View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Competitiveness and Price
Setting in Dealer Markets
L U C Y F. A C K E R T A N D
B R YA N K . C H U R C H
Ackert is a senior economist in the financial section
of the Atlanta Fed’s research department. Church
is an associate professor in the DuPree College of
Management at the Georgia Institute of Technology.
They thank Stephanie Mannis for research assistance
and Jerry Dwyer, Saikat Nandi, Larry Wall, and
Madeline Zavodny for helpful comments.

T

HE

NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF SECURITIES DEALERS AUTOMATED QUOTATIONS (NASDAQ) SYS-

TEM IS AN ELECTRONIC MARKET FOR OVER-THE-COUNTER
LARGEST SECURITIES MARKET IN THE

(OTC)

STOCKS. IT IS THE SECOND-

UNITED STATES. ALLEGATIONS THAT DEALERS COLLUDE TO

WIDEN BID-ASK SPREADS HAVE LED TO SWEEPING CHANGES IN THE RULES GOVERNING TRADING IN THE

NASDAQ STOCK MARKET.
Bid and ask quotes are prices at which dealers or market makers are willing to transact. A market maker is an
individual or firm that risks its own capital to provide
investors with immediacy of supply and demand. The bidask spread represents the cost to investors of transacting
with the market maker. Investors prefer a narrow spread
because it reduces trading costs and improves liquidity
(Amihud and Mendelson 1986). Bid-ask spreads, like other
transaction costs, significantly affect the efficiency of capital markets (Bhushan 1994; Kim and Verrechia 1994). In
an efficient market, prices quickly reflect new information
so that the information cannot be used to derive abnormal
trading profit. Stock markets are thought to be more efficient when spreads are narrow because information is disseminated more quickly. Yet, at the same time, dealers
must receive adequate compensation for making a market
in a security, or the market’s liquidity is threatened.
Regulators and investors have asserted that
Nasdaq dealers conspire to widen bid-ask spreads in
order to in-crease their profit at investors’ expense.
Academics have amassed a substantial body of evidence
relating to the Nasdaq scandal. Yet there is no consensus
concerning whether dealers collude to fix prices and
widen bid-ask spreads.1 Observed spreads may result
4

from institutional features particular to the Nasdaq market rather than collusion among market makers.
This article explores the Nasdaq pricing controversy
in light of economic theory and evidence of alleged collusion, including evidence contained in U.S. Department of
Justice and Securities and Exchange Commission reports
(1996). The following section examines the important
role that securities markets play in promoting a stable
economy. Then the discussion reviews specifics of the two
organizational structures commonly adopted—auction
and dealer markets. These initial sections provide a foundation for understanding the significance of the Nasdaq
controversy. Subsequently the article considers the
sources and economic consequences of divergence in
spreads. Finally, it elaborates on what constitutes collusive behavior and summarizes the case against Nasdaq.

Functions of Securities Markets
egulation of securities markets in the United
States changed dramatically following documented abuses and market irregularities in the 1920s
and early 1930s. At that time there was little confidence
in the stability of the U.S. market. The stock market crash
of 1929 and poor economic conditions brought the role of

R

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

stock market to the forefront of the policy debate. New
federal laws resulted, and a powerful federal agency, the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), was established to enforce those laws. According to the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, a national securities exchange
must provide a “free and open market” that “protect(s)
investors and the public interest” (15 U.S.C. 78f[b][5]and
78o-3[b][6]).
It is clear that well-functioning financial markets are
vital in a thriving economy. A primary function of these
markets is the allocation of capital and financial
resources. Financial markets move capital from savers to
those with productive uses for the capital (that is, those
with good investment opportunities). In so doing, a wellfunctioning securities market maintains continuous and
active trading, which allows investors to enter and exit
when necessary. Market participants want to receive the
best price with speedy execution at low cost. Investors
have greater confidence in a market that is fair, open, and
orderly and offers low transaction costs. At the same time,
an effective securities market facilitates price discovery
so that prices quickly reflect information and reveal this
news to the market’s observers and participants.
Financial markets also permit individuals to transfer consumption across time. Well-being improves when individuals are permitted to smooth consumption over their life
cycle. Designing a securities market that meets these
objectives involves trade-offs because these goals typically conflict (Ganley and others 1998).

Dealer versus Auction Markets
he rules governing securities trading vary across
organizational structures. Economists debate the
merits of two commonly adopted organizational
forms: auction and dealer market structures. In an auction market an investor buys or sells at a price set by
another investor’s limit order. A limit buy order specifies
the maximum price that an investor is willing to pay,
whereas a limit sell order specifies the minimum price
that an investor is willing to receive. By comparison, in
dealer markets investors trade with market makers who
simultaneously quote prices at which they are willing to
buy (the “bid” price) and sell (the “ask” price) a particular security. The best bid (highest) and ask (lowest)
prices determine the inside spread.
The New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) is an auction
market that maintains a specialist system, wherein one
dealer maintains a market in a particular stock. The specialist enters offers to buy at bid prices and sell at ask
prices in order to provide liquidity and continuous trading. Investors place market orders to sell or buy at prevailing market prices, and the specialist fills the orders at

T

the inside (best) bid and ask prices. The specialist also
maintains a record or limit order book of investors’ unexecuted limit orders. Although a specialist in a sense has
a monopoly franchise in a particular stock, the presence
of one market maker does not necessarily lead to excessive bid-ask spreads because the limit order book provides
competition for order flow. Execution costs are expected to
be low because the inside spread is often determined by
customers’ limit orders
and investors can trade
directly with each other.
Investors get the best
available prices, whether
Regulators and investors
the prices are from the
have asserted that Nasdaq
specialist or from other
investors’ limit orders.
dealers conspire to widen
In contrast to the
bid-ask spreads in order to
NYSE, the Nasdaq is a
increase their profit at
multiple-dealer market,
where several dealers
investors’ expense.
maintain a market in a
particular stock. Other
important dealer markets include most bond
and foreign currency
markets, as well as the Chicago Board Options Exchange
and the London Stock Exchange. Traders in the Nasdaq
market do not gather in one location as in an organized
exchange but rather are connected electronically through
a computer system. To make a market, dealers simultaneously quote prices at which they are willing to buy and
sell a particular stock. Because each Nasdaq stock has at
least two market makers, a dealer’s spread is not necessarily the inside spread. However, investors’ market
orders get the “best execution” in that orders to sell or buy
at the current market price are filled at the inside bid or
ask price, whether or not the dealer receiving the order
issued that particular price quote. Prior to the recent
Nasdaq rule changes (discussed below), limit orders were
not revealed to all market participants and were filled by
a dealer when the dealer’s quote reached the limit price.
The presence of multiple market makers is designed to
produce narrow bid-ask spreads through competition for
order flow among individual dealers. In addition, dealer
markets are more flexible and can handle different types
of orders from different types of customers.

Why Might Spreads Differ?
large body of literature examines the determinants of bid-ask spreads and the effects of institutional structure on pricing in securities markets
(Benston and Hagerman 1974; Stoll and Whaley 1990;

A

1. There is not even agreement on whether Nasdaq spreads are wider than those of stocks listed on other U.S. exchanges. See, for
example, Kleidon and Willig (1995) and Woodward (1997).
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

5

Neal 1992). The width of the spread reflects the costs of
inventory, order processing, and trading with informed
agents (Glosten and Milgrom 1985; Stoll 1985; Amihud
and Mendelson 1986). By standing ready to buy or sell,
the market maker provides a useful service. However,
while providing immediacy to investors the market maker
is exposed to the risk of a market movement that results
in a decrease in the value of inventory held. Additional
risk arises because some investors’ trades are motivated
by private information, and the dealer may trade (unknowingly) with an investor who has superior knowledge
about a stock. A market maker will quote a wider spread
if the chance of trading with an informed investor is
greater. Thus, market makers can pass the cost of trading with informed traders on to uninformed traders
through the bid-ask spread.
The average bid-ask spread appears to be smaller
in specialist markets like the NYSE than in dealer markets such as Nasdaq. Huang and Stoll (1996) found that
in 1991 the average quoted spread for a sample of 175
Nasdaq stocks was $0.50 whereas a carefully matched
sample of 175 NYSE stocks had an average spread of
only $0.26. The difference in spreads does not appear to
be generated by differences in inventory, order processing, or asymmetric information costs across the two markets. However, these stock markets have different
institutional features that can affect the bid-ask spread,
in addition to having divergent pricing systems. Disentangling the effects of various factors is difficult, if not
impossible, so the competitiveness of the Nasdaq market
continues to be debated.
An institutional factor that must be considered when
comparing spreads across markets is the handling of commissions. On the NYSE all traders are charged explicit
commissions whereas on Nasdaq commissions are frequently included in the stock’s price, lowering the bid
price and raising the ask price. For this reason alone, one
should expect to find wider spreads on Nasdaq. However,
commissions cannot fully explain the difference in
spreads across markets because small traders usually pay
explicit commissions on Nasdaq as well as on the NYSE
(Huang and Stoll 1996).
Another factor that clearly affects how orders are
processed, and in turn the bid-ask spread, is the handling
of limit orders. As discussed above, on the NYSE limit
orders narrow the spread because limit prices can determine the inside spread. Hence, the best prices are available to investors, whether these prices come from the
specialist or from other investors through limit orders.
On Nasdaq, prices are set by market makers. Prior to the
rule changes made effective last year, limit orders were
recorded by individual dealers and did not determine the
inside spread. Because of this procedural difference, the
measured spread on the two exchanges came from different sources. The reservation prices of market makers
6

and investors also differ, leading to further differences in
quoted prices and spreads. Dealers derive earnings by
recycling stock rather than through long-run speculation. Dealers’ earnings come from buying stock and reselling it at higher prices. Investors, on the other hand,
generally trade for the long run and buy or sell based on
anticipated increases or decreases in a security’s value.
Despite a recognition that the treatment of limit orders
affects the spread, it appears to provide only a partial
explanation for wider Nasdaq spreads (Demsetz 1997).
Other institutional arrangements that affect pricing
in securities markets are agreements between brokers
and dealers to direct order flow, either internally or externally (Godek 1996; Kandel and Marx 1997). When an
order is internalized, a dealer trades with a customer at
the inside price quote for the dealer’s own account, even
if the dealer did not issue the best price quote. When an
order is preferenced, a dealer forwards the order to another market maker, who fills the order at the best price
quote. The dealer who receives a preferenced order is not
necessarily the market maker who issued the best price
quote. Internalization and preferencing lead to interdependencies across dealers and limit their incentives to
narrow spreads because they do not compete over incoming orders through their price quotes.2 Experimental economics methods have been used to provide insight into
the effect of order preferencing on quoted spreads in dealer markets (Ackert and Church 1998; Bloomfield and
O’Hara 1998).3 These studies conclude that preferencing
has striking effects on pricing behavior, even if dealers are
not permitted to communicate overtly.
Besides recognizing that the ability to direct customer order flow has important effects on quoted spreads,
Dutta and Madhavan (1997) argue that dealers compete
for orders along dimensions other than price. Nonprice
competition for order flow can take the form of research
services or agreements with brokers in which dealers pay
brokers for order flow.4 Because these other inducements
reduce the per share value of order flow to the dealer, conclusions about the competitiveness of markets are complex and cannot be based simply on price.5 Empirical
evidence suggests that dealers will compete for order flow
using methods other than price (Ackert and Church 1998).
Finally, spreads in dealer markets may be wider than
in other market structures if market makers conspire to
fix prices. Proponents of dealer markets argue that competition among dealers will produce narrow spreads. With
a large number of competitive dealers, cooperative agreements may be difficult to design and enforce. However,
Dutta and Madhaven (1997) argue that even dealers who
behave noncooperatively can set spreads that exceed the
competitive level. They show that self-interested dealers
can accrue abnormal profit despite acting noncooperatively. Institutional arrangements, like preferencing,
result in abnormal profit levels because these arrange-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

ments reduce dealers’ incentives to compete for order
flow using price. From a public policy standpoint this
result is important because dealers are not explicitly cooperating to fix prices; that is, excess spreads can arise
without explicit collusion.

Collusion in Securities Markets
n the Nasdaq market, more than thirty dealers are
involved in the pricing of an actively traded issue, so
it is likely that competitive pressures will come to
bear. Collusion may be difficult because of the absence of
explicit barriers to entry (Grossman and others 1997). In
addition, the “product” or service provided is not necessarily homogeneous because market makers may offer
cash payments for order flow and other noncash services.
However, it is difficult to ignore the words of the dealers
themselves (see Box 1). Their testimony, from depositions taken during the Department of Justice investigation, and audiotaped conversations suggest that Nasdaq
market makers followed an industrywide practice or
quoting convention that fixed transaction prices. The
practice of violating the industry’s quoting convention,
referred to by traders as making a Chinese market, was
actually viewed within the industry as unethical and
unprofessional conduct.
In understanding recent U.S. securities market experience, it is important to consider what sorts of behavior
are deemed anticompetitive. Collusion to raise prices is
certainly not a practice or a concern of recent origin.
According to Adam Smith, “People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but
the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public,
or in some contrivance to raise prices” ([1776] 1994, 148).
The dictionary defines collusion as a “secret agreement or
cooperation for an illegal or deceitful purpose.” American
law on overt price fixing is clear. Such behavior is illegal
per se. However, in many cases there is no explicit agreement to fix prices. Under the Sherman Act, the U.S. courts
developed the conscious parallelism doctrine. The
Supreme Court explained the doctrine as follows: “No formal agreement is necessary to constitute an unlawful con-

I

spiracy. Often crimes are a matter of inference deduced
from the acts of the person accused and done in pursuance of a criminal purpose. . . . The essential combination or conspiracy in violation of the Sherman Act may be
found in a course of dealings or other circumstances as
well as in an exchange of words. . . . Where the circumstances are such as to warrant a jury in finding that the
conspirators had a unity of purpose or a common design
or understanding, or a meeting of minds in an unlawful
agreement, the conclusion that a conspiracy is established is justified” (American Tobacco Co. et al. v. the U.S.
328 U.S. 781 [1946]).

The Case against Nasdaq
erious questions about the competitiveness of the
Nasdaq market surfaced in two widely publicized
studies by Christie and Schultz (1994) and Christie,
Harris, and Schultz (1994). The allegations led to investigations by the Department of Justice and the SEC, as well
as numerous on-going civil lawsuits (see Box 2). Christie
and Schultz report that odd-eighth price quotes are nearly nonexistent for many Nasdaq stocks and suggest that
market makers implicitly collude to widen spreads by
avoiding odd-eighth price quotes.6 According to the Justice
Department, this pricing convention existed for at least
three decades. However, following the publicity of the first
study, Christie, Harris, and Schultz report a sudden
decline in the spreads for several actively traded issues
and a concomitant increase in the use of odd-eighth price
quotes for those stocks. In fact, the inside spreads for
Amgen Inc., Cisco Systems, and Microsoft Corporation
fell by almost 50 percent immediately after newspapers
reported the results of the first Christie and Schultz study.
Average spreads for these stocks fell from between $0.25
and $0.45 to between $0.151 and $0.175.
The United States brought a civil action under the
Sherman Act with the claim for relief justified as follows:
“Beginning at least as early as 1989, and continuing to the
date of this Complaint, a common understanding arose
among the defendants and other Nasdaq market makers
concerning, among other things, the manner in which

S

2. Although orders are preferenced and internalized on the NYSE, the arrangement is more prevalent on Nasdaq (Huang and
Stoll 1996).
3. Experimental economics methods allow the researcher to conduct investigations that cannot be conducted in naturally
occurring markets and complement studies using traditional archival data. In the laboratory the experimental researcher
can control factors that are extraneous to the investigation. For example, Ackert and Church (1998) are able to directly
examine how dealers’ spreads are affected by order preferencing while controlling the overt communication among dealers.
4. Competition for order flow from brokers may result in order flow payments to the brokers that reduce market makers’ profits and can be viewed as a way for dealers to share their profits with brokers. The extent to which brokers, in turn, pass these
earnings on to individual investors is unclear.
5. Another complication when using price quotes to assess competitiveness arises because many transactions are negotiated
and occur between the best bid and ask price (Bessembinder 1997).
6. In June 1997 the NYSE followed the AMEX and Nasdaq and permitted trading in increments of one-sixteenth. Historically,
most stocks listed on large U.S. exchanges were quoted in increments of one-eighth, though moving to decimalization is debated. See, for example, Angel (1997).

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

7

B O X

1

Making a Chinese Market
s reported in the Department of Justice’s Competitive
Impact Statement, the traders’ testimony provides
insight into the degree of interdependence in the Nasdaq
market and the entrenchment of the pricing convention.
According to the market makers, those who attempted to
“break the spread” by violating the pricing convention created a “Chinese market.” For example, the following trader’s
testimony suggests that creating a Chinese market was not
only considered unprofessional but traders were actually
trained to conform to the convention:

A

Q: And through the period December ’93 through
December of ’94, do you observe the market makers entered very—relatively few odd-eighths. And
by that I mean, with perhaps one or two exceptions
under 10 percent of their quotes were odd eighths
in McCormick.
A: Yes, ma’am.
Q: And again, is that, in your professional opinion, because those market makers had three-quarter point dealer spreads and did not want to enter
what were termed “unprofessional markets”?
A: Yes, ma’am.
Q: How is it that all of the market makers knew
that entering an odd eighth quote could be unprofessional?
A: Young traders were trained over the years not
to put in unprofessional markets, “Chinese markets.” . . . This was part of the—of the traditional
and ethical on-the-job training that all of us got,
and it encompasses not only that you don’t put in
unprofessional-looking “Chinese markets,” it . . .
grew out of a self-imposed industry standard of
ethics and conduct. So that’s my answer as to why
everybody seems to be doing this, because most of
the people were trained the same way. (1996, 21;
italics in original)
In fact, the widely held belief that making a Chinese
market was unethical was reflected in the Security Traders
Association of New York’s (STANY) newsletter in 1989. The
Security Traders Association is the largest national trade
organization for security traders. In reporting on a speech

8

given at an “Ethics Conference” the newsletter misreported
a speaker’s comments. The correction was as follows:
In the recently issued STANY NEWSLETTER, we
are certain that you will realize that **** was
grossly misquoted when a portion of his speech
was extracted for publication. A corrected copy is
featured below.
As *** and you are all aware, it is clearly
UNETHICAL to make a Chinese Market or to run
ahead of an order. (22–23; italics in original)
Most of the communication between Nasdaq traders is
on the telephone. Phone calls were used to ensure compliance with the pricing convention as the following audiotape
excerpt suggests:
Trader 1: Who trades CMCAF in your place
without yelling it out?
Trader 2: . . . Sammy
Trader 1: Sammy who?
Trader 2: It may be the foreign department . . .
Trader 1: What?
Trader 2: The foreign didn’t realize they had to
trade it.
Trader 1: Well, he’s trading it in an eighth and
he’s embarrassing . . .
Trader 2: . . . foreign department
Trader 1: He’s trading it in eighths and he’s
embarrassing your firm.
Trader 2: I understand.
Trader 1: You know. I would tell him to straighten up his [expletive deleted] act and stop being a
moron. (24; italics in original)
Additional testimony and taped conversations revealed
that when firms continued to violate the pricing convention
they were punished in other ways, including the refusal of
other market makers to execute deals. The Department of
Justice’s investigation uncovered other anticompetitive conduct such as “moves on request.” A move on request is made
when one market maker agrees to change a price quote when
requested to do so by another, the purpose being to influence
the market in a stock.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

bids and asks would be displayed on Nasdaq (the ‘quoting convention’). Under the quoting convention, stocks
with a dealer spread of 3/4 point or greater are quoted in
even-eighths (quarters). Under the quoting convention,
market makers used odd-eighth fractions in their bid and
ask prices only if they first narrow their dealer spread in
the stock in question to less than 3/4 of a point.”
The quoting convention has two aspects. Under the
first part, stocks with spreads that exceed three-quarters
could not be quoted on odd-eighths. This practice ensures
that the inside spread of the stock is at least one-quarter
because off-eighth quotes are eliminated from the set of
possible price quotes. Hence only quarter points (for
example, 1/4, 1/2, 3/4) remain and the inside spread, which
is the difference between two prices at quarter points,
could not be less than a quarter point. Under the second
part of the convention, dealers could only use odd-eighth
quotes if they narrow their spread to less than $0.75.
Market makers are reluctant to narrow their spreads to
less than three-quarters of a point because at narrower
spreads they are exposed to greater trading risk. In general, at any point in time, a dealer has greater interest in
either buying or selling so that a single market maker’s
quotes do not normally constitute both sides of the
spread. Together the two parts of the pricing convention
allowed dealers to increase their earnings.
The Department of Justice and twenty-four major
dealers reached a settlement on July 17, 1996. The Department of Justice did not assert that dealers had an
explicit agreement to collude. However, there was a “conscious commitment to a common scheme,” and such
agreement is condemned by the Sherman Act. The department’s order, which was designed to prevent and detect
adherence to the pricing convention, required the firms
to tape traders’ telephone conversations.
The SEC conducted a concurrent investigation of the
Nasdaq market and concluded that the NASD failed to
properly oversee trading in the Nasdaq market and enforce
compliance with its own rules (1996). The SEC’s goal is to
promote price competition, and the recommendations in
its proposal reflect this goal. Prices should be determined
by supply and demand forces and customer order interaction. The proposal included requirements for order handling and execution designed to enhance price
competition. Specifically, the SEC ordered Nasdaq dealers
to publicly display investor limit orders that are at least 100
shares but not more than 10,000 shares. Dealers were also
directed to notify the public of the best available prices.
Despite its conclusion that Nasdaq market makers
engaged in abusive practices that suppressed competi-

tion, the SEC recognized that various institutional features also could affect the width of spreads. Its report
acknowledged the importance of preferencing, internalization, and payment for order flow, concluding that these
practices lead to price interdependencies and reduce
price competition. Because market makers have a stake
in each other’s quotes, nonprice forms of competition for
order flow provide economic incentives to engage in price
fixing. Although direction of and payment for order flow
were not prohibited, dealers were strongly chastised for
improper behavior, including price fixing and intimidation of rival dealers.7 The SEC summarized its position as
follows: “Vigorous price competition is a hallmark of a free
and open market and is critically important to the efficient functioning and regulation of a dispersed dealer
market. Because Nasdaq market makers trade securities
which are otherwise fungible, price should be a principal
means of competition in the Nasdaq market. Any significant hindrance to price competition impedes the free and
open market prescribed by the Exchange Act. The investigation found that certain activities of Nasdaq market
makers have both directly and indirectly impeded price
competition in the Nasdaq market” (1996, 13).

