salvador.
The table shows the results of the regression for loan-loss provisions (or loan
quality), liquidity, and profitability. As expected, the coefficient of the dollarization
dummy is positive and significant in the explanation of loan quality. Given the
absence of a lender of last resort, banks need to hold adequate reserves to respond
to any sudden increase in nonperforming loans. Trade as a percentage of GDP has a
direct relationship with loan provisions, indicating that banks may allocate more
reserves for loans given an increase in the openness of the economy that could bring
more fluctuations as a result of external shocks. The coefficient on the interest rate
is negative and significant, suggesting that an increase in the interest rate could
reduce the demand for loans. Economic growth is significant with a negative sign,
meaning that economic growth is an incentive to decrease loan-loss provisions.
Inflation is also significant with a negative sign; a possible explanation is that unexpected inflation will benefit borrowers and reduce the incentive to increase loan-loss
provisions. Relatively larger banks will have a greater loan-loss provision ratio.
The second column of the table shows the results for liquidity, which is net loans
over deposits. The dollarization dummy has a negative and significant coefficient; as
expected, official dollarization will restrict liquidity in the overall economy, and banks
need to make reserves to support their liquidity needs. In this regression, macroeconomic variables and financial structure indicators are also significant. Economic
growth has a negative and significant coefficient, showing a direct relationship
between economic growth and liquidity. Inflation and bank liquidity have an inverse
and significant relationship: Higher inflation increases the demand for money (for
example, less deposits) competing with banks. In the case of trade as a percentage of
GDP, the relationship with bank liquidity is also indirect: The more open an economy
is, the higher the demand for cash for international transactions, competing with
bank liquidity.

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

69

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Table
Regressions on Bank Performance Indicators for Ecuador and El Salvador, 1995–2004
Loan quality:
Loan-loss
provisions

Liquidity: Net
loans/deposits

Profitability:
Before-tax
profits

0.1532**
(0.0772)

–2.1611**
(0.8520)

–0.168
(0.1727)

Economic growth

–0.0106***
(0.0035)

–0.4524***
(0.1704)

0.017*
(0.0097)

GDP per capita

–0.0003
(0.0003)

–0.0047
(0.0040)

0.0010
(0.0010)

Inflation

–0.0010**
(0.00068)

0.0547***
(0.0206)

0.0033
(0.0030)

Trade as a percent of GDP

0.0039**
(0.0016)

0.2588***
(0.0952)

–0.0096
(0.0066)

Interest rate

–0.0014**

0.0645*

0.0095

(0.0005)

(0.0355)

(0.0092)

Independent variables
Dollarization dummy

Macroeconomic variables

Financial structure variables
Bank assets/central bank assets

–1.676
(1.9096)

Private credit by banks as a percent of GDP

Bank deposits as a percent of GDP

–58.8336**
(22.6876)
0.0111
(0.6214)

Bank variables
Asset share in total banks

0.0006
(0.0016)

–0.0213
(0.0119)

0.0003
(0.0013)

Equity-to-loan ratio (t – 1)

–0.00002
(0.000016)

0.0004
(0.00048)

0.00004***
(0.00002)

391

391

Number of observations

391

Notes: The table does not include country dummies and year dummies. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Source: Authors’ regressions using data from Latin Finance, the IMF, Banco Central del Ecuador, Banco Central de Reserva de El Salvador, and
the World Bank

The regression on profitability indicates that neither the official dollarization
dummy, macroeconomic variables (except for economic growth), nor financial structure
variables explain bank profitability. Lagged variables that are specific to the bank—such
as the ratio of equity to assets and to loans, indicators of bank solvency—are positive
and significant in the explanation of bank profitability. This result is similar to that found
in the general literature on bank performance. Economic growth has a direct relation
with profitability, as expected.

70

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F AT L A N TA

Conclusion
In both Ecuador and El Salvador, the banking system has initially benefited from the
implementation of full dollarization. Even though the two countries adopted the U.S.
dollar as their country’s currency for entirely different reasons, both countries have
experienced improvements in banking regulations and in the overall stability of the
banking systems. According to our estimations, official dollarization has played a significant role in improving bank liquidity and asset quality. Macroeconomic variables and
financial structure indicators have also been relevant in explaining bank liquidity and
loan quality, and bank profitability has responded to variables that are bank specific.
While it is still too early to determine whether these initial benefits of dollarization will be sustainable in the long term, both countries have been able to modernize
and improve upon the overall safety and soundness of the banking system.

REFERENCES
Beckerman, Paul, and Andrés Solimano, eds. 2002. Crisis
and dollarization in Ecuador: Stability, growth and
social equity. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Gale, Douglas, and Xavier Vives. 2002. Dollarization,
bailouts, and the stability of the banking system.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 2:467–502.

Calvo, Guillermo A. 2001. Capital markets and the
exchange rate with special reference to the dollarization debate in Latin America. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 33, no. 2, pt. 2:312–34.

Gulde, Anne-Marie, David Hoelscher, Alan Ize, David
Marston, and Gianni De Nicoló. 2004. Financial stability
in dollarized economies. International Monetary Fund
Occasional Paper 230.

Chang, Roberto, and Andrés Velasco. 2000. Financial
fragility and the exchange rate regime. Journal of
Economic Theory 92, no. 1:1–34.

International Monetary Fund. 1998. El Salvador:
Recent economic developments. Staff country report
98/32, April.

De la Torre, Augusto, Roberto Garcia-Saltos, and Yira
Mascaró. 2001. Banking, currency and debt meltdown:
Ecuador crisis in the late 1990s. Washington, D.C.:
World Bank manuscript.

Jacome, Luis. 2004. The late 1990s financial crisis in
Ecuador: Institutional weaknesses, fiscal rigidities, and
financial dollarization at work. International Monetary
Fund Working Paper WP/04/12, January.

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Harry Huizinga. 1999. Determinants of commercial bank interest margins and profitability: Some international evidence. World Bank
Economic Review 13, no. 2:379–408.

Minda, Alexandre. 2005. Official dollarization: A last
resort solution to financial stability in Latin America?
Groupment de Recherches Economiques et Sociales
Working Paper 2, January.

Duncan, Roberto. 2003. Exploring the implications
of official dollarization on macroeconomic volatility.
Central Bank of Chile Working Paper 200, February.

Moreno-Villalaz, Juan Luis. 1999. Lessons from the
monetary experience of Panama: A dollar economy
with financial integration. Cato Journal 18,
no. 30:421–39.

Edwards, Sebastian. 1995. Crisis and reform in Latin
America: From despair to hope. Washington, D.C.:
World Bank.
Edwards, Sebastian, and I. Igal Magendzo. 2006.
Strict dollarization and economic performance: An
empirical investigation. Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 38, no. 1:269–82.
Fitch Ratings. 2003. Country Reports, Financial
Institutions. The Ecuadorian prudential regulations
and The Ecuadorian banking system: An overview,
January 31. <www.fitchratings.com>.

Structural Adjustment Participatory Review International Network (SAPRIN). 2001. The liberalization of
the financial system in El Salvador: Executive summary.
<http://www.saprin.org/elsalvador/research/els_sum_
financial_sys.pdf> (September 11, 2006).
Towers, Marcia, and Silvia Borzutzky. 2004. The socioeconomic implications of dollarization in El Salvador.
Latin American Politics and Society 46, no. 3:29–54.
World Bank. 2004. Financial structure database.
<www.worldbank.org/research/projects/finstructure/
index.htm> (September 11, 2006).

ECONOMIC REVIEW

Third Quarter 2006

71