Conclusion
he behavior of security dealers has been closely
scrutinized in the 1990s. Recent investigations of
the NASD and the Nasdaq market by the Justice
Department and SEC suggest that prior to 1996 market
makers colluded to fix prices and widen bid-ask spreads.
At a minimum, market makers appeared to have adopted
a quoting convention that can be viewed as anticompetitive behavior. The purpose of this practice was to increase dealers’ profits at investors’ expense.
The results of recent academic studies also shed insight into dealer markets and pricing behavior. Important
findings suggest that spreads may be large on Nasdaq
because dealers had little incentive to compete using price
and to narrow the spread. In addition to collusion, institutional features such as preferencing may limit competition
for order flow, the effect of which is to produce spreads that
are wider than observed in a purely competitive setting.
Through the bid-ask spread market makers are
compensated for providing immediacy and liquidity to investors. These dealers also provide other services to their
customers such as research. Because they compete along
nonprice dimensions, a judgment regarding the competitiveness of the Nasdaq market based solely on the width
of the bid-ask spread is problematic. However, the Department of Justice and SEC clearly state that competition on

T

7. Other evidence of price fixing is reported by the Justice Department and the SEC. For example, price quotes on Instinet, a private electronic market, differed from Nasdaq quotes for the same stocks. Instinet is a proprietary system accessible to the institutional investors and dealers who are subscribers. Price quotes on Instinet may not be directly comparable to those on Nasdaq for
several reasons (Woodward 1997). For instance, Instinet prices do not generally include commissions whereas Nasdaq prices do.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

9

B O X

2

The Nasdaq Investigation: A Chronology
May 24, 1994: Approximately 100 security traders meet in
New York at the offices of Bear Stearns & Company and are
urged to narrow spreads.
May 26–27, 1994: Newspapers report the results of an
academic study of the behavior of Nasdaq dealers by
Professors William G. Christie and Paul H. Schultz. Christie
and Schultz report that market makers attempt to widen
spreads by avoiding odd-eighth price quotes. They conclude
that the most plausible explanation for this behavior is
implicit collusion. The results of the study were released to
the press on May 24.
May 31, 1994: Within one week after the release of
Christie and Schultz’s results, dealer spreads on four prominent Nasdaq stocks narrowed and market makers began
entering odd-eighth prices quotes in those stocks. Christie,
Harris, and Schultz later reported the change in behavior.
July 1994: Civil lawsuits are filed against thirty-three
major dealers alleging collusion.
October 1994: The Justice Department begins an investigation of antitrust law violations.
November 1994: The Securities and Exchange Commission
launches an investigation into the NASD’s self-regulatory
activities.
September 15, 1995: The Rudman Committee submits its
report to the NASD. The NASD Board of Governors appointed the committee in November 1994 to review NASD governance and oversight structure. The committee made several
recommendations intended to separate the regulatory and

price is essential for protecting the public interest.
Policymakers can, and in the Nasdaq case did, encourage
price competition by removing institutional obstacles.
New rules approved by the SEC and recently implemented in the Nasdaq market, including an open book of
limit orders, should enhance price competitiveness. If
orders are exposed to the entire market, dealers have
greater incentive to improve inside price quotes. However,

10

oversight functions of the NASD. These recommendations
were later implemented.
July 17, 1996: The United States files a complaint alleging that twenty-four major dealers fixed prices, in violation
of federal antitrust acts. The same day, the Justice Department settles with the dealers who agree to random taping of
trading-desk telephone calls but neither admit nor deny
wrong-doing.
August 7, 1996: The SEC concludes that the NASD violated
the Exchange Act of 1934, citing deficiencies in market oversight and failure to enforce NASD and federal securities laws.
In its settlement with the SEC, NASD agrees to spend $100
million over five years on additional market surveillance.
January 20, 1997: The SEC’s new order-handling rules for
the Nasdaq market take effect. Market makers are required
for the first time to show investors the size and prices for
certain orders. The SEC also directs the market to open previously exclusive electronic systems, including Instinet and
SelectNet.
December 24, 1997: Thirty securities firms settle a classaction suit alleging price-fixing for $910 million. The
agreement is believed to be the largest civil antitrust settlement in U.S. history. Six other firms had previously settled individually for a total of $98.9 million.
Currently: The SEC continues to investigate individual
traders in connection with price fixing, and additional civil
suits remain unsettled.

as dealers focus on price, they may compete less on nonprice dimensions and offer fewer services to their clients.
Finally, stern warnings and scrutiny from regulators and
investors are likely to dampen dealers’ incentives to
engage in collusive arrangements, whether explicit or
implicit. Recent changes in the Nasdaq market will lead to
narrower spreads and, in turn, improved market efficiency.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

REFERENCES
ACKERT, LUCY F., AND BRYAN K. CHURCH. 1998. “Bid-Ask Spreads
in Multiple Dealer Settings: Some Experimental Evidence.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 98-9, June.
AMIHUD, YAKOV, AND HAIM MENDELSON. 1986. “Asset Pricing and
the Bid-Ask Spread.” Journal of Financial Economics
17:223–49.
ANGEL, JAMES J. 1997. “Tick Size, Share Prices, and Stock
Splits.” Journal of Finance 52, no. 2:655–81.

HUANG, ROGER D., AND HANS R. STOLL. 1996. “Dealer versus
Auction Markets: A Paired Comparison of Execution Costs on
Nasdaq and the NYSE.” Journal of Financial Economics 41,
no. 3:313–57.
KANDEL, EUGENE, AND LESLIE M. MARX. 1997. “NASDAQ Market
Structure and Spread Patterns.” Journal of Financial
Economics 45, no. 1:61–90.
KIM, OLIVIER, AND ROBERT E. VERRECHIA. 1994. “Market
Liquidity and Volume around Earnings Announcements.”
Journal of Accounting and Economics 12:41–67.

BENSTON, GEORGE J., AND ROBERT L. HAGERMAN. 1974. “Determinants of Bid-Asked Spreads in the Over-the-Counter
Market.” Journal of Financial Economics 1:353–64.
BESSEMBINDER, HENDRIK. 1997. “The Degree of Price Resolution
and Equity Trading Costs.” Journal of Financial Economics
45:9–34.
BHUSHAN, RAVI. 1994. “An Informational Efficiency Perspective
on the Post-Earnings Announcement Drift.” Journal of
Accounting and Economics 18:45–65.
BLOOMFIELD, ROBERT, AND MAUREEN O’HARA. 1998. “Does Order
Preferencing Matter?” Journal of Financial Economics,
forthcoming.
CHRISTIE, WILLIAM G., JEFFREY H. HARRIS, AND PAUL H. SCHULTZ.
1994. “Why Did NASDAQ Market Makers Stop Avoiding OddEighth Quotes?” Journal of Finance 49 (December): 1841–60.
CHRISTIE, WILLIAM G., AND PAUL H. SCHULTZ. 1994. “Why Do
NASDAQ Market Makers Avoid Odd-Eighth Quotes?” Journal
of Finance 49 (December): 1813–40.
DEMSETZ, HAROLD. 1997. “Limit Orders and the Alleged Nasdaq
Collusion.” Journal of Financial Economics 45:91–95.
DUTTA, PRAJIT K., AND ANANTH MADHAVAN. 1997. “Competition
and Collusion in Dealer Markets.” Journal of Finance 52
(March): 245–76.

KLEIDON, ALLAN W., AND ROBERT WILLIG. 1995. “Why Do Christie
and Schultz Infer Collusion from Their Data?” Cornerstone
Research and Princeton University Working Paper.
NEAL, ROBERT. 1992. “A Comparison of Transactions Costs
between Competitive Market Maker and Specialist Market
Structures.” Journal of Business 65:317–34.
SMITH, ADAM. [1776] 1994. An Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Reprint, New York: Modern
Library.
STOLL, HANS R. 1985. The Stock Exchange Specialist System:
An Economic Analysis. Monograph Series in Finance and
Economics, no. 1985-2. New York: Salomon Brothers Center
for the Study of Financial Institutions.
STOLL, HANS R., AND ROBERT E. WHALEY. 1990. “Market Structure
and Volatility.” Review of Financial Studies 3, no. 1:37–71.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE. ANTITRUST DIVISION. 1996. United
States v. Alex. Brown & Sons Inc., et al.—Competitive
Impact Statement. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of
Justice. Available on-line at <http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/
f0700/0739.htm> [July 16, 1998].

GANLEY, JOE, ALLISON HOLLAND, VICTORIA SAPORTA, AND ANNE
VILA. 1998. “Transparency and the Design of Securities
Markets.” Bank of England Financial Stability Review
(Spring): 8–17.

U.S. SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION. 1996. Report
Pursuant to Section 21(a) of the Securities Exchange Act
of 1934 regarding the NASD and the Nasdaq Market.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission.
Available on-line at <http://www.sec.gov/news/extra/21a.txt>
[May 7, 1998].

GLOSTEN, LAWRENCE R., AND PAUL R. MILGROM. 1985. “Bid, Ask,
and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market with Heterogeneously Informed Traders.” Journal of Financial
Economics 14:71–100.

WOODWARD, SUSAN E. 1997. Price Fixing at Nasdaq? A
Reconsideration of the Evidence. Report commissioned by
the Special Studies Division of the Congressional Budget
Office. July.

GODEK, PAUL E. 1996. “Why Nasdaq Market Makers Avoid OddEighth Quotes.” Journal of Financial Economics 41:465–74.
GROSSMAN, SANFORD J., MERTON H. MILLER, KENNETH R. CONE,
DANIEL R. FISCHEL, AND DAVID J. ROSS. 1997. “Clustering and
Competition in Dealer Markets.” Journal of Law and
Economics 40:23–60.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

11

How Powerful Is Monetary
Policy in the Long Run?
M A R C O A . E S P I N O S A - V E G A
The author is a senior economist in the macropolicy
section of the Atlanta Fed’s research department.
He thanks Frank King for comments on an earlier
version of this article and Steve Russell for detailed
and thoughtful editorial suggestions.

P

RESS REPORTS ABOUT THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY OFTEN GIVE READERS THE IMPRESSION
THAT MONETARY POLICY AND THE PEOPLE WHO DIRECT IT ARE QUITE POWERFUL.
PLE, AN ARTICLE IN THE
PRESIDENT,

CHAIRMAN OF THE

WASHINGTON POST IN MARCH 1997 ASSERTS THAT “SECOND TO THE

ALAN GREENSPAN

IS ARGUABLY THE NATION’S MOST POWERFUL PERSON.

AS

FED, HE GUIDES U.S. MONETARY POLICY, ADJUSTING SHORT-RUN INTEREST RATES.”1

Many prominent academic economists seem to agree
that monetary policy is quite powerful. In reviewing the
monetary policy experience of the 1970s, Nobel Laureate
James Tobin wrote, “In one respect demand-management
policies worked as intended in the 1970s. . . . the decade
is distinguished by its three recessions, all deliberately
induced by policy. Likewise the expansionary policies
adopted to reverse the first two recessions, beginning in
1971 and 1975 respectively, promoted recoveries and in
1977 expansion . . . The major turns in direction conformed to the desires and intentions of the managers of
aggregate demand” (1980, 20–21).
Monetary policymakers themselves often describe
their role as powerful. Consider, for example, Federal
Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan’s testimony before
Congress in July of last year. Attempting to explain the
influence of monetary policy on the current state of the
economy, he stated that “the preemptive actions of the
Federal Reserve in 1994 contained a potentially destabilizing surge in demand, short-circuiting a boom-bust business cycle in the making” (1997). Without attempting to
explain the full meaning of Greenspan’s statement here, it
is clear from his language that he believes the Federal
Reserve System is powerful enough to have a profound
influence on the course of economic activity.

12

FOR EXAM-

Both Greenspan’s statement and Tobin’s comments
focus on the short-run effects of monetary policy. One
might suspect that if Greenspan really is the second
most powerful person in the United States then the policy tools he controls must have some long-run influence
on the U.S. economy. Ironically, however, although many
academic economists and most Federal Reserve policymakers believe that monetary policy is quite powerful in
the short run, they also believe that it is virtually powerless in the long run.
Although opinion on this subject is far from uniform, most economists seem to believe that monetary
policy can affect the level of real (inflation-adjusted)
economic activity—that is, economic variables such as
real interest rates, real gross domestic product (GDP)
and the unemployment rate—over periods of one or two
years. For example, the Fed can create economic recessions or strengthen cyclical expansions. It can do so,
according to the conventional view, by increasing the
growth rate of the money supply if it wants the economy
to grow faster and reducing it if it wants the pace of economic activity to slow. However, increases in the money
supply growth rate eventually cause the inflation rate to
rise, and decreases in the money growth rate have the
opposite effect. When policymakers discuss the short-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

run effects of monetary policy they usually describe
some version of this trade-off between higher inflation,
which almost everyone considers undesirable, and
desirable changes in other economic variables: higher
inflation vs. lower interest rates, lower unemployment,
or faster growth in real GDP.
As indicated, however, most economists believe
that the long-run effects of changes in monetary policy
are very different from their short-run effects. Federal
Reserve Governor Meyer has clearly stated the nature of
this difference in beliefs, commenting that “there is, to
be sure, no trade-off and hence no inconsistency between full employment and price stability in the long
run” (1997, 19).
A pair of simple diagrams illustrates the conventional views about the short- and long-run effects of
monetary policy. Chart 1 depicts a negatively sloping
curve that describes a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. In contrast, Chart 2, which displays a vertical line at the level of full employment,
illustrates a scenario in which there is no trade-off
between the level of unemployment and the rate of inflation. A low rate of inflation (price stability) is compatible with full employment, but so is a high rate of
inflation. If Chart 2 accurately describes the long-run
relationship between unemployment and inflation, then
changes in monetary policy that lead to changes in the
inflation rate have no effect on the long-run levels of
unemployment or real output. In the jargon of economists, this diagram describes a situation in which money
is superneutral in the long run.2
Although the view that monetary policy has real
effects in the short run but is superneutral in the long
run is widely accepted by academic economists, business economists, and economic policymakers, these
groups are not in complete agreement about the ultimate real effects of monetary policy. One source of differences involves the magnitude of the short-run
effects. Business economists and policymakers tend to
believe that the short-run effects of monetary policy are
very large, but most of their academic counterparts see
these effects as rather tame and inconsequential. A
related difference involves the questions of whether any
short-run power that the Fed may have can survive
repeated use. Most nonacademics seem to believe that
the Fed can use its policy tools as often as it wishes

without fear that they will lose their short-run effectiveness. On the other hand, most academic economists
believe that repeated, systematic efforts to use the Fed’s
power to affect real economic activity will grow less and
less effective over time.
This article reviews the development of the consensus view that monetary policy can have short-run effects
but that it is long-run superneutral. The discussion
emphasizes the fact that
the basis for this view is
the assumption that the
only way monetary policy
Most economists seem
can affect real economic
activity is via “money
to believe that monetary
illusion”—that is, by crepolicy can affect the level
ating changes in the
of real (inflation-adjusted)
price level that are misunderstood by houseeconomic activity over
holds and firms and
periods of one or two
cause them to make bad
years.
economic decisions. If
monetary policy can affect real economic activity by means other than
money illusion then it
may be possible for money to be nonsuperneutral in the
long run.
This article hopes to challenge economists and policymakers to devote more attention to investigating
alternative explanations for the real effects of monetary
policy—explanations that may imply that money is not
long-run superneutral. In order to develop these alternative explanations it is necessary to make very explicit assumptions about the role of money in an economy,
how it interacts with real variables and how economic
decisionmakers react to the changes in its supply.
Different assumptions will turn out to have very important implications for both the nature and the magnitude
of the results of policy changes. This point is illustrated
in the review of the small but growing branch of the
academic literature on the real effects of monetary policy literature that studies models in which money may
not be long-run superneutral. In these models the ultimate source of the real effects of monetary policy is the
credit markets. By linking monetary policy with the supply of credit these models can analyze an alternative

1. Linton Weeks and John Berry, “The Shy Wizard of Money: Fed’s Enigmatic Greenspan Moves Easily in His Own World,”
Washington Post, March 24, 1997, sec. A.
2. Money is said to exhibit long-run neutrality if permanent changes in the level of the supply of money have no long-run effects
on real interest rates or the growth rate of real output. In this case, the levels to which prices and other nominal variables
will increase are postulated to vary one for one with changes in the level of the money supply. Similarly, an economy is said
to display long-run superneutrality if permanent changes in the rate of growth of the money supply have no long-run effects
on either real interest rates or the rate of output growth, and the rates of inflation and other nominal variables are postulated to vary one for one with changes in the rate of growth of the money supply.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

13

CHART 1

Inflation

A Short-Run InflationUnemployment Trade-Off

M 3 V = P 3 T,

Unemployment

mechanism for evaluating the long-run effects of monetary policy that does not rely on money surprises.
Another important message of this article is that the
very idea that monetary policy is powerful in the short
run but powerless in the long run may be internally inconsistent.3 If monetary policy is indeed as powerful as
many informed people seem to believe, then theories of
its real effects that rely on money illusion may have to be
replaced by theories in which money is not superneutral
in the long run.

The Precursors
his section briefly reviews the evolution of two
prominent views on the neutrality of money: the
Keynesian view and the monetarist view. The discussion begins with a look back at the classical theory
that preceded Keynesianism and monetarism. It concludes by describing the clash between the Keynesians
and the monetarists and the resulting “unilateral synthesis” of the 1970s.
The Early Quantity Theory. Classical macroeconomic theory, which developed during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, was characterized
by its focus on economic fundamentals (“real” economic
conditions) such as individuals’ propensity to save, the
state of technology, and so on. In the classical view monetary policy played no long-run role in determining real
economic activity. In particular, it had no long-run
effect on the level of real interest rates. Classical theorists acknowledged that monetary policy might have a
minor influence over economic activity (particularly
interest rates) in the short run. In the long run, however, they viewed money as having a direct influence only
on prices.
This early view of the influence of money on prices
came to be known as the quantity theory of money. Like

T

14

many economic concepts, the quantity theory has a rich
history of reinterpretations. One of the earliest statements of the theory in its modern form was presented by
Fisher (1926). According to Fisher, an economy’s general price level is a function of the quantity of money in
circulation, the economy’s efficiency, or velocity, of circulation (the average number of times a year money is
exchanged for goods), and the volume of trade (the
quantity of goods purchased with money). Notationally,
Fisher expresses the equation of exchange as:

where M is the supply of money, V is the velocity of
money, P is the general price level, and T is the total value
of transactions or trade. Fisher held that in the long run
there was a “natural” level of real economic activity determined by economic fundamentals that could not be
affected by increases in the amount of money in the economy. In his words, “An inflation of the currency cannot
increase the product of farms and factories . . . The
stream of business depends on natural resources and
natural conditions, not on the quantity of money” (1926,
155). This hypothesis that there was a natural long-run
level of real economic activity, together with the assumption that the only role of money is to serve as a unit of
account, formed the basis of Fisher’s quantity theory
analysis that prices varied proportionately to changes in
the quantity of money. According to this equation, if
velocity of money and the value of transactions were fairly stable—at least in the long run—as the economy
approached its natural level, then changes in the quantity of money would be met with proportional changes in
the price level.
Fisher conceded that monetary policy might have
some temporary effects on real economic activity, commenting that “the ‘quantity theory’ will not hold true
strictly and absolutely during transition periods” (1926,
161). In his mind, however, these effects were mainly due
to temporary changes in velocity. If velocity was fairly stable in the long run, though, as he assumed, then it had to
be the case that prices varied proportionately with the
supply of money.
As this description indicates, the basic current consensus on the short- and long-run effects of monetary policy can be traced to the early quantity theorists.
According to their view, as represented by Fisher, monetary policy could have temporary real effects but it would
be superneutral in the long run. However, even the theory’s adherents understood that the theory needed further refinement.4 This task was undertaken a few years
later by Milton Friedman (see below). By the time of
the Great Depression, moreover, classical theory had
lost much of its popularity and a new, completely different macroeconomic theory was appearing.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

CHART 2
An Inflation-Unemployment
Relationship with No Trade-Off

Inflation

The Keynesians and Money: The First Time Around.
The first nonclassical macroeconomic theory was the
creation of John Maynard Keynes and is laid out in his
General Theory (1936). One of Keynes’s principal goals
was to identify the causes of the persistently high rates of
unemployment that were afflicting virtually the entire
world during the Great Depression. He also sought to
identify government policies that could help reduce
these high levels of unemployment. Although Keynes’s theory discussed the long-term implications of government
policies, his focus was on the short run. And although monetary factors played a role in determining real economic
activity in his theory (unlike in classical theory),
Keynes’s analysis emphasized fiscal policy. Keynes
believed fiscal policy was the most powerful tool a government could use to lift the economy out of a recession
or depression. In fact, his theory predicted that under
certain conditions increases in the money supply would
be unable to drive interest rates down low enough to
stimulate economic activity by generating additional
demand for credit. This situation was known as the liquidity trap. In liquidity trap situations money was
superneutral even in the short run.
Nonneutrality of Money in the Long Run: The
Chicago School. For many years after the Depression
and the world war that followed it the question of the
long-run implications of government policies received
very little attention. One of the early assessments of the
long-run effects of monetary policy came from, of all
places, the University of Chicago. The university’s department of economics—which was and remains perhaps the
world’s most influential collection of academic economists—has always been associated with the economic
principles of the classical economists. The Chicago economics department was instrumental in the development
of monetarism, which is usually considered to be a direct
descendant of classical macroeconomic theory. In 1951,
however, Lloyd Metzler, a prominent member of the economics faculty at Chicago, published a paper describing
the long-run implications of central bank open market
operations in which he asserted that under some circumstances monetary factors could interact with real
variables in such a way as to help determine the level of
real economic activity in both the short run and the long
run. Metzler wrote that “by purchasing or selling securi-

Full Employment

Unemployment

ties, the banking authorities can alter not only the temporary interest rate which prevails while the open-market transaction is taking place but also the rate at which
the system will return to equilibrium after the bank’s
transactions in securities have ceased” (1951, 107). He
continued, “By purchasing securities, the central bank
can . . . [cause] the system to attain a new equilibrium at
a permanently lower interest rate and a permanently
higher rate of capital accumulation” (112).
It is important to note that Metzler’s conclusion that
monetary policy–induced changes in the government’s
portfolio of liabilities could potentially have long-run real
effects does not rely on the monetary authority’s ability to
produce inflation surprises or on workers’ or firms’
inability to correctly appraise conditions in the labor
market. His analysis is therefore very different from most
modern analyses, which view monetary surprises and
their impact on naive participants in labor markets or
short-run market frictions as the main channel by which
monetary policy can affect real economic variables.
Although Metzler’s analysis is less than fully rigorous by modern standards, it is worth recalling because it
represents one of the first careful descriptions of a mechanism through which monetary policy can have long-run
real effects. As noted above, Metzler’s conclusions ran
counter to the classical tradition of the Chicago school.

3. If monetary policy has real effects only because of money illusion then it is likely these effects will be very limited in scale.
On the other hand, if monetary policy derives its real effects from other sources, then its short-run effects may be relatively
large. Thus, limited short-run real effects may go hand in hand with long-run superneutrality while deviations from longrun superneutrality may produce powerful short-run effects.
4. In particular, as stated, this description of the quantity theory is really more of an accounting identity than a theory that
qualitatively relates money to relevant macroeconomic variables. An accounting identity does not specify what is a given in
the analysis and how different variables will change as a result of alternative policy changes. A theory or model, on the other
hand, is specific about what is assumed to be exogenous to the model as well as what is determined within it and how different variables react to exogenous changes. A number of complimentary assumptions were really necessary for this equation to spell the list of properties Fisher attached to the quantity theory.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

15

Perhaps for this reason Metzler’s ideas failed to stimulate
a research program at Chicago (or elsewhere). Instead,
Chicago’s monetarists pressed ahead with refinements
of the quantity theory of money.
The Monetarists and the Modern Quantity Theory.
During the 1950s the monetarists attempted to recover the
popularity that classical theory had lost as a result of the
Great Depression and the development of Keynesian
macroeconomics. The most prominent monetarist was
(and remains) Milton Friedman, an economist at the
University of Chicago.
One of Friedman’s first
major contributions to
monetarism was a refinement of Fisher’s
quantity theory.
As Friedman pointIn the classical view moneed
out,
both the size of
tary policy played no longthe money supply and
run role in determining
the general level of
prices can be considreal economic activity.
ered public knowledge.
However, for a theory to
be able to make predictions regarding the
effects of changes in
monetary policy or
changes in the price level, it is necessary to establish some
assumptions about what differentiates the behavior of
money supply from the behavior of money demand. In
Friedman’s words, “The quantity theory is in the first
instance a theory of the demand for money. It is not a theory of output, or of money income, or of the price level.
Any statement about these variables requires combining
the quantity theory with some specifications about the
conditions of the supply of money . . . ” (1956, 4).
Friedman’s version of the quantity theory is based
on the postulate that there is a stable demand for real
money balances—that is, for purchasing power in monetary form. He assumes that in the long run the level of
money demand depends on economic fundamentals such
as real income, the interest rate, and the nature of the
technology for conducting transactions. Under this
assumption, changes in the nominal supply of money
engineered by the Fed have no long-run impact on the
real demand for money and consequently lead inevitably
and exclusively to changes in the price level. This observation is true both for one-time changes in the money
supply and for changes in the rate at which the money
supply is growing, which would result in changes in the
inflation rate but not in the levels or growth rates of real
variables. Thus, one implication of Friedman’s restatement of the quantity theory of money is that changes in
monetary policy would have no real effects in the long
run—that is, money would be long-run superneutral.
16

Money in Keynesian Analysis: The Second Time
Around. As the discussion has shown, early Keynesians
focused their attention on fiscal policy. They believed
that under normal circumstances changes in the general price level would be both infrequent and relatively
inconsequential. As a result, for many years after the
Second World War monetarists enjoyed a virtual monopoly over monetary analysis. This situation changed in the
mid-1960s, when Keynesians developed a strong interest
in the role of monetary policy.
Keynes himself rejected the quantity theory approach
to determining the price level. For Keynes, the magnitude
of the money supply in the economy was only one of a number of factors affecting the general level of prices. Another
important factor was the level of employment. In Keynes’s
view it was impossible to determine the ultimate impact
of a change in the quantity of money on the price level
without considering the economy’s overall level of
employment. More specifically, Keynes believed that “an
increase in the quantity of money will have no effect whatever on prices, so long as there is any unemployment”
(1964, 295). Since Keynes saw persistent unemployment
as the central problem facing industrialized economies,
he did not think it would be unusual for economies to go
for extended periods of time without observing significant changes in the price level. During the 1950s the general price level was indeed fairly stable. This circumstance
lent credence to the Keynesian view that focusing on fiscal
policies that might help solve chronic unemployment
problems was likely to be more fruitful than devoting a lot
of energy to analysis of price level determination.
As the postwar era wore on, inflation began to pick
up in both the United States and Western Europe. This
development stimulated interest in analyzing the causes
of and cures for inflation. In 1958 British economist A.W.
Phillips published an empirical analysis of historical data
for the U.K. labor market. He hoped to find empirical
support for the Keynesian hypothesis that the rate of
wage inflation depended on the tightness of the labor
market. Phillips found that from 1861 to 1957 the growth
rate of nominal wages was negatively related to the rate
of unemployment. This “Phillips curve” seemed to link the
real side of the economy (the rate of unemployment) to
the nominal side (nominal wages). And since wages are
the biggest single component of firms’ costs, most economists were willing to assume that persistent increases in
wage rates would eventually force firms to begin increasing their prices, producing economywide price inflation.5
Although Phillips’s findings were empirical in nature,
they have had a profound and lasting effect on the development of economic theories about the relationship
between inflation and real economic variables. As the
discussion has shown, Keynesian theory holds that it is
possible to use fiscal or monetary policy to increase or
decrease the level of aggregate demand and through it

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

the level of employment. The Phillips curve created a
link between the level of aggregate demand and the rate
of inflation. As a result economic policymakers began to
think of demand management policies as involving a
trade-off between the unemployment rate (and, more
generally, the level of real economic activity) and the
inflation rate. And if the Phillips curve was stable over
time then this trade-off would exist in both the short run
and the long run.
Long-Run Nonsuperneutrality of Money: The
Keynesian School. The first attempt to formalize the
Keynesian view about the long-run real effects of monetary policy was presented by James Tobin. Unlike the
classical economists (but like Metzler), Tobin saw real
economic activity in general, and real interest rates in
particular, as being determined jointly by economic fundamentals and by monetary policy—even in the long run.
In Tobin’s words, “Keynes gave reasons why in the short
run monetary factors and portfolio decisions modify, and
in some circumstances dominate, the determination of
the interest rate and the process of capital accumulation.
I have tried to show here that a similar proposition is true
for the long run. The equilibrium interest rate and degree
of capital intensity are in general affected by monetary
supplies and portfolio behavior, as well as by technology
and thrift” (1965, 684).
Tobin’s analysis resembled Metzler’s in abstracting
from labor markets and concentrating on portfolio
adjustments as the channel by which monetary policy
could have long-run real effects. According to Tobin’s
theory, both money and physical capital were elements
of an individual’s portfolio of savings. For a given real
rate of return on capital, an increase in the rate of inflation would make money less attractive and capital more
attractive, inducing individuals to reduce their holdings
of money in favor of holdings of physical capital. As a
consequence, one would observe additional accumulation of capital, a higher capital stock, and a higher output level in the long run.
Long-Run Superneutrality of Money: The
Monetarist School. What was the monetarist reaction
to Keynesians’ claim about the long-run effects of monetary policy? Monetarists did not address Tobin’s arguments directly. Instead, they attempted to provide a
theoretical underpinning for empirical work of the type
conducted by Phillips (1958) that analyzed the relationship between nominal and real variables. Once the
theoretical framework was in place, the monetarists used
it to explain why monetary policy–induced changes in
real economic activity would be short-lived.
While Phillips’s statistical evidence involved nominal
wages, standard economic theory assumes that house-

holds and firms base their employment decisions on real
(inflation-adjusted) variables such as real wages, real
interest rates, real profits, and so forth. Thus, additional
assumptions were needed to reconcile standard economic theory with Phillips’s findings. Ironically, the point of
departure for this reconciliation was Keynes’s observation
that “every trade union will put up some resistance to a
cut on money wages, however small, but no trade union
would dream of striking on every occasion of a rise in the
cost of living” (1964, 14–15). Friedman (1968) and Phelps
(1967) used Keynes’s
observation in an attempt to extract some
economic content from
One implication of
the statistical relationFriedman’s restatement
ship discovered by
of the quantity theory of
Phillips. Their explanation for the behavior
money is that changes in
Keynes described was
monetary policy would have
based on two assumpno real effects in the long
tions—one about the
nature of monetary polrun—that is, money would
icy, and the other about
be long-run superneutral.
economic decisionmaker’s responses to the
effects of monetary policy. The first assumption is that increases in the money supply often cause
“monetary surprises”—unexpected increases in the rate
of inflation. The second assumption was that economic
decisionmakers’ reaction to monetary surprises often
involves temporary money illusion, which is a temporary
failure to recognize that there has been an increase in
the price level. The basic idea here is that although monetary surprises increase the prices of all goods and services, economic decisionmakers usually notice the
effects of these increases on particular prices in which
they have a special interest—their wages or the prices of
the goods they produce—well before they notice their
effects on the overall price level. Until they discover that
the overall price level has increased, they mistakenly
believe that the increases in the money (nominal) prices
of the goods they care about represent increases in the
real prices (relative prices) of those goods. This mistaken belief can lead households or firms to make decisions
about saving, consumption, work effort, investment, production, and so forth that are quite different from the
decisions they would have made otherwise. As a result, by
creating monetary surprises monetary policy can influence the level of real economic activity.
Here is a hypothetical sequence of events that
illustrates how temporary money illusion can empower

5. For this explanation to make sense some additional assumptions are required. See Espinosa and Russell (1997) for an explanation of these assumptions.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

17

monetary policy: Suppose the economy starts out in its
long-run equilibrium at its normal inflation rate and its
“natural” real rate of interest. Suppose further that the
monetary authority begins to increase the money supply
at a faster pace than previously. The most immediate
consequence of this move will be a drop in nominal interest rates. Friedman explains, “Let the Fed set out to keep
interest rates down. How will it try to do so? By buying
securities. This raises
their prices and lowers
their yields . . . In the
process, it also increases . . . the total quantity
Tobin saw real economic
of money. The initial
activity as being determined
impact of increasing
the quantity of money
jointly by economic fundaat a faster rate than it
mentals and by monetary
has been increasing is
policy—even in the long
to make interest rates
lower for a time than
run.
they would otherwise
have been” (1968, 5–6).
The next step in
Friedman’s chain of
causation is that lower
interest rates will stimulate spending, and this increase in
spending will have a multiplier effect on the overall level
of economic activity. Friedman writes, “The more rapid
rate of monetary growth will stimulate spending . . . one
man’s spending is another man’s income” (1968, 5–6).
From this point, Friedman’s analysis can be illustrated
using the aggregate demand and aggregate supply (AD
and AS) diagram that appears in many textbooks in
introductory macroeconomics. The economy starts out in
a long-run equilibrium at the intersection of the AD and
AS curves. The intersection point represents the long-run
equilibrium levels of real output and the price level. In
the AD-AS framework, a change in a variable like the
market interest rate leads to changes in the market environment that determined the location of the AD and AS
curves and consequently produces a shift in at least one
of these curves. In this case, the increase in spending
that results from the decline in interest rates (which was
caused by the increase in the money supply growth rate)
is represented by a rightward shift in the AD curve. This
increase in aggregate demand produces an increase in
output and prices along the original aggregate supply
curve.
According to Friedman, this change in the equilibrium will be strictly a short-run phenomenon. As soon as
households and firms realize that lower interest rates
and faster-rising wages and product prices are also
associated with a more rapid rate of increase in the
overall price level—as soon, that is, as they realize that
real wages and prices have not changed—the house18

holds will reduce their supply of labor and the firms will
cut back their production. On the diagram, this behavior is represented by a leftward shift in the aggregate
supply schedule that exactly offsets the effects of the
increase in aggregate demand. In the end, the economy
will return to the original long-run natural level of economic activity but a higher rate of inflation. Friedman
writes, “Rising income will raise the liquidity preference
. . . and the demand for loans; it may also raise prices,
which will reduce the real quantity of money. These
three effects will reverse the initial downward pressure
on interest rates in something less than a year. Together
they will tend, after . . . a year or two to return [real]
interest rates to the level they would otherwise have
had” (1968, 5–6).
Friedman’s theory of the short-run effects of monetary policy is sometimes described as the liquidity effect
theory. In recent years this theory has been the basis for
a great deal of recent research, both empirical and theoretical, about the short-run effects of monetary policy.
As the discussion has indicated, Friedman’s liquidity effect theory is based on the belief that in the short
run the decisions of firms and households are influenced
by money illusion. In this theory, an increase in production and employment occurs not because there has been
a change in economic fundamentals but because a more
rapid rate of monetary growth has produced a higher
rate of inflation. In Friedman’s words, “The monetary
authority can make the market rate less than the natural rate [of interest] only by inflation” (1968, 7).
The monetary surprises/money illusion hypothesis
of Friedman and Phelps seemed to reconcile classical
economic principles with the existence of Phillips-type
relationships (a negative relationship between inflation
and the real interest rate, a positive relationship between
inflation and the level of real output, and so forth) created by monetary policy. Under this hypothesis the Phillips
curve continued to represent a menu of choices involving trade-offs between real and nominal variables that
were available to monetary policymakers—but only in
the short run.
The Accelerationist Hypothesis. In tandem with
this money illusion hypothesis, monetarists held firm to
the classical premise that in the long run all real economic variables such as the real interest rate or the real
unemployment rate have a natural level that is determined by economic fundamentals and is completely independent of the nature of monetary policy. In their view,
temporary money illusion was the only mechanism by
means of which monetary policy could affect real economic activity. It followed from these premises that continuous efforts by monetary policymakers to stimulate
economic activity would translate mostly into an everincreasing rate of inflation. While it might be possible for
monetary policy to influence the level of interest rates (in

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

particular) and real economic activity (in general) in the
short run, once households and firms recognized that the
rate of inflation had increased, the aggregate supply
would shift back and the real effects of an increased inflation rate would disappear. Further reductions in interest
rates and further stimulus to economic activity could be
attained only via further increases in the rate of inflation.
In Friedman’s words, “Let the monetary authority keep
the nominal market rate for a time below the natural rate
by inflation. That in turn will raise the nominal natural
rate itself, once anticipations of inflation become widespread, thus requiring still more rapid inflation to hold
down the market rate” (1968, 7–8). The view underlying
this “accelerationist” hypothesis is that while economic
decisionmakers cannot be fooled permanently by a single increase in the inflation rate, they can be fooled persistently by accelerating inflation—that is, by a price
level that increases over time at an increasing rate.

The Monetarists and the
Keynesians in Perspective
he monetarists’ persistent attacks on the
Keynesians failed to convince the Keynesians
that systematic efforts to use monetary policy to
affect economic activity would fail. The monetarist argument that attempts to exploit the short-run inflationunemployment trade-off would lead to accelerating
inflation convinced Keynesians that balancing the competing economic goals of keeping inflation low and
keeping real economic activity brisk would be harder
than they had thought. However, the argument did not
convince them that this balancing act was impossible.
To reiterate, during the 1960s Keynesian theorists
came to regard the Phillips curve as a menu of options
between inflation and unemployment from which policymakers could choose. They assumed that the Phillips
curve was stable, which implied that monetary policy
was powerful both in the short run and in the long run
(that is, that money was not long-run superneutral). To
Keynesians, the job of macroeconomic policymakers was
to design demand-management policies that would
strike the right balance between the competing problems of sustaining robust economic activity and controlling inflation.
Monetarists, on the other hand, believed the economy would be better off if the Federal Reserve supplied
money according to a fixed, publicly announced formula
and did not try to influence the level of real economic
activity. Monetarists such as Friedman and Phelps disagreed with Keynesians regarding the effectiveness and
usefulness of demand management. They viewed the “natural rate of unemployment” (the analog of Friedman’s
natural rate of interest: see above), together with the
quantity theory of money, as solid enough arguments to
assert beyond doubt the undesirability of activist mone-

T

tary policy and the long-run superneutrality of money.
Monetarists acknowledged the possibility that monetary
policy might have short-run effects on employment, interest rates, and private spending, but they believed that
these effects arose exclusively from the public’s misperception of the impact of changes in the price level.
According to the monetarists, the only way the monetary
authority could have persistent real effects was by producing an ever-accelerating
rate of inflation.
The debate between
the monetarists and the
Keynesians sometimes
Friedman’s liquidity effect
took the form of distheory is based on the
agreements about the
slope of the Phillips
belief that in the short run
curve. These disagreethe decisions of firms and
ments reflected differing
households are influenced
views about the effectiveness of monetary policy
by money illusion.
in the short run versus
the long run. During the
1970s, the Keynesians attempted to capitalize on
the monetarists’ tendency to frame the debate about monetary policy in
terms of short- and long-run effects. Their strategy
involved reinterpreting the Phillips curve in a way that
reconciled the Keynesian and monetarist views of the
timing of the inflation-unemployment relationship. This
strategy forced the Keynesians to acknowledge that there
were limits on the exploitability of the Philips curve.
A key element of the “compromise” offered by the
Keynesians was the NAIRU, an acronym that stands for
“non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment” (see
Espinosa and Russell 1997). In a diagram of the Phillips
curve, the NAIRU is the unemployment rate at which the
negatively sloping Phillips curve intersects Friedman’s natural rate of unemployment. Monetarists believed that the
existence of a natural rate implied that there was no useful trade-off between inflation and unemployment.
Keynesians, however, interpreted the natural rate as a
long-run constraint that policymakers have to face when
trying to exploit an inflation-unemployment trade-off
that remained both available and helpful in the short
run. This revised Keynesian view of the trade-off was
accepted by most policy-oriented economists and most
economic policymakers. In the words of Tobin, the “consensus view accepted the notion of a nonaccelerating
inflation rate of unemployment . . . as a policy constraint
on policy” (1980, 24).
In retrospect it is clear that as much as the monetarists tended to dismiss Keynesian views, in many ways
the two schools were not very far from each other—particularly in their analyses of the short-run consequences

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

19

of monetary policy. These similarities become more evident when the monetarist-Keynesian debate is put in
historical perspective. The years since the 1970s have
witnessed the development of “neoclassical” macroeconomics—a new school of macroeconomic thought that is
based on classical principles even more firmly than monetarism. One of the most influential branches of neoclassical macroeconomics is real business cycle theory.
According to real business cycle pioneers such as
Kydland and Prescott (1982) and Nelson and Plosser
(1982), the cyclical pattern of recessions and expansions
has little to do with monetary policy and can be explained
almost entirely by “real shocks”—technological developments, changes in tax policy, and other unpredictable
changes in economic fundamentals. Thus, the real business cycle theorists believe monetary policy has few or
no effects even in the short run.
As economist Joseph Stiglitz points out, “Friedman
is, in many ways, closer to the Keynesians than to the
real business cycle theorists. He believes, for instance,
that there are short run rigidities . . . such that any
action by the monetary authority cannot immediately
and costlessly be offset by changes in the price level”
(1991, 48). Stated differently, the short-run predictions
of the Keynesians and the monetarists differed in magnitude but not in direction. Both groups believed in a
monetary policy transmission mechanism under which
an increase in the money supply leads to an increase in
economic activity accompanied by an increase in the general price level. The disagreement about magnitudes
could, in principle, have been settled by the analysis of
the empirical evidence (although in practice this was no
easy task). But as long as the monetarists conceded that
monetary policy had some short-run real effects it was
impossible for them to make an unequivocal case against
the exploitability of the Phillips curve.
In summary, the classical school saw the long-run
level of economic activity as being determined independently of monetary policy. Metzler (1951) accepted
much of the classical analysis but believed that there
were situations in which monetary policy could have
long-run real effects. The monetarists focused on money
illusion as the only mechanism through which monetary
policy could have real effects. In their view, economic
fundamentals helped determine an individual’s demand
for money for transaction purposes. In the absence of
surprises this money-demand relationship was fairly stable. It followed that in the long run, changes in the rate
of money growth would produce proportional changes in
the rate of inflation but would not affect real variables.
Tobin (1965) sketched out a formal model in which
changes in the rate of money growth could have long-run
real effects. In his portfolio-based analysis, a permanent
increase in the inflation rate led to more capital accumulation and a lower real rate of return on physical cap20

ital. Keynesians implicitly accepted the monetarist view
of the role of money illusion in empowering monetary
policy. They came to view Friedman’s natural rates,
which could be interpreted as long-run equilibrium values determined exclusively by fundamentals, as long-run
constraints on policy strategies that remained effective
in the short run. The short-run policy effect predictions
of the Keynesians and the monetarists differed in regard
to magnitude and persistence but not in regard to direction. Both schools agreed that in the short run a higher
rate of money growth was associated with a higher rate
of inflation, a lower real interest rate, and a spurt in economic activity. Keynesians did not themselves develop
theories in which monetary policy was powerful in the
short run but money was superneutral in the long run.
Instead, they implicitly accepted the theoretical framework provided by their critics, the monetarists, although
the two schools continued to disagree about some of the
implications of this framework.
To this day, much of the economics profession continues to regard Keynesians’ acceptance of the monetarists’ position regarding long-run superneutrality as
proof that there has been a rigorous scientific synthesis
of the two theories. As discussed below, however, any synthesis of this sort is likely to be internally inconsistent.

The Neoclassical School
he arguments made by Friedman and Phelps
against Keynesian theory were extended by economists such as Lucas (1972) and Sargent and
Wallace (1976), who became the founders of the neoclassical school.6 Lucas’s 1972 article set the standards for
neoclassical macroeconomics and, to a large extent, for
all modern macroeconomics. The two pillars of his analysis were his assumption that economic decisionmakers
had rational expectations and his use of a dynamic general equilibrium model. A dynamic general equilibrium
model is a model that takes into account the intertemporal nature of many economic decisions and recognizes
that economic variables interact with each other.
Therefore, to determine the consequences of a postulated
policy experiment one has to consider the relevant economic variables simultaneously and through time.
Lucas’s article presented a very rigorous description
of a situation in which (1) money is superneutral in the
long run, and (2) the short-run real effects of monetary
policy are bound to be rather limited, even in a scenario
involving accelerating prices. A first step toward understanding Lucas’s analysis is to recognize a key distinction
between his assumptions and those of Friedman and
Phelps. A simple way to describe this distinction is to say
that the Friedman and Phelps analysis permitted persistent money illusion while Lucas’s analysis ruled out persistent money illusion. Stated differently, the Friedman
and Phelps analysis was based on the assumption that

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

changes in prices or wages could cause households and
firms to make “bad” economic decisions—decisions they
would not have made if they had used available economic information more efficiently and had displayed more
flexibility in reacting to the changes. Lucas, in contrast,
assumes that the public processes economic information
as efficiently as possible: in particular, individuals base
their current decisions on the best possible forecasts of
future events. His description of this decision-making
process includes specific assumptions about how people
form their economic expectations.
In Lucas’s model there are two types of changes in
prices: temporary changes in prices in particular industries, which are caused by short-run fluctuations in the
demand for the goods produced by those industries, and
changes in the price level, which are caused by changes
in the growth rate of the money supply. There are also
two types of changes in the growth rate of the money
supply: systematic, permanent changes in the average
(long-run) money growth rate and unsystematic, temporary changes in the current (short-run) money growth
rate. The systematic changes result from deliberate
changes in policy by the central bank; they produce a
permanent increase in the average rate of inflation. The
unsystematic changes result from errors in the implementation of the central bank’s operating procedures.
They do not reflect deliberate policy decisions, and they
do not affect the long-run average money growth rate or
inflation rates. They do, however, produce temporary
changes in the current rate of inflation.
As has been indicated, Friedman and Phelps had
assumed implicitly that economic decisionmakers have
access to complete economic information but fail to use
it efficiently. Lucas, on the other hand, assumes explicitly that decisionmakers use any information available to
them in the most efficient way but do not always have
access to complete information. The particular aspect of
the economy that Lucas assumes decisionmakers do not
have complete information about is the relationship
between changes in the relative prices of the particular
goods they produce and changes in the overall price
level. This information gap is important because fully
informed decisionmakers will react very differently to
changes in the prices of their goods that represent
changes in relative prices—that is, to situations in
which the prices of their goods change but the general
price level remains constant, or situations in which the
general price level changes but the prices of their goods
change by a larger or smaller proportion—than to
changes in the prices of their goods that simply follow
along with changes in the overall price level. More
specifically, decisionmakers have no incentive to
increase their work effort and production in response to

increases in the overall price level for the same reason
that one would not be any happier if a doubling of salary
coincided with a doubling of the price of every good purchased. On the other hand, it makes sense for a person
to increase effort and output if the relative price of the
good produced has increased. Under Lucas’s assumptions any such increases in effort and output will be temporary because the demand fluctuations that induce
them are also temporary.
Now suppose that at a given moment in time, and in
the absence of any changes in the economy’s fundamentals, the overall inflation
rate increases because of
an unsystematic increase
To Keynesians, the job of
in the money supply. As
the overall inflation rate
macroeconomic policymakincreases, prices in every
ers was to design demandsector or industry inmanagement policies that
crease. However, individuals are unable to tell,
would strike the right balimmediately, whether
ance between the competthe price increases afing problems of sustaining
fecting their sector are
relative or absolute
robust economic activity
changes. The reason is
and controlling inflation.
that people are assumed
to have better information about prices of the
goods and services in their industry than about the many
different prices that figure in the overall price level. This
lack of complete information about the overall level of
prices leads people to assume that at least part of the
increase in the price of their product has been caused by an
increase in its relative price. As a result, they increase their
work effort and production.
The situation just described seems quite consistent
with the Keynesian notion that there is a short-run tradeoff between rate of inflation and the level of economic
activity. But does this trade-off indicate that monetary
policy is powerful, in the sense that the central bank can
use it to control the level of economic activity? Is this a
model of the “tightrope walk” that aggregate demand
managers are often described as having to perform? If
the central bank in the model can use monetary policy
actions to exert continuous and repeated influence over
individual decisions concerning work effort and production, then the answer to these questions may be yes.
This situation turns out not to be possible, however.
Suppose that the central bank announces a permanent
change in the average growth rate of the money supply.
Lucas’s assumption that people have rational expectations implies that they understand the nature of the
relationship between money growth and inflation. As a

6. For a detailed nontechnical description of Lucas’s contribution see Espinosa and Russell (1997).
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

21

result, they will not increase their work effort or production in response to the resulting increase in the average
rate at which prices change. Thus, permanent increases
in the money growth rate have no effect on the level of
output or employment, while temporary increases in the
money growth rate will produce temporary increases in
both output and employment.
Thus, in Lucas’s model the rational expectations
assumption implies that systematic changes in monetary
policy should not have real effects. The rigorous nature of
Lucas’s analysis made his
argument seem very convincing. It is important to
To this day, much of the
note, however, that the
economics profession conargument also depends
on Lucas’s assumption,
tinues to regard Keynesians’
which is built into the
acceptance of the monestructure of his model,
tarists’ position regarding
that the effects of monetary policy on real ecolong-run superneutrality as
nomic activity are caused
proof that there has been a
only by money illusion.
rigorous scientific synthesis
Lucas’s argument
can
be illustrated furof the two theories.
ther by returning to the
context of his model and
exploring its implications in a somewhat less rigorous way. Suppose that the
central bank in his model attempts to exploit the apparent trade-off between inflation and output by increasing
the average money growth rate without making any
announcement that it has done so. It is hoping that people will make inflation-forecasting mistakes because they
will not recognize that any policy change has occurred.
The increase in money growth will, of course, produce a
permanent increase in the average inflation rate.
Initially, people will mistake this systematic, policyinduced increase in the inflation rate for an unsystematic inflation rate increase caused either by a temporary
demand disturbance or by an error in the execution of
the original monetary policy rule. Since they will not be
sure which of these two types of unsystematic increase
has occurred, their work effort and production will rise
(see above). Soon, however, people will start to recognize
that there is a pattern to the unusually high rates of inflation they are observing. As a result, they will begin to
think it less and less likely that the next above-average
increase in the inflation rate was caused by a demand
disturbance, and they will begin to cut back on their
above-normal production and work effort. Ultimately,
they will realize that the central bank has changed policy in a way that has caused the average inflation rate to
increase. At this point, the increase in the average inflation rate will no longer have any effect on work effort and
production.
22

The scenario just described suggests that systematic changes in monetary policy may have substantial
short-run effects but no long-run effects, just as the monetarists argued and just as the Keynesians ultimately
conceded. Suppose, however, that the central bank tries
to repeat its short-run success by changing the average
inflation rate from time to time in response, say, to other
changes in the state of economy. In the real world people
learn from past mistakes: as a result, each time the central bank engineers another systematic change in the
inflation rate people will catch on to the policy change
more quickly and the effects of the change will disappear
more quickly. At some point, moreover, people will figure
out which events motivate the central bank to change
policy; they will then be able to detect policy changes as
soon as they occur. At this point the policy changes will
no longer have any effects, even in the short run.
These modified rational expectations assumptions
about the way people obtain and use information seem
consistent with one’s economic intuition about the
behavior of actual households and firms. In real-life
economies, most people have a very good “micro” picture
of the status of their firm or industry but a fairly fuzzy
“macro” picture of the state of the economy at large.
However, once they start getting surprised by unexpected price changes that make their decisions work out
badly they become more interested in identifying the
causes of changing prices. They start to use any information available to them to try to anticipate changes in
the price level and distinguish them from changes in relative prices. As a result, future price level increases have
less and less surprise effect. This sort of intelligently
adaptive behavior is the real-life analogue of Lucas’s formal assumption that economic decisionmakers have
rational expectations.
Lucas’s argument, and the closely related arguments
of neoclassical economists such as Sargent and Wallace
(1976), left Keynesians with only two intellectually legitimate choices. First, they could have tried to capture their
intuition about the effects of monetary policy in a rational
expectations general equilibrium model in which money
was not long-run superneutral because monetary policy
derived its real effects from some source other than monetary surprises. Many economists expected this approach.
Sargent, for example, writes that “in the early 70’s, I
thought that Modigliani, Solow, and Tobin—our heroes in
those days—were missing the boat by resisting the intrusion of rational expectations into macroeconomics,
instead of commandeering it. Despite the appearances of
its early incarnations like Lucas’s 72 JET paper, the
canons of rational expectations models . . . were evidently wide enough to include Lucas’s brand of monetarism or,
just as readily, accommodate the completion of Tobin’s
criticism of monetarism by fully bringing to bear the logic
of Modigliani and Miller. Modigliani, Solow, and Tobin

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

chose not to commandeer the movement, and left it to
Kareken, Wallace, Chamley, Bryant and others to draw out
many of the nonmonetarist implications then waiting to be
exposed.” (1996, 545). In retrospect it seems clear, as this
quotation indicates, that an important reason Keynesians
did not pursue this strategy was because they mistakenly
believed that rational expectations implied long-run
superneutrality of money.
Another alternative for Keynesians might have been
to concede that monetary policy was long-run superneutral but to argue that frictions of various sorts might allow
monetary policy to have real effects in the short run.
Taylor’s work on staggered contracts (1980), his work on
slow adjustment of prices (1994), and the work of Ball and
Mankiw (1995) concerning “menu costs” are illustrations
of this line of research. This research has faced criticisms
on two fronts. First, there is little empirical evidence to
support this type of nominal rigidities (see, for example,
Wynne 1995). Second, there has not been a clear explanation as to why these frictions could prevent people from
changing their behavior so as to offset the effects of systematic changes in monetary policy. For example, what
prevents individuals from relying on mechanisms such as
indexing of nominal contracts to guard against the potential negative effects of nominal rigidities?
Most Keynesians chose to ignore the neoclassical critique and the potential problems with short-term frictions. They continued to claim that monetary policy had
powerful short-run effects, while accepting the monetarist critique that it was powerless in the long run. For
the most part, economists outside academia—business
economists and economic policymakers—have adopted
this “Keynesian consensus” view. To the extent that either
group of economists has attempted to justify this view,
they have done so by arguing that rational expectations is
a sensible assumption only in the long run. In the short
run, they argued, people could and often did misread the
nature and effects of changes in monetary policy.
What is wrong with the Keynesian consensus? Lucas
points out that, while it may seem reasonable on its face,
it suffers from serious logical problems. Com-menting on
Tobin’s description of the Keynesian consensus, Lucas
writes, “Here we have Model A, that makes a particular
prediction. We have model B, that makes a strikingly different prediction concerning the same event. The event
occurs, and Model B proves more accurate. A proponent
of model A concludes: ‘All right, I “accept” Model B too.’
Consensus economics may be a wonderful thing, but
there are laws of logic which must be obeyed . . . These
models gave different predictions about the same event
because their underlying assumptions are mutually
inconsistent. If the Friedman-Phelps assumptions are
now ‘accepted,’ which formerly accepted Keynesian
assumptions are now viewed as discarded? Tobin does
not say” (1981, 560–61). Lucas goes on to spell out the

monetarist (model B)-Keynesian (model A) consensus,
as viewed through the Keynesian glass. He writes,
“Though I refer to Tobin as ‘evading’ a central issue, I do
not think he sees it this way at all. He writes as though
he is willing to concede the ‘long-run’ to Phelps and
Friedman [the Monetarists], claiming only the ‘shortrun’ for Keynesians. Where is the conflict?” (561). Lucas
goes on to explain that the long run consists of a sequence
of short runs. If a policymaker conducts short-run policy
by choosing an annual money growth rate based on model
A (the Keynesian model)
every year, then he or she
has implicitly used
model A to pick the average rate of money growth
for the long run. It is logLucas’s 1972 article set
ically inconsistent to prethe standards for neoclastend that the long-run
average money growth
sical macroeconomics and,
rate using model B (the
to a large extent, for all
monetarist model) can
modern macroeconomics.
be a guide. Suppose, for
example, that the central
bank decides that in the
long run the optimal
growth rate of the money
supply is 5 percent per
year. However, it decides on the basis of short-run considerations that it would be a good idea to increase the money
growth rate to 6 percent for the coming year. The same
thing happens again in the following year, and in the year
after, and so on. The end result is a departure from the
optimal long-run money growth rate that may have
adverse consequences for the economy. Thus, Lucas
observes that “if we concede that Model A gives us an inaccurate view of the ‘long-run,’ then we have conceded that
it leads us to bad short-run situations as well” (560–61).
Monetary Policy after Lucas. Starting in the late
1960s, Keynesian economic theory was the victim of a
succession of setbacks, including the monetarist critique
of Friedman and Phelps, the combination of high inflation and high unemployment that the United States
experienced during the 1970s, and the neoclassical critique of Lucas (1972) and Sargent and Wallace (1976).
As Keynesian theory lost ground in the academic community, so did belief in the power of monetary policy. In
fact, much of the early work by neoclassical economists
followed Lucas (1972) by constructing models that made
debating points against the Keynesians by demonstrating
that systematic changes in monetary policy would have
no real effects, even in the short run. Unsystematic policy actions might have a short-lived influence on the level
of economic activity, but any attempt to use systematic
changes in policy to exploit this influence would be frustrated by changes in the expectations of the public.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

23

The fact that the model described by Lucas (1972)
became the “industry standard” in neoclassical theory
has encouraged other neoclassical economists to focus
on models that display long-run superneutrality of
money. In recent years, the most popular vehicle for
research on monetary policy by neoclassical economists
has been the real business cycle model. In this model
money is long-run superneutral, but temporary changes
in monetary policy can generate small “liquidity effects”
of the sort described in Friedman (1968). (See, for
example, Lucas 1990; Christiano and Eichenbaum 1991,
1992; Fuerst 1992; Dow 1995).
During the mid1970s economist Harry
Johnson, reviewing
Lucas’s article presented
what
he labeled the
a very rigorous description
Keynesian revolution
of a situation in which (1)
and the monetarist
counterrevolution, commoney is superneutral in
mented that “the monethe long run, and (2) the
tarist counterrevolution
short-run real effects of
has served a useful purpose, in challenging and
monetary policy are bound
disposing of a great deal
to be rather limited, even
of the intellectual nonin a scenario involving
sense that accumulates
after a successful ideoaccelerating prices.
logical revolution . . . If
we are lucky, we shall
be forced as a result of the counterrevolution to be both
more conscious of monetary influences on the economy
and more careful in our assessment of their importance”
(1975, 106).
In fact, the monetarist counterrevolution had
mixed effects on economists’ views concerning the
importance of monetary policy. On the one hand, monetarist arguments convinced many Keynesians that monetary policy had many of the same powers that they had
attributed to fiscal policy. On the other hand the monetarists, as has been pointed out, completely dismissed
the possibility that monetary policy might have long-run
real effects. To the extent that Keynesians conceded
this point they were also conceding that the importance
of monetary policy was quite limited.
As shown above, the period of the monetarist counterrevolution was also a period when a few economists
began to try to identify explicit mechanisms that would
allow monetary policy to have long-run real effects.
Metzler (1951) and Tobin (1965) developed theories
that allowed the Keynesian, conventional wisdom to be
extended to the long run. These theories allowed permanent increases in the money supply growth and inflation rates to be causally associated with permanently
lower real interest rates and permanently higher levels
of output.
24

Lucas’s (1972) work suggested that macroeconomic theories of all sorts were in need of reevaluation. The
theories of Metzler, Tobin, and the ones derived from
Phillips’s analysis were no exception. Lucas’s interpretation of the Phillips curve analysis has been described
above. The next section reviews subsequent research
that tries to reformulate Metzler’s and Tobin’s theories
using the neoclassical methodology Lucas introduced.
This research indicates that departures from long-run
superneutrality are possible because monetary policy
does not necessarily derive all (or any) of its power from
money illusion. Instead, changes in monetary policy may
have lasting effects because it affects the supply of or the
demand for credit.

Some Neoclassical Models That Deliver
Long-Run Nonsuperneutralities
his section looks at the three challenges facing
economists who want to develop neoclassical models that deliver results similar to those of Metzler,
Phillips, and Tobin. The first challenge is simply to construct a plausible neoclassical model in which money is
not long-run superneutral. The second challenge is to
identify a mechanism under which the departures from
superneutrality work in the “right direction,” that is, a
mechanism that allows increases in the money supply
growth rate to be causally associated with lower real
interest rates and higher levels of output. The third challenge is to find a mechanism that has some hope of generating departures from superneutrality that are large
enough to have practical importance.
The Tobin Effect. An answer to the first challenge
is to rely on the credit market as the ultimate source of
the real effects of monetary policy. In this respect one
could follow Tobin (1965). Tobin’s analysis is based on
the idea that the increase in the inflation rate that is
induced by an increase in the money supply growth rate
increases the supply of credit at any real interest rate. It
does so because when the inflation rate rises money
becomes a relatively unattractive asset, and the public
wishes to cut back on its money balances and increase its
holdings of bank accounts, bonds, stock, and other financial assets. Thus, there is a decrease in the demand for
money and a matching increase in the supply of credit.
The Tobin effect mechanism allows a permanent easing
of monetary policy (a higher money growth rate) to lead
to a higher inflation rate, a lower real interest rate (due
to the increased supply of credit), and a higher level of
output (due mostly to an increase in the capital stock).
Many economists believe that financial intermediation is one of the most important channels through which
changes in monetary policy affect the economy (see for
instance Bernanke and Gertler 1995). The central bank
may be able to affect the composition of financial intermediaries’ portfolios without relying on monetary sur-

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

prises. Thus, permanent changes in monetary policy may
affect financial intermediaries in a fundamental way and
may have long-run real effects. It follows that a natural
environment in which to analyze the Tobin effect would
be one in which financial intermediaries were explicitly
developed.
The starting point for assessing this possibility
should be a realistic model of financial intermediation.
Bencivenga and Smith (1991) were among the first
economists to include financial intermediaries in a
dynamic general equilibrium macroeconomic model.
The Bencivenga-Smith intermediaries are similar to
actual intermediaries in accepting deposits from, and
lending to, a large number of individuals. They are also
similar to actual intermediaries in making loans that are
less liquid than the deposits they accept. As a result,
they are forced to hold a liquid asset (money) on reserve
to cover sudden deposit withdrawals.
In the Bencivenga-Smith model individuals could,
in principle, manage their own asset portfolios (as in
Tobin 1965). However, the financial intermediaries have
an actuarial advantage over individuals in structuring a
portfolio. Consequently, under most circumstances people will prefer to delegate this activity to financial intermediaries. Although Bencivenga and Smith’s work
contains the elements needed to pursue an analysis of
the long-run effects of permanent changes in monetary
policy, their analysis concentrates on the long-run implications of financial intermediaries for an economy’s
long-run performance. Based on the Bencivenga and
Smith model, Espinosa and Yip (1998) study the growthinflation implications of alternative fiscal and monetary
policies in the presence of financial intermediaries.
Espinosa and Yip can, thus, draw some qualitative
lessons on the Tobin effect in a dynamic general equilibrium model that explicitly models financial intermediaries. Before listing their findings, it is useful to briefly
review some recent empirical results on the relationship
between inflation and growth.
Inflation and Growth. In part because money has
been assumed to be long-run superneutral, there has not
been much research on the long-run relationship between inflation and growth. Recently, however, interest
in theoretical and empirical analysis of this relationship
has revived. The empirical findings are not always in
agreement. DeGregorio (1992) and Barro (1995) uncover a significant negative correlation between inflation
and economic growth. On the other hand, Bullard and
Keating (1995) and Bruno and Easterly (1998) do not
find strong support for such an inverse relationship.
Bullard and Keating find that the direction of the growthinflation relationship depends crucially on the initial
level of the inflation rate. In countries in which the rate
of inflation starts out relatively low, a permanent
increase in the inflation rate actually increases the long-

run level of economic activity. Only for countries with relatively high initial inflation rates do Bullard and Keating
find that permanent increases in the rate of inflation negatively affect long-run growth. These findings are partly
confirmed by Bruno and Easterly, who are able to find an
inverse relationship between inflation and growth only
when the rate of inflation exceeds some critical value.
Clearly, these empirical studies do not settle whether
monetary policy can have real effects that do not spring
from monetary surprises and whether these effects are
likely to be of the type described by Tobin, with higher
inflation being associated with higher rates of growth.
Espinosa and Yip (1998)
address these questions
in a model based on the
model developed by
Bencivenga and Smith
(1991). Their analysis
Keynesians mistakenly
emphasizes the point
believed that rational
(to be made very explicexpectations implied
itly below) that fiscal
and monetary policy are
long-run superneutrality
inevitably linked by the
of money.
government budget constraint. In their model,
monetary policy consists
of changes in the growth
rate of the money supply
that are necessitated by
changes in fiscal policy—specifically, by changes in the
government budget deficit as a fraction of GDP.
Espinosa and Yip show that their model can produce
the positive long-run relationship between inflation and
growth that was predicted by Tobin. However, it is also possible for the model to produce situations in which lower
rates of inflation result in higher rates of growth. The
direction of the inflation-growth relationship depends on,
among other things, the initial inflation rate, the degree of
risk aversion of the average depositor, and the size of the
government budget deficit. Thus, the Espinosa-Yip analysis provides a theoretical framework that helps reconcile
the conflicting empirical findings about the direction of
the long-run relationship between inflation and growth
that were described in the preceding subsection.
Fiscal Policy and Open Market Operations. The
Tobin effect has a potential drawback as a theory of the
real effects of monetary policy (see, for example,
Danthine, Donaldson, and Smith 1987). The shift in the
credit supply curve produced by an increase in the inflation rate is essentially equal to the reduction in money
demand that the increased inflation induces. Money
demand is quite small (a small fraction of total output, or
total assets, and so forth) and statistical evidence (for
example, Hoffman and Raasche 1991) suggests that it is
not very sensitive to changes in the inflation rate. As a

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

25

result, the Tobin effect of moderate changes in the inflation rate on real interest rates and output is likely to be
small.7
An alternative mechanism for linking monetary
policy and the supply of credit has been developed by
Sargent and Wallace (1981). This mechanism is based
on the fact that changes in monetary policy affect the
government’s stream of revenues and thus necessitate
changes in fiscal policy. To gain a better understanding
of this mechanism, it is useful to review some basic elements of a government’s budget constraint.
An important premise of the research described in
this section is that both fiscal and monetary policy
actions are constrained by the government’s need to
finance its expenditures. Consequently, these two types
of government policy cannot be devised or executed
independently from each other. The government of a
country must decide on the level of government spending to finance domestically, how much of its domestic
financing will rely on current taxes, and how much will
take the form of newly issued debt. Stated differently, it
is the government budget deficit that determines the
need for new issues of government debt. Since government borrowing competes with private borrowing in the
credit market, the amount of government borrowing is
likely to influence the level of real interest rates.
Government policy concerning taxes, debt, and
deficits is usually described as fiscal policy. The analysis just presented suggests that fiscal policy may affect
real interest rates. However, monetary policy has a fiscal policy aspect to it because it may play a role in
determining the size of the government budget deficit.
To the extent that monetary policy has this effect, this
analysis suggests that it will also have an impact on real
interest rates. Thus, monetary policy may influence the
real economy in ways that do not involve inflation surprises. If this influence can persist in the long run then
money may not be long-run superneutral.
In practice, monetary policy is carried out via open
market operations. Open market operations produce
changes in the composition of the government’s portfolio
of liabilities—debt (bonds and bills) versus money.8
Given the amount of government bonds currently outstanding, the government must decide what fraction of
these bonds (if any) it will “monetize” by purchasing
them with newly created currency. This decision, which
determines the composition of the government’s liability
portfolio, also determines the amount of outstanding
government debt in the credit markets and consequently has an impact on the market real rate of interest. More
specifically, changes in the growth rate of the money
supply affect the volume of government revenue from
currency seigniorage (the “inflation tax”). Sargent and
Wallace (1981) assume that the government’s primary
(net of interest) budget deficit is fixed by the tax and
26

spending decisions of Congress and is not affected by
changes in monetary policy. Consequently, the only way
the government can offset the changes in its revenues
that are caused by changes in monetary policy is to
change the size of the national debt. Thus, this mechanism can be thought of as the neoclassical successor of
Metzler (1951) (because of Metzler’s emphasis on open
market operations as the mechanism through which
non-long-run superneutrality results could be attained).
The size of the national debt has substantial effects
on the state of the government budget. On the one hand,
the government has to pay interest on the debt. On the
other hand, as the economy grows the government can
allow the national debt to grow at the same rate without
increasing the size of the debt relative to the economy.9
The relationship between these two factors determines
whether debt service is a financial burden for the government or whether the existence of the national debt
actually increases the amount of government revenue.
To see why the latter situation is possible, suppose
the government borrows just enough each year to keep
the debt-GDP ratio constant. If the economy is growing,
it will increase its borrowing each year by an amount
that causes the real national debt to grow at the same
rate as real GDP. Although the government will have to
use some of the proceeds of this new borrowing to pay the
interest on the current debt, if the real (also inflationadjusted) interest rate on the debt is lower than the real
GDP growth rate then the government will have funds
left over to use for other purposes. In this case, the
national debt actually provides the government with revenue on net. This source of revenue is sometimes
referred to as bond seigniorage.10 The difference between
the real growth rate and the real interest rate is the net
real amount that each real dollar of debt contributes to
the government budget each year.
If the real interest rate on the government debt is
higher than the output growth rate then the government’s new borrowing will not be enough to cover the
interest on the existing debt. As a result, some of this
interest will have to be covered by funds from other
sources. In this case the national debt is a financial burden for the government. (One can think of this as a case
in which bond seigniorage revenue is negative.) The difference between the real interest rate and the real
growth rate is the net real amount that each real dollar
of debt costs the government each year.11
Once it is known whether the national debt is a
source or a use of government funds one is in a position
to determine how a change in the size of the national
debt will affect the government’s budget position. Other
things being equal, an increase in government borrowing
that increases the size of the national debt represents an
increase in the quantity of credit demanded at each real
rate of interest and will consequently produce an

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

increase in the real interest rate. If the real interest rate
is relatively high, so that the debt is a burden on the government budget, then the combination of a larger debt
and a larger unit cost of financing the debt means that
the debt will definitely become costlier to the government. Conversely, a smaller debt that will result in a
lower real interest rate will reduce the government’s
costs. As a result, when the government cuts the money
supply growth and inflation rates and loses money from
currency seigniorage, it must compensate by cutting
back on its borrowing and driving the real interest rate
down. As a result, tighter monetary policy produces
lower real interest rates and a higher level of output.
Suppose, on the other hand, that the real interest rate
is relatively low, so that the national debt is a source of revenue for the government. In this case, a given change in the
size of the debt (say, an increase) can either increase or
decrease government revenue from bond seigniorage. An
increase in the size of the debt tends to cause bond
seigniorage revenue to increase: this is the “tax base effect”
of the increase. On the other hand, an increase in the government debt drives the real interest rate closer to the output growth rate and reduces the real seigniorage revenue
produced by each real dollar of debt. This is the “tax rate
effect” of the increase. If the tax base effect is stronger than
the tax rate effect then an increase in the size of the debt
will increase the government’s bond seigniorage revenue;
otherwise, the amount of revenue will fall.
The tax rate effect tends to be largest when the government debt is large, because in this case any change in
the real interest rate affects the revenue produced by a
large volume of debt. Conversely, the tax base effect
tends to be largest when the real interest rate is low
because each dollar of debt generates a lot of revenue. A
low real interest rate tends to be associated with a small
volume of government debt, since when the real interest
rate is low private credit demand is high and private
debt crowds out government debt. Conversely, a high
real interest rate tends to be associated with a large government debt. As a result, when the real interest rate is
relatively low—well below the output growth rate—an
increase in the size of the national debt tends to increase
bond seigniorage revenue while when the real interest
rate is higher an increase in the size of the debt tends to
decrease the amount of revenue.

One can now put all the pieces of this story together to
determine the possibilities for the long-run real effects of
monetary policy. If the real interest rate is higher than the
output growth rate, or lower than the output growth rate
but not too much lower, then an increase in the size of the
national debt decreases government bond seigniorage revenue and vice-versa. Thus, a decrease in the money growth
and inflation rates that reduces government revenue from
currency seigniorage will force the government to reduce
the size of its debt and
will drive the real interest rate down. This is
the scenario described
by Wallace (1984); it
has the implication that
The proposition that
monetary tightening
monetary policy does
will increase the level of
not have long-run real
real GDP in the long
run. On the other hand,
effects is far from unif the real interest rate
equivocally established.
is substantially below
the output growth rate
then a decrease in the
money growth and inflation rates will allow the
government to increase
the size of its debt and will drive the real interest rate up.
This is the scenario described by Espinosa and Russell
(1998a, b). It is similar to the Tobin effect in having the
Keynesian, or conventional, implication that a monetary
tightening will reduce the level of real output.
Historically, the average real interest rate on U.S. government debt has been well below the average U.S. output
growth rate. This situation makes Espinosa and Russell’s
Keynesian scenario seem plausible empirically. An additional reason why the scenario is appealing is that it weakens the link between the size of the money supply and the
size of the shift in the credit supply curve that is induced
by a change in monetary policy—the link that keeps the
Tobin effect small. Although the fact that the money supply is small relative to GDP means that a change in the
inflation rate will have a relatively small impact on government revenue (from currency seigniorage), if it takes a
relatively large increase in the real interest rate to produce
a substantial decrease in government revenue from bond

7. Of course, if fiscal and monetary policy interactions led not only to long-run output level changes but to output growth
changes, the Tobin effect could be of more significance.
8. In principle, of course, there exists the possibility that such a swap of liabilities results in no effects either real or nominal,
either in the short or long term (a case made by Wallace 1984 and Sargent and Smith 1987 but not reviewed here), but under
most circumstances it will.
9. The debt-GDP ratio cannot continue to grow forever. Otherwise, at some point the debt would get so large relative to households’ income that it would be impossible for them to save enough to hold it.
10. This term seems to have been first used by Miller and Sargent (1984).
11. Thus, if the real interest rate is 2 percent higher than the real growth rate then each dollar of debt costs the government two
cents each year, adjusted for inflation.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

27

seigniorage then the resulting change in the real interest
rate and the level of output could still be large.
Why might it take a large change in the real interest
rate to produce a substantial change in the revenue from
bond seigniorage? When the real interest rate is low, the
tax rate effect and the tax base effect tend to work against
each other. As a result, the net change in the amount of revenue that is produced by
a change in the real interest rate can be quite
small. In fact, there is
always a range of real
The possibility that moneinterest rates over which
tary policy has substantial
the two effects offset
each other almost perlong-run real effects
fectly. Over this range,
deserves more attention
the ratio of the change
from economists and
in the real interest rate
to
the change in the
policymakers.
amount of revenue it
produces will be extremely large.
The bottom line
here is that, at least in
principle, the Espinosa-Russell variant of the SargentWallace “unpleasant arithmetic” can give us just what is
needed: a theory that explains how a moderate but permanent increase in the money supply growth and inflation
rates might result in a fairly large decrease in the real interest rate and a fairly large increase in the level of output.
Before concluding this section it is important to
emphasize that the research just reviewed composes a
relatively small part of the growing academic literature
that studies the long-term effects of monetary policy in
neoclassical models. Related work in this area includes
Haslag (1998), Bhattacharya and others (1997), Schreft
and Smith (1997), and Bullard and Russell (1998a, b).
One implication of this line of research is that monetary
economists may have spent too much time trying to forge
direct links between changes in monetary policy and
changes in the unemployment rate and the output growth
rate. Instead, they perhaps should be devoting more effort
to understanding the relationship between monetary policy and the economic fundamentals that drive saving and
production decisions and also to exploring the relationship between monetary policy variables and “real” macroeconomic variables such as the government deficit, real
interest rates, reserve requirements, and other variables
that link the money market to the credit market.

Conclusion
his article has reviewed the history of the view that
monetary policy has real effects in the short run
but no such effects in the long run (so that money
is long-run superneutral). This view grew out of a debate

T
28

between the adherents of two influential schools of
macroeconomic thought, the monetarists and the
Keynesians. The final result of this conflict was a unilateral, Keynesian-produced synthesis that developed during the 1970s. Under this synthesis the Keynesians
accepted the monetarists’ view that money was
superneutral in the long run but continued to disagree
with them about the magnitude and desirability of the
short-run effects of monetary policy on real interest
rates, real GDP, unemployment, and other real variables.
The article has argued that the beliefs that monetary policy is powerful in the short run and that money
is superneutral in the long run may not be mutually
consistent. The basic problem with most theories that
reconcile these beliefs is that they rely directly or indirectly on the assumption that economic decisionmakers
are victims of money illusion. If money illusion is the
reason monetary policy has real effects, however, then
its short-run real effects will be small and policymakers
will not be able to exploit them systematically to
achieve their goals. This point has been demonstrated
in seminal work by Lucas (1972).
In the years since the 1970s, academic macroeconomics has slowly but surely embraced the neoclassical
methodology pioneered by Lucas, which employs dynamic
general equilibrium models and assumes that decisionmakers have rational expectations. The results of Lucas’s
work and that of a number of other neoclassical economists has served to further strengthen the monetarist
position concerning long-run superneutrality of money.
In recent years, empirical studies of the impact of
monetary policy have concentrated on identifying its
short-run effects. This focus has been motivated, at
least in part, by the conviction that money is long-run
superneutral. Many researchers seem to believe that
there is overwhelming empirical evidence in favor of
long-run superneutrality. In reality, however, the proposition that monetary policy does not have long-run real
effects is far from unequivocally established: indeed, an
exploration of the empirical literature on long-run
superneutrality could easily be the subject of a separate
article. For the purposes of this article, it may suffice to
cite a remark by Robert King and Mark Watson, two
prominent macroeconomists whose empirical research
has produced evidence both for and against long-run
superneutrality. King and Watson (1992) report that for
the United States during the postwar period the data do
not appear to be consistent with the hypothesis that,
over the long run, money is superneutral or that nominal interest rates move one-for-one with inflation.
The fact that the empirical evidence on the long-run
superneutrality of monetary policy is not as overwhelming as some analysts believe suggests that there may be a
need to look at theories that explore potential sources of
long-run real effects for monetary policy. As this article

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

has explained, Lucas’s path-breaking work was an
attempt to conduct a rigorous analysis of the logical consequences of the monetarist assumption that the real
effects of monetary policy result from monetary surprises—a fact that has led Tobin, a leading Keynesian, to
refer to Lucas’s model as the “Monetarist Mark II” model.
Lucas did not attempt to argue that every reasonable
combination of assumptions would produce superneutrality, and it is consequently a mistake—albeit a very
common mistake, even in the academic community—to
equate neoclassical economics with the proposition that
money is superneutral.
To repeat, Lucas’s renowned 1972 paper employed
innovative methodology to explore the implications of a
very particular set of assumptions. The methodology is
logically separate from the assumptions and can be used
to analyze the consequences of very different assumptions. In fact, it is possible that monetary policy influences
real economic activity for reasons completely different
from the ones Lucas identified. In a recent interview in

New Yorker magazine, Lucas acknowledges that the real
effects of monetary policy may not result from unexpected policy changes. He comments, “Monetary shocks just
aren’t that important. . . . There’s no question, that’s a
retreat in my views” (Cassidy 1996, 55).
Abandoning the assumption that policy surprises are
the main reason monetary policy can have real effects
leaves two options. One is to accept the view of the real
business cycle theorists that Federal Reserve policy actions
are essentially irrelevant. A second option is to attempt to
identify alternative channels through which the monetary
authority could affect real economic activity. This article
has reviewed a small part of the recent academic literature
that explores the second option. The results reported in
this literature indicate that monetary policy may be a great
deal more powerful than most academic economists
believe. They also suggest that the possibility that monetary
policy has substantial long-run real effects deserves more
attention from economists and policymakers.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

29

REFERENCES
BALL, LAURENCE, AND N. GREGORY MANKIW. 1995. “Relative-Price
Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics (February): 161–93.

———. 1998a. “Can Higher Inflation Reduce Real Interest
Rates in the Long Run?” Canadian Journal of Economics
31:92–103.

BARRO, ROBERT J. 1995. “Inflation and Economic Growth.”
Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin (May): 166–76.

———. 1998b. “The Long-Run Real Effects of Monetary
Policy: Keynesian Predictions from a Neoclassical Model.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 98-6, April.

BENCIVENGA, VALERIE R., AND BRUCE D. SMITH. 1991. “Financial
Intermediation and Endogenous Growth.” Review of
Economic Studies 58:195–209.
BERNANKE, BEN S., AND MARK GERTLER. 1995. “Inside the Black
Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission.”
NBER Working Paper No. 5146.
BHATTACHARYA, JOYDEEP, MARK G. GUZMAN, ELISABETH HUYBENS,
BRUCE D. SMITH. 1997. “Monetary, Fiscal, and Reserve
Requirement Policy in a Simple Monetary Growth Model.”
International Economic Review 38:321–50.

AND

BRUNO, MICHAEL, AND WILLIAM EASTERLY. 1998. “Inflation Crises
and Long-Run Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics,
forthcoming.
BULLARD, JAMES, AND JOHN KEATING. 1995. “The Long-Run
Relationship between Inflation and Output in Postwar
Economies.” Journal of Monetary Economics 36:477–96.
BULLARD, JAMES, AND STEVEN RUSSELL. 1998a. “How Costly Is
Sustained Low Inflation for the U.S. Economy?” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis and IUPUI Working Paper.
———. 1998b. “An Empirically Plausible Model of Low Real
Interest Rates and Unbacked Government Debt.” Journal of
Monetary Economics, forthcoming.
CASSIDY, JOHN. 1996. “The Decline of Economics.” The New
Yorker, December 2, 50–60.
CHRISTIANO, LAWRENCE, AND MARTIN S. EICHENBAUM. 1991.
“Liquidity Effects, Monetary Policy, and the Business Cycle.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and Northwestern
University Working Paper.

ESPINOSA-VEGA, MARCO, AND CHONG YIP. 1998. “Fiscal and
Monetary Interactions in an Endogenous Growth Model with
Financial Intermediaries.” International Economic Review,
forthcoming.
FISHER, IRVING. 1926. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its
Determination and Relation to Credit Interest and Crises.
New York: Macmillan Company.
FRIEDMAN, MILTON. 1956. “The Quantity Theory of Money—A
Restatement.” In Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money,
edited by Milton Friedman. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
———. 1968. “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American
Economic Review 68:1–17.
FUERST, TIMOTHY J. 1992. “Liquidity, Loanable Funds, and Real
Activity.” Journal of Monetary Economics 29:3–24.
GREENSPAN, ALAN. 1997. “Monetary Policy Testimony and
Report to the Congress.” Humphrey-Hawkins Testimony.
Available on-line at <http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/boarddocs/
HH/9707Test.htm> [August 12, 1998].
HASLAG, JOSEPH. 1998. “Monetary Policy, Banking and
Growth.” Economic Inquiry 36:489–500.
HOFFMAN, DENNIS L., AND ROBERT H. RAASCHE. 1991. “Long-Run
Income and Interest Elasticities of Money Demand in the
United States.” Review of Economics and Statistics
73:665–74.
JOHNSON, HARRY G. 1975. On Economics and Society. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.

———. 1992. “Liquidity Effects and the Monetary
Transmission Mechanism.” American Economic Review
82:346–53.

KEYNES, JOHN M. 1964. The General Theory of Employment,
Interest, and Money. San Diego: Harcourt Brace and
Company. Original edition, 1953.

DANTHINE, JEAN-PIERRE, JOHN B. DONALDSON, AND LANCE SMITH.
1987. “On the Superneutrality of Money in a Stochastic
Dynamic Macroeconomic Model.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 20:475–99.

KING, ROBERT, AND MARK W. WATSON. 1992. “Testing Long Run
Neutrality.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper No. 4156.

DEGREGORIO, JOSE. 1992. “The Effects of Inflation on
Economic Growth.” European Economic Review 36:417–24.
DOW, JAMES P., JR. 1995. “The Demand and Liquidity Effects of
Monetary Shocks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 36
(December): 91–115.
ESPINOSA-VEGA, MARCO, AND STEVEN RUSSELL. 1997. “History and
Theory of the NAIRU: A Critical Review.” Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 82 (Second Quarter):
4–25.

30

KYDLAND, FINN, AND EDWARD PRESCOTT. 1982. “Time to Build and
Aggregate Fluctuations.” Econometrica 50 (November):
1345–70.
LUCAS, ROBERT E. 1972. “Expectations and the Neutrality of
Money.” Journal of Economic Theory 4:103–24.
———. 1981. “Tobin and Monetarism: A Review Article.”
Journal of Economic Literature 19:558–67.
———. 1990. “Liquidity and Interest Rates.” Journal of
Economic Theory 50 (April): 237–64.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

METZLER, LLOYD A. 1951. “Wealth, Saving, and the Rate of
Interest.” Journal of Political Economy 59 (April): 93–116.

———. 1981. “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review
(Fall): 1–17.

MEYER, LAURENCE H. 1997. “Monetary Policy Objectives and
Strategy.” Business Economics 32 (January): 17–20.

SCHREFT, STACEY L., AND BRUCE D. SMITH. 1997. “Money,
Banking, and Capital Formation.” Journal of Economic
Theory 73:157–82.

MILLER, PRESTON J., AND THOMAS J. SARGENT. 1984. “A Reply to
Darby.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review (Fall): 21–26.
NELSON, CHARLES R., AND CHARLES I. PLOSSER. 1982. “Trends and
Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 10:139–62.
PHELPS, EDMUND. 1967. “Phillips Curves, Expectations of
Inflation, and Optimal Unemployment over Time.”
Economica 34 (August): 254–81.
PHILLIPS, A.W. 1958. “The Relationship between Unemployment
and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United
Kingdom, 1861–1957.” Economica 25 (November): 283–99.
SARGENT, THOMAS J. 1996. “Expectations and the
Nonneutrality of Lucas.” Journal of Monetary Economics
37:535–48.

STIGLITZ, JOSEPH E. 1991. “Alternative Approaches to
Macroeconomics: Methodological Issues and the New
Keynesian Economics.” NBER Working Paper No. 3580.
TAYLOR, JOHN B. 1980. “Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered
Contracts.” Journal of Political Economy 88, no.1:1–23.
———. 1994. “The Inflation/Output Variability Trade-off
Revisited.” In Goals, Guidelines, and Constraints Facing
Monetary Policymakers. Conference Series No. 38. Boston:
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.
TOBIN, JAMES. 1965. “Money and Economic Growth.”
Econometrica 33:671–84.
———. 1980. “Stabilization Policy Ten Years After.”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity no. 1:19–71.

SARGENT, THOMAS J., AND BRUCE SMITH. 1987. “Irrelevance of
Open Market Operations in Some Economies with
Government Currency Being Dominated in Rate of Return.”
American Economic Review 77 (March): 78–92.

WALLACE, NEIL. 1984. “Some of the Choices for Monetary
Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review (Winter): 15–24.

SARGENT, THOMAS J., AND NEIL WALLACE. 1976. “Rational
Expectations and the Theory of Economic Policy.” Journal of
Monetary Economics 2:169–83.

WYNNE, MARK A. 1995. “Sticky Prices: What Is the Evidence?”
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review (First
Quarter): 1–12.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

31

Credit Union Issues
A R U N A S R I N I VA S A N A N D
B . F R A N K K I N G
Srinivasan is an assistant vice president in the
Atlanta Fed’s credit and risk management department. King is the associate director of research at the
Atlanta Fed. They thank Larry Wall, Gerald Dwyer,
and Scott Frame for comments on previous versions
of this article.

C

REDIT UNIONS AND THEIR LEGAL STATUS HAVE MADE THE FINANCIAL NEWS MORE THAN USUAL
THIS YEAR. IN

FEBRUARY

THE

U.S. SUPREME COURT

PARTIALLY SETTLED A LONG-RUNNING

CONTROVERSY ABOUT THE CONCEPT AND EXTENT OF COMMON BOND LIMITS ON THESE INSTITUTIONS’ MEMBERSHIP.

THE COURT INTERPRETED THE FEDERAL CREDIT UNION ACT AS LIM-

ITING MEMBERSHIP IN A FEDERAL CREDIT UNION TO INDIVIDUALS SHARING A SINGLE COMMON BOND.

The ensuing debate about limits of credit union
membership has extended, quite naturally, to credit union
tax status (see, for example, Bickley 1997; McConnell
1998; Robinson 1998). Meanwhile, the U.S. House of
Representatives and Senate have overwhelmingly passed
and the President has signed a bill that would substantially annul the Supreme Court decision; grandfather past
common bonds, membership, and membership eligibility;
and establish principles for regulation and determining
safety and soundness while leaving credit unions’ favorable tax status intact and limiting their business lending
(Anason and McConnell 1998; Anason 1998a, b).
The controversy swirling around credit unions is
often depicted as a simple fight between a group of small
mutual institutions with limited membership, limited
(primarily consumer) product powers, and tax exemption and a group of generally larger, generally stockholderowned institutions that are not tax exempt (for example,
see McConnell 1998; National Association of Federal
Credit Unions 1997; Robinson 1998; and Schaefer 1997).
However, the issues and implications of solutions for the
conflict are not so simple. Changes in credit union organization and taxation are likely to affect credit unions,
their customers, and their competitors in several ways.
These include impacts on ease of access to credit union
services by consumers; credit unions’ costs, risks, and
methods of corporate decision making; their competitive
position relative to other financial institutions; and the
32

extent of operations allowed for tax-subsidized entities in
providing consumer financial services.1
This article attempts to provide a basis for thinking
about current credit union issues. It begins with a brief
outline of credit unions’ current place among American
depository financial institutions. In order to explain the
development of credit unions’ special legal status around
the beginning of this century, it outlines the origins of
these features as attempts to solve a set of problems that
plagued most depository financial institutions of the
time. The problems included limited information about
individual borrowers who could provide no security and
costly procedures for collecting unsecured debt. The article describes how classic credit union characteristics—
mutuality and common bond structure—developed to
attack these listed problems and how more recent developments are generating pressures to relax common bond
limits. The discussion considers the spillover of common
bond issues into a debate on tax exemption for credit
unions.2 In conclusion, the article turns to some of the
likely impacts of changes in credit unions’ legal structure.

Credit Unions’ Place in the Current
American Financial System
s Table 1 shows, credit unions have played an
increasingly important role in consumer banking
over the last thirty-five years. From 1960 to 1985
their share of the consumer credit market almost dou-

A

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

bled, increasing to 12.4 percent. Since 1985 they have
lost less than a 1 percent share, while commercial banks
were losing a 5 percent share.
As they do with commercial banks and thrifts, both
state and federal governments charter credit unions. A
federal insurance fund, the National Credit Union Share
Insurance Fund (NCUSIF), insures individuals’ shares
of a majority of state and all federal institutions to a
$100,000 per shareholder limit. The remaining state
credit unions secure share insurance from various state
and private funds. There were 6,957 federal and 4,396
state credit unions at the end of 1997. State laws govern
state-chartered credit unions’ common bond limits and
powers, which vary from state to state; however, state
credit unions and their regulators have been subject to
legal attacks on common bond restrictions similar to
those recently waged on federal credit unions.3
Table 2 shows that about 30 percent of all Americans
are members of credit unions. At year-end 1997, there
were more credit unions—over 11,000—than any other
type of depository financial institution. Although that
number represents a significant decline during the past
decade, the number of Americans doing business at credit unions rose during that period.
Among depository financial institutions, credit
unions are generally the smallest. Their median share
value (equivalent to banks’ total domestic deposits)
totaled $5.1 million as of the end of 1997. This amount
contrasts with a median total domestic deposits figure
of $57.4 million for commercial banks.
Most credit unions offer a simple set of deposit and
loan products to consumers. There are, however, some
larger, more complex credit unions. For instance, the
largest twenty have a median share value of $1.4 billion;
they account for 12.5 percent of total credit union share
accounts. The next 100 largest have a median share value
of about $480 million; they account for 17.4 percent of
total share accounts. It is these credit unions that have
drawn much of their competitors’ fire and received the
most legislative attention in recent debates on common
bond and taxation (see McConnell 1998, for example).
To the extent that they accept deposits (called
shares) and make loans, credit unions resemble other depository institutions such as commercial banks. However,
credit unions have several distinguishing legal characteristics. Each credit union member (holder of credit

union shares) has one vote in selecting its board members and making other management and organization
decisions. This voting structure (one member–one vote)
differs from other mutual financial institutions such as
mutual savings banks. The latter allocate voting rights in
proportion to the size of a member’s deposit. Credit
unions derive their net worth by accumulating retained
earnings. They do not issue capital stock. Most credit
unions rely on unpaid, volunteer boards of directors elected by, and drawn from, each institution’s membership, with
the board setting policies for the credit union. In smaller
credit unions most of
the staff is composed of
member-volunteers as
well. Some credit unions
In this country credit
also receive subsidies in
the form of office space
unions have, until recently,
or member time from
had rather strict limitatheir sponsors or emtions on their membership,
ployers (GAO 1991).
Credit unions are
generally based on an
not-for-profit instituaffinity or “common bond”
tions. They return earnamong members.
ings to their members as
reduced fees, reduced
interest rates on loans,
or as higher “dividends
on shares” (which is
equivalent to interest on deposits). They may also reinvest
the earnings in the credit union as “retained earnings.”
Important to recent debates on their status, credit unions
are exempt from federal corporate income taxes.4
In this country credit unions have, until recently,
had rather strict limitations on their membership, generally based on an affinity or “common bond” among members. For federal credit unions, this bond may be based on
a common employer, association, or religious, social, or
community organization.
Credit unions’ competitors often assert that much
of the growth in credit unions’ share of consumer lending
have been driven by the relaxation of membership requirements implemented in 1982 and later by federal credit
unions’ regulator, the National Credit Union Administration
(NCUA), combined with continuing exemption from federal corporate income taxes.5 In recent years, this concern has manifested itself primarily in litigation over the

1. For more detailed discussions of credit unions and current policy issues related to them, see studies by the U.S. General
Accounting Office (GAO) (1991) and the U.S. Department of the Treasury (1997).
2. Debate on the appropriate range of credit union products is also occurring. Typically, their limited ability to offer small commercial and farm loans is questioned (GAO 1991). However, few credit unions offer these loans, and they made up less than
1 percent of total assets of credit unions in the United States and its territories at the end of 1997.
3. For a summary of current state suits, see CUNA & Affiliates Legal Division (1998).
4. For a more detailed discussion of credit union characteristics, see GAO (1991) and Moysich (1990).
5. Specifically, NCUA reinterpreted section 109 of the Federal Credit Union Act to allow multiple common bonds in individual
credit unions.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

33

T A B L E 1 Composition of the U.S. Consumer Credit Market

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

43.14

46.41

49.10

51.23

50.69

49.82

47.71

44.86

Thrifts

3.27

3.08

3.29

4.88

6.39

9.68

6.12

3.54

Credit Unions

6.37

7.49

9.73

12.41

12.41

12.44

11.29

11.65

Asset-Backed
Securities Issuers

——

——

——

——

——

——

9.57

18.94

Finance Companies

26.31

25.36

24.03

19.94

22.19

22.26

17.04

13.48

Other a

20.92

17.66

13.85

11.54

8.33

5.80

8.27

7.52

Banks and Bank
Holding Companies

Note: The market here includes the institutions reported by the source as holders of consumer debt. Figures are percentages.
a

Includes nonfinancial corporate and nonfarm, noncorporate businesses

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, table L.222

T A B L E 2 Characteristics of U.S. Credit Unions, 1987 and 1997

December 31, 1987

December 31, 1997

15,049

11,353

53.2

72.1

181.5

244.4

1.8

5.1

Median Share Value of Top 20 Firms
($ million)

529.7

1,444.4

Median Share Value of Next 100 Firms
($ million)

217.5

482.6

1.8

4.8

4.97

8.37

Number of Credit Unions
Number of Members (millions)
Number of Potential Members (millions)
Median Share Value
($ million)

Median Share Value of Remaining Firms
($ million)
Market Share of Credit Unions among
Depository Institutions (percentage)

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, private data base

34

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

definition of the common bond and in proposals for
eliminating consumers’ access to credit unions’ government subsidies from federal income tax exemption.

Origins of American Credit Unions
and Their Special Features
redit unions developed in response to a gap in the
supply of consumer banking services in the United
States at the turn of the century. At this time and
into the post–World War II era, commercial banks concentrated primarily on providing services to businesses and
affluent individuals or making secured loans to homebuyers and farmers. In the financial environment of the time,
information upon which to base decisions on the creditworthiness of potential borrowers was difficult and costly to
come by.
Historically, credit unions used the common bond
requirement for membership to help determine the creditworthiness of individual borrowers and to provide peer
pressure on borrowers to pay their debts. Credit unions
based their lending decisions largely on the reputation of
loan applicants in the relevant affinity group. Because
credit union members were individually liable for the
loans made to other members, strict membership criteria
like the common bond helped limit the lending risks
borne by members and encouraged their monitoring of
borrowers. Founders of early credit unions often voluntarily imposed common bond restrictions to reduce
default risk and reduce the costs of monitoring loans. This
country’s first credit union law, passed in Massachusetts
in 1909, permitted organizers to specify in their charter
“conditions of residence or occupation, which qualify for
membership” (Moody and Fite 1971). Other states and
eventually the federal government followed suit in making the common bond a key organizing principle for credit unions.
The Federal Credit Union Act in 1934 limited membership in a federal credit union to “groups having a common bond of occupation or association, or to groups within
a well-defined neighborhood, community, or rural district”
(GAO 1991). The act neither elaborated on this definition
at the time nor stated the reason for the requirement.
Some courts have inferred that the purpose of the 1934
common bond requirement was to facilitate safe and sound
operations. Until this year Congress had not addressed this
issue in subsequent amendments to the Federal Credit
Union Act or other law.6

C

What Is Implied by Credit Unions’
Differences from Banks?
redit unions’ special features are more than cosmetic. They result in important differences between
credit unions and stockholder-owned financial insti-

C

tutions, like commercial banks, in goals, customer base,
operations, and competitiveness.
The most fundamental difference between banks
and credit unions lies in two aspects of ownership—
common bond and mutuality. As discussed above, common bond restrictions promote members’ knowledge of
the creditworthiness of other members and allow exercise
of moral suasion on debtors. Lack of these limits on commercial banks and other stock institutions allows broader
ownership, but, arguably, it also makes credit analysis more costly.
Borrowers typically have more and better
information about their
The most fundamental
own financial condition
difference between banks
than anyone else does,
and credit unions lies in
including lenders. It is
sometimes in their intwo aspects of ownership—
terest to withhold adcommon bond and mutuality.
verse information, knowing that revealing it to a
lender could affect the
amount and terms of
lending. Lenders deal
with this situation in a
variety of ways. They obtain relevant information on potential borrowers from sources other than the borrowers, write
contracts that provide protection against events about
which they have little information, and monitor borrowers’ financial condition to varying degrees. In the case of
business loans, a requirement that the borrower maintain a deposit account provides a mechanism for monitoring on a continuing basis.
In the past, credit unions’ common bond and mutuality organizational structure has addressed asymmetric
information problems by requiring that these institutions
lend only to members. The valuable information provided
by records of size and pattern of balances in share
accounts is often supplemented by the lending officer’s
personal knowledge of the borrower. In occupational
credit unions, knowledge of an employer’s condition can
also be helpful. Prior to the general availability of on-line
credit reports, the common bond and mutuality arrangement reduced costs of extending and monitoring credit to
consumers whose financial statements and credit
records had been difficult to acquire.
Credit unions’ mutuality also has impacts on their
corporate governance. The primary difference between
stockholder and mutually owned institutions lies in who
controls the firms and receives the earnings. A commercial bank’s or stock thrift’s stockholders vote for the
firm’s managers, distribute its profits, and are free to

6. The history of American credit unions is discussed more fully in Moody and Fite (1971).
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

35

sell their privileges. A mutual association, on the other
hand, is owned by its depositors (called shareholders in
the case of credit unions). In credit unions and mutual
thrifts, each depositor has the right to vote for the managers of the firm.
Owners of a firm often employ managers to actively do
that firm’s business. These managers are their agents. What
economists call agency
problems refer to the difficulty that owners have
in making sure that their
agents—that is, managers—work in the ownA feature of credit unions’
ers’ best interest. Managers, who may or may
mutuality is the diversity
not also be stockholders,
of interests among their
often have better informembers/owners.
mation about the firm and
different motivations
from those of stockholders, who are often more
widely dispersed geographically. This agency
problem can result in
improperly managed and inefficient operations with high
management compensation.
Manager/owner problems exist both in commercial
banks and credit unions. Approaches to their solution are
influenced by organizational structure. In mutuals like
credit unions, officers and directors are often unpaid and,
therefore, cannot inflate their salaries. In some credit
unions other perks (such as office space) are constrained
by sponsor contributions. These conditions go a long way
toward mitigating the results of conflicts between owners
(members) and managers. As members themselves, directors and unpaid officers have an incentive to monitor paid
managers in the interest of all members. In stock firms
like banks, creating incentives to resolve potential agency
conflicts, including stock options for managers, can lead
to higher costs. The threat of takeovers and stockholder
and director revolts may also act as a check on wasteful
expenditures.7
Some evidence indicates that credit unions’ one
depositor–one vote structure allows them to adapt successfully to change. A feature of credit unions’ mutuality
is the diversity of interests among their members/owners.
Conflict amoung member groups can affect the manner
in which a mutual, not-for-profit credit union is operated since the credit union cannot simultaneously maximize the dividend rate for savers and minimize loan
rates for borrowers.
Some evidence on the results of member conflicts in
mutual organizations comes from a study of German cooperative banks by Emmons and Mueller. Like credit unions
in the United States, cooperative banks in Germany are
36

mutual institutions that have been steadily increasing
their market share relative to other types of financial
institutions.8 Emmons and Mueller focus on the diversity
of interests between members of cooperative banks and
highlight the dual role of members as borrowers and
lenders. They develop a model showing that “a shift in
the median (hence pivotal) member of the cooperative
from predominantly a borrower orientation to a lender
orientation causes the cooperative bank to shift its policy from underpricing credit towards the provision of
competitively priced credit and deposit services” (1997,
abstract). This result depends on cooperative financial
institutions’ one member–one vote, organization.
Emmons and Mueller conclude that the democratic
nature of cooperatives’ ownership in fact creates opportunities for adaptation and survival. Together with a
nationwide supporting infrastructure to capture scale
and scope economies, the organization of German cooperative banks has allowed them to compete successfully
with other, stockholder-held banking groups.
While the Emmons and Mueller model has not been
directly tested on U.S. credit union data, some of the similarities between the structure and performance of U.S.
credit unions and German cooperatives suggests that
both gain ability to adapt from their one member–one
vote characteristic.

Pressures on the Common Bond
n the past three decades, various changes in the
environment in which financial institutions, particularly credit unions, operate have caused reconsideration of and changes in credit unions’ common bond
requirements. Developments in information technology
have diluted the effect of restricting membership to a
tight community. Increasing complexity and size have
pushed more credit unions to seek professional managers. Extension of deposit insurance to credit union
shares has lessened both member need and incentive
credit monitoring. Dealing with credit union financial
problems has made broader common bonds quite practical for their insurers and regulators.
Technological Change. Common bond requirements have become less important for the analysis of
credit risks with the development of credit reporting
services and other advances in collecting, transmitting,
and analyzing credit information that have made it less
costly to assess the likelihood of default on a particular
loan. Both credit unions’ competitors and credit unions
themselves have adopted newer information technologies and greatly expanded the variety and availability of
loans, both secured and unsecured.
Many credit unions—to meet customer demand
and to compete with other depository institutions—also
offer technology-based services such as ATMs and computer and electronic banking to take advantage of elec-

I

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

tronic account and transaction processing. The technology needed to provide such services involves substantial
fixed costs. Adding more membership groups makes such
investments more economical by allowing a credit union
to spread its fixed costs over more members. A study of
the productive efficiency of credit unions by Fried,
Lovell, and Vanden Eeckaut (1993) concluded that credit unions can improve their performance by increasing
their total membership as well as by increasing the number of accounts per member.
Credit-analysis advances provided by new technologies have not, however, eased another risk feature of the
tight common bond. The more that a credit union’s membership shares a common bond of employment or otherwise has similar exposure to plant closings or other economic risks, the less diversified is its exposure to credit
risk. Diversifying the membership base makes the credit
union more resilient in the face of problems experienced
by any one local employer. This diversification can be
accomplished by multiple common bonds.
Managerial Factors. Managerial factors may also create incentives for credit unions to grow by adding new
membership groups. A credit union board of directors seeking to attract high-quality, professional managers may find
it easier to do so if the credit union is large or has growth
opportunities. Moreover, as nonprofit cooperatives, credit
unions do not generally compensate their managers on the
basis of profit or stock performance. Instead, management
compensation often reflects a credit union’s size and product offerings. Managers may therefore have an incentive to
increase the credit union’s size. Adding new membership
groups is an obvious method of doing so (GAO 1991).
Share Insurance. Discipline to control risk taking
by mutual depository institutions can be provided by
creditors, depositors, owners, and managers. In the case
of credit unions, if bankruptcy occurs creditors other
than depositors are generally fully protected. Creditors
have this protection because their position in the liquidation of a failed credit union is senior to that of depositors, whose shares are judged to represent equity, not
debt. An important feature of the traditional common
bond between members of a credit union was the willingness of some members to put their personal savings
at risk by letting the credit union lend these funds to
other members. This relationship between borrowers
and savers originated to engender a higher sense of
obligation than borrowers might otherwise feel toward
ordinary creditors (GAO 1991).
The monitoring relationship between savers and
borrowers has no doubt diminished since the introduction of share insurance in 1970. Credit union members

still own their institutions. Since 1970, however, to the
extent that their share accounts fall under $100,000, they
are insured owners. This insurance dilutes the impact of
the common bond in inducing shareholders to monitor
borrowers and management.
Further dilution of the risk-management impact of
the common bond may also have come from the increase
in credit union size with
the expansion of the common bond in the 1980s.
Credit union membership
has increased. The averDiversifying the memberage credit union had more
ship base makes the credit
than 6,000 members as of
year-end 1997.
union more resilient in the
Financial Difficulface of problems experities. In the early 1980s,
enced by any one local
the technical and organizational pressures on the
employer.
common bond, discussed
above, combined with a
practical need to reduce
economic distortions associated with credit union
financial troubles. These factors induced significant easing of common bond restrictions. In 1982, faced with
major difficulties in the industry, the NCUA reinterpreted the National Credit Union Act to substantially ease its
common bond policy. Through this change, credit unions
were allowed to have more than one common bond group
in the same organization. The NCUA adopted and later
expanded this policy to allow merging of credit unions that
had financial problems, to provide a diversity of membership that would help credit unions weather economic
downturns, and to make credit unions’ services more widely available (Burger and Dacin 1991; Murphy 1996).
This relaxation has also enabled credit unions to
grow larger (Good 1996; Murphy 1996; Smale 1997). As of
June 1996 more than half of the 7,244 federal credit
unions had multiple group fields of membership. These
credit unions had a total membership of 32.6 million and
accounted for approximately 80 percent of total federal
credit union shares (Smale 1997).9
Other Factors. Several other factors have encouraged credit unions to add new membership groups:
Downsizing or closings at manufacturing firms, military
bases, and other large employers have shrunk the membership base of many occupational credit unions. Worker
mobility has made the membership base less stable than
in the past, when many members had a long-standing
relationship with their employers. In addition, restricting

7. See Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Fama and Jensen (1983) for a more complete discussion of agency problems.
8. Unlike U.S. credit unions, cooperative banks in Germany do not enjoy tax advantages.
9. Comparable information on state-chartered credit unions is not available.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

37

credit unions to a single common bond has made credit
union services unavailable to many segments of the population. Finally, since the minimum viable size of a credit union has been generally understood to be around 500,
employees of small companies have faced barriers to
forming successful credit unions (Evans and Shull 1998).

The Tax Exemption Issue
s credit unions have grown larger and developed
more diverse membership, their long-standing
exemption from federal income taxes has drawn
more fire from competitors. One should not be surprised
that tax exemption has become an issue that is attached to
common bond extension.
Credit unions’ exemption from federal
income tax dates back to
the Revenue Act of 1916,
Credit unions’ special legal
which provided taxand tax status is often
exempt status to mutual
related to their role in prothrift institutions and
cooperatives. Because
viding an alternative source
they were found to be
of financial services for less
“organized and operated
affluent individuals with few
for mutual purposes and
without profit,” the U.S.
alternatives.
Attorney General ruled
in 1917 that credit unions, which were all
state-chartered then,
were entitled to the exemption. According to Moody and
Fite (1971) this ruling was relatively noncontroversial at
the time. The first federal credit unions were chartered in
1934 and granted tax-exempt status in 1935 under a ruling by the Internal Revenue Service.
Since 1937 Congress has reconsidered the taxexempt status of mutual financial institutions on several
occasions. In 1951 it repealed the tax exemption for all
mutual institutions except credit unions. This decision
was based on the view that credit unions (unlike other
mutual financial institutions) had remained true to their
original purpose of providing cooperative financial services to members. Mutual savings banks, on the other
hand, were deemed in a 1951 report by the Senate Finance
Committee to be “in active competition with commercial
banks . . . for the public savings, and . . . with many types
of taxable institutions in the security and real estate markets” (cited in Burger and Lypny 1991, 16).
Competitor financial institutions as well as legislators attempting to balance the federal budget have challenged the tax-exempt status of credit unions since at
least 1970. Commercial banks and thrifts have claimed
that the easing of common bond limits and the expanded products and services that credit unions have been
allowed to provide their members have eroded the dis-

A

38

tinction between banks and credit unions. This argument
closely parallels arguments made a half-century ago,
when Congress removed tax exemption from mutual savings and loan associations and savings banks (Moody and
Fite 1971).
The credit union industry has evolved over the last
sixty years in an environment that treats credit unions as
nonprofit cooperatives. Without tax exemption the industry would probably have evolved differently. It is likely
that credit unions would not have grown as fast, and some
credit unions might not have formed. Moreover, credit
union customers would have received some combination
of lower deposit rates and higher borrowing rates.

Credit Unions’ Public Purposes
redit unions’ special legal and tax status is often
related to their role in providing an alternative
source of financial services for less affluent individuals with few alternatives. Evidence on the current
economic status of credit union membership and on available alternative sources of loans and deposit services may
dilute the strength of these public purpose arguments.
The purpose of the Federal Credit Union Act as set
forth in 1934 was “to make more credit available to people of small means” (GAO 1991). None of the common
bond criteria in that law, however, address the economic status of members or potential members. While there
are no statistically reliable data on the economic status
of credit union members earlier in the century, it was
accepted that members were generally not affluent
(Moody and Fite 1971).
Expansions of the common bond requirement in the
1980s may have contributed to changes in membership
characteristics. The little publicly available data on
membership characteristics suggest that members are
not all “of small means” but may still not be as well off as
commercial banks’ individual customers. Two recent
published surveys give information. A Gallup Organization poll reported in the American Banker found that
the average annual family income of credit union members was lower than the income of bank customers
(Seiberg 1997). The average income for credit union
members was also slightly below the 1996 level for the
entire population. An earlier survey by the Secura Group
for the American Bankers Association suggests that the
typical credit union member is in his or her “early 40s,
employed, with above-average income, better educated
than a non-member and with access to financial services
from a variety of sources” (reported in GAO 1991). This
evidence is consistent with the results of an earlier survey in 1987 by CUNA & Affiliates, a credit union trade
group (reported in GAO 1991).
Another major public purpose argument in the
development of credit union laws hinged on the existence of few borrowing alternatives for consumers

C

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

(Moody and Fite 1971). While a paucity of alternatives
may have characterized the beginning of this century
and even the early postwar period, consumers now have
a rather broad set of alternatives for credit for most purposes. Several types of suppliers exist for each type of
consumer credit, and they make their services available
in many markets.

Challenges in Court
elaxing previously limited common bond restrictions has brought credit unions into more direct
competition with other depository institutions
such as banks. These institutions, banks in particular,
have argued that credit unions’ less restrictive common
bond makes credit unions very similar to taxed financial
institutions. They conclude that tax exemption amounts
to a federal subsidy to credit unions and their members
and gives credit unions unfair competitive advantages
(Fettig 1996; Marshall 1996).
Banks have gone to court to limit the scope of credit unions whose charters define particularly large fields
of membership on the grounds that potential members
do not share the requisite common bond. Their suits
have been filed in both federal and state courts. Until a
recent U.S. Supreme Court decision, the federal suits
had met with mixed results.10 In the 1980s two courts
found that the common bond contributed to the sound
management of a credit union and thus to the safety and
soundness of the industry as a whole. Yet neither court
found much legislative guidance on limitations of the
common bond. One of the courts inferred from a state
statute that the common bond requirement had been
imposed to promote the institution’s financial stability.
In a later case, a federal court dismissed the banking
industry’s challenge to a proposed charter for a multiplebond credit union on the grounds that Congress had
“purposefully sacrificed the competitive interest of
banks” in favor of making credit more readily available
to people of small means through the chartering of
credit unions (GAO 1991).
Earlier this year, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled on
a pivotal case involving the AT&T Family Credit Union
(Supreme Court 1998). The institution had expanded
from its original core group of employees of Western
Electric Company in three North Carolina cities to
112,000 members in fifty states and more than 150 separate employer groups. The lower courts disagreed on
the interpretation of the common bond language in the
original statute. The district court ruled that the statutory language was ambiguous and deferred to the NCUA’s
interpretation of the law. However, the appeals court
found the actual language of the statute to be clear in

R

defining credit unions to include a single group with a
common bond. Any subsequent groups wanting to join
the credit union would have to share a common bond
with the original group. According to the appeals court,
Congress had used the common bond mechanism to
“ensure both that those making the lending decisions
would know more about applicants and that borrowers
would be more reluctant to default. . . . [and, thereby to
unite] credit union members in a cooperative venture”
(U.S. Court of Appeals 1996).
The Supreme Court ruled that the NCUA’s interpretation of the common bond language of section 109 of the
Federal Credit Union Act was illegal. The case returned to
lower court for a decision on whether common bond requirements
should revert to their
status as defined in 1982
Relaxing previously limited
or continue at their curcommon bond restrictions
rent status and, if so,
whether credit unions
has brought credit unions
with multiple common
into more direct competibonds should be allowed
tion with other depository
membership expansion
in their existing groups.
institutions such as banks.
These questions became
moot when President
Clinton signed the legislation recently passed by
the House and Senate.
This law maintains the concept of common bond but
allows combining of groups with different common bonds
in a single credit union. It does not change credit unions’
tax exemption, but it limits credit unions’ commercial
loans of more than $50,000. The NCUA must still issue
regulations based on the new law.

Conclusion
ecent and future actions on credit unions’ common bond limits and federal tax status may well
have implications for the efficiency, risk, and
competitiveness of these institutions—and their competitor financial institutions. Clearly, credit union customers would be affected.
Allowing past multiple common bonds to stand and
leaving open the way for others has positive implications
for credit unions and their customers but negative implications for their competitors, their competitors’ customers, and taxpayers. Individual credit unions and the
industry will be better able to expand and to offer customers more products, taking advantage of scale economies, diversification, and tax exemption. Their growth

R

10. Currently thirteen states have suits on common bond in process (see CUNA & Affiliates Legal Division 1998).

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

39

and market share expansion will probably be greater.
Countering these positive effects might be some small
overall diminution in credit unions’ ability to gather credit
information and collect debts. This loss will be particularly true for small credit unions. Credit unions’ gains will
come at the expense of competitor financial institutions.
Their individual customers would have the choice of moving to credit unions, and some likely would. Taxpayers,
considered as a separate group in the abstract, would pay
more subsidy for provision of consumer financial services.

If easing common bond restrictions allows larger
credit unions and the industry grows, and if some credit
unions approach their business loan limits, one might
expect the movement to remove credit unions’ tax- exempt
status to become more active and credible. Credit unions
would appear more like other financial institutions, such
as mutual thrifts, that are taxed. Issues of whether they
still primarily serve people of small means and whether
they are one of a limited set of consumer financial alternatives are likely to receive a great deal of attention.

REFERENCES
ANASON, DEAN. 1998a. “Senate Passes Credit Union Bill; Big
Loss for Banks.” American Banker, July 29.
———. 1998b. “The Major Provisions of Controversial New
Law.” American Banker, August 10, available by subscription
on-line at <http://www.americanbanker.com>.
ANASON, DEAN, AND BILL MCCONNELL. 1998. “Banking Panel
Backs Broad Credit Union Membership.” American Banker,
March 27, available by subscription on-line at <http://www.
americanbanker.com>.
BICKLEY, JAMES M. 1997. Should Credit Unions Be Taxed?
Congressional Research Service Report No. 97-548E. May.
BURGER, ALBERT E., AND TINA DACIN. 1991. Field of Membership: An Evolving Concept. Madison, Wisc.: Filene Research
Institute.
BURGER, ALBERT E., AND GREGORY M. LYPNY. 1991. Taxation of
Credit Unions. Madison, Wisc.: Filene Research Institute.
CUNA & AFFILIATES LEGAL DIVISION. 1998. “Field of
Membership Litigation Summary.” Available on-line at
<http://www.cuna.org/data/spec_reports/litsum.html>
[June 22, 1998].
EMMONS,

WILLIAM R., AND WILLI MUELLER. 1997. “Conflict
of Interest between Borrowers and Lenders in Credit
Cooperatives: The Case of German Cooperative Banks.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper No.
97-009A, March.
EVANS, DAVID S., AND BERNARD SHULL. 1998. Economic Role
of Credit Unions in Consumer Banking Markets. Paper
prepared for Boeing Employees’ Credit Union. January.
FAMA, EUGENE F., AND MICHAEL C. JENSEN. 1983. “Separation of
Ownership and Control.” Journal of Law and Economics 26,
no. 2:301–25.
FETTIG, DAVID. 1996. “Banks Turn Up the Heat against Credit
Unions.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Fed Gazette 8
(July): 1, 3–4.

40

FRIED, HAROLD O., C.A. KNOX LOVELL, AND P. VANDEN EECKAUT.
1993. “Evaluating the Performance of U.S. Credit Unions.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 17:251–65.
GOOD, BARBARA A. 1996. “The Credit Union Industry: An
Overview.” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic
Commentary, May 15.
JENSEN, MICHAEL C., AND WILLIAM H. MECKLING. 1976.
“Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs,
and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics
3, no. 4:305–60.
MARSHALL, JEFFREY. 1996. “Credit Unions: True Threat or Mere
Nuisance?” U.S. Banker 106 (November): 53–59.
MCCONNELL, WILLIAM T. 1998. “Viewpoints: Larger Credit
Unions Ruining the Movement.” American Banker, March 13,
available by subscription on-line at <http://www.
americanbanker.com>.
MOODY, J. CARROLL, AND GILBERT C. FITE. 1971. The Credit
Union Movement: Origins and Development, 1850–1970.
Lincoln, Nebr.: University of Nebraska Press.
MOYSICH, ALANE K. 1990. “An Overview of the U.S. Credit
Union Industry.” FDIC Banking Review 3 (Fall): 12–26.
MURPHY, MAUREEN M. 1996. Multiple Group Credit Unions:
Litigation and Potential Legislative Responses. Congressional
Research Service Report No. 96-997. December.
NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF FEDERAL CREDIT UNIONS. 1997. “Why
Congress Must Support the ‘Credit Union Membership Access
Act.’” Available on-line at <http://www.nafcunet.org/cuc/
k4.htm> [June 22, 1998].
ROBINSON, KEN. 1998. “Viewpoints: Compromise by Banks
Is Bait-and-Switch Tactic.” American Banker, March 13,
available by subscription on-line at <http://www.
americanbanker.com>.
SCHAEFER, MARCUS. 1997. “Comment: Banks Could End Up
Losing If They Win Credit Union War.” American Banker,
November 20, available by subscription on-line at
<http://www.americanbanker.com>.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

SEIBERG, JARET. 1997. “The Bank-Credit Union Battle May
Hinge on Service to Poor.” American Banker, February 7,
available by subscription on-line at <http://www.
americanbanker.com>.
SMALE, PAULINE. 1997. Multiple-Group Federal Credit Unions:
An Update. Congressional Research Service Report No. 97267E. May.
SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES. 1998. National Credit
Union Administration v. First National Bank & Trust Co.
et al. Decided February 25, 1998. Available on-line at
<http://supct.law.cornell.edu/supt/html/96-843.ZS.html>
[July 30, 1998].

U.S. COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT.
1996. First National Bank and Trust Company et al. v.
National Credit Union Administration and AT&T Family
Federal Credit Union and Credit Union National
Association. Decided July 30, 1996. Available on-line at
<http://laws.findlaw.com/DC/945295a.html> [July 24, 1998].
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY. 1997. Credit Unions.
Report to Congress. December.
U.S. GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE. 1991. Credit Unions:
Reforms for Ensuring Future Soundness. Report to
Congress. July.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

41

The Federal Government’s
Budget Surplus: Cause for
Celebration?
G E R A L D P. D W Y E R J R .
A N D R . W. H A F E R
Dwyer is vice president in charge of the financial section of the Atlanta Fed’s research department. Hafer is
a professor in the Department of Economics, Southern
Illinois University at Edwardsville, and a visiting
scholar at the Atlanta Fed. They thank Lucy Ackert,
Frank King, Larry Wall, and Madeline Zavodny for
helpful comments.

P

ROJECTED SURPLUSES IN THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT’S BUDGET HAVE GENERATED FANFARE
SOMETIMES VERGING ON EUPHORIA.
PLUS IN

1969,

BECAUSE

THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT LAST HAD A SUR-

A PROJECTED SURPLUS FOR FISCAL YEAR

1998

AND LATER YEARS IS BEING

VIEWED AS SOMETHING OF A MILESTONE. UNLIKE POLICIES OF THE LAST THREE DECADES THAT

HAVE SOUGHT TO LOWER THE DEFICIT, POLICY OPTIONS NOW MAY INCLUDE WAYS TO USE THE SURPLUS.

The budget surplus and projections of surpluses for a
number of years have brought forth a variety of opinions
and suggestions about what to do with them. Some have
called for lowering taxes. Others have suggested that the
federal government could now engage in greater spending. And some have called for retiring government debt.
Herbert Stein, a former chairman of the president’s Council of Economic Advisers, recently suggested that “We had
an agreed-upon answer for what to do about deficits:
Reduce them. . . . Now no one knows what the surplus constraint is. We are at sea” (1998).
Some of this rhetoric might be interpreted as hyperbole. Still policy discussions often seem to have focused
on how to reduce the deficit to the exclusion of all else.
This single-minded approach to the budget reflects the
argument that federal government deficits absorb saving.
As Benjamin Friedman put it, the claim is that deficits in
the 1980s “consumed most of what individuals and businesses . . . saved during this period” (1988, 167). In this
42

view deficits are bad because they reduce national saving,
decrease funds available for net investment, and therefore retard economic growth. While the evidence has not
been kind to this argument (Seater 1993), this reasoning
suggests that a balanced budget or, even better, a surplus
should be the goal of the federal government’s fiscal policy.
The size of the deficit by itself does not provide
much information about the federal government’s activities. Federal government spending and taxation are more
informative. Suppose that two economies both have balanced budgets. Conventional wisdom about deficits
might suggest that the impact of the two governments on
their economies is similar: both budgets are balanced. In
one economy, though, government spending and taxes
might be 90 percent of gross domestic product (GDP); in
the other economy, government spending and taxes
might equal 10 percent of GDP. The impact of the governments on the two economies is likely to be quite different even though both have balanced budgets.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

The purpose of this article is to amplify on the
importance of considering spending and taxes when analyzing the federal government’s budget. The first section
looks at the behavior of federal government budgets in
the past, with special emphasis on trends in spending
and taxation. The article then considers in more detail
the prospects for future surpluses. A key element in the
recent projections of surpluses is the role of trust funds,
especially the Social Security trust fund, in federal budget accounting.

Perspective on the Surplus
oosely speaking, when spending exceeds tax receipts, there is a deficit; when spending is less
than tax receipts, there is a surplus. Although
deficit is a more convenient term at times and surplus
is more convenient at other times, the terms are mirror
images. A negative deficit is a surplus and a negative
surplus is a deficit.
Deficits characterize the federal budget for most of
the last fifty years: the federal government’s spending
has generally exceeded its receipts. Chart 1 shows the
federal government’s unified budget surplus for fiscal
years since 1950. The unified budget consolidates the
spending and revenues of all federal government agencies and trust funds into an overall budget to reflect the
government’s transactions with the rest of the economy
(Office of Management and Budget [OMB] 1998a, 323).1
The fiscal year ends on June 30 through 1976 and on
September 30 since then. Chart 1 reflects the change in
fiscal year by not connecting the values for 1976 and
1977.2 The surpluses in the chart are deflated by the
GDP chain price index to put the figures in terms of
1992 dollars.3 Many discussions of the deficit rely on
current dollar measures of the deficit, a practice that is
quite misleading for comparing deficits across time
when there is substantial inflation. For instance, the
federal government deficit was about $53.2 billion for
fiscal year 1975 and about $107.4 billion for 1996, values
that indicate a roughly doubled deficit. The level of
prices as measured by the GDP chain price index, however, was 2.6 times higher in 1996 than in 1975. Hence,
the larger deficit in terms of current dollars is really
smaller in terms of the inflation-adjusted amount.
Changes in the economy, such as recessions and
expansions, are one major reason the deficit changes, as
Chart 1 shows. The shaded bars indicating recessions
show how recessions are related to changes in the surplus. The surplus tends to decrease during recessions
for two reasons. First, federal government tax receipts

L

decrease during recessions, largely because income and
related tax receipts fall. Second, recessions trigger
automatic increases in federal government spending;
for example, payments for unemployment compensation increase during recessions because more individuals are unemployed.
Chart 1 also includes projections of the budget surplus made by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO).
The projections made in
March 1998 indicate
that federal government
receipts will exceed outlays throughout the next
Does the current federal
decade. The CBO progovernment surplus signal
jects that by 2008 the
budget surplus will
the onset of a new age in
reach $95 billion in 1992
government fiscal policy?
dollars. As the chart
The answer to this quesmakes clear, a decade of
continued budget surtion is not so obvious.
pluses would be extraordinary compared with
the past fifty years. Another ten years without
a recession also would
be extraordinary, which is one reason for being uncertain about this projection. Ten years of expansion would
be longer than the previous record expansion of almost
eight years from November 1982 to July 1990, and the
implied expansion would be significantly longer than
this, from April 1991 through September 2008.
Recessions are hard to predict, however, and no evidence in March 1998 (or as of this writing) indicates
much likelihood of one in the predictable future. Overall, based on current laws, this projection of a decade of
budget surpluses is based on the best available information.
What are the trends in government spending and
taxes that have produced the past deficits and projections of surpluses? Chart 2 shows federal government
spending and revenue in 1992 dollars. The current dollar
values are deflated by the GDP price index to make the
dollar amounts more comparable across time. In addition, the vertical axis has a proportional rather than a linear scale. On this proportional scale any given distance
on the vertical axis represents the same proportional dollar amount rather than the same dollar amount, as would
be the case with a linear scale. As a result, the slope of the
line connecting any two points in the chart is the growth
rate. The chart indicates that the projected surpluses

1. Evans (1997) provides a good introduction to the terminology and concepts of the budget.
2. The transition quarter in 1976 is excluded.
3. Additional adjustments, not necessary for this article, would improve the deficit as a measure of the change in indebtedness
of the federal government (Dwyer 1982; Eisner 1986, chap. 2; Kotlikoff 1992; Penner 1982; Webb 1991).
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

43

C H A R T 1 The Federal Government Unified Budget Surplus

Billions of 1992 Dollars

100

0

–100

–200

–300
1950

1960

1980

1970

1990

2000

F i s c a l Ye a r

Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions.
Sources: OMB (1998b, 23–24, table 1.3); CBO (1998a, table 2); recession dates from the National Bureau of Economic Research

result from a higher projected growth rate for revenue
than for spending.
It would be easy to place too much reliance on the
projected budget surpluses in Charts 1 and 2. As already
mentioned, the projections rely on the absence of a recession. In addition, federal government laws affecting spending are not likely to stay the same. Even without these
possibilities, ten years is a long time in terms of achieving
any reliability in budget projections; the Congressional
Budget Office calls the figures projections rather than
forecasts to make the tentative nature of the numbers
clear (CBO 1998a, chap. 1). Budget projections are subject to large changes. In January 1997 the CBO’s forecast
of the 1997 fiscal-year deficit was $100 billion too large
(CBO 1998a, chap. 2). Fiscal year 1998 illustrates the difficulties again. In February 1998 the CBO forecast that
the federal government would run a budget deficit of $5
billion in the fiscal year ending September 1998 (CBO
1998a, chap. 2). By May this deficit projection became a
projected surplus of $43 billion to $63 billion, a change of
$48 billion to $68 billion in the deficit projection for the
fiscal year in progress (CBO 1998c). By July the projection was that the surplus would be “near the upper end of
this range” (CBO 1998d).
While a ten-year period is long for reliable forecasts,
it can be short for evaluating the long-run state of the
budget. The projection of surpluses until 2008 shown in
Charts 1 and 2 masks important concerns over longer
periods. Most importantly, the trust funds for Social
Security are projected to have a surplus of about $93 billion in fiscal year 1998 but are projected to begin running
44

deficits by 2006 to 2018 (Social Security Administration
1998, 25). Partly because of the Social Security trust
funds, the CBO also projects that the unified budget will
swing from surpluses to persistent, increasing deficits by
2020 (CBO 1998b).
The next section of the article examines trends in
federal government spending and revenues and taxes and
discusses the implications of current policies for future
spending and tax policies.

Federal Government Spending and Receipts
pending. Federal government spending (also
called outlays) is the sum of the amounts spent on
goods and services and transfer payments plus net
interest paid on outstanding federal debt. These parts of
spending can have quite different effects on the economy.
Government Purchases. Government purchases are
purchases by the government of newly produced goods
and services; they represent withdrawals of resources
from the economy that are used by the government for its
activities rather than by private individuals for private
purposes. Government purchases cover a wide range of
goods, from airplanes and computers to pencils. They
also include earnings received by government employees.
When the government buys a computer, the value of the
good is reflected in its price. Government employees’
earnings also reflect the value of resources withdrawn
from the economy if the employees’ earnings are equal to
their opportunity cost and that opportunity cost equals
the value of goods or services the employees would have
produced in private employment. Thus, government em-

S

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

C H A R T 2 Federal Government Spending and Taxes

Billions of 1992 Dollars

2000

Outlays
Receipts
900
700
500
300

100
1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

F i s c a l Ye a r

Note: Shaded areas indicate recessions.
Sources: OMB (1998b, 23–24, table 1.3); CBO (1998a, table 2)

ployees’ earnings is a reasonable measure of the value of
forgone private goods and services.4 Based on this supposition, government purchases equal the value of payments
made by the government for goods and services currently
produced. The government uses the goods and services
purchased as well as government employees’ services to
provide services such as defense, education, and police
protection that can provide benefits to the economy.5
Transfer Payments. Transfer payments, unlike purchases, are not payments for goods currently produced
or services currently rendered. Instead, transfer payments redirect income from one person to another via
the government. Transfer payments include payments
made to recipients in programs such as Aid to Families
with Dependent Children, Medicaid, unemployment
insurance, and Social Security. Perhaps less obviously,
transfer payments also include pension payments to
retired government employees, both civilian and military. These payments are, after all, for services rendered
in the past, not services currently provided.
Net Interest Payments. Net interest paid is interest
paid by the federal government less interest received.
Net interest payments by the government, like transfer
payments, also are not for goods and services that could
have been used directly to produce other goods and ser-

vices during the current period. Interest payments are
made to the holders of government securities—those
who lend funds by purchasing these securities. Unlike
many other categories of spending, net interest payments
are not under the federal government’s immediate control, at least short of default. Net interest payments are a
function of conditions that are largely determined by the
federal government’s past actions: the size of the outstanding debt issued in earlier years and the interest
rate on that debt when issued.
Interest payments on outstanding federal government debt are sometimes viewed as a pernicious result of
government deficits. Interest payments finance past
spending that was financed by issuing debt rather than
raising taxes. The payment of interest to service the current debt has led some observers (for example, Stein
1998) to suggest that current and prospective surpluses be
used to retire outstanding federal government debt. From
one point of view, it is always preferable that interest payments be lower. Current taxpayers would prefer to pay
lower taxes, other factors being equal, and they could pay
lower taxes if it were possible to have lower interest payments and keep everything else the same. In general,
though, it is not possible to have everything else the same.
For example, if the government had spent less in the past

4. This supposition is not always a good one. When there was a military draft in the United States, the wages paid were not sufficient to induce people to join the military, so people were drafted.
5. Purchases are not the only way the federal government affects the allocation of resources in the economy. Legal requirements
and regulations do not appear in the budget but also affect the economy.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

45

C H A R T 3 Federal Government Spending as a Percentage of GDP

25

Percent of GDP

20

Transfer Payments
15

Other
10

Net Interest Paid

Purchases
5

0
1950

1960

1980

1970

1990

2000

F i s c a l Ye a r

Source: OMB (1998b, 262–64, table 14.1)

on highways, there would be fewer highways today and
transportation costs would be higher. More generally,
interest payments can be the result of past spending that
provides current benefits, an arrangement that has the
potential to make everyone better off. Interest on government debt is the price paid for postponing payment, just as
for private interest payments, and interest payments similarly can reflect optimal or improvident behavior.
Chart 3 shows the trend of federal government
spending relative to GDP since 1950. The chart breaks
spending into four broad components: purchases, transfer payments, net interest payments, and other. The
residual category denoted other includes grants to state
and local governments and subsidies less surpluses of
federal government enterprises.6 The chart indicates a
number of important developments during the past several decades. The most obvious development is the
increase in federal government spending relative to
GDP. In 1950, total spending was about 18 percent of
GDP; in 1997 it was 22 percent of GDP.7 Another development is a decline in the ratio of spending to GDP
since the early 1980s. In 1983 spending was over 23 percent of GDP, higher than in any fiscal year since 1950.
Chart 3 also shows that the distribution of spending has changed over time. During the 1950s transfer
payments accounted for a relatively small proportion of
spending. For example, in 1951, transfer payments were
3.5 percent of GDP. Transfer payments increased in
importance in the 1960s and 1970s, and by 1997 transfer
payments accounted for about 9.9 percent of GDP. This
growth of transfer payments understates the change in
domestic transfer payments. Foreign aid, or transfers to
46

foreigners, was 1 percentage point of GDP in 1951 and 0.2
percentage points in 1997. Domestic transfer payments
almost quadrupled during that period, from 2.5 percent
of GDP in 1951 to 9.7 percent in 1997. This shift in spending from purchases to domestic transfer payments indicates that the government is now withdrawing fewer
resources from the economy than in the past and is redistributing more income.
Receipts. Federal government receipts primarily
are taxes, which fund most of the government’s spending. Descriptions of the sources of taxes often characterize them according to who writes the check for the tax.
Common lists include individual income taxes, corporate
income taxes, excise taxes, and social insurance payroll
taxes. While such a division may be useful for some purposes, it is misleading for determining where the final tax
burden lies. First, corporations do not pay taxes; people,
whether they are shareholders, employees, or customers,
do. Second, whether shareholders, employees, or customers ultimately bear the burden of a tax depends on
the tax’s effects on the prices paid and received and
incomes of shareholders, employees, and customers. The
burden of the tax is not necessarily, or even in general,
borne by whoever has the legal liability for writing a
check to the government.
Chart 4 shows total taxes as a percentage of GDP
since 1950.8 The federal government’s tax receipts increase substantially, from 14 percent of GDP in 1950 to 20
percent in 1997. Chart 4 also indicates the composition of
receipts. Income and profit taxes are the largest portion—about 66 percent of total tax receipts in 1950 and
about 57 percent in 1997.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

C H A R T 4 Federal Government Taxes as a Percentage of GDP

25

Percent of GDP

20

Social Insurance Taxes
15

Indirect Business Tax and
Nontax Accruals

10

Income and Profit Taxes
5

0
1950

1960

1980

1970

1990

2000

F i s c a l Ye a r

Source: OMB (1998b, 262–64, table 14.1)

Relative to GDP, social insurance taxes are noticeably
higher in 1997 than in 1950. Sometimes called “contributions” instead of taxes because the individuals making the
payments become entitled to certain benefits, these taxes
generally are mandatory, not optional. In 1950 social insurance taxes were about 2 percent of GDP and 14 percent of
federal government receipts; in 1997 they were about 8 percent of GDP and 39 percent of federal government receipts.
The increase in this component is largely due to increases
in receipts from Social Security and Medicare taxes.
This growth in Social Security tax receipts has come
about primarily through increases in underlying tax rates.
Measuring tax receipts relative to GDP removes the effect
of general increases in income. The Social Security taxes
paid are determined partly by the tax rate and the income
subject to the tax, generally labor income (or earnings).
In addition, there is a maximum level of earnings subject
to the tax for Old Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance
(OASDI). There is no limit on earnings subject to the tax
for Medicare (Hospitalization Insurance, or HI). The first
payment in 1937 of Social Security taxes was quite small
compared with payments in later years. When introduced,
the total Social Security tax rate was 2 percent of earn-

ings up to $3,000. In 1998 the total Social Security tax rate
includes an OASDI tax rate of 12.4 percent payable on
earnings up to $68,400 and an HI tax rate of 2.9 percent
on all earnings.
Chart 5 shows the combined tax rate for OASDI and
HI and the maximum income subject to the OASDI tax
from 1937 through 1997. The tax rate includes both
employees’ and employers’ contributions. Other than the
legal distribution of tax liability, the only difference
between the employers’ and employees’ share of the tax
is whether the tax is included in employees’ gross pay. If
all Social Security taxes were paid by either employers or
employees, the before-tax wage paid by employers, the
after-tax wage received by employees, and the level of
employment would be the same.9
The adjustment of earnings for inflation is important. From the inception of Social Security until 1951,
the maximum amount of earnings subject to tax was
$3,000, which is less than one-twentieth of the maximum
earnings of $68,400 subject to OASDI tax in 1998. When
adjusted for changes in the level of prices, however, the
difference in taxable earnings is not even the same order
of magnitude. The consumer price index was about 11.1

6. This category also includes wage disbursements less accruals, an item that was 0.1 percent of GDP in 1950 and 1996.
7. These figures include only the federal government; including all governments—federal, state, and local—magnifies the size
of the increase.
8. These numbers do not include revenues from providing goods and services, such as selling electricity or admitting people
into national parks. If state and local government receipts from taxes were included, government receipts would be 21 percent of GDP in 1950 and 30 percent in 1997 (OMB 1998a, 270, table 15.3).
9. This observation assumes that other tax rates would be adjusted to reflect the change in income subject to those taxes.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

47

C H A R T 5 Social Security and Taxable Earnings

16
1997
14

1990
1980

Total Tax Rate

12
1975
10

1970

8
6

1960

4
1950
2

1937

0
10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

60,000

Maximum OASDI Taxable Ear nings (1992 dollars)

Source: Social Security Administration (1998, table II.B1)

times higher in 1997 than in 1937. Hence, the $3,000 subject to OASDI tax in 1937 would buy about the same
amount as $33,600 in 1998. Still, with the maximum
amount of earnings subject to Social Security tax in 1998
at over $68,000, the amount adjusted for inflation is twice
what it was in 1937, not twenty times larger.
Chart 5 shows that the tax rate for Social Security
has risen substantially since the program’s inception. The
rate was 15.3 percent in 1997, quite a bit higher than the
2 percent rate in 1937.
Such tax increases affect economic decisions and
behavior. Consider a change in the Social Security tax
rate on earnings. If other factors remain the same, an
increase in the marginal tax rate on earnings lowers the
private marginal return from activities that generate
labor income, resulting in fewer hours worked and less
output produced in the economy.
Social Security taxes are not unique in affecting private behavior. Virtually all, if not all, taxes and transfer
payments change relative prices and consequently the
decisions people make. Income taxes lower the marginal
return from generating income. Transfer payments generally have implicit tax rates. Qualifying for a transfer payment generally depends on a person’s income and assets.
A higher income often reduces the size of the transfer
payment, with the loss offsetting part of the increase in
income, but the after-transfer change in income is less
than the gross change in income.
Perhaps obviously, it does not follow that, because
tax rates change people’s behavior, there should be no
taxes. Tax effects such as reductions in the quantity of
labor supplied represent an excess burden of taxes—a
48

cost of government actions that should be considered
when making choices about the government’s activities.

Fiscal Policy Now and in the Future
s there a federal government surplus that somehow
must be distributed? In one sense, the answer is yes.
At a broad level, the government’s unified budget is
nothing more than a cash-flow identity that can be written

I

surplus = tax – pur – tr – int
or
deficit = pur + tr + int – tax,
where tax is government tax receipts, pur is government
purchases, tr is transfer payments, and int is net interest
payments. The deficit approximately equals the amount of
additional debt issued by the Treasury. During 1998, it has
become apparent that the federal government has an unexpected surplus, at least partly because of unexpectedly
higher tax receipts. Something must happen with these
higher receipts: they cannot disappear into a void. Either
taxes will be decreased; government spending, interest
payments, or transfer payments will be increased; or the
federal government will reduce its outstanding debt.
Does the current federal government surplus signal the onset of a new age in government fiscal policy,
as Herbert Stein suggested? The answer to this question
is not just a matter of arithmetic and is not so obvious.
There are developments in the budget that throw
cold water on euphoria about a surplus, whether due to
lower federal government spending or higher taxes. In
particular, the Social Security trust fund (OASDI plus HI)

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

T A B L E 1 Projected Unified Budget Surpluses and Trust Fund Surpluses

Surplus in Fiscal Year (billions of dollars)
Actual
1997

Projected
1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Unified Budget

–22

8

9

1

13

67

53

Trust Funds

126

149

171

173

177

201

202

Note: The unified budget projections are the CBO’s projections issued in March 1998. The projections for the trust funds are from
the budget proposed for fiscal year 1999 in January 1998 by the OMB (1998a) and therefore reflect any pertinent budget
proposals.
Sources: Unified budget surplus projections from CBO (1998e, table 1); trust fund surpluses from OMB (1998a, 323).

has a projected surplus of about $93 billion in fiscal year
1998, which is greater than any estimate of the surplus in
the unified budget. If Social Security were removed from
the unified budget and no other changes were made, the
federal government’s budget would have a deficit on the
order of $25 billion to $45 billion for fiscal year 1998.
While small by recent standards, this deficit has rather
different connotations than a budget surplus.
The federal government’s unified budget includes
current federal government activities and the receipts
and expenditures of various dedicated funds established
by legislation. Social Security’s trust funds are the most
prominent, but there are others that are nearly as large.
Table 1 shows the overall surplus for the trust funds for
fiscal years 1997 to 2003 along with corresponding estimates of the federal government’s unified surplus.
Overall, the trust funds are running surpluses and, consequently, accumulating nonmarketable federal government debt.10 If the trust funds were not accumulating
federal government debt and other taxes and spending
were the same, deficits instead of surpluses would be
projected for the federal government for these years.
The current Social Security surplus is not accidental:
it is an expected result of changes in taxes in 1983 to
cover future Social Security spending. The Social Security
trust funds are accumulating nonmarketable Treasury
securities in anticipation of increases in spending. When
the projected increases in Social Security spending occur,
the trust fund will exchange the securities with the
Treasury for funds to pay for the increases. If federal government spending other than interest payments and taxes
is unaffected, the Treasury then will issue debt to the pub-

lic to acquire the funds to finance the higher spending. In
sum, the current budget surplus reflects taxes paid now to
finance expected increases in future spending.
Why might it be desirable to have the Social Security
trust funds run surpluses now? A common justification is
to tax people now who will receive benefits in the future.
The fact that Social Security is designed partly to redistribute income limits the force of this argument.
An arguably more important reason to run surpluses is to smooth tax rates over time. If Social Security
spending now and in the future remains unchanged, the
only issue is when—not whether—taxes will be paid to
finance the spending. Lowering taxes today implies raising taxes in the future, and, conversely, raising taxes
today implies lowering taxes in the future. In short, pay
now or pay later, but pay you will.
If Social Security spending were unchanged and
Social Security tax rates were lower now, tax rates would
have to be increased in the future from their current
level. Lower tax rates now would lower the excess burden
of the tax today at the cost of an increase in the excess
burden in the future. Higher tax rates would increase the
excess burden of the tax more in the future than it would
decrease the burden today if, as is likely, the excess burden increases more at higher tax rates. Hence, higher tax
rates today can be interpreted at least partly as an attempt to smooth the excess tax burden.
The CBO’s projections of ten years of unified budget
surpluses actually mask longer-term difficulties concerning the federal government’s budget and Social Security.
Even though Social Security is projected to have a surplus
of about $93 billion in fiscal year 1998, Social Security

10. Nonmarketable securities are issued by the federal government but never sold to the public, to outside agencies, or in secondary markets. In effect, these securities represent funds borrowed and lent between different parts of the federal government. The Treasury borrows from trust funds when the latter run surpluses and uses these funds to replace borrowing from
the public. Evans (1997, chap. 7) and the OMB (1998a, sec. 17) provide more detailed analyses.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

49

spending is projected to exceed receipts by about 2012,
and the trust fund is projected to be depleted by about
2032 (Social Security Administration 1998, 25). Obviously, projected depletion in precisely 2032 is subject to
substantial uncertainty: any projection of what might
happen decades from now based on current policies is
fraught with peril.11 Ten years of surpluses do not resolve
these future problems (Social Security Administration
1998; CBO 1998b). As a recent CBO analysis states, “fundamental long-term budgetary problems will remain.
Eventually the federal debt and deficit will start to rise as
a result of pressures on the budget from Social Security,
Medicare, Medicaid, and other programs that serve the
elderly” (CBO 1998b, 1). Without a policy change, the
CBO projects that the federal government’s unified
deficit would increase to 10 percent of GDP by the year
2040 (CBO 1998b, chap. 2). This situation hardly resembles financial well-being, and, indeed, changes in Social
Security—whether cutting benefits, raising taxes, or privatizing Social Security—are quite likely.

Conclusion
hether or not the projected federal government
budget surplus for fiscal year 1998 is desirable,
it is not a panacea. The projected budget surpluses in 1998 and succeeding years are based on projections of slower growth in federal government spending
than in receipts. These surpluses have generated calls to
decrease taxes, increase expenditures, or retire federal
government debt. Actually, the surpluses can be interpreted as largely reflecting taxes paid now to finance
expected increases in spending in the future, in particular on Social Security.
More generally, a budget surplus or deficit is not an
adequate summary of how federal government spending
and taxes affect the economy. A surplus or deficit is a
result of choices concerning spending and taxation,
choices that have substantial implications for the allocation of resources in the economy. Any analysis of fiscal
policy that neglects spending, taxes, and tax rates is woefully deficient.

W

11. As Cogan (1998) points out, even assuming that the surplus will result in a reserve is inconsistent with the federal government’s past behavior.

50

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

REFERENCES
COGAN, JOHN F. 1998. “Social Security Surpluses Never Last.”
Wall Street Journal, July 31, sec. A.

KOTLIKOFF, LAURENCE J. 1992. Generational Accounting:
Knowing Who Pays, and When, for What We Spend.
New York: Free Press.

CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE. 1998a. The Economic and
Budget Outlook: Fiscal Year 1999–2008. Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office. January.
———. 1998b. Long-Term Budgetary Pressures and Policy
Options. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office. May.
———. 1998c. Monthly Budget Review: Fiscal Year 1998,
May 6, 1998. Available on-line at <www.cbo.gov/showdoc.
cfm?index=469&sequence=0&from=1> [July 13, 1998].

OFFICE OF MANAGEMENT AND BUDGET. 1998a. Budget of the
United States Government, Fiscal Year 1999, Analytical
Perspectives. Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.
———. 1998b. Budget of the United States Government,
Fiscal Year 1999, Historical Tables. Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office.
PENNER, RUDOLPH G. 1982. “How Much Is Owed by the Federal
Government?” In Monetary Regimes and Protectionism, edited by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer. Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 16. Amsterdam:
North-Holland Publishing Company.

———. 1998d. Monthly Budget Review: Fiscal Year 1998,
July 9, 1998. Available on-line at <www.cbo.gov/showdoc.
cfm?index=648&sequence=0&from=7> [July 13, 1998].
———. 1998e. Revised Baseline Budget Projections for
Fiscal Years 1999–2008, March 3, 1998. Available on-line
at <http://www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=356&from=
4&sequence=0> [July 13, 1998].

SEATER, JOHN J. 1993. “Ricardian Equivalence.” Journal of
Economic Literature 31 (March): 142–90.
SOCIAL SECURITY ADMINISTRATION. 1998. 1998 Annual Report
of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors
Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds.
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.

DWYER, GERALD P., JR. 1982. “Is Inflation a Consequence of
Government Deficits?” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Economic Review 67 (August): 25–32.

STEIN, HERBERT. 1998. “At Sea with Surpluses.” Wall Street
Journal, May 19, sec. A.

EISNER, ROBERT. 1986. How Real Is the Federal Deficit?
New York: Free Press.
EVANS, GARY R. 1997. Red Ink: The Budget, Deficit, and Debt of
the U.S. Government. San Diego: Academic Press.

WEBB, ROY H. 1991. “The Stealth Budget: Unfunded Liabilities
of the Federal Government.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Review 77 (May/June): 23–33.

FRIEDMAN, BENJAMIN M. 1988. The Day of Reckoning: The
Consequences of American Economic Policy under Reagan
and After. New York: Random House.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Third Quarter 1998

